ArticlePDF Available

Abstract and Figures

The reform of the Colombian health sector in 1993 was founded on the internationally advocated paradigm of privatization of health care delivery. Taking into account the lack of empirical evidence for the applicability of this concept to developing countries and the documented experience of failures in other countries, Colombia tried to overcome these problems by a theoretically sound, although complicated, model. Some ten years after the implementation of "Law 100," a review of the literature shows that the proposed goals of universal coverage and equitable access to high-quality care have not been reached. Despite an explosion in costs and a considerable increase in public and private health expenditure, more than 40 percent of the population is still not covered by health insurance, and access to health care proves uncreasingly difficult. Furthermore, key health indicators and disease control programs have deteriorated. These findings confirm the results in other middle- and low-income countries. The authors suggest the explanation lies in the inefficiency of contracting-out, the weak economic, technical, and political capacity of the Colombian government for regulation and control, and the absence of real participation of the poor in decision-making on (health) policies.
Content may be subject to copyright.
The Consequences of Neoliberalism
COLOMBIA: IN VIVO TEST OF HEALTH
SECTOR PRIVATIZATION IN THE
DEVELOPING WORLD
Tony De Groote, Pierre De Paepe,
and Jean-Pierre Unger
The reform of the Colombian health sector in 1993 was founded on the
internationally advocated paradigm of privatization of health care delivery.
Taking into account the lack of empirical evidence for the applicability
of this concept to developing countries and the documented experience of
failures in other countries, Colombia tried to overcome these problems by
a theoretically sound, although complicated, model. Some ten years after
the implementation of “Law 100,” a review of the literature shows that the
proposed goals of universal coverage and equitable access to high-quality
care have not been reached. Despite an explosion in costs and a considerable
increase in public and private health expenditure, more than 40 percent of the
population is still not covered by health insurance, and access to health
care proves uncreasingly difficult. Furthermore, key health indicators and
disease control programs have deteriorated. These findings confirm the results
in other middle- and low-income countries. The authors suggest the explan
-
ation lies in the inefficiency of contracting-out, the weak economic, technical,
and political capacity of the Colombian government for regulation and
control, and the absence of real participation of the poor in decision-making
on (health) policies.
Privatization of health care delivery in developing countries received support from
virtually all international aid agencies (1–3). Expressions such as “stewardship”
and “steering rather than rowing,” used in policy documents on the global agenda
for health sector reform from the World Bank and the World Health Organization
(WHO) (4, 5), allude to the desired characteristics of this new public-private
partnership. The recommendation that clinical care delivery be contracted out to
International Journal of Health Services, Volume 35, Number 1, Pages 125–141, 2005
© 2005, Baywood Publishing Co., Inc.
125
private for-profit organizations, while Ministry of Health first-line facilities limit
their field of operations to disease control, changes the role of the public sector to
provide less and control more. Article 1.3(c) of the World Trade Organization
(WTO) General Agreement on Trade in Services could even be interpreted as
prohibiting the provision of health care services that are not related to disease
control programs within subsidized government health services. The current wave
of sector reforms is underpinned by seductive theoretical arguments (6). However,
there is a lack of empirical evidence that in developing countries, private for-profit
health care companies and providers can deliver high-quality care that covers
entire populations (7).
Colombia is probably one of the rare developing countries that has adopted
contracting-out as the key paradigm of its national health care policy and com
-
mitted a sufficient budget to health care, with an increase in national budget
allocated to health from 3.5 percent of GDP in 1993 to 5.5 percent in 1999 (8).
This article examines evidence in the published and the “gray” literature to
assess whether health care privatization in Colombia has managed to (a) improve
insurance coverage, (b) improve access to and utilization of health services,
(c) improve the health status of the population, and (d) control health expendi-
tures growth. It goes on to look at the mechanisms involved and relates these
findings to the country’s health policy.
FEATURES OF COLOMBIA’S
REFORM
Reform of the health sector in Colombia started in the 1980s with a process
of political, fiscal, and administrative decentralization. This was followed by
the implementation of Law 100 in 1993, which resulted in a general system of
social health security with two main features: purchaser-provider split and
contracting-out. The separate effects of decentralization and Law 100 are some
-
times difficult to distinguish because “at times they are synergic and at other times
antagonistic” (9). Nevertheless, correlation over time can give an inkling of the
causal effect of one of these reform processes.
Law 100 provided the legal framework for the creation of a decentralized
social health insurance with universal coverage, based on the principles of
equity, solidarity, efficiency, quality, and community participation. This
ambitious proposal was made possible by petroleum discovery, providing
the financial capacity to introduce a “Big R” reform (10). Two systems
were created:
The contributory system for those who can afford it, mainly the formally
employed, who contribute 12 percent of their salary for health insurance. The
Health Promoting Enterprises (HPE; Empresas Promotores de Salud, EPS)
receive a premium per capita, adjusted according to age, sex, and geographic
126 / De Groote, De Paepe, and Unger
location. The Obligatory Health Plan, managed by the HPE, covers a complete
package of health interventions.
The subsidized system, which covers the rest of the population. Funding
is obtained by an input from the contributory system and by government
subsidies. The capitation fee, and the accompanying package of services
offered, was arbitrarily fixed at 50 percent of the value of the contributory
system. Subsidized System Administrators (SSA; Administradores de
Regimen Subsidiado, ARS) are responsible for the management of this
scheme.
It was foreseen that by 2001 the benefits in the subsidized scheme would equal
those of the obligatory plan of the contributory system (11).
A national survey (Sistema de Selección de Beneficiarios a Programas Sociales
del gobierno, SISBEN) assessed the socioeconomic status of the population
and categorized it in six strata (1 being the poorest, 6 the richest). Those belong-
ing to strata 3 to 6 would join the contributory system, and the subsidized system
accommodated strata 1 and 2. This was the theory. In practice, 13.7 percent
of the non-poor were in the subsidized system and 10.7 percent of the poor
population was registered in the contributory system (12). Health care delivery
institutions (HCDI; Instituciones Prestadores de Servicios de Salud, IPS) and
the autonomous former public hospitals and health centers (Empresas Sociales
del Estado, ESE) were contracted by the insurance entities for health service
delivery. HPE, SSA, and HCDI could be public or private or mixed, and for-profit
or not-for-profit.
