Michael Wallerstein’s research while affiliated with University of New Haven and other places

What is this page?


This page lists works of an author who doesn't have a ResearchGate profile or hasn't added the works to their profile yet. It is automatically generated from public (personal) data to further our legitimate goal of comprehensive and accurate scientific recordkeeping. If you are this author and want this page removed, please let us know.

Publications (70)


Union Organization in Advanced Industrial Democracies
  • Article

June 1989

·

18 Reads

·

129 Citations

American Political Science Association

Michael Wallerstein

Few features of economic, social, or political life in industrialized democracies differ as much as the relative size of the trade union movement. The current density of union membership in the labor force ranges over almost the entire spectrum from above 90% in Sweden to under 20% in the United States (Goldfield 1987, 16). The level of unionization varies far more than such other characteristics of the labor force as the sectoral distribution of workers, the share of wages in GNP, rates of unemployment, or even the size of the public sector. Unionization rates vary more than such other forms of popular mobilization as electoral turnout or the share of the vote received by parties bearing communist, socialist, social democratic, or labor labels. The economic effects of high levels of unionization are ambiguous. Unions that are large relative to the economy may simultaneously have more power in the labor market and more of an incentive to moderate their wage demands. A union that covers only a small fraction of an industry’s work force, for example, can gain wage increases partly at the expense of employment among nonunion members, provided that union members have specialized skills not readily available elsewhere. In contrast, an industrial union covering the entire work force would be concerned with employment in all job categories. Bigger unions are not necessarily more militant unions (Cameron 1984; Olson 1982, chap. 4).


The Structural Dependence of the State on Capital

March 1988

·

211 Reads

·

460 Citations

American Political Science Association

A central claim of both Marxist and neoclassical political theory is that under capitalism all governments must respect and protect the essential claims of those who own the productive wealth of society. This is the theory of “structural dependence of the state on capital.” Using a formal model, the internal logic and the robustness of the theory is examined. We conclude that in a static sense the theory is false: virtually any distribution of consumption between wage earners and owners of capital is compatible with continual private investment once an appropriate set of taxes and transfers is in place. Yet the state may be structurally dependent in a dynamic sense. Policies that, once in place, redistribute income without reducing investment do reduce investment during the period in which they are anticipated but not yet implemented.


Unemployment, Collective Bargaining, and the Demand for Protection

November 1987

·

17 Reads

·

49 Citations

American Journal of Political Science

There is a widespread consensus among nonacademic observers that labor unions with large numbers of unemployed members have been central actors in political coalitions demanding protectionist trade policies since the mid-1970s in advanced industrial societies. Yet trade unions and unemployment are hardly mentioned in most theories of the politics of international trade. The purpose of this paper is to develop a theoretical framework for understanding the importance of unemployment as a determinant of protectionist demands that is consistent with optimizing behavior on the part of union members and firms. Models of labor negotiations derived from cooperative bargaining theory are used to illustrate why the material benefits of protection received by union members and their employers in protected industries increase when union members are unemployed, even when workers are risk neutral and capital is immobile.



The Structure of Class Conflict in Democratic Capitalist Societies

June 1982

·

8 Reads

·

64 Citations

American Political Science Association

The article presents a theory of class conflict between workers and capitalists who pursue their material interests under a form of societal organization that combines private ownership of instruments of production with representative political institutions. There exist economic and political conditions under which both classes would simultaneously choose courses of action that constitute a class compromise: workers consent to the institution of profit and capitalists to democratic institutions through which workers can effectively press claims for material gains. When these conditions hold and a compromise is in force, the role of the state consists in institutionalizing, coordinating, and enforcing the terms of a compromise that represents the preferences of workers as well as capitalists.


