Luca Mungo’s research while affiliated with University of Oxford and other places

What is this page?


This page lists works of an author who doesn't have a ResearchGate profile or hasn't added the works to their profile yet. It is automatically generated from public (personal) data to further our legitimate goal of comprehensive and accurate scientific recordkeeping. If you are this author and want this page removed, please let us know.

Publications (9)


(a) Datasets for link prediction are usually built by filling rows with two nodes features (fu , fv , fu,v ) and by indicating if there is a link between the two nodes ( Au,v ). (b) These datasets are usually undersampled: in the original dataset, a small minority of the rows will be s.t. Au,v=1 (blue), while most of the rows will be s.t. Au,v=0 (red); undersampling discards a portion of them to generate a more balanced dataset.
Reconstructing supply networks
  • Article
  • Full-text available

March 2024

·

79 Reads

·

4 Citations

Luca Mungo

·

·

Diego Garlaschelli

·

François Lafond

Network reconstruction is a well-developed sub-field of network science, but it has only recently been applied to production networks, where nodes are firms and edges represent customer-supplier relationships. We review the literature that has flourished to infer the topology of these networks by partial, aggregate, or indirect observation of the data. We discuss why this is an important endeavour, what needs to be reconstructed, what makes it different from other network reconstruction problems, and how different researchers have approached the problem. We conclude with a research agenda.

Download

Cryptocurrency co-investment network: token returns reflect investment patterns

February 2024

·

121 Reads

·

11 Citations

EPJ Data Science

Since the introduction of Bitcoin in 2009, the dramatic and unsteady evolution of the cryptocurrency market has also been driven by large investments by traditional and cryptocurrency-focused hedge funds. Notwithstanding their critical role, our understanding of the relationship between institutional investments and the evolution of the cryptocurrency market has remained limited, also due to the lack of comprehensive data describing investments over time. In this study, we present a quantitative study of cryptocurrency institutional investments based on a dataset collected for 1324 currencies in the period between 2014 and 2022 from Crunchbase, one of the largest platforms gathering business information. We show that the evolution of the cryptocurrency market capitalization is highly correlated with the size of institutional investments, thus confirming their important role. Further, we find that the market is dominated by the presence of a group of prominent investors who tend to specialise by focusing on particular technologies. Finally, studying the co-investment network of currencies that share common investors, we show that assets with shared investors tend to be characterized by similar market behaviour. Our work sheds light on the role played by institutional investors and provides a basis for further research on their influence in the cryptocurrency ecosystem.



Illustration of a 3-player game with 2 actions per player (left) and its associated best-response digraph (right). The axes shown in the center give us our coordinate system: player 1 selects rows (along the depth), player 2 selects columns (along the width), and player 3 selects levels (along height). In the left-hand panel, the payoffs of players 1, 2, and 3 are listed in that order. The unique pure Nash equilibrium at the profile (1, 2, 1) is a sink of the digraph and is underlined
Frequency of convergence to a PNE for the clockwork best-response dynamic
Frequency of convergence to a PNE for clockwork vs. random best-response dynamics
Frequency of convergence to a PNE for p-periodic best-response dynamics in n=3\documentclass[12pt]{minimal} \usepackage{amsmath} \usepackage{wasysym} \usepackage{amsfonts} \usepackage{amssymb} \usepackage{amsbsy} \usepackage{mathrsfs} \usepackage{upgreek} \setlength{\oddsidemargin}{-69pt} \begin{document}$$n=3$$\end{document} player games
Conditional speed of convergence to a PNE for p-periodic best-response dynamics in n=3\documentclass[12pt]{minimal} \usepackage{amsmath} \usepackage{wasysym} \usepackage{amsfonts} \usepackage{amssymb} \usepackage{amsbsy} \usepackage{mathrsfs} \usepackage{upgreek} \setlength{\oddsidemargin}{-69pt} \begin{document}$$n=3$$\end{document} player games
Best-response dynamics, playing sequences, and convergence to equilibrium in random games

June 2023

·

101 Reads

·

8 Citations

International Journal of Game Theory

We analyze the performance of the best-response dynamic across all normal-form games using a random games approach. The playing sequence—the order in which players update their actions—is essentially irrelevant in determining whether the dynamic converges to a Nash equilibrium in certain classes of games (e.g. in potential games) but, when evaluated across all possible games, convergence to equilibrium depends on the playing sequence in an extreme way. Our main asymptotic result shows that the best-response dynamic converges to a pure Nash equilibrium in a vanishingly small fraction of all (large) games when players take turns according to a fixed cyclic order. By contrast, when the playing sequence is random, the dynamic converges to a pure Nash equilibrium if one exists in almost all (large) games.