The state assumed a steering role of policy formulation, monitoring, and
evaluation, freeing itself quasi-completely from directly offering services. Excep
-
tions were activities with high externalities (mainly disease control programs) and
health care delivery for the uninsured (the vinculados). Managed competition
between public and private providers of care, with free choice of insurer by the
population, would safeguard the quality and efficiency of health care. In practice,
the provider was chosen by the insurer, limiting people’s freedom to choose a
provider to an indirect option.
INSURANCE COVERAGE
Two achievements were claimed to illustrate the success of the Colombian
health reform:
A considerable advance in social insurance coverage following the health
sector reform. Health insurance almost doubled between 1992 and 1997, from
26 to 52 percent of the population (13) (Figure 1).
A growth in health insurance coverage that was highest among the poor:
coverage in the poorest 10 percent of the population rose from 4 to 41 percent
Health Sector Privatization in Colombia / 127
between 1992 and 1997, a tenfold increase, whereas the increase among the
richest 10 percent was from 65 to 80 percent (13).
1
Let’s assess these claims. First, although before the reform 69 percent of the
population did not have any form of insurance, this does not imply that they did
not receive medical treatment. The reform entailed a shift from a supply-oriented
model (without the need to register) to a demand-oriented model (14). According
to the National Household Survey (Encuesta Nacional de Hogares) of 1992, dating
from before the reform, 81 percent of the population claimed to have access to
health services (15).
Another issue is equity in insurance coverage. Most poor people were not
covered by the pre-reform health insurance, which was mainly for the officially
employed. The tenfold increase in coverage from 4 to 41 percent for the poorest
10 percent of the population differs greatly from the progress among the richest
10 percent (from 65 to 80 percent), but insurance coverage among the poor is
128 / De Groote, De Paepe, and Unger
Figure 1. Evolution of health insurance coverage, 1993–2002, as percentage. Source:
G. Rivero, Ministerio de Salud de Colombia, Pan American Health Organization,
Diez años de la reforma a la seguridad social de salud en Colombia (1993–2003).
www.isapre.cl/seminarios/SeminarioColombia/Dr_Riveros.ppt.
1
Most information is derived from two national surveys: the National Household Survey (Encuesta
Nacional de Hogares) of 1992 with data from the pre-reform period, and the National Quality of Life
Survey of 1997, conducted three years after implementation of the reform. Much of our discussion
therefore compares the 1992 and 1997 situations.
still only half that of the rich. Furthermore, only one-quarter of the newly insured
entered the subsidized system, while the rest enrolled in the contributory scheme
(13). The largest share of expansion of enrollment in the contributory system was
due to incorporation of family members and dependents of those previously
covered by the social security regime—an increase in family coverage from
18 percent of members to 100 percent (16). This increase was thus not accom
-
panied by an increase in revenues from contributions, as these still consisted of
12 percent of the salary of those officially employed.
In fact, the curve depicting the evolution of the percentage of people enrolled
shows a stagnating trend over several years (see Figure 1). More than 40 percent of
the population remains without health insurance—more than 16 million people.
These vinculados receive treatment in public hospitals against a payment of
30 percent of the actual cost, as a continuation of the pre-reform supply-oriented
model. Most of these people are in the lower income groups. Figure 2 shows
the distribution of these vinculados over the different income groups. This dis-
tribution casts doubt on the process of equity, as the difference in improve-
ment between the lowest and highest income groups is less impressive and the
coverage increase is similar across income percentiles. For example, in income
percentile 1, the percentage of uninsured diminished 37 percent, and in per-
centile 10 dropped 35 percent (15). The largest proportion of uninsured popu-
lation—the challenge to achieving universal coverage—remains in the lowest
income groups.
The number of persons enrolled in a health insurance scheme has stagnated
at around 55 percent since 1998 (Figure 1). Twenty-five percent of the two
Health Sector Privatization in Colombia / 129
Figure 2. Percentage of uninsured (vinculados) as function of income percentile, 1992
and 1997. Source: Colombia Country Management Unit, PREM Sector Management Unit
(13). Graphed by authors.
richest deciles remain outside these schemes, because they have the means to
opt for private insurance, thus avoiding responsibility for solidarity. Furthermore,
two-thirds of those eligible have not enrolled in the subsidized system, although
their enrollment is free. The lack of information available to the poor, the prime
target group of the reform mechanisms, has sometimes been invoked to explain
this (17). But ten years after implementation of Law 100, this is unlikely. Even
if the government and insurance companies were not duly informing people,
information would have spread by word of mouth if the health services were
providing effective, affordable care. Rather, the failure to interest the poorest
Colombians could be rooted in the reform process itself.
While Law 100, Article 153, states that “the General Social Health Insurance
System will gradually provide health services of equal quality to all the inhabitants
of Colombia, independent of their capacity to pay,” the creation of two different
systems runs counter to this objective. Insufficient solidarity between rich and
poor, reflected in the financing schemes, results in a package of services for
the subsidized system that is generally only half of a reference standard of
what is possible and necessary in Colombia—that is, the package of the contribu-
tory scheme (18). For instance, hospitalization in an internal medicine ward or
follow-up for chronic diseases—which typify the epidemiological transition—
are excluded from the subsidized package (e.g., diabetes; cardiovascular diseases
other than hypertension). The reluctance of those in the poorest percentiles
to enroll in the subsidized system might reflect a refusal of such a package—even
if fashioned along a cost-effectiveness rationale. An additional explanation—
cream-skimming (risk selection)—could be invoked if data on insurance coverage
of the poor by private companies were available (we did not have access to
such data).
It has been argued that only those with full insurance coverage should
be counted when determining enrollment rate (18). Those with half the
package (in the subsidized system) cannot really be considered insured, as they
are entitled only to essential clinical services, some surgical interventions, and
the treatment of catastrophic diseases (14). This is important, as the law
foresaw an equal health plan for all. In practice, the health plan of the sub
-
sidized system has never exceeded 70 percent of the contributory system
package (19).
