Ben R. Newell’s research while affiliated with University of South Wales and other places


Ad

What is this page?


This page lists works of an author who doesn't have a ResearchGate profile or hasn't added the works to their profile yet. It is automatically generated from public (personal) data to further our legitimate goal of comprehensive and accurate scientific recordkeeping. If you are this author and want this page removed, please let us know.

Publications (294)


An illustration of the structure of the catastrophe avoidance game. At the start of the game, $40 is credited to the personal account of each player (N = 6). In the certainty treatment, players are instructed that the threshold is $120, whereas in the uncertainty, warning-wide and warning-narrow treatments, players are told the threshold is a uniform random value between $0 and $240, but they will not know the actual value of the threshold until the end of the game. In each of the 10 rounds, R⁣1−10, each player must decide simultaneously and independently whether to contribute $0, $2 or $4 from their personal account into a damage prevention account. At the start of round 1—and again in round 6—players simultaneously and independently submit two non-binding announcements before making their contribution decision. First, each player submits a ‘proposal’ regarding the target level of contributions the group should aim for by round 10, and the average of these proposals becomes the agreed collective target. Next, each player submits a ‘pledge’ regarding the total amount that they will personally contribute across the 10 rounds toward reaching the agreed collective target. In the warning-wide and warning-narrow treatments, before players submit their second set of non-binding proposals in round 6, they are instructed that the uncertainty about the threshold has reduced and that the threshold is now a uniform random value between $84 and $156 (warning wide) or $108 and $132 (warning narrow). At the end of the game, the contributions in the damage prevention account are compared with the known (certainty treatment) or randomly chosen (uncertainty, warning-wide and warning-narrow treatments) threshold. In the uncertainty treatments, the computer determines the exact threshold amount by drawing a random number from a uniform distribution either over the interval [0, 240] (uncertainty treatment), [84, 156] (warning-wide treatment) or [108, 132] (warning-narrow treatment). If the total contributions equal or exceed the threshold, then the damage is avoided, and players get to keep the remaining contents of their personal accounts; otherwise, they lose 90% of their remaining funds.
Contributions in the catastrophe avoidance game as a function of the four treatments. (a) Average group contributions in the first (rounds 1−5) and second (rounds 6−10) halves of the game (error bars represent standard errors). (b) Average group contributions as a function of each individual round of the game.
Probability of avoiding catastrophe as a function of the four treatments. (a) Percentage of groups avoiding catastrophe for various hypothetical threshold values. (b) Probability of avoiding catastrophe per group (denoted by the dots) and average catastrophe avoidance probability by treatment (denoted by the bars) after taking stochastic uncertainty into account.
Average group proposals, pledges and contributions as a function of the four treatments.
Threshold uncertainty, early warning signals and the prevention of dangerous climate change
  • Article
  • Full-text available

March 2025

·

3 Reads

Royal Society Open Science
Mark J. Hurlstone

·

Ben White

·

Ben R. Newell

The goal of the Paris Agreement is to keep global temperature rise well below 2°C. In this agreement—and its antecedents negotiated in Copenhagen and Cancun—the fear of crossing a dangerous climate threshold is supposed to serve as the catalyst for cooperation among countries. However, there are deep uncertainties about the location of the threshold for dangerous climate change, and recent evidence indicates this threshold uncertainty is a major impediment to collective action. Early warning signals of approaching climate thresholds are a potential remedy to this threshold uncertainty problem, and initial experimental evidence suggests such early detection systems may improve the prospects of cooperation. Here, we provide a direct experimental assessment of this early warning signal hypothesis. Using a catastrophe avoidance game, we show that large initial—and subsequently unreduced—threshold uncertainty undermines cooperation, consistent with earlier studies. An early warning signal that reduced uncertainty to within 10% (but not 30%) of the threshold value catalysed cooperation and reduced the probability of catastrophe occurring, albeit not reliably so. Our findings suggest early warning signals can trigger action to avoid a dangerous threshold, but additional mechanisms may be required to foster the cooperation needed to ensure the threshold is not breached.

Download




Can Cognitive Discovery Be Incentivized With Money?

January 2025

·

13 Reads

·

1 Citation

Journal of Experimental Psychology General

The ability to discover patterns or rules from our experiences is critical to science, engineering, and art. In this article, we examine how much people’s discovery of patterns can be incentivized by financial rewards. In particular, we investigate a classic category learning task for which the effect of financial incentives is unknown (Shepard et al., 1961). Across five experiments, we find no effect of incentive on rule discovery performance. However, in a sixth experiment requiring category recognition but not learning, we find a large effect of incentives on response time and a small effect on task performance. Participants appear to apply more effort in valuable contexts, but the effort is disproportionate with the performance improvement. Taken together, the results suggest that performance in tasks that require novel inductive insights is relatively immune to financial incentives, while tasks that require rote perseverance of a fixed strategy are more malleable.


