Kenneth D. West’s research while affiliated with University of Wisconsin–Madison and other places

What is this page?


This page lists works of an author who doesn't have a ResearchGate profile or hasn't added the works to their profile yet. It is automatically generated from public (personal) data to further our legitimate goal of comprehensive and accurate scientific recordkeeping. If you are this author and want this page removed, please let us know.

Publications (93)


Erratum
  • Article

February 1992

·

4 Reads

Journal of Monetary Economics

Kenneth D. West

A comparison of the behavior of Japanese and US inventories

July 1991

·

9 Reads

·

13 Citations

International Journal of Production Economics

This paper compares the cyclical and secular behavior of Japanese and US inventories at the aggregate and sectoral level, 1967–1987. While, as is well known, US inventories are sharply procyclical, Japanese inventories are only mildly procyclical. In neither country do inventory and sales move together in the long run, in the sense that the two series do not seem to be cointegrated. In Japan, but not in the US, there is a secular decline in the inventory-sales ratio.


The Sources of Fluctuations in Aggregate Inventories and GNP

November 1990

·

23 Reads

·

64 Citations

Quarterly Journal of Economics

A simple real linear-quadratic inventory model is used to determine how cost and demand shocks interacted to cause fluctuations in aggregate inventories and GNP in the United States, 1947–1986. Cost shocks appear to be the predominant source of fluctuations in inventories and are largely, though not exclusively, responsible for the fact that GNP is more variable than final sales. Cost and demand shocks are of roughly equal importance for GNP. These estimates, however, are imprecise. With different, but plausible, values for a certain target inventory-sales ratio, cost shocks are less important than demand shocks for GNP fluctuations.


Evidence from seven countries on whether inventories smooth aggregate output

February 1990

·

7 Reads

·

21 Citations

Engineering Costs and Production Economics

Casual examination of annual postwar data on inventories and aggregate output for seven developed countries -- Canada, France, West Germany, Italy, Japan, United Kingdom, United States -- suggests that in these countries the primary function of aggregate inventories is not to smooth aggregate output in the face of aggregate demand shocks. Japan is a possible exception to this generalization.


Estimation of Linear Rational Expectations Models in the Presence of Deterministic Terms

November 1989

·

5 Reads

·

15 Citations

Journal of Monetary Economics

Hansen and Sargent (1981b) discussed instrumental variables procedures for estimating linear rational expectations models, under the assumption that all variables have zero unconditional means. This note points out two implications if variables instead have nonzero unconditional means: first, there are additional restrictions beyond those noted by Hansen and Sargent (1981b), and second, imposing these restrictions results in more efficient estimates of the parameters that are the focus of Hansen and Sargent (1981b). Explicit formulas are given for the restrictions generated by some commonly assumed deterministic terms.


Order Backlogs and Production Smoothing

July 1989

·

9 Reads

·

22 Citations

Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems

Empirical examination of some aggregate manufacturing data suggests that order backlogs may help explain two puzzling facts: (1) the variability of production appears to be greater than that of demand, and (2) inventories appear to be drawn down when demand is low, built up when demand is high.


On the Interpretation of Near Random-Walk Behaviour in GNP

February 1988

·

18 Reads

·

97 Citations

American Economic Review

It is shown that GNP will have an autoregressive root very close to unity in a variant of Taylor's (1980a,b) overlapping wage contracts model, for stylized versions of simple money supply rules and plausible values for the model's parameters. In this variant, monetary policy is the only reason for serial correlation in GNP. It is premature, therefore, to conclude, as some authors, have, that the presence of such a root in U.S. GNP is inconsistent with either a stationary natural rate or with nominal shocks playing a major role in the business cycle.


The Insensitivity of Consumption to News About Income

February 1988

·

16 Reads

·

100 Citations

Journal of Monetary Economics

This paper uses a variance bounds test to see whether consumption is too sensitive to news about income to be consistent with a standard permanent income model, under the maintained hypothesis that income has a unit root. It is found that, if anything, consumption is less sensitive than the model would predict. This implication is robust to the representative consumer having private information about his future income that the econometrician does not have, to wealth shocks, and to transitory consumption. This suggests the importance in future research on the model of allowing for factors that tend to make consumption smooth.


Dividend Innovations and Stock Price Volatility

February 1988

·

70 Reads

·

434 Citations

A standard efficient markets model states that a stock price equals the expected present discounted valu e of its dividends, with a constant discount rate. This is shown to i mply that the variance of the innovation in the stock price is smalle r than that of a stock-price forecast made from a subset of the marke t's information set. The implication follows even if prices and divid ends require differencing to induce stationarity. The relation betwee n the variances appears not to hold for some annual U.S. stock-market data. The rejection of the model is both quantitatively and statisti cally significant. Copyright 1988 by The Econometric Society.