Finally, insurance coverage was overestimated because of multiple enrollments.
In a survey in March 2000, 2.3 percent of the population (500,000 people)
declared that they held more than one insurance card. People enroll with different
insurance companies with the futile idea of getting better care—although all
companies offer the same legal package. Further distortion of insurance estimates
may be related to the fact that some names are not immediately erased from
an insurance list while the individuals are changing insurer or losing their job
(14). This frequent practice permits insurers to obtain the full capitation fee
while providing a fraction of the required care.
130 / De Groote, De Paepe, and Unger
ACCESS TO AND USE OF HEALTH SERVICES
What does “enrollment in a health insurance plan” really mean? Basically nothing
more than a person holding an insurance card. Indeed, several obstacles keep
cardholders from accessing health care services (17):
Some insurance companies have declared persons or families, especially
the poor, to be registered for their scheme without issuing an insurance
card, thus collecting premiums without providing service.
The poor are frequently unaware of their rights. They do not know how to
use their insurance card, and they continue to pay for the services they receive.
Sometimes, they simply do not use the services because of a lack of psycho
-
logical, intra-institutional, financial (see below), or geographic accessibility.
Investigations about enrollment are abundant because data are easy to obtain,
but evidence on actual access to care is rare, and data on real utilization of the
health services even more so.
A comparison of pre-reforrn 1992 National Household Survey with 1997
National Quality of Life Survey data suggests an improvement in access to care
in absolute numbers. However, when converted to the percentage of population
covered by health insurance who report receiving treatment when sick, the
comparison reveals a reduction of 3 percent (13). This lower treatment rate
may in part be attributable to the larger demands placed on the system.
Other proxies permit one to indirectly assess access to care:
High percentages of death without diagnosis are typical of poor municipalities
with a high prevalence of unsatisfied basic needs. In Colombia, institutionally
certified mortality is higher in the richer municipalities: 50.5 percent for
stratum 6, according to unsatisfied basic needs, versus 28.6 percent for
stratum 1 (12).
Yearly doctor utilization rate: before the reform, 61.7 percent of people
needing health care were actually seen by a doctor. In 2000, this proportion
had fallen to 51.1 percent (13, 20).
Copayments—meant to put a limit on demand related to moral hazard—can
also limit access to health care (21). Admittedly, in 1992, 51 percent of patients did
not consult a doctor because they lacked the money to do so (1992 National
Household Survey), versus 41 percent in 1997 (17). But this is certainly not an
impressive gain, even if the data are reliable despite different methodologies in the
two surveys. Moreover, national rates erase significant geographic fluctuations,
ranging from 29.1 percent in Bogota to 62.2 percent in the poor Atlantic region
(22). In the population without health insurance, finances remained the first
Health Sector Privatization in Colombia / 131
obstacle to consulting a doctor, and for insured persons was the second (perceived
lack of seriousness of the illness was the first) (16).
DISEASE CONTROL AND HEALTH INDICATORS
In the decades preceding reform, Colombia, like most developing countries,
underwent a decrease in most morbidity and mortality indicators. This trend
changed direction in the second half of the 1990s.
Infant mortality rate is known to reflect general social and economic conditions,
not just access to medical care (23). However, child mortality due to acute
respiratory infections and acute diarrheal diseases can be considered avoidable
mortality and these deaths can be used as tracer pathologies for quality of care
(24), also in less developed countries (25). These deaths are clearly on the rise
since 1997 (12). Disorders of the perinatal period, including perinatal mortality,
are also known to be an indicator for access to quality health care. The rate doubled
from 1996 to 1997 and continues to rise (12).
A decline of vaccination coverage was documented both at local (26) and
national levels (22). Between 1990 and 2000, the national coverage for total
vaccination of children below 1 year of age dropped from 67.5 to 52 percent
(20), even more in rural areas (27). This deterioration could be related to exces-
sive emphasis on programs that adhere to an explicit demand (28), difficul-
ties in accessing vaccination services, excessive procedures and documentation
requested by the insurers (26), and decreased budgets (29).
Malaria and tuberculosis control and the Extended Program of Immuniza-
tion (EPI) are vertical disease control programs in Colombia. They form an
important part of the public health functions assumed by the government. Malaria
transmission was on the increase, and the magnitude of the rise cannot be
explained just by better diagnosis and by environmental conditions (El Niño
1997–1998). A decline of protective measures due to the decentralization process
and fragmentation of responsibilities probably contributed to the problem (30).
In line with Pérez (31), data on tuberculosis control can give some insight
into the functioning of the whole Colombian health system, as suspicion of TB
(and often diagnosis) occurs in the private sector while treatment and follow-up
are the responsibility of Ministry of Health services. The steady and progressive
decline in TB incidence reversed trend in 1997 and rose steadily, from 8,042
reported cases in 1997 to 11,261 in 2002 (31). At the same time, the already low
notification rate further deteriorated with the introduction of the social security
system, to reach an all-time low of 20 to 25 percent (see Figure 3). Other studies
have shown a marked decrease in the number of TB patients under treatment (30).
It is difficult to disentangle the numerous determinants of TB incidence,
among them Colombia’s five-year recession and the HIV epidemic. However,
some control programs’ organizational features, related to the Colombian reform,
have probably played a significant role:
132 / De Groote, De Paepe, and Unger
The reform caused fragmentation of responsibilities of the different aspects
of diagnosis, treatment, and follow-up of patients and contacts (30).
Insurance companies and private health care providers are not pre-
pared to spend time and resources on activities that are not rewarded
financially (32, 33). Lack of health care–disease control integration is
known to reduce detection and cure rates while increasing delays for
patients (34).
FINANCING
Health expenditure has skyrocketed since the introduction of managed com
-
petition in Colombia. On theoretical grounds, the trend could have been predicted
as inherent to the system (35). It has also been observed in other countries that
have introduced a system based on a demand-oriented model (36), from the United
States (37) to Lebanon (38) and Vietnam (39).