The Structure of Class Conflict in Democratic Capitalist Societies

June 1982

·

58 Reads

·

178 Citations

American Political Science Association

The article presents a theory of class conflict between workers and capitalists who pursue their material interests under a form of societal organization that combines private ownership of instruments of production with representative political institutions. There exist economic and political conditions under which both classes would simultaneously choose courses of action that constitute a class compromise: workers consent to the institution of profit and capitalists to democratic institutions through which workers can effectively press claims for material gains. When these conditions hold and a compromise is in force, the role of the state consists in institutionalizing, coordinating, and enforcing the terms of a compromise that represents the preferences of workers as well as capitalists.


Unions, Employers Associations, and Wage-Setting Institutions in North and Central Europe, 1950-1992

22 Reads

·

32 Citations

The increase of tourist activity for many destinations and their increased mobility within host countries has implied a rise in tourism associated externalities with vehicle crashes being the most common cause of injury for tourists. Within the transport literature, the number and variations in the amount of accidents has been related to a large set of determining variables, including weather conditions, socio-economic characteristics, exposure, physical characteristics of the road and a variety of dummies which try to capture effects such as safety laws and seasonal variations. However, the presence of tourism has been neglected. Using the case study of the Balearic Islands, the present study estimates the role of tourism in determining the number of accidents on a daily context, using the set of variables suggested by the literature and incorporating a daily measure for the stock of tourists at a host destination. Results show how tourism can be associated to a significant amount of the accidents that take place in the Balearics.


Figure 1: Inequality (90/10 ratio) in Nine Countries (1980-2000)
Table 1 : The Causes of Growing Pay Inequality in the 1980s Dependent variable: The growth in pay inequality
Figure 2: Shares of Industrial and Tertiary Employment in 16 Countries (1980-2000)
Table 2 : Summary of the impact of the controls in the 1980s Dependent variable: The growth in pay inequality
Figure 3: Total Trade and Trade with LDCs as Percent of GDP for 16 Countries (1980-2000)

+5

Domestic and International Causes for the Rise of Pay Inequality: Post-Industrialism, Globalization and Labor Market Institutions
  • Article
  • Full-text available

1,078 Reads

·

8 Citations

Download



Citations (52)


... Derudover er Tyskland udvalgt som repraesentant for et større ikke-nordisk land. Selv om Tyskland med sin føderale struktur adskiller sig fra de nordiske lande, så deler Tyskland og Danmark også en raekke karakteristika (Ganghof og Bräuninger, 2006: 527), herunder en lang tradition for en korporativ organisering af arbejdsmarkedet (Lange, Wallerstein og Golden, 1995;Toens, 2008;Ilsøe, 2017). Tyskland er desuden udvalgt som repraesentant for et europaeisk land, der siden 1951 har reguleret lobbyisme på forskellig vis -også selv om reguleringen betragtes som svag (Ronit og Schneider, 1998). ...

Reference:

Mark Blach-Ørsten og Eva Mayerhöffer Skal svingdørslobbyisme i Danmark reguleres?
The End of Corporatism? Wage Setting in the Nordic and Germanic Countries
  • Citing Article
  • April 1995

... The literature on this subject has revealed two strands of research in these subject matter. The first strand, based on the fiscal theory of income distribution, argues that fiscal policy through government expenditure is detrimental to income inequality (Moene and Wallerstein, 2003;Samanta & Cerf, 2009;Bhatti et al., 2015;Aye and Odhiambo. 2022;Abramovsky and Selwaness, 2023;Gunasinghe et al., 2020;Smith, 2024;Kebalo & Zouri, 2024). ...

EARNINGS INEQUALITY AND WELFARE SPENDING: A DISAGGREGATED ANALYSIS
  • Citing Chapter
  • March 2008

... Taxes are compulsory and forceful levies for individuals and companies that are paid to the state in accordance with law number 16 of 2009. The general rules of taxation explain that tax rewards cannot be felt directly but for the welfare of society (Fitriandi et al., 2010;Reybold, 2009;Wallerstein & Przeworski, 2008). Therefore, one of the largest sources of state revenue is taxes (Hayati, 2019;Kusumo et al., 2022;Lidya Rikayana et al., 2023;Priyogo & Nasrudin, 2023). ...

