Amitai Aviram’s research while affiliated with Illinois College and other places

What is this page?


This page lists works of an author who doesn't have a ResearchGate profile or hasn't added the works to their profile yet. It is automatically generated from public (personal) data to further our legitimate goal of comprehensive and accurate scientific recordkeeping. If you are this author and want this page removed, please let us know.

Publications (13)


Cyclical Market Power
  • Article

April 2003

·

20 Reads

SSRN Electronic Journal

Amitai Aviram

Market power is not ubiquitous; it is limited to certain products, in certain areas, and to certain times. Understanding the limits of the market power possessed by a firm in a given case is essential to the correct assessment of the firm's behavior and its antitrust implications. The most common method used to identify the scope as well as the strength of a firm's market power is through the definition of relevant markets, calculation of market share and identification of relevant market conditions (e.g., barriers to entry). Correct assessment of suspected market power should relate to all the limits on that power. For that reason, when exploring the possibility that a certain firm possesses market power, a product market definition is of limited use without the support of the relevant geographic market definition. This is also true of temporal restraints on market power. Some firms may be expected to possess market power (within certain product and geographical bounds) continuously, until a substantial and unexpected change in the industry diminishes their market power or changes its boundaries.


Non-Spontaneous Evolution of Private Legal Systems

March 2003

·

5 Reads

Scholarship on private legal systems (PLS) explains the evolution of norms created and enforced by PLSs, but rarely addresses the evolution of institutions that form PLSs. Such institutions are assumed to form spontaneously (unless suppressed by law) when law is either unresponsive or incapable of directing behavior in welfare-maximizing manners. But, as this paper demonstrates, PLSs typically cannot form spontaneously. Newly formed PLSs cannot enforce cooperation since the effectiveness of mechanisms used to secure this cooperation (e.g., the threat of exclusion) depends on the PLS's ability to confer benefits to its members, and newly formed PLSs do not yet confer such benefits. Successful PLSs bypass this barrier by building on extant foundations - preexisting institutions that already benefit members, typically through functions requiring less costly enforcement. The threat of losing preexisting benefits disciplines members to abide by the PLSs' rules, which in turn allows the PLSs to regulate behavior. This pattern indicates that rather than developing spontaneously, PLSs develop in phases, initially facilitating activities that are unrelated to regulating behavior and incur lower enforcement costs, the provision of which enables the PLS to regulate behavior in the second stage.


Regulation by Networks

March 2003

·

18 Reads

·

121 Citations

SSRN Electronic Journal

The private ordering literature examines how nongovernment institutions mitigate opportunistic behavior in transactions. It emphasizes two elements that facilitate cooperation and reduce opportunism: repeated play and reputation. This paper explores the implications of a third element: network effects. Network effects create an incentive for a unique form of opportunism that exists only in network environments - degradation. On the other hand, network effects facilitate mechanisms that may be very effective in mitigating opportunism. Therefore, in certain industries, networks mitigate opportunism, largely displacing in that role the parties to the transaction and the government. This paper identifies mechanisms used by networks to reduce opportunism, and market characteristics that are conducive to the effectiveness of these mechanisms (and therefore to the efficiency of networks as regulators). This helps explain the prevalence of networks in certain markets as compared to others, and gives tools to assess networks' ability to self-regulate and anticipate the type of opportunism that is more likely to plague a given environment.


Citations (7)


... The current study investigates a potential conflict of interest faced by corporate directors that has implications for risk management, corporate governance, ethics and law. This conflict, termed bias arbitrage, occurs when agents attempt to extract personal benefit from principals" misperceptions of risk (Aviram 2007). For example, if shareholders (principals) perceive that the risk of financial reporting fraud is 1%, but directors (agents) estimate that the probable risk 1 of financial reporting fraud is 0.01%, the directors can personally benefit from publicly announcing new programs ostensibly designed to reduce the probable risk of fraud. ...

Reference:

Will Corporate Directors Engage in Economically Harmful Bias Arbitrage?
Bias Arbitrage
  • Citing Article
  • September 2006

... 414 An illustration of such a situation was given by Aviram. 415 He explains that if two individuals were caught for robbing a bank, without being able to talk to one another prior to a criminal court's decision and both individuals were given two options, namely to betray the other person or not to talk at all, either party will choose the option that minimalizes his risk to go to prison, even though this would go against the common interest. Aviram exemplifies this by using the following three options that can, but do not necessarily, result in a prison sentence. ...

A Paradox of Spontaneous Formation: The Evolution of Private Legal Systems
  • Citing Article
  • February 2005

... the Conflict Commission rests in its ability to integrate existing norms and practices into a new adjudicative body. Though it represents a formalized institutional body within the bazaar, the Commission relies on the informal practices that have long permeated the bazaar, including social networks that regulate the behavior of exchangers through the dual threats of reputational damage and social ostracism (Aviram 2003). As Roderick Macdonald (2013, 316) writes, these "informal, unwritten rules are significant not just because they are evidence of the 'law in action' but also because they are resources from which explicit, written rules typically draw their power and content." ...

Regulation by Networks
  • Citing Article
  • March 2003

SSRN Electronic Journal

... In this way, while IR scholars have suggested that non-state actors are part of normmaking processes, the literature on cyber norms often maintains a focus on the role of states (Kuebris and Badiei 2017). For the purposes of this paper, taking for granted this notion of cyber norms is particularly problematic in the sense that it discounts the participation of a wider spectrum of actors, namely private actors (Aviram 2004). This section thus focuses on the role of private companies in setting norms within cybersecurity. ...

Network Responses to Network Threats: The Evolution Into Private Cyber-Security Associations
  • Citing Article
  • July 2004

SSRN Electronic Journal

... Therefore, the argument can be made that SIS may be associated with human behavior. Indeed, prior research argues that the understanding of SIS requires an analysis of what behavior may motivate humans to participate in SIS and what may deter them from doing so [8,10]. ...

Overcoming Impediments to Information Sharing
  • Citing Article
  • October 2010

SSRN Electronic Journal