The efforts of the Colombian government to increase its health care budget did
not prevent private expenditures reaching 45 percent of total health expenditure
in 1999 (more than 60 percent were out-of-pocket payments, the rest mainly
employers’ contributions). This is why, in a list of proportion of households with
catastrophic health expenditure, Colombia ranked fourth out of 60 countries, after
Vietnam, Brazil, and Azerbaijan (40). The cost escalation is probably due to the
financing method. Rise in cost per capita for the contributory system (74 percent
between 1997 and 2002) was comparable to the changes in the subsidized system
Health Sector Privatization in Colombia / 133
Figure 3. Tuberculosis notification rate, 1980–2001, as percentage. Source: WHO,
Global Tuberculosis Control: Surveillance, Planning, Financing, Report 2003, Geneva,
2003.
(88 percent for the same period). By contrast, the cost per capita for those who
continued to be served by a system based on a supply-oriented model (the
vinculados) remained under control between 1997 and 2002, increasing by 36
percent (Figure 4).
Although there was no strict regulation of contracts between providers and
suppliers, there was a tendency to contract general practitioners on salary and to
reimburse specialist and hospital services and procedures on a fee-for-service
basis (41). Such a practice induced overconsumption of expensive care. Figure 5
shows that costs of health care delivery were out of control in the 1990s, prob
-
ably because of this stimulation of high-cost care. Besides, the majority of the
hospitals fulfilled both first- and second-line functions—despite evidence
showing that the costs of handling first-line disorders increase with the
institution’s complexity (42).
Finally, the complex administrative structure has absorbed a substantial
amount of funds (Figure 6). In 2001, 52 percent of the capitation fee was still
spent on administrative costs (14). In 1995, only 10 percent of the resources
assigned to the subsidized system was spent appropriately, the rest was diverted
into bureaucracy costs, frozen in bank accounts, or used in sectors other than
the health sector (28). This finding echoes the comparison between Canada,
which has a health system with a single purchaser and administrative costs
representing 16.7 percent of health expenditure, and the United States, which
has a health system with multiple purchasers and where this share of costs is
31 percent (43).
134 / De Groote, De Paepe, and Unger
Figure 4. Evolution of cost per capita for the contributory and subsidized systems and
the uninsured (“vinculated”), 1997 to 2002. Source: Departamento Nacional de Planeación
et al. (8). Graphed by authors.
Health Sector Privatization in Colombia / 135
Figure 5. Public, private, and total health expenditures, 1993–1999. Source: Ministry
of Health of Colombia et al. (14). Graphed by authors.
Figure 6. Health Promoting Enterprises—EPS: expenditures, 1996–2002. Source:
Ministry of Health of Colombia et al. (14).
DISCUSSION
Can these disappointing outcomes be linked to the reform? Colombia’s prolonged
civil war has frequently been invoked to explain the poor results in the coverage,
cost control, and impact of the health insurance system. In 2001, 190,500 new
refugees were registered in Colombia, bringing the total number of internally
displaced persons (IDPs) to 720,000 (44). Although this number puts Colombia
in the second rank of countries with IDPs, it represents only 1.7 percent of the
total population, far from the target of 40 percent that must be included in the
health insurance scheme to reach universal coverage.
Rather, we believe it is the inefficiency of the reform’s approach, contracting-
out, that has undermined Colombia’s health care reform. Total expenditure on
health as a percentage of GDP stagnated at 3 percent during the period 1990–1995
(45). In 1993, Law 100 was introduced at the behest of international develop
-
ment agencies (46). This process attracted widespread support from sectors with
significant influence on state decision-making, such as senior health managers,
pharmaceutical companies, medical manufacturers, and international health
insurance corporations (47). The Colombian government tried to accommodate
their wishes (48).
This conjunction of interests explains why health care expenditure almost
doubled by 1997, to 5.5 percent (2), while health care coverage remained below
55 percent and actual treatment rates decreased. The World Bank claims that
countries with structural adjustment programs spend more on health through
public provision (49). Hypothetically, in Colombia as in other countries, the
bulk of this “medical inflation” has been channeled to the private sector, the
extent of which remains to be calculated.
The Colombian state has proved unfit to regulate and control the private
sector. Is this a specific or a general feature of middle (and low) income countries?
Let’s examine whether the public authorities in such countries possess the
economic, technical, and political capacity to face this challenge.
First, European governments hold the purse strings; developing countries’
administrations do not. Although the available data are not always reliable, the
public share within total health care expenditure is obviously far greater in western
Europe than in developing countries. Public expenditure as a percentage of
total expenditure on health amounts to 77.5 percent in Germany, 76.9 percent
in France, 96.9 percent in the United Kingdom, and 83.2 percent in Belgium
(2). By contrast, public expenditure on health care represents 54.5 percent in
Colombia, 48.7 percent in Brazil, 24.9 percent in China, 13 percent in India,
36.8 percent in Indonesia, and 28.2 percent in Nigeria. This paucity of funds
also explains why so few developing countries have managed to apply the
demand-side reforms recommended by the World Bank.
Second, as Figueras and Saltman (50) acknowledge, the success of reform
strategies in Europe required “the availability of public health skills to assess
136 / De Groote, De Paepe, and Unger
health needs, evaluate interventions and monitor outcome.” The management
skills required for contracting-out and regulating contractual arrangements seem
well beyond the capacity of many developing countries, including middle-income
countries. One of the few published studies on contracting-out to the private sector
underlines the difficulties encountered in South Africa, a country with a mature
public administration system (51). The author concluded that “these problems are
likely to occur to an even greater extent in countries with less well-developed
systems of administration,” a conclusion shared by the authors of a case study
from Zimbabwe (52).
Efforts by public authorities in the less developed countries to set care standards
among private providers have remained inconclusive (53, 54) or failed (55).
In Europe, as Figueras and Saltman (50) observe, in contrast to supply-side
reforms, “the existing evidence, taken together, appears to indicate that reforms
have been decidedly more fraught—financially, politically, socially, and even
clinically—when undertaken on the demand side, specifically in the application
of market-style incentives to individual patient-based demand. Measures such as
choice of insurer, increased cost sharing at the point of use, or removing services
from the publicly financed package of care have generated both equity and
organisational problems.” These problems are even more acute in developing
countries, where purchasing power is much lower.
