David Altig’s research while affiliated with Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland and other places

What is this page?


This page lists works of an author who doesn't have a ResearchGate profile or hasn't added the works to their profile yet. It is automatically generated from public (personal) data to further our legitimate goal of comprehensive and accurate scientific recordkeeping. If you are this author and want this page removed, please let us know.

Publications (35)


Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle
  • Article

March 2010

·

146 Reads

·

284 Citations

Review of Economic Dynamics

·

·

David E. Altig

·

This paper formulates and estimates a three-shock US business cycle model. The estimated model accounts for a substantial fraction of the cyclical variation in output and is consistent with the observed inertia in inflation. This is true even though firms in the model reoptimize prices on average once every 1.8 quarters. The key feature of our model underlying this result is that capital is firm-specific. If we adopt the standard assumption that capital is homogeneous and traded in economy-wide rental markets, we find that firms reoptimize their prices on average once every 9 quarters. We argue that the micro implications of the model strongly favor the firm-specific capital specification. (Copyright: Elsevier)



Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle

January 2010

·

21 Reads

·

28 Citations

International Finance Discussion Paper

This paper formulates and estimates a three-shock US business cycle model. The estimated model accounts for a substantial fraction of the cyclical variation in output and is consistent with the observed inertia in inflation. This is true even though firms in the model reoptimize prices on average once every 1.8 quarters. The key feature of our model underlying this result is that capital is firm-specific. If we adopt the standard assumption that capital is homogeneous and traded in economy-wide rental markets, we find that firms reoptimize their prices on average once every 9 quarters. We argue that the micro implications of the model strongly favor the firm-specific capital specification.


Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle

January 2005

·

80 Reads

·

439 Citations

SSRN Electronic Journal

Macroeconomic and microeconomic data paint conflicting pictures of price behavior. Macroeconomic data suggest that inflation is inertial. Microeconomic data indicate that firms change prices frequently. We formulate and estimate a model which resolves this apparent micro - macro conflict. Our model is consistent with post-war U.S. evidence on inflation inertia even though firms re-optimize prices on average once every 1.5 quarters. The key feature of our model is that capital is firm-specific and predetermined within a period.


Figure 6: Historical decomposition − monetary policy shocks only 
Figure 7: Historical decomposition − neutral technology shocks only 
Figure 9: Historical decomposition − monetary policy and technology shocks 
Technical Appendix to "Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle"
  • Article
  • Full-text available

January 2004

·

162 Reads

·

38 Citations

Technical appendix for the Review of Economic Dynamics article

Download

Simulating Fundamental Tax Reform in the United States

March 2003

·

2 Reads

·

8 Citations

David Altig

·

·

·

[...]

·

Originally published in 2003, this book contains fifteen major essays on international economics. The authors investigate five principal themes: theory, and empirics, of financial issues in open economies; economic growth; public economies; and political economy. Written to honor Professor Assaf Razin of Tel Aviv and Cornell Universities on the occasion of his sixtieth birthday, the essays pay close attention to policy issues as well as formal analysis. The contributors include renowned specialists in international economics based in North America, Europe, Israel, and China. This volume of avanced research will be of interest to scholars, policy makers, and advanced students alike.



A Conference on Liquidity, Monetary Policy, and Financial Intermediation

July 2002

·

24 Reads

Introduction In September 1994, the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland and the Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking sponsored a conference on liquidity, monetary policy, and financial intermediation. This symposium was the fifth in a jointly sponsored series aimed at promoting research on basic issues in monetary policy, financial markets, and the payments system. This particular conference dealt with monetary policy issues. The papers included examinations of the macroeconomic effects of price rigidity and "sluggish" savings decisions by households (that is, the assumption of limited participation in financial markets), the interaction of inflation and financial intermediation, and the "deep structural" estimation of parameters in models with money and financial intermediation. The common thread in all of these studies is the attempt to move us farther down the road to understanding the fundamental structures that ultimately determine the economic consequences of monetary policy. A co


Table 7. Percentage of Initial Population with Gains from Reform 
Simulating Fundamental Tax Reform in the U.S.

