ArticlePDF Available

On Making the Right Choice: The Deliberation-Without-Attention Effect

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

Contrary to conventional wisdom, it is not always advantageous to engage in thorough conscious deliberation before choosing. On the basis of recent insights into the characteristics of conscious and unconscious thought, we tested the hypothesis that simple choices (such as between different towels or different sets of oven mitts) indeed produce better results after conscious thought, but that choices in complex matters (such as between different houses or different cars) should be left to unconscious thought. Named the "deliberation-without-attention" hypothesis, it was confirmed in four studies on consumer choice, both in the laboratory as well as among actual shoppers, that purchases of complex products were viewed more favorably when decisions had been made in the absence of attentive deliberation.
Content may be subject to copyright.
13. E. J. Eide, H. Kang, S. Crapo, M. Gallego, D. M. Virshup,
Methods Enzymol. 393, 408 (2005).
14. S. Martinek, S. Inonog, A. S. Manoukian, M. W. Young,
Cell 105, 769 (2001).
15. M. Abe, E. D. Herzog, G