Christina Connell’s scientific contributions

What is this page?


This page lists works of an author who doesn't have a ResearchGate profile or hasn't added the works to their profile yet. It is automatically generated from public (personal) data to further our legitimate goal of comprehensive and accurate scientific recordkeeping. If you are this author and want this page removed, please let us know.

Publications (4)


Sensitivity analysis of key components in large-scale hydroeconomic models
  • Article

December 2008

·

19 Reads

·

C. R. Connell

·

·

This paper explores the likely impact of different estimation methods in key components of hydro-economic models such as hydrology and economic costs or benefits, using the CALVIN hydro-economic optimization for water supply in California. In perform our analysis using two climate scenarios: historical and warm-dry. The components compared were perturbed hydrology using six versus eighteen basins, highly-elastic urban water demands, and different valuation of agricultural water scarcity. Results indicate that large scale hydroeconomic hydro-economic models are often rather robust to a variety of estimation methods of ancillary models and components. Increasing the level of detail in the hydrologic representation of this system might not greatly affect overall estimates of climate and its effects and adaptations for California's water supply. More price responsive urban water demands will have a limited role in allocating water optimally among competing uses. Different estimation methods for the economic value of water and scarcity in agriculture may influence economically optimal water allocation; however land conversion patterns may have a stronger influence in this allocation. Overall optimization results of large-scale hydro-economic models remain useful for a wide range of assumptions in eliciting promising water management alternatives.


An Ancient Struggle: A Game Theory Approach to Resolving the Nile Conflict

May 2008

·

294 Reads

·

29 Citations

The Nile River has been the center of water resources development tensions among four main riparian actors: Egypt, Sudan, Ethiopia, and other upstream nations. Each player has a desire to meet its national demands under increasingly stressed limited resources. Egypt, the most powerful of the actors, strives to maintain the status quo: securing the water supply that is barely sufficient for its growing population. Sudan is wedged between its 1959 treaty with Egypt and potentially economically beneficial cooperation with Ethiopia. Ethiopia, the source of most of the Nile, strives to increase its water share to secure its food supply and facilitate economic development. Finally, the upstream nations seek to be released from the water development restrictions placed on them by the current system. All nations fear retaliation from Egypt. This study applies game theoretic methods to study this interstate water problem using the Graph Model for Conflict Resolution, which provides insights into the strategic behaviors of the conflicting parties. The developed model attempts to determine most likely outcomes of the conflict given the nations options and preferences. Results indicate that the current situation is not stable and that stable outcomes include retaliation by Egypt. A sensitivity analysis shows that the model is highly sensitive to Egypt's preferences, however, but not very sensitive to Sudan's or Ethiopia's preferences.


Statewide Impacts of Climate Change on Hydroelectric Generation and Revenues in California
  • Article
  • Full-text available

29 Reads

·

1 Citation

Download

Figure F.S1 -Average Delta exports for a given level of Delta outflow for the two regulatory alternatives (reduced exports and increased minimum net Delta outflow)  
Figure F.19 -Average Delta exports for a given level for Delta outflow for the two alternatives (reduced export capacity and increased minimum net Delta outflow)  
Figure F.20 -Average Delta export pumping and associated statewide net costs Note: As average Delta exports increase, average net costs decrease as more water becomes available. Changing the minimum net Delta outflow requirement is a more expensive means of controlling Delta exports than directly restricting export volumes (note that the 'Minimum Delta Outflow Requirement' line is above the 'Reduced Export Requirement' line).  
Figure F.21 -Average Delta outflows and associated statewide net costs Note: As average Delta outflows increase, the average net costs increase as water becomes scarcer and users switch to more costly supply alternatives. Generally, restricting exports is a more expensive means of increasing the average Delta outflow (note the 'Reduced Export Requirement' line tends to be above the 'Minimum Delta Outflow Requirement' line)  
Figure F.S2 -Average Delta export pumping and associated statewide net costs Note: As average Delta exports increase, average net costs decrease as more water becomes available. Changing the minimum net Delta outflow requirement is a more expensive means of controlling Delta exports than directly restricting export volumes (note that the 'Minimum Delta Outflow Requirement' line is above the 'Reduced Export Requirement' line).  

+12

The Economic Costs and Adaptations for Alternative Delta Regulations Technical Appendix F

96 Reads

·

4 Citations

Stacy K. Tanaka

·

Christina R. Connell

·

·

[...]

·

Citations (3)


... Because these disputes have multiple political, economic, social, and environmental aspects and are related to the issue of national sovereignty, they have many complexities and are mostly difficult to resolve. ese include the Jordan River conflict between Israel, Jordan, Lebanon and Syria [21], the Nile conflict between Egypt, Sudan and Ethiopia [22], the Tigris and Euphrates rivers between Syria, Turkey and Iraq [13], cited the Ganges River conflict between Bangladesh and India [23]. e ultimate goal of GMCR is to help decision-makers involved in a conflict to find a solution that is acceptable to all parties. ...

Reference:

Transboundary Water Resources Conflict Analysis Using Graph Model for Conflict Resolution: A Case Study—Harirud River
An Ancient Struggle: A Game Theory Approach to Resolving the Nile Conflict
  • Citing Conference Paper
  • May 2008

... In addition, the CALVIN-based estimates include both operational costs (e.g., the variable cost of running the pumps, treating water, expanding supply through efficiency and desalinization) and scarcity costs (i.e., the cost of receiving less than an economically optimal amount of water); the CALSIM-based studies only include scarcity costs. Ultimately the key difference between the Hanemann et al. (2006) and Medellin-Azuara et al. (2008) and Tanaka et al. (2006) scarcity cost estimates may lie in the extent to which water users have the ability to trade. Importantly, neither approach includes capital costs, which in this case will be dominated by the need for more water storage and conveyance infrastructure. ...

Statewide Impacts of Climate Change on Hydroelectric Generation and Revenues in California

... Developing a statewide water resources management model, policy impact assessment, identifying best management policies Hydroeconomic optimization California, U.S.A. Draper et al. (2003); Jenkins et al. (2004); Tanaka et al. (2008) Increasing competition among major demand sectors and degraded water quality Optimizing water allocation, reservoir operation, and irrigation scheduling Hydroeconomic simulation and optimization Chile Cai et al. (2006) Inefficient water management and system operation ...

The Economic Costs and Adaptations for Alternative Delta Regulations Technical Appendix F