Research suggests that contracting-out is an acceptable alternative to public
provision, if the following conditions are met: (a) real competition exists between
competent and substantial private providers, (b) there is adequate government
capacity to assess needs and to negotiate and monitor contract terms, and (c)a
legal and political environment exists that can enforce regulations and resist
patronage and corruption (56). In industrialized countries, it is clear that
“Managed market...success will ultimately depend upon improvements in
the underlying organisation, structure and functioning of the public sector” (57).
Based on these criteria, the only settings in developing countries where monitoring
could be effective are urban centers in a few middle-income countries with
elaborate political and administrative structures and real competition between
providers. Apparently, Colombia is not a member of this club.
Third, the relative success of contracting-out in France, Germany, and Belgium
arose in a particular political and socioeconomic context. Medical costs as a
percentage of GDP are lower in Europe than in the United States, because of
the supply-side cost-sharing. Although the “poorest” still experience problems
of access to health care, they represent only a minority in western Europe. The
main reason why these governments were able to secure access to (private) health
care for the majority is that low-income groups managed to have their interests
defended within the political system. In western Europe, workers’ parties and
mutual aid associations have been included in government health policy planning
and administrations since 1945 and have acted as a counterweight to the vested
interests (58). In Europe, social and health care policies were largely defined by
Health Sector Privatization in Colombia / 137
“the poor” and their representatives, while in the United States and Colombia,
policies for “the poor”—in line with those favored for developing countries by
U.N. agencies—failed to improve social standards and to reduce medical costs.
Health expenditure in the United States as a proportion of GDP is now the highest,
by far, of all industrialized countries.
Unlike in Europe, the poor are rarely represented in the ruling circles of
developing countries and so play little part in shaping health care policies or
setting budgets. The Colombian reform aggravated this situation by undermining
people’s attempts to develop community health services (48). This is a familiar
feature of administrations in developing countries, when a ruling elite uses its
monopoly power to weaken solidarity between rich and poor and so increase
income inequality (59).
In conclusion, the skyrocketing costs linked to the Colombian reform cast
doubts on the efficiency of the new social security system, more so because
the increase in spending is not related to an increase in real access to health
services or to improvement in disease control. The impressive increase in
public and private funds did not prove to be value for money. The Colombian
case seriously undermines claims that the neoliberal international aid policy
is evidence-based.
REFERENCES
1. Human Development Network. Health, Nutrition and Population. Sector Strategy
Paper. World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1997.
2. WHO. The World Health Report 2000—Health Systems: Improving Performance.
Geneva, 2000.
3. COM. Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European
Parliament: Health and Poverty Reduction in Developing Countries, p. 129. Brussels,
2002.
4. Human Development Network. Health, Nutrition and Population. World Bank,
Washington, D.C., 1993.
5. WHO. The World Health Report 1999: Making a Difference. Geneva, 1999.
6. Preker, A. S., Harding, A., and Girishankar, N. The Economics of Private Participation
in Health Care: New Insights from Institutional Economics. World Bank, Washington,
D.C., 1999.
7. Sen, K., and Koivusalo, M. Health care reforms and developing countries—a critical
overview. Int. J. Health Plann. Manage. 13(3): 199–215, 1998.
8. Departamento Nacional de Planeación et al. Proyecto: Cuentas nacionales en salud
de Colombia. Síntesis general: aspectos conceptuales, metodológicos y principales
resultados del periodo 1993-1999. Santafé de Bogotá D.C., 2001.
9. Yepes, F., and Sánchez, L. La reforma del sector de salud en Colombia: ¿un modelo
de competencia regulada? Rev. Panam. Salud Publica 8(1/2): 34–41, 2000.
10. Berman, P., and Bossert, T. A Decade of Health Sector Reform in Developing
Countries: What Have We Learned? DDM Report No. 81, Harvard School of Public
Health, 2000. www.hsph.harvard.edu/ihsg/ihsg.
138 / De Groote, De Paepe, and Unger
11. El Congreso de Colombia. Ley 100 de 1993 100/Art.162, 1993.
12. Pan American Health Organization Program on Organization and Management of
Health Systems and Services, Division of Health Systems and Services Development.
Profile of the Health Services System of Colombia. 2002.
www.lachsr.org/documents/healthsystemprofileofcolombia-EN.pdf.
13. Colombia Country Management Unit, PREM Sector Management Unit. Latin America
and the Caribbean Region. Colombia Poverty Report. World Bank, Washington,
D.C., 2002.
14. Ministerio de Salud de Colombia, Dirección general de Aseguramiento, Organización
Mundial de la Salud, and Organización Panamericana de la Salud. Evaluación integral
del equilibrio financiero del sistema general de seguridad social en salud. Bogotá,
2001.
15. Jaramillo, J. Evaluación de la descentralización de la salud y la reforma de la seguridad
social en Colombia. GAC Sanit. 16(1): 48–53, 2002.
16. Almeida, C., et al. Efectos de la reforma de la seguridad social en salud en Colombia
sobre la equidad en el acceso y la utilización de servicios de salud. Rev. Salud Pública,
Universidad de Antioquia 20: 9–19, 2000.
17. Plaza, B., Barona, A. B., and Hearst, N. Managed competition for the poor or poorly
managed competition? Lessons from the Colombian health reform experience. Health
Policy Plann. 16: 44–51, 2001.
18. Félix, M., Robayo, G., and Valencia, O. Hygeia no es Panacea: Condiciones para
dialogar sobre cobertura de la seguridad social en salud. Rev. Salud Pública 4(2):
103–119, 2002.
19. Hernández, M. Reforma sanitaria, equidad y derecho a la salud en Colombia. Cad
Saúde Pública 18(4): 991–1001, 2002.
20. Yepes, A. The violation of social rights within market rationale. In Social Watch:
Annual Report 2003. Social Watch, Montevideo, Uruguay, 2003.
