January 2024
SSRN Electronic Journal
This page lists works of an author who doesn't have a ResearchGate profile or hasn't added the works to their profile yet. It is automatically generated from public (personal) data to further our legitimate goal of comprehensive and accurate scientific recordkeeping. If you are this author and want this page removed, please let us know.
January 2024
SSRN Electronic Journal
January 2024
SSRN Electronic Journal
January 2023
·
9 Reads
SSRN Electronic Journal
January 2023
·
1 Read
·
1 Citation
SSRN Electronic Journal
January 2022
·
1 Read
·
4 Citations
SSRN Electronic Journal
January 2020
·
19 Reads
·
10 Citations
SSRN Electronic Journal
October 2019
·
3,115 Reads
·
12 Citations
The Big Tech companies, including Google, Facebook, Amazon, Microsoft and Apple, have individually and collectively engaged in an unprecedented number of acquisitions. When a dominant firm purchases a start-up that could be a future entrant and thereby increase competitive rivalry, it raises a potential competition issue. Unfortunately, the antitrust law of potential competition mergers is ill-equipped to address tech mergers. We contend that the Chicago School’s assumptions and policy prescriptions hobbled antitrust law and policy on potential competition mergers. We illustrate this problem with the example of Facebook. Facebook has engaged in 90 completed acquisitions in its short history (documented in the Appendix to this paper). Many antitrust commentators have focused on the Instagram and WhatsApp acquisitions as cases of mergers that have reduced potential competition. We show the impotence of the potential competition doctrine applied to these two acquisitions. We suggest that the remedy for Chicago School damage to the potential competition doctrine is a return to an empirically tractable structural approach to potential competition mergers.
September 2019
·
20 Reads
·
2 Citations
The Antitrust Bulletin
Since the publication of Robert Bork’s The Antitrust Paradox, lawyers, judges, and many economists have defended “consumer welfare” (CW) as a standard for decisions about antitrust goals and enforcement priorities. This article argues that the CW is actually an empty concept and is an inappropriate goal for antitrust. Judge Bork adopted CW from economics where welfare unambiguously measured utility or well-being. Welfare economists concede that there is no credible measurable link between price and output and human well-being. This means that the concept of CW does not legitimate limited antitrust enforcement nor does it justify the exclusion of other antitrust goals that require more active enforcement practices. This article contends that antitrust policy is not welfare based at all and, that if it were, antitrust policy and enforcement would differ significantly from the Chicago School vision. Without the fiction that economists can establish that in the short run lower price and higher output measurably increase welfare more than other goals, recent defenses of the CW standard resolve down to arguments based on unsupported assumptions.
September 2019
·
19 Reads
·
21 Citations
The Antitrust Bulletin
This article presents an historical analysis of the antitrust laws. Its central contention is that the history of antitrust can only be understood in light of U.S. economic history and the succession of dominant economic policy regimes that punctuated that history. The antitrust laws and a subset of other related policies have historically focused on the negative consequences resulting from the rise, expansion, and dominance of big business. Antitrust specifically uses competition as its tool to address these problems. The article traces the evolution of the emergence, growth, and expansion of big business over six economic eras: the Gilded Age, the Progressive Era, the New Deal, the post–World War II Era, the 1970s, and the era of neoliberalism. It considers three policy regimes: laissez-faire during the Gilded Age and the Progressive Era, the New Deal, policy regime from the Depression through the early 1970s, and the neoliberal policy regime that dominates today and includes the Chicago School of antitrust. The principal conclusion of the article is that the activist antitrust associated with the New Deal that existed from the late 1930s to the 1960s resulted in far stronger economic performance than have the policies of the Chicago School that have dominated antitrust policy since the 1980s.
July 2019
·
36 Reads
·
1 Citation
Since the publication of Robert Bork’s The Antitrust Paradox, lawyers, judges, and many economists have defended “Consumer welfare” (CW) as a standard for decisions about antitrust goals and enforcement priorities. This paper argues that the CW is actually an empty concept and is an inappropriate goal for antitrust. Welfare economists concede that there is no credible measurable link between price and output and human well-being. This means that the concept of CW does not legitimate limited antitrust enforcement, nor does it justify the exclusion of other antitrust goals that require more active enforcement practices. This paper contends that antitrust policy is not welfare based at all, and that if it were, antitrust policy and enforcement would differ significantly from the Chicago School vision. Without the fiction that economists can establish that in the short run lower price and higher output measurably increases welfare more than other goals, recent defenses of the CW standard resolve down to arguments based on unsupported assumptions.
... The company has access to the best researchers, including great talents such as Demis Hassabis, Shane Legg, and Mustafa Suleyman. One benefit of accessing great talent and innovation is that Google significantly reduced energy consumption [6]. The element led to reduced costs and thus improved revenues. ...
January 2020
SSRN Electronic Journal
... Besides, in the tradition of Chicago Schools the real concern in terms of acquisitions emerges when the operation ends up in a monopoly. Otherwise, the merger becomes a efficiency increasing operation (Glick and Ruetschlin, 2019;Anderson and Purnell, 2023). ...
October 2019
... (p. 132) Lastly, it should be noted that Bork's interpretation of this criterion prevents any sanction of undue transfers of welfare compared with a 44 However, these two criteria are challenged on their theoretical grounds by welfare economists (Glick, 2019b hypothetical situation of perfect competition (i.e., if the firms were price-takers) and does not protect the competitive process itself. Therefore, it departs significantly from the decisional practice of us antitrust until the 1970s and the ordoliberal foundations of European competition policy. ...
July 2019
... Footnote 14 (continued) addressed to GAFAM corporations which receive favorable tax regimes and lax antitrust policies (Rikap and Lundvall 2021; see also Glick 2019;Kahn 2017) and which also benefit from "colossal public investments in R&D and the strengthening and broadening of Intellectual Property Rights (IPRs) 17 " (Rikap and Lundvall 2021, p. 10). This means that the regulation activity itself is involved in the multi-agent process in which the capitalist, since he possesses the means to preserve the collective and public interest, uses them as a bargaining chip to regulate himself. ...
September 2019
The Antitrust Bulletin
... Une part de la littérature interroge la possibilité de répondre à ces problèmes en recourant à des démantèlements de firmes (Khan, 2019 ;Lamoreaux, 2019). Une autre discute de l'adéquation du critère du bien-être du consommateur et de l'approche par les effets (Glick, 2018 ;Melamed et Petit, 2019). La tension entre un antitrust technique basé sur une approche plus économique et un antitrust politique prenant à sa charge des objectifs plus larges, tels l'accès au marché des tiers, la liberté de choix des consommateurs, est-elle aggravée par la numérisation des activités ou les outils algorithmiques peuvent-ils euxmêmes permettre de meilleures décisions concurrentielles ? ...
December 2018
The Antitrust Bulletin