Hui Chen’s research while affiliated with Massachusetts Institute of Technology and other places

What is this page?


This page lists works of an author who doesn't have a ResearchGate profile or hasn't added the works to their profile yet. It is automatically generated from public (personal) data to further our legitimate goal of comprehensive and accurate scientific recordkeeping. If you are this author and want this page removed, please let us know.

Publications (17)


Figure 2: Illustration of Gaussian Process Regression. The dotted is the true function while the solid line is the posterior mean of the fitted GP. The shaded region plots the 95% confidence interval.
Figure 4: Solution after defaulting. Panel A plots the scaled value function after defaulting v D pt, sq; it is related to the unscaled value function through equation (17). Panel B plots the optimal allocation to stocks after defaulting.
Figure 11: Life cycle dynamics. This figure illustrates the life cycle dynamics of the LP's portfolio. The solid line plots the average outcome in each year while the shaded region provides the 95% confidence interval. Panels A through D plot the outcomes for new commitments, uncalled commitments, liquid wealth, and the stock allocation, respectively. All outcomes are shown relative to total wealth.
Figure 15: Business cycles and total wealth outcomes. This figure illustrates the distribution of total wealth outcomes at the end of the investment horizon t " T . The initial total wealth is W 0 ` P 0 " 1. Panel A plots the distribution for total wealth W T ` P T . Panel B plots the distribution for the realized growth in total wealth per annum, logpW T ` P T q{10. The solid (dashed) bars plot the outcomes conditional on the LP experiencing a lower (higher) than expected number of recessions over its investment horizon.
Figure 17: Total wealth outcome without accounting for business cycles. This figure illustrates the distribution of total wealth outcomes at the end of the investment horizon t " T . The initial total wealth is W 0 ` P 0 " 1. Panel A plots the distribution for total wealth W T ` P T . Panel B plots the distribution for the realized growth in total wealth per annum, logpW T ` P T q{10. The solid and dashed bars plot the outcomes for the baseline and a naive investor that ignores business cycles, respectively.

+1

A Dynamic Model of Private Asset Allocation
  • Preprint
  • File available

March 2025

·

19 Reads

Hui Chen

·

Giovanni Gambarotta

·

·

Yu Xu

We build a state-of-the-art dynamic model of private asset allocation that considers five key features of private asset markets: (1) the illiquid nature of private assets, (2) timing lags between capital commitments, capital calls, and eventual distributions, (3) time-varying business cycle conditions, (4) serial correlation in observed private asset returns, and (5) regulatory constraints on certain institutional investors' portfolio choices. We use cutting-edge machine learning methods to quantify the optimal investment policies over the life cycle of a fund. Moreover, our model offers regulators a tool for precisely quantifying the trade-offs when setting risk-based capital charges.