21. Manning, W. G., et al. Health insurance and the demand for medical care: Evidence
from a randomized experiment. Am. Econ. Rev. 77(3): 251–277, 1987.
22. Profamilia Colombia. Encuesta nacional de demografía y salud (ENDS)—Salud sexual
y reproductiva en Colombia 2000. Bogotá, 2000.
23. Van Lerberghe, W., and De Brouwere, V. Assessment of appropriate child care at
district level: How useful are mortality rates? Trans. R. Soc. Trop. Med. Hyg. 83(1):
23–26, 1989.
24. Rutstein, D. D., et al. Measuring the quality of medical care: A clinical method.
N. Engl. J. Med. 294(11): 582–588, 1976.
25. Westerling, R. Commentary: Evaluating avoidable mortality in developing
countries—An important issue for public health. Int. J. Epidemiol. 30(5): 973–975,
2001.
26. Ayala, C., and Kroeger, A. La reforma del sector salud en Colombia y sus efectos en
los programas de control de tuberculosis e inmunización. Cad Saúde Pública 18(6):
1771–1781, 2002.
27. Málaga, H., et al. Equidad y reforma en salud en Colombia: X Jornadas Colombianas
de Epidemiología. Boletín APS 6(10): 80–98, 2001.
28. Jaramillo, I. El futuro de la salud en Colombia: La puesta en marcha de la ley 100.
Tercer Mundo Editores, Bogotá, 1997.
29. Same as 27.
Health Sector Privatization in Colombia / 139
30. Kroeger, A., Ordonez-Gonzalez, J., and Avina, A. I. Malaria control reinvented: Health
sector reform and strategy development in Colombia. Trop. Med. Int. Health 7(5):
450–458, 2002.
31. Pérez Gilberto, R. La tuberculosis en Colombia: A propósito del Día Mundial de
la Tuberculosis 24 de marzo 1882–2003 (editorial). Rep. Med. Cirugía 12, 2003.
www.medilegis.com/BancoConocimiento/R/RepertorioV12-No2-Editorial/Editorial.htm.
32. Uplekar, M., Pathania, V., and Raviglione, M. Private practitioners and public health:
Weak links in tuberculosis control. Lancet 358(9285): 912–916, 2001.
33. Lonnroth, K., et al. Delay and discontinuity—a survey of TB patients’ search of
a diagnosis in a diversified health care system. Int. J. Tuberc. Lung Dis. 3(11):
992–1000, 1999.
34. Unger, J. P., De Paepe, P., and Green, A. A code of best practice for disease control
programmes to avoid damaging health care services in developing countries. Int.
J. Health Plann. Manage. 18: S27–S39, 2003.
35. Broomberg, J. Managing the health care market in developing countries: Prospects
and problems. Health Policy Plann. 9(3): 237–251, 1994.
36. Labelle, R., Stoddart, G., and Rice, T. A re-examination of the meaning and importance
of supplier-induced demand. J. Health Econ. 13(3): 347–368, 1994.
37. Tabbush, V., and Swanson, G. Changing paradigms in medical payment. Arch. Intern.
Med. 156(4): 357–360, 1996.
38. Van Lerberghe, W., et al. Reform follows failure: I. Unregulated private care in
Lebanon. Health Policy Plann. 12(4): 296–311, 1997.
39. Bloom, G. Primary health care meets the market in China and Vietnam. Health Policy
44(3): 233–252, 1998.
40. Xu, K., et al. Household catastrophic health expenditure: A multicountry analysis.
Lancet 362(9378): 111–117, 2003.
41. Gutiérrez, C., Molina, C., and Wüllner, A. Las formas de contratación entre
prestadores y administradores de salud: Sus perspectivas en el nuevo marco de la
seguridad social. Editora Guadalupe Ltda, Santafé de Bogotá, 1996.
42. Van Lerberghe, W., and Lafort, Y. The Role of the Hospital in the District. SHS Paper
No. 2. WHO/SHS/CC/90.2. World Health Organization, Geneva, 1990.
43. Woolhandler, S., Campbell, T., and Himmelstein, D. U. Health care administration in
the United States and Canada: Micromanagement, macro costs. Int. J. Health Serv.
34(1): 65–78, 2004.
44. UNHCR. Refugees by numbers. 2002.
www.irinnews.org/webspecials/idp/pdfs/unhcr_2002.pdf.
45. World Bank. World Development Report 1998/1999: Knowledge for Development.
Oxford University Press, Washington, D.C., 1999.
46. Bossert, T., et al. Transformation of ministries of health in the era of health reform:
The case of Colombia. Health Policy Plann. 13(1): 59–77, 1998.
47. Stocker, K., Waitzkin, H., and Iriart, C. The exportation of managed care to Latin
America. N. Engl. J. Med. 340(14): 1131–1136, 1999.
48. Restrepo, H. E., and Valencia, H. Implementation of a new health system in Colombia:
Is this favourable for health determinants? J. Epidemiol. Community Health 56(10):
742–743, 2002.
49. van der Gaag, J., and Barham, T. Health and health expenditures in adjusting and
non-adjusting countries. Soc. Sci. Med. 46(8): 995–1009, 1998.
140 / De Groote, De Paepe, and Unger
50. Figueras, J., and Saltman, R. B. Building upon comparative experience in health
system reform. Eur. J. Public Health 8: 99–101, 1998.
51. Mills, A. Improving the efficiency of public sector health services in developing
countries: Bureaucratic versus market approaches. In Marketizing Education and
Health in Developing Countries: Miracle or Mirage? ed. C. Colclough. Clarendon
Press, Oxford, 1997.
52. McPake, B., and Hongoro, C. Contracting out of clinical services in Zimbabwe.
Soc. Sci. Med. 41(1): 13–24, 1995.
53. Brugha, R., and Zwi, A. Improving the quality of private sector delivery of public
health services: Challenges and strategies. Health Policy Plann. 13(2): 107–120, 1998.
54. Paredes, P., et al. Factors influencing physicians’ prescribing behaviour in the treat
-
ment of childhood diarrhoea: Knowledge may not be the clue. Soc. Sci. Med. 42(8):
1141–1153, 1996.