Nudges for people who think

January 2025

·

11 Reads

Psychonomic Bulletin & Review

The naiveté of the dominant ‘cognitive-miser’ metaphor of human thinking hampers theoretical progress in understanding how and why subtle behavioural interventions—‘nudges’—could work. We propose a reconceptualization that places the balance in agency between, and the alignment of representations held by, people and choice architects as central to determining the prospect of observing behaviour change. We argue that two aspects of representational (mis)alignment are relevant: cognitive (how people construe the factual structure of a decision environment) and motivational (the importance of a choice to an individual). Nudging thinkers via the alignment of representations provides a framework that offers theoretical and practical advances and avoids disparaging people’s cognitive capacities.


Learning the Lie of the Land: How People Construct Mental Representations of Distributions

December 2024

·

15 Reads

·

3 Citations

Journal of Experimental Psychology Learning Memory and Cognition

An unexamined assumption in many studies of learning and decision making is that people learn underlying probability distributions. However, the acquisition of distributional knowledge is rarely the focus of investigations. We report five experiments (N = 580 adults) that provide this focus and highlight the factors that impact people’s ability to accurately learn and reproduce underlying distributions. We find that people accurately reproduced the distribution only when either the environmental signal is strong (e.g., discrete bimodal distributions) or sufficient cues are provided to aid construction of mental representations (e.g., items from the modes in a noisy bimodal distribution are presented in different colors). We interpret these results in terms of participants testing and learning discrete rules corresponding to salient features of the environment rather than spontaneously representing entire distributions. As such, the findings challenge strong assumptions about the role of probability distribution knowledge in explanations of learning and decision making.


Risk, Time, and Psychological Distance: Does Construal Level Theory Capture the Impact of Delay on Risk Preference?

December 2024

·

34 Reads

Journal of Experimental Psychology General

Do people change their preferences when they are offered the same risky lotteries at different times (now vs. the future)? Construal level theory (CLT) suggests that people do because our mental representation of events is moderated by how near or distant such events are in time. According to CLT, in the domain of risk preferences, psychological distance causes payoffs and probabilities to be differentially weighted or attended between present and future timepoints: Temporal distance increases the influence of payoffs and decreases the influence of probabilities. Specifically, CLT predicts that high probability/low amount lotteries (i.e., %-lotteries) are preferred in the present, whereas low probability/high amount lotteries (i.e., $-lotteries) are preferred in the future, even when the expected value of these lotteries is identical. We present a functional characterization and systematic investigation of this putative pattern of risk preferences and develop a formal model that incorporates CLT’s predictions. In five experiments, we examined several factors that could moderate the effect (e.g., outcome and probability magnitude, lottery presentation format, incentivization procedures). Both our behavioral observations and modeling results suggest the effect is labile, and if it does occur, it is not fully consistent with our formal model of CLT.


Investigating the trust gap between scientists and climate scientists in 68 countries

November 2024

·

332 Reads

·

·

·

[...]

·

Public trust in scientists may be essential for widespread acceptance of science-based solutions to societal problems, including climate change. Across 68 countries (N = 69,534), individuals expressed less trust in climate scientists than scientists in general. In most countries and overall, conservative political orientation was more strongly associated with lower trust in climate scientists than with trust in scientists in general.



Ad

Citations (34)


... Additionally, studies have shown that performance in high-level cognitive tasks, such as tasks that require learning, is relatively immune to financial incentive, in contrast to tasks that require a fixed strategy [43]. This result rises the question of how motivation might impact performance in Maze Search, suggesting that increasing motivation could lead to faster reaction times in people who use heuristics, but is unlikely to impact the depth to which people plan. ...

Reference:

Approximate planning in spatial search
Can Cognitive Discovery Be Incentivized With Money?

Journal of Experimental Psychology General

... Considering people to be "intuitive scientists" puts the focus on the process of how representations are generated and not on a particular kind of complex representation (Szollosi & Newell, 2020;Szollosi, Donkin, & Newell, 2022). From this perspective, understanding how people develop relatively simple representationssuch as of integer numbers (Carey & Barner, 2019) or of the frequency of various events (Mason, Szollosi, & Newell, 2022)can provide a useful starting point by enabling clearer ways to measure or manipulate the range of factors that Johnson et al. (rightly) claim play into any decision. ...