Download


Confidence regions of (p,ξ)$(p, \xi)$ for the baseline model and equity premium isoquants. This figure shows the 95% and 99% confidence regions of (p,ξ)$(p, \xi)$ for the baseline model and the equity premium isoquants implied by the asset pricing moment restriction (41) for γ=3,10,24$\gamma = 3, 10, 24$. The parameter p$p$ represents the disaster probability, and ξ$\xi$ characterizes the inverse of the average disaster size. The efficient GMM estimates are (p̂,ξ̂)=(0.012,78.79)$(\widehat{p}, \widehat{\xi }) = (0.012, 78.79)$, indicated by the red dot inside the confidence region. Four additional points mark the intersections of the equity premium isoquants for γ=3$\gamma = 3$ and γ=24$\gamma = 24$ and the boundary of the 95% confidence region. Only p$p$ and ξ$\xi$ are treated as unknown to the econometrician; all other parameters are treated as auxiliary parameters with fixed known values, as a part of the functional‐form specification. [Color figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]
Asymptotic confidence regions for parameters (p,ξ)$(p, \xi)$ and the identified worst‐case direction. This figure depicts the dark‐matter measure through the 95% confidence regions for the asymptotic distribution of the efficient GMM estimators for four “acceptable” calibrations. In Panels A through D, the dark‐matter measure is equal to ϱ(θ)=1.78×104$\varrho (\theta) = 1.78\times 10^4$, 5.60×102$5.60\times 10^2$, 74.03, and 1.49, respectively, which are obtained in the direction marked by the vector vmax$v_{\max }$. Parameter p$p$ is the disaster probability, and ξ$\xi$ characterizes the inverse of average disaster size. Only p$p$ and ξ$\xi$ are treated as unknown to the econometrician; all other parameters are auxiliary parameters with fixed known values as a part of the functional‐form specification. Therefore, the dark‐matter measure is defined based only on θ=(p,ξ)T$\theta = (p, \xi)^T$. [Color figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]
Monte Carlo experiments for disaster risk models. In Panel A, we simulate 1,000 independent yearly time series with length n=2,200$n = 2,200$ to capture a pooled sample of 100 years for 22 countries, similar to Wachter (2013). In Panels B and C, we set δr=0.4$\delta _r = 0.4$ and simulate 400 independent yearly time series with length n=100$n = 100$ (i.e., 100 years) and break point π=1/2$\pi = 1/2$. Only the uncertainties about p$p$ and ξ$\xi$ are accounted for; all other parameters are auxiliary parameters as a part of the functional‐form specification. [Color figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]
Monte Carlo experiments for time‐varying disaster risk models. In this simulation experiment where all of the parameters except ρ$\rho$ are treated as auxiliary parameters, the dark‐matter measure is equal to ϱ(θ)=1.5×105$\varrho (\theta) = 1.5 \times 10^5$ and ϱ(θ)=4.3×102$\varrho (\theta) = 4.3 \times 10^2$ for model M1 and M2, respectively. In Panel A, we simulate 1,000 independent yearly time series with length n=2,200$n = 2,200$ to capture a pooled sample of 100 years for 22 countries similar to Wachter (2013). In Panels B and C, we set δr=0.05$\delta _r = 0.05$ and simulate 400 independent yearly time series with length n=100$n = 100$ (i.e., 100 years) and break point π=1/2$\pi = 1/2$. Only the uncertainty about ρ$\rho$ is accounted for; all other parameters are treated as auxiliary parameters as part of the functional‐form specification. [Color figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]
Monte Carlo experiments for long‐run risk models. In this simulation experiment where all the parameters except ν$\nu$ are treated as auxiliary parameters, the dark‐matter measure is equal to ϱ(θ)=1.03×105$\varrho (\theta) = 1.03 \times 10^5$ and ϱ(θ)=22.34$\varrho (\theta) = 22.34$ for model M1 and M2, respectively. In Panel A, we simulate 1,000 independent monthly time series with length n=1200$n = 1200$ (i.e., 100 years). In Panels B and C, we simulate 400 independent monthly time series with length n=1,200$n = 1,200$ (i.e., 100 years) and break point π=1/2$\pi = 1/2$. We set δr=0.02$\delta _r = 0.02$ for Panels B and C. In the simulation experiment, we assume that all of the parameters except ν$\nu$ are treated as auxiliary parameters, fixed at known constant values and subsumed into the functional form of the moment function (i.e., model specifications). [Color figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]
Measuring “Dark Matter” in Asset Pricing Models

March 2024

·

91 Reads

·

7 Citations

We formalize the concept of “dark matter” in asset pricing models by quantifying the additional informativeness of cross‐equation restrictions about fundamental dynamics. The dark‐matter measure captures the degree of fragility for models that are potentially misspecified and unstable: a large dark‐matter measure indicates that the model lacks internal refutability (weak power of optimal specification tests) and external validity (high overfitting tendency and poor out‐of‐sample fit). The measure can be computed at low cost even for complex dynamic structural models. To illustrate its applications, we provide quantitative examples applying the measure to (time‐varying) rare‐disaster risk and long‐run risk models.







Deep Structural Estimation: With an Application to Option Pricing

February 2021

·

228 Reads

We propose a novel structural estimation framework in which we train a surrogate of an economic model with deep neural networks. Our methodology alleviates the curse of dimensionality and speeds up the evaluation and parameter estimation by orders of magnitudes, which significantly enhances one's ability to conduct analyses that require frequent parameter re-estimation. As an empirical application, we compare two popular option pricing models (the Heston and the Bates model with double-exponential jumps) against a non-parametric random forest model. We document that: a) the Bates model produces better out-of-sample pricing on average, but both structural models fail to outperform random forest for large areas of the volatility surface; b) random forest is more competitive at short horizons (e.g., 1-day), for short-dated options (with less than 7 days to maturity), and on days with poor liquidity; c) both structural models outperform random forest in out-of-sample delta hedging; d) the Heston model's relative performance has deteriorated significantly after the 2008 financial crisis.