FIG. 2. (A) The distribution ρ (g) of the growth rates for every firm i and time t. A normal distribution is provided as a reference. (B) Growth time series correlation spectrum. The two random benchmarks are obtained by sampling random time series from the empirical distribution ρ (g) (Empirical benchmark) and the normal distribution (Gaussian benchmark). The starting points and duration of the random time series match those of the real ones. The spectrum shown is the average of 10 sets of random time series.
FIG. 3. (A): Average correlation on the production network C (τ) S and several random network benchmarks. (B): Average "cleaned" correlation on the production network˜Cnetwork˜ network˜C (τ) S and several random network benchmarks. (C):Correlations along the supply chain decays with distance. At distance d = 4 (d = 3 for the cleaned correlation), firms' average correlation is the same of the Erdos-Renyi benchmark. Results for the cleaned time series are flagged with a (C)
FIG. 4. An illustration of network distance. Nodes 2, 3 and 4 are at a distance k = 1 from node 10. Even though the path 1 → 3 → 4 exists, we do not consider 4 to be at distance k = 2 from 1
FIG. 5. (A) A stylised representation of an adjacency matrix with two sectors. The density of links between the n A firms in sector A is ρ A , the density of links between the n B firms in sector B is ρ B , and the density of links across the two sectors is ρ AB . (B) Another adjacency matrix. There are two group of firms of size n A (right bottom corner of the matrix) and n B (top left corner of the matrix). The density within firms in the first group is ρ B , the density between firms in the second group is ρ A , and the density across the groups is ρ AB . The graph Laplacian of the matrix in (A) and that of the matrix in (B) will have the same spectrum. However, the density within and across sectors in (B) is different from that in (A).
FIG. 6. Reconstruction of the supply chain networks. The original correlation matrix (A) is split in the different industry sectors. First, we reconstruct the diagonal blocks (B). Then, we reconstruct the off-diagonal blocks (C). Finally, we reassemble the blocks together (D).
Revealing production networks from firm growth dynamics

February 2023

·

91 Reads

·

1 Citation

We study the correlation structure of firm growth rates. We show that most firms are correlated because of their exposure to a common factor but that firms linked through the supply chain exhibit a stronger correlation on average than firms that are not. Removing this common factor significantly reduces the average correlation between two firms with no relationship in the supply chain while maintaining a significant correlation between two firms that are linked. We then demonstrate how this observation can be used to reconstruct the topology of a supply chain network using Gaussian Markov Models.



Crypocurrency co-investment network: token returns reflect investment patterns

January 2023

·

132 Reads

Since the introduction of Bitcoin in 2009, the dramatic and unsteady evolution of the cryptocurrency market has also been driven by large investments by traditional and cryptocurrency-focused hedge funds. Notwithstanding their critical role, our understanding of the relationship between institutional investments and the evolution of the cryptocurrency market has remained limited, also due to the lack of comprehensive data describing investments over time. In this study, we present a quantitative study of cryptocurrency institutional investments based on a dataset collected for 1324 currencies in the period between 2014 and 2022 from Crunchbase, one of the largest platforms gathering business information. We show that the evolution of the cryptocurrency market capitalization is highly correlated with the size of institutional investments, thus confirming their important role. Further, we find that the market is dominated by the presence of a group of prominent investors who tend to specialise by focusing on particular technologies. Finally, studying the co-investment network of currencies that share common investors, we show that assets with shared investors tend to be characterized by similar market behavior. Our work sheds light on the role played by institutional investors and provides a basis for further research on their influence in the cryptocurrency ecosystem.