55. Kumaranayake. L. The role of regulation: Influencing private sector activity within
health sector reform. J. Int. Dev. 9(4): 641–649, 1997.
56. Mills, A. To contract or not to contract? Issues for low and middle income countries.
Health Policy Plann. 13(1): 32–40, 1998.
57. Broomberg, J. Health Care Markets for Export? Lessons for Developing Countries
from European and American Experience. LSHTM, London, 1994.
58. Criel, B., and Van Dormael, M. Mutual health organizations in Africa and social health
insurance systems: Will European history repeat itself? (editorial). Trop. Med. Int.
Health 4(3): 155–159, 1999.
59. Haubert, M., Frelin, C., and Leimdorfer, F. Etats et société dans le tiers-monde: De
la modernisation à la démocratisation? Publications de la Sorbonne, Paris, 1992.
Direct reprint requests to:
Prof. Dr. Jean-Pierre Unger
Institute of Tropical Medicine
Prince Leopold
Nationalestraat 155
2000 Antwerpen
Belgium
e-mail: jpunger@itg.be
Health Sector Privatization in Colombia / 141
... For instance, critical infrastructure systems around the world have been transferred from public authorities to private actors. This has often compromised social inclusion, for example, by limiting access to healthcare for lower income groups in Europe and South America [151][152][153] . Similarly, the management of local infrastructure services, such as water supply, by transnational corporations has increased social inequities and negative ecological impacts [154][155][156][157] . ...
Article
Full-text available
Cities have grown rapidly—while they provide opportunities for many, they must also confront pervasive and rising inequality, unsustainable consumption, and growing vulnerability to the impacts of climate change. Recent research emphasizes the need to improve urban resilience and sustainability in the face of climate change, but offers circumscribed approaches that mostly focus on either (1) resource management and service provision, (2) social processes and capacities for transformation, or (3) governance and power relations among actors. Here, we embrace the emerging approach that considers urban areas as interdependent social-ecological-technological systems (SETS) and consider the implications for sustainable service provision; the role of bottom-up efforts in initiating urban transformations; and how governance may, under certain conditions, coordinate these efforts to effect broader change.
Chapter
International health and aid policies of the past two decades have had a major impact on the delivery of care in low and middle-income countries. This book argues that these policies have often failed to achieve their main aims, and have in fact contributed to restricted access to family medicine and hospital care. Presenting detailed evidence, and illustrated by case studies, this book describes how international health policies to date have largely resulted in expensive health care for the rich, and disjointed and ineffective services for the poor. As a result, large segments of the population world-wide continue to suffer from unnecessary casualties, pain and impoverishment. International Health and Aid Policies arms health professionals, researchers and policy makers with strategies that will enable them to bridge the gaps between public health, medicine and health policy in order to support robust, comprehensive and accessible health care systems in any political environment.
Chapter
International health and aid policies of the past two decades have had a major impact on the delivery of care in low and middle-income countries. This book argues that these policies have often failed to achieve their main aims, and have in fact contributed to restricted access to family medicine and hospital care. Presenting detailed evidence, and illustrated by case studies, this book describes how international health policies to date have largely resulted in expensive health care for the rich, and disjointed and ineffective services for the poor. As a result, large segments of the population world-wide continue to suffer from unnecessary casualties, pain and impoverishment. International Health and Aid Policies arms health professionals, researchers and policy makers with strategies that will enable them to bridge the gaps between public health, medicine and health policy in order to support robust, comprehensive and accessible health care systems in any political environment.
Chapter
International health and aid policies of the past two decades have had a major impact on the delivery of care in low and middle-income countries. This book argues that these policies have often failed to achieve their main aims, and have in fact contributed to restricted access to family medicine and hospital care. Presenting detailed evidence, and illustrated by case studies, this book describes how international health policies to date have largely resulted in expensive health care for the rich, and disjointed and ineffective services for the poor. As a result, large segments of the population world-wide continue to suffer from unnecessary casualties, pain and impoverishment. International Health and Aid Policies arms health professionals, researchers and policy makers with strategies that will enable them to bridge the gaps between public health, medicine and health policy in order to support robust, comprehensive and accessible health care systems in any political environment.
Chapter
International health and aid policies of the past two decades have had a major impact on the delivery of care in low and middle-income countries. This book argues that these policies have often failed to achieve their main aims, and have in fact contributed to restricted access to family medicine and hospital care. Presenting detailed evidence, and illustrated by case studies, this book describes how international health policies to date have largely resulted in expensive health care for the rich, and disjointed and ineffective services for the poor. As a result, large segments of the population world-wide continue to suffer from unnecessary casualties, pain and impoverishment. International Health and Aid Policies arms health professionals, researchers and policy makers with strategies that will enable them to bridge the gaps between public health, medicine and health policy in order to support robust, comprehensive and accessible health care systems in any political environment.
Book
This book moves away from the orthodox neoliberal paradigm to suggest a new framework linking social policy with citizenship and transformation. The interjection of nation building, public society and public provisioning to the study of education, healthcare and employment caters to the needs of citizens equitably. By combining and coagulating these three broad arenas of politico-economic discussion, this book takes a new approach to the analysis of social policymaking in developing countries to indicate the drivers and triggers of transformation. It makes comprehensive, thorough critical comparisons between the trajectories of developed and developing countries, finds out the gaps in transformation and suggests drivers for changes. The intentions of social policymaking, as proposed in the book, are to curb the growing inequalities in the forms of class, power and marginalisation. The chapters on education focus on provisioning of public goods for skills formation, innovation and citizenship education. The sections on healthcare centre on universal health care as opposed to universal health coverage by analysing access, healthcare-seeking behaviour, price setting, market provisioning etc. For the chapters on employment, propositions are posited regarding the expansion of productive capacity, factor mobility and social security to ensure work for all. Besides theorising education, healthcare and employment based on public provisioning by the people’s state, underwritten by a public society, the book provides feasible solutions through data sourced from all major international organisations. In addition, it recognises the unique postcolonial struggles and aspirations of the developing countries, and accordingly resorts to defining the normative principles, reflecting nuances, subtleties and peculiarities. This book is a continuation of the author's Fiscal and Monetary Policies in Developing Countries: State, Citizenship and Transformation (Routledge) and will draw the attention of scholars and researchers who wish to gain a deeper understanding of, and pragmatic solutions to, social policies that address the transformational pathways of developing countries, accentuated by the COVID-19 pandemic.