Citations (8)


... Typically, this is a volatility regime indicator (e.g., instructing the model to generate high volatility or low volatility time-series). Note that conditioning can introduce correlation among time-series; for example, [Sun et al., 2023] uses the same random seed for four US ETF time-series, creating a dependency, and [de Meer Pardo, 2019] first generates one timeseries corresponding to the first PCA component of returns, then conditions the other two series on this first step. ...

Reference:

Synthetic Data for Portfolios: A Throw of the Dice Will Never Abolish Chance
Decision-Aware Conditional GANs for Time Series Data
  • Citing Conference Paper
  • November 2023

... In addition, we do not consider the endogenous choice of in this research, because it is beyond our scope, and it is difficult to control the effect of weight and performance indicators. Second, in dynamic price competition, previous studies indicate that CEOs can engage in tacit collusion to obtain higher profits using the performance evaluation (Opp et al., 2014;Chen et al., 2024). On the other hand, other previous studies consider whether tacit collusion is effective, depending on the persistence of market leadership (Dou et al., 2021(Dou et al., , 2022. ...

Feedback and Contagion Through Distressed Competition
  • Citing Article
  • January 2023

SSRN Electronic Journal

... They provide early evidence that learning methods may complement parametric ones in terms of pricing and hedging. Chen et al. (2021) use deep neural networks to approximate the option pricing model by a surrogate function, which treats the state, parameters of model as well as the hidden state (e.g. volatility) as input. ...

Deep Structural Estimation: With an Application to Option Pricing
  • Citing Article
  • January 2021

SSRN Electronic Journal

... First, they are consistent with models on investor attention (e.g., DellaVigna and Pollet, 2009;Hirshleifer, Lim, and Teoh, 2009;Ben-Rephael, Da, and Israelsen, 2017;Anastassia, 2023). Investors tend to pay more attention to bad news than good news, which is supported by Wall Street adage that "markets take the stairs up and the elevator down" and by index option trading where fund managers focus on hedging downside risk (e.g., Chen, Joslin, and Ni, 2019). Hence they react more quickly to so bad news, making it has little predictability. ...

Demand for Crash Insurance, Intermediary Constraints, and Risk Premia in Financial Markets
  • Citing Article
  • January 2019

Review of Financial Studies

... This paper extends a growing literature on introducing the business cycle into investment decisions. Recent literature introduces the business cycle into the investment model and obtains many novel conclusions (e.g., Chen and Manso [7], Chen and Strebulaev [9], Chen et al. [8]). They highlighted the role of business cycle risk in investment choices and default decisions. ...

Systematic risk, debt maturity, and the term structure of credit spreads
  • Citing Article
  • September 2020

Journal of Financial Economics

... By building general equilibrium models with endogenous firm entry, both these papers examine the interaction between product market competition and asset prices. Our paper is also related more generally to Chen et al. (2021) and Dou, Ji, and Wu (2021). Chen et al. (2021) study the dynamic interactions between endogenous strategic competition and financial distress. ...

Online Appendix for 'Feedback and Contagion through Distressed Competition'
  • Citing Article
  • January 2020

SSRN Electronic Journal

... Wiseman also provides several historically important anecdotes of predatory behavior. Chen et al. (2019) model a dynamic duopoly with the possibility of default. They show that the possibility of default can soften future punishments, and thus weaken the conditions for collusion. ...

Predation or Self-Defense? Endogenous Competition and Financial Distress

SSRN Electronic Journal

... The concept of dark matter in asset pricing models draws a connection to economic components that are difficult to measure directly and quantifies its impact on model stability, which was formalized by Chen et al. (2022). Using a semimartingale-based approach, Bakshi et al. (2022) show how to decompose equity option risk premiums and examine the dynamics of jumps crossing the strike and local time. ...

Measuring the 'Dark Matter' in Asset Pricing Models
  • Citing Article
  • January 2013

SSRN Electronic Journal