Figure 5. Frequency of convergence to a PNE for the clockwork bestresponse dynamic with Γ = 0. In the bottom panel, the horizontal axis is rescaled according to Corollary 1.
Figure 6. Frequency of convergence to pure Nash equilibria under clockwork, random, and simultaneous best-response dynamics. The solid line corresponds to Γ = 0, the darker dashed lines to Γ = n−1 5 , 2 n−1 5 , . . . , (n − 1), and the lighter dashed lines to Γ = −0.2, −0.4, . . . , −1.
Figure 7. The frequency of convergence to PNE under best-response dynamics compared to the frequency of convergence to (mixed and pure) Nash equilibria under the other learning rules for Γ = 0.
Figure 9. The frequency of convergence to PNE under best-response dynamics against the frequency of convergence to (mixed or pure) Nash equilibria under the three learning rules, for varying values of n, m, and Γ and m = 5.
Best-response dynamics, playing sequences, and convergence to equilibrium in random games

January 2021

·

129 Reads

We show that the playing sequence--the order in which players update their actions--is a crucial determinant of whether the best-response dynamic converges to a Nash equilibrium. Specifically, we analyze the probability that the best-response dynamic converges to a pure Nash equilibrium in random n-player m-action games under three distinct playing sequences: clockwork sequences (players take turns according to a fixed cyclic order), random sequences, and simultaneous updating by all players. We analytically characterize the convergence properties of the clockwork sequence best-response dynamic. Our key asymptotic result is that this dynamic almost never converges to a pure Nash equilibrium when n and m are large. By contrast, the random sequence best-response dynamic converges almost always to a pure Nash equilibrium when one exists and n and m are large. The clockwork best-response dynamic deserves particular attention: we show through simulation that, compared to random or simultaneous updating, its convergence properties are closest to those exhibited by three popular learning rules that have been calibrated to human game-playing in experiments (reinforcement learning, fictitious play, and replicator dynamics).


Citations (6)


... The use of machine learning for mapping supply chains has also been explored in several efforts. This includes supervised machine learning models capable of predicting firm-level supply chains (Mungo et al. [32]). Yet despite achieving high accuracy, these models often grapple with limitations such as reliance on sector-specific data (e.g., automotive (Kosasih and Brintrup [22]), energy (Kosasih et al. [23]), aerospace (Brintrup et al. [7])), countryspecific data (e.g., the United Kingdom (U.K.), Japan (Mori et al. [31]), or South Korea (Lee and Kim [25])), and a notable absence of product-level information. ...

Reference:

Mapping global value chains at the product level
Reconstructing supply networks

... Cryptocurrency markets, particularly Bitcoin, have emerged as a significant financial domain in recent years, attracting the attention of both individual and institutional investors (Mungo, et al., 2023;Kogan, et al., 2023). Bitcoin's price movements, characterized by high volatility, draw attention while presenting investors with both substantial opportunities and considerable risks (Kogan, et al., 2023). ...

Cryptocurrency co-investment network: token returns reflect investment patterns

EPJ Data Science

... This involves strategic decisionmaking to optimize various functions, improve system robustness, and achieve balanced resource utilization [19]. The goal is to understand and analyze the behaviors and strategies of individual network users, who are typically driven by self-interest to maximize their own benefits [20]. ...

Best-response dynamics, playing sequences, and convergence to equilibrium in random games

International Journal of Game Theory

... These are, for example, the treatment of investments in physical capital, the financial and retail sector, and international trade, along with aspects related to classification and the time of recording. We also show that the structure of the highly granular 5-digit SIC Payment network matches relevant stylised facts from the literature, such as growth rate fluctuations and centrality distributions (Carvalho, 2014;Mungo and Moran, 2023;Magerman et al., 2016;Bacilieri et al., 2023). This paves the way for applied economic research exploiting the granular network structure. ...

Revealing production networks from firm growth dynamics

... For example, the economic processes underlying the preferential attachment include (among others) the fact that only some suppliers produce the products needed [53], the social network underlying the formation of business ties [33,34], and of course price differences [31]. The situation might become more transparent when more data on the involved firms could be included, such as geography, productivity, sales, etc. [57], which is impossible for us at this stage. In future work higher order processes could be added to the model, such as triadic closure mechanisms, firm splitting or merging, or introducing explicit seasonality. ...

Reconstructing production networks using machine learning
  • Citing Article
  • February 2023

Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control

... payoffs (Rinott andScarsini, 2000, Mimun et al., 2024) or from the assumption of continuous distributions (Amiet et al., 2021b). Moreover, the focus moved from the number of pure Nash equilibria to the behavior of learning dynamics (see, e.g., Amiet et al., 2021a,b, Wiese and Heinrich, 2022, Heinrich et al., 2023, Johnston et al., 2023, Mimun et al., 2024. ...

Best-response dynamics, playing sequences, and convergence to equilibrium in random games
  • Citing Article
  • January 2021

SSRN Electronic Journal