Chapter
Throughout medical history, physicians have rarely formed unions and/or carried out strikes. Today, the medical profession worldwide seems in a heightened state of discontent, but their chosen directions to fight back over their conditions of labor appear blurry and ineffective. With the continual increase in corporatization schemes, physicians continue to be drawn into the role of employee of ever-larger organizations which leave the independent physician-run practice behind; it has become financially more and more difficult to maintain a practice while procuring sufficient reimbursement from insurance companies and patients. As a result, they are not able to maintain their professional independence, which would allow them to act as their patient’s agent in determining what would be done and where it would be done. Because they now have to obey the corporate mandate of revenue enhancement and cost cutting, they no longer have free rein to do as they wish in their professional practice. This condition may impair patient well-being and may surely affect the larger public health.
Chapter
Full-text available
Medical malpractice has been one of the most misunderstood American policy debates over the past 40 years. This chapter explores the concept of medical malpractice, what is currently discussed as policy alternatives, and some possible ways to address the real crisis, which is not too many physicians getting sued, but rather that too many patients are being harmed in healthcare settings. It is our belief that such altering the focus from liability avoidance and defensive medicine to patient safety, harm reduction, and transparency is necessary. Therefore, documenting, discussing, and fixing systemic issues that cause medical errors to occur can result in better and safer patient care, as well as improved quality at lower cost.
Article
Full-text available
In order to evaluate the effects of the new health system upon the equity to access and use of the health services, two cross sections of the population were compared: before Law 100 of 1993, which created the General System for Social Security in Health-SGSSS-, and after the law was passed. The changes in the distribution of an indicator of equity in access to health care services, the affiliation to the General System for Social Security in Health, were assessed. Additionally, two groups were compared in the 1997 cross section, affiliated and non-affiliated to the SGSSS, in order to assess the changes in the equity of use of hospital services and health care services in general. The results obtained show that between 1993 and 1997 the coverage of the SGSSS increased from 23% to 57%. This increase in coverage was more dramatic amongst the poorest sectors of the population: in the homes of people in the lowest tenth percentile of income the coverage increased from 3.1% to 43.7%, and the index of concentration of affiliation to the SGSSS decreased by half: from 0.34 to 0.17. By contrast, the indicators of concentration corresponding to the use of health services varied very little even after the adjustments by age, gender and needs. These results suggest a positive impact of the SGSSS on the inequities of access to health services, but the effects upon the inequities of use of health services are not clear.
Article
Although health care reforms have been implemented in both developed and developing countries since the 1980s, there has been little discussion of the historical, social and political contexts in which such reforms have taken place. Health care reforms in developing countries, for instance, have been an integral component of structural adjustment policies, yet scant attention has been paid to these connections nor to their implications. The basic assumptions behind the reforms, and in particular, the ideological underpinnings of health care reorganization, need to be taken into account when considering long-term strategies and policies to provide health services in developing countries.Copyright © 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Article
The enormous level and rate of increase in health care expenditures in the United States during the past several years has been well documented. A combination of increased health insurance coverage and advances in medical technology, coupled with perverse economic incentives resulting in supplier-induced demand and cost-unconscious demand from patients, has created this explosion in health care spending. This explosive increase has given rise to a variety of private and public sector initiatives to reform the system. With a greater concentration of purchasing power among managed care payors and increased competition among providers, a trend toward dramatically reduced payment for providers continues. Under capitation, the most rapidly growing form of managed care, providers have contracts from insurance companies that call for them to provide care for a fixed per patient annual payment, regardless of what this provision actually costs. This form of per capita payment typically offers drastically reduced payment to providers, forcing them to adopt a cost-reduction strategy. Providers must contain costs while enhancing quality or else perish in this new cost-conscious environment. This new payment paradigm means that price, which is often dictated by the payors, including government, determines the providers' cost rather than cost determining price as it was under the traditional indemnity insurance schemes. It is this new imperative to contain costs while maintaining or else improving the quality of health outcomes that is behind many of the recent mergers and other collaborative activities that we are witnessing nationwide among hospitals and other health care organizations. (Arch Intern Med. 1996;156:357-360)
Article
Contracting is increasingly recommended to developing countries as a way of improving the efficiency of the health sector. However, empirical evidence regarding its effectiveness in this respect is almost completely absent. In Zimbabwe, a long standing contract exists between the Ministry of Health and Wankie Colliery to provide clinical services in the Colliery's 400 bed hospital. This paper details a study of the Zimbabweans' experience with the contract. Its success is assessed using comparisons with a neighbouring government hospital of the price of services (vs the cost in the government hospital); the situation of hospital workers; and the quality of services delivered. The Colliery has established a monopoly position for hospital services in the district. However, it appears to offer services of at least as good quality at prices which are lower than the unit costs of the government hospital when capital costs are included. Nevertheless, the contract cannot be considered a success due to the failure to contain its total cost. Approximately 70% of provincial non-salary recurrent expenditure is consumed by the contract while only a minority of the province's population have access to the Colliery hospital. Screening patients, both with respect to their ability to pay and to their need for secondary level services does not take place with the result that utilization levels are not controlled. The study highlights a number of important issues affecting contracting in developing country settings: First, contracted institutions attain powerful bargaining positions if there are no viable competitors and the government does not itself retain capacity to offer an alternative service. Second, specific skills are needed for the management of contracts at all levels. If the process of contract development responds to a crisis driven agenda resulting from civil service retrenchment and public expenditure cuts, it is unlikely that adequate consideration will be given to the development of such skills and the retention of key personnel. If such details are neglected, otherwise feasible efficiency gains will prove elusive.