June 2001

·

780 Reads

·

385 Citations

American Economic Review

This paper uses a new, large-scale, dynamic life-cycle simulation model to compare the welfare and macroeconomic effects of five fundamental alternatives to the U.S. federal income tax: a proportional income tax, a proportional consumption tax, a flat tax, a flat tax with transition relief, and a progressive variant of the flat tax called the X tax. The model incorporates intragenerational heterogeneity and detailed specification of alternative tax systems. It predicts significant long-run increases in output from the wholesale replacement of the progressive federal income-tax with a low-rate proportional consumption tax. In the long run, middle- and upper-income groups gain from this policy. But their gains come at the expense of the current and future poor, who suffer from the removal of the current tax structure's progressivity, and the wealthiest members of initial, older generations, who are hurt by the policy's implicit capital levy. The flat tax adds a standard deduction to the consumption tax. This feature improves outcomes for the current and future poor. But it does so at an additional cost; long-run output increases less than half as much as under the proportional consumption tax, and middle-income groups experience a welfare loss, even in the long run. Moreover, the flat tax continues to leave some of the initial elderly worse off. Although one can insulate these individuals through transition relief, doing so further reduces the long-run gains from tax reform. Switching to a proportional income tax without deductions or exemptions is an alternative way to reform the federal income tax. Although the policy raises long-run output to roughly the same extent as the flat tax, eliminating the federal income tax's progressivity hurts the poor, whether they are ...


Sources of Business Cycles in Korea and the United States

March 1999

·

12 Reads

·

3 Citations

This paper applies and extends Gali's contribution. We estimate common and nation-specific components of technology shocks, real demand shocks, and (combined common and nation-specific) monetary shocks using quarterly data for Korea and the United States. We attempt to contribute both to the fundamental macroeconomic issue of the sources of business cycles as well as issues of the international transmission of business cycles and the determination of exchange rates. 2


Citations (23)


... Both are limited to the long run effects and conclude for the regressivity of the reform. Examples of work that compute the whole transition path are Altig et al (2001), that impose an exogenous amount of debt over time across reforms, being its main contribution the formalization of intragenerational heterogeneity in a dynamic life cycle model and the specific calibration for the U.S. tax code. The other example is Ventura (1999) that compares distributions by income and wealth and not by welfare. ...

Reference:

Consumption Taxes and Redistribution
Simulating Fundamental Tax Reform in the United States
  • Citing Chapter
  • March 2003

... It requires taking a stand on the percentage contribution of each type of shocks to output growth volatility. We set the marginal efficiency of investment shock contribution to 50 percent of output volatility based on evidence produced by Justiniano, Primiceri, and Tambalotti (2011) and others (Fisher, 2006a;Justiniano and Primiceri, 2008b;Justiniano, Primiceri, and Tambalotti, 2010a;Altig et al., 2011), 35% for the neutral technology, 10% for the monetary policy shock and 5% for the shock to the trend inflation. ...

Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle
  • Citing Article
  • January 2010

International Finance Discussion Paper

... In addition, it should be noted that the literature is focused mainly on the effects of monetary policy on personal income distribution, not on functional income distribution (Kappes 2023). Notable exceptions can be found, among others, in the works of Christiano et al. (1997Christiano et al. ( , 2005, Altig et al. (2011), and Cantore et al. (2021). ...

Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle
  • Citing Article
  • January 2010

SSRN Electronic Journal

... During the 1990s, a new family of DSGE models incorporated in them fiscal policy, market imperfections, and shocks on other relevant variables such as the preferences (Benassy, 1995;Bernanke et al., 1999;Christiano & Eichenbaum, 1992;Clarida et al., 1999;Kim, 1998;King & Watson, 1996;Leeper & Sims, 1994;Rotemberg & Woodford, 1997). In the first decade of the current century, another family of DSGE models made its appearance, being in essence very similar to the previous, yet having higher mathematical complexity than ever before in order to reach the highest level of accuracy when representing an economy (Adolfson et al., 2007;Altig et al., 2005;Christiano et al., 2005;Iacoviello, 2005;Smets & Wouters, 2003;Smets & Wouters, 2007). ...