Asymptotic Normality When Regressors Have a Unit Root

February 1988

·

27 Reads

·

285 Citations

Under fairly general conditions, ordinary least squares and linear instrumental variables estimators are asymptotically normal when a regression equation has nonstationary right hand side variables. Standard formulas may be used to calculate a consistent estimate of the asymptotic variance-covariance matrix of the estimated parameter vector, even if the disturbances are conditionally heteroskedastic and autocorrelated. So inference may proceed in the usual way. The key requirements are that the nonstationary variables share a common unit root and that the unconditional mean of their first differences is nonzero. Copyright 1988 by The Econometric Society.


Citations (75)


... The production costs for businesses rise and are likely to be passed on to consumers in the form of higher prices for consumer goods. The inflation rate increases as a consequence [5]. As a result, there will always be a trade-off between inflation and full employment for the policymakers in the Federal Reserve to carefully consider about. ...

Reference:

Analysis of Interest Rate Hikes and Exchange Rate Between U.S. and China
Interest Rates and Exchange Rates in the Korean, Philippine, and Thai Exchange Rate Crises
  • Citing Chapter
  • January 2003

... Empirically, Lunsford and West (2019) conclude demographic variables can explain some of the variability in U.S. real interest rates over more than one hundred years, while Fiorentini et al. (2018) highlight the importance of the share of young workers in accounting for the rise and fall of real rates between 1960 and 2016. Our empirical analysis expands on this second paper. ...

Some Evidence on Secular Drivers of US Safe Real Rates
  • Citing Article
  • October 2019

American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics

... In Table 2 we report coefficient estimates, adjusted Rsquared and F-statistics. The Newey-West standard error [55] with lag = 5 is shown in parenthesis under the coefficient estimates, and the statistical significance levels are indicated by the stars. ...

Discussion of Lazarus, Lewis, Stock, and Watson, “HAR Inference: Recommendations for Practice”
  • Citing Article
  • October 2018

... 5 The economic forces reducing the equilibrium real interest rate likely include lower productivity growth, changing demographics, a decline in the price of capital goods, and strong precautionary saving flows from emerging market economies, which have tended to increase global savings, reduce desired investment, and push down the steady-state real interest rate. Discussions include Summers (2014), Kiley (2015), Rachel and Smith (2015), Hamilton et al. (2016), Laubach and Williams (2016), Johannsen andMertens (2016, 2018), Christensen and Rudebusch (2017), Del Negro et al. (2017), Holston et al. (2017) and Lunsford and West (2017). In macroeconomics, r * t is often labeled the neutral or natural rate of interest although, as noted below, there can be subtle dfferences among various definitions. ...

Some Evidence on Secular Drivers of U.S. Safe Real Rates
  • Citing Article
  • January 2017

SSRN Electronic Journal

... average R 2 from these estimations across all years. In the spirit of Campbell and Thompson (2008) and Clark and West (2006), if the realized growth rate series is truly unpredictable, then in a finite sample the predictive regression will on average have a higher mean squared prediction error. Therefore, the expected R 2 under the null of unpredictability is negative, and a 0 or positive R 2 can be interpreted as evidence of predictability. ...

Using Out-of-Sample Mean Squared Prediction Errors to Test the Martingale Difference Hypothesis
  • Citing Article
  • January 2004

SSRN Electronic Journal

... The models in competition are the continuous-time three-and five-factor AFDNS models, the fourand five-factor CKLS models on one side, and the more parsimonious univariate and vector autoregressive (AR and VAR) models, and the random walk process, on the other side. The out-of-sample model performances are evaluated using formal statistical tests including the equal predictability tests of Diebold and Mariano (1995) and Clark and West (2007), as well as the superior predictive ability (SPA) test of Hansen (2005) and the model confidence set of Hansen et al. (2011) (hereafter, MCS). ...

Approximately Normal Tests for Equal Predictive Accuracy in Nested Models
  • Citing Article
  • January 2005

SSRN Electronic Journal

... is a kernel function, and M > 0 is the associated kernel bandwidth parameter. In this section, we use the Bartlett kernel with M set equal to the integer part of 4(T/100) 2/9 , as recommended by Newey and West (1994). As Moon et al. (2014) show, provided that their linear process assumption is met, the local power envelope is unaffected by the HAC modification to account for serial correlation. ...

Autocovariance lag selection in covariance matrix estimation
  • Citing Article
  • January 1994

Review of Economic Studies

... The data for short-term nominal interest rate are either overnight or three-month official rates (see Table A3 for details). To construct expected inflation, we follow the approach in Hamilton et al. (2016) and calculate the one-year-ahead forecast from AR (1) ...

The Equilibrium Real Funds Rate: Past, Present, and Future
  • Citing Article
  • November 2016

IMF Economic Review

... Forecast precision in economic models has long been critical in financial decision making, with significant advances in methodologies and tools over time (Brandl et al., 2006;Pincheira & West, 2016). The seminal work of Meese and Rogoff (1983) in 1983 catalyzed a shift in focus toward prediction evaluation in economic models, particularly in the context of exchange rates (Engel et al., 2007). ...

A Comparison of Some Out-of-Sample Tests of Predictability in Iterated Multi-Step-Ahead Forecasts
  • Citing Article
  • April 2016

Research in Economics