CAPITAL TAXATION WITH OPEN BORDERS
  • Citing Chapter
  • March 2008

... Finally, we explore the impact of bargaining structure. The corporatist literature reviewed above suggests that unions in more coordinated or centralised bargaining structures (Golden et al. 1999;Soskice 1990) are more likely to internalise the negative externalities of wage militancy. If unions' preferences are reflective of the preferences of workers, these corporatist institutions should be associated with lower levels of individual wage dissatisfaction. ...

Postwar Trade-Union Organization and Industrial Relations in Twelve Countries
  • Citing Chapter
  • January 1999

... According to Rojas (1991) and Esping-Andersen (1990), this model preserves the rights to capitalist accumulation while implementing centralized bargaining of wages, creating a balance that supports economic stability and growth. Moene and Wallerstein (2003) and Moene (2003) further explain that this Nordic model harmoniously combines wage compression with a "socially acceptable" high return on capital. This distinctive arrangement results in a notably low inequality of earnings, as highlighted by Fochesato and Bowles (2015), yet it paradoxically coexists with high wealth inequality, as documented by Davies et al. (2012). ...

Social Democracy as a Development Strategy
  • Citing Chapter
  • October 2020

... According to the OECD (2011), technological change and globalization do not alone explain the higher levels of income inequality. Scholars have extensively studied voters' preferences for income redistribution (Alesina, Giuliano, Bisin, & Benhabib, 2011;Barnes, 2015;Beramendi & Rehm, 2016;Gingrich & Ansell, 2012), the role of labour market institutions (Moene & Wallerstein, 1999;Western & Rosenfeld, 2011), as well as party ideology and party competition (Alt & Iversen, 2017;Gingrich & Häusermann, 2015;Iversen & Soskice, 2006, 2015Korpi & Palme, 2003;Roemer, 2005). Income distribution is the outcome of a complex process broken down to multiple interactions between personal income, income and employment risk, the progressivity of the tax and welfare state and party competition, which itself is affected directly by the electoral system. ...

Social Democratic Labor Market Institutions: A Retrospective Analysis
  • Citing Chapter
  • January 1999

... Our conclusion does not depend on the assumption of a linear production function. Auerbach (1983) and Przeworski and Wallerstein (1985) present models of investment-neutral taxes on profits using the standard production function with diminishing returns to investment. Nor is our conclusion restricted to the case of logarithmic utility functions. ...

Comment on Katz, Mahler, & Franz (Vol. 77, December 1983, pp. 871-886)
  • Citing Article
  • June 1985

American Political Science Association

... On the other hand, changes in tax progressivity have minor and often insignificant effects, suggesting that indirect behavioral responses play a more substantial role when it comes to tax progressivity. These findings imply that governments aiming to reduce inequality should emphasize increasing social expenditure rather than solely relying on enhancing the progressivity of income taxes.Furthermore,Moene & Wallerstein (2001) explored the relationship between political support for welfare policy and income inequality, utilizing a model conceptualizing welfare policy as publicly-funded insurance with redistributive benefits. They found that the impact of inequality on support for welfare expenditures is contingent upon how benefits are targeted. ...

Inequality, Social Insurance, and Redistribution
  • Citing Article
  • December 2001

American Political Science Association

... First, the empirical evidence provided by these models is inconclusive. While several studies find that income and employment improve with globalization in LDCs (Ghose, 2000;Brunner, 2003), others determine that globalization actually worsens workers' economic position. The latter studies arrive at their conclusion by additionally considering the possible countervailing effects of structural conditions, that is, high surplus labor, lack of access to new technology, and rising global demands for skilled labor rather than low-skilled labor. ...

Postwar trade-union organization and industrial relations in twelve countries
  • Citing Chapter
  • March 2008