Technical Appendix to "Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle"

... In the literature, financial shocks most often take the form of monetary policy surprises (for instances King and Plosser (1984), Altig et al. (2004), and Clarida et al. (2002) or exchange rate regime changes (for instance, Baxter and Stockman (1989)). Once nominal frictions, like fixed prices and wages, are introduced, these models can generate impulse responses similar to those of technology shocks. ...

Firm specific capital etc
  • Citing Article

... However, even these rich models have not had the detail on domestic economic developments, such as specifications of highly disaggregated expenditure decisions, to address the range of questions typically analyzed by large models like the Federal Reserve's FRB/US model. 3 The Esti-3 See Reifschneider et al. [1997] for a discussion of the use of models (including the FRB/US model) in forecasting at the Federal Reserve and Brayton et al. [1997] for a discussion of the use of models in policy 5 mated, Dynamic, Optimization-based (Edo) model project at the Federal Reserve has been designed to build on earlier work at policy institutions, as well as academic research such as Smets and Wouters [2007] and Altig et al. [2004], by expanding the modeling of domestic economic decisions while investigating the ability of such DSGE models to examine a range of policy questions. For a detailed description and discussion of previous applications, the reader is referred to Edge et al. [2008], Edge et al. [2007a], and Edge et al. [2007b]. ...

An Estimated Model of the US Business Cycle
  • Citing Article

... where y t is the endogenous variable vector with dimension r x 1 , x t is the observable state variables vector with dimension n x 1 , z t is the m x 1 exogenous state variables vector and " t is an m x 1 vector of stocastic variables such that E(" t ) = 0, E(" t " 0 t ) = , E(" t " 0 j ) = 0 for j 6 = t and where is a diagonal matrix, if n < m , the only …nite order representation of the model is a VARMA (p,q) representation 1 . It is argued that if the number of the exogenous variables exceeds the number of the observable state variables, the VARMA (p,q) can still be approximated by a …nite order VAR (p), provided that the VAR is characterized by a su¢ ciently high value of p. ...

An Estimated Dynamic, General Equilibrium Model for Monetary Policy Analysis ∗ (Preliminary and Incomplete)

... The smaller is σ the more slowly marginal utility falls as consumption rises, so households are more willing to allow changes in 6 While the development of growth literature in the mainstream macroeconomics during the last few decade has been encouraging, application of these models in policy analysis has not been fully successful owing to the limited institutional structures and scant sectoral details in these models (Abel and Blanchard 1983, Romer 1986, Lucas 1988, Rebelo 1991, Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1995, Leeper and Sims 1994, Romer 1996. 7 Whalley (1977), Adelman & Robinson (1978), Ballard (1983), Ballard-Fullerton-Shoven-Whalley (1985), Mansur & Whalley (1986), Feltenstein (1986), Aurbach and Kotlikoff (1987), Goulder and Summers (1989), Devarajan and Lewis (1990), Go (1993), Mercenier & Michel (1994). consumption over time. ...

and J. Wha lley, A General Equilibrium Model for Tax Policy Evaluation
  • Citing Article

... Christiano, Eichenbaum and Vigfusson (2003), also, challenge the result that a positive shock to technology drives down per capita hours worked. Similarly to Altig et al. (2002), they argue that a specification error in modelling the low frequency component of hours worked lies behind it. On the theoretical side, in addition to the interpretation based on price rigidity, alternative explanations have been advanced to back the finding of contractionary technology improvements. ...

Technology Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations∗ (Preliminary and Incomplete)

... Additionally, price and wage stickiness are set at 2/3 and 3/4, respectively. This is based on findings from Altig et al. (2011) andErceg et al. (2000), which have shown that prices and wages do not frequently adjust in real-world economies. And finally, we vary the value of λ, representing the ratio of rule-of-thumb households, from 0 to 4 to examine the effects caused by changes in the ratio of rule-of-thumb households in response to a technology shock. ...

Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle
  • Citing Article
  • March 2010

Review of Economic Dynamics