Learning the Lie of the Land: How People Construct Mental Representations of Distributions

Journal of Experimental Psychology Learning Memory and Cognition

... This interactive online tool allows individuals to assess their personalised risk estimates based on user inputs such as age, sex, and transmission intensity 21 . Here, we respond to public interest in the additional outcome of long COVID indicated by user testing and evaluation of the earlier model 22 , and built on this framework to develop an online tool to estimate the probability of long COVID after SARS-CoV-2 infection based on known risk factors. ...

Using health literacy principles to improve understanding of evolving evidence in health emergencies: Optimisation and evaluation of a COVID-19 vaccination risk-benefit calculator
  • Citing Article
  • September 2024

Vaccine

... To mitigate this problem in future work, such analyses could be supplemented with open-ended exit surveys or concurrent verbal reports, allowing researchers to collect real-time information about the nature of the rules and strategies that participants employ in both the learning and reproduction phases of the task (cf. Ostrovsky & Newell, 2024). ...

Verbal Reports as Data Revisited: Using Natural Language Models to Validate Cognitive Models

Decision

... Labeling these different strategiesmemorization and rule testing-as indicative of Type 1 and Type 2 processing, respectively, is common but, to our minds, does not add explanatory value in this particular instance. While we cannot directly rule out a dual-process account with our data (in part because of the inherent flexibility of such theories; Newell & Shanks, 2023), we leave the pursuit of experimental designs that could provide unequivocal support for such an interpretation to future research. ...

Open Minded: Searching for Truth about the Unconscious Mind
  • Citing Book
  • August 2023

... There is increasing recognition that behavioural change techniques can help to embed sustainable practices [6]. Simple frameworks such as COM-B (capability, opportunity, motivationbehaviour) can assist residents in strategising how best to advance the sustainability agenda. ...

Behavioural change interventions encouraging clinicians to reduce carbon emissions in clinical activity: a systematic review

BMC Health Services Research

... Recently, suboptimal choice has been the focus of renewed interest and a growing variety of theoretical perspectives (e.g., Ajuwon et al., 2023;Anselme, 2022Anselme, , 2023Daniels & Sanabria, 2018;González et al., 2020;Iigaya et al., 2016;McDevitt et al., 2016;Orduña & Alba, 2020;Vasconcelos et al., 2015;Zentall, 2016). Moreover, the tendency to choose options that provide signals for reward (noninstrumental information seeking) is increasingly of interest in neuroscience, cognitive science, and reinforcement learning (Blanchard et al., 2015;Bromberg-Martin & Monosov, 2020;FitzGibbon et al., 2020;Liew, Embrey, & Newell, 2023b;Rodriguez Cabrero et al., 2019). ...

The non-unitary nature of information preference

Psychonomic Bulletin & Review

... For example, a common approach is to directly ask individuals how curious they are about a particular outcome (e.g., Bromberg-Martin & Hikosaka, 2009Charpentier et al., 2018;Jezzini et al., 2021;Kelly & Sharot, 2021;Kobayashi & Hsu, 2019;Liew et al., 2022;van Lieshout et al., 2018;Vasconcelos et al., 2015). Another approach is to ask participants how much of a particular commodity they are willing to sacrifice in return for noninstrumental information-for example, food (Embrey et al., 2020), water (Blanchard et al., 2015), time (Iigaya et al., 2016), money (Bennett et al., 2016;Brydevall et al., 2018;Cabrero et al., 2019), effort (Goh et al., 2021), or even pain . Such studies have clearly demonstrated the utility of non-instrumental information, but in the context of decisions that are solely about the properties of the information itself. ...

Do you want to know a secret? The role of valence and delay in early information preference

... Despite the ubiquity of effort expenditure, subjective experiences of mental effort remain somewhat of a mystery. Sometimes, difficult tasks feel effortful and aversive, leading to avoidance when individuals are given the choice (Embrey et al., 2023;Kool & Botvinick, 2018;Kool et al., 2010;Westbrook et al., 2013). However, not all effort-demanding tasks necessarily feel effortful. ...

Is all mental effort equal? The role of cognitive demand-type on effort avoidance
  • Citing Article
  • March 2023

Cognition

... AGF peer facilitators, both of whom worked as physicians on general medicine and hospitalist wards, helped advance the agenda towards planning for change. This is consistent with the emphasis on facilitation by a respected peer with an understanding of the contextual nuances of the topic that is described by the CAFF for inperson AGF sessions [33,34]. Our peer facilitators shared their own reports to discuss its implications on their practice as a motivator to facilitate sustainable change in established behaviour of colleagues [11,33]. ...

Nudge interventions to reduce unnecessary antibiotic prescribing in primary care: a systematic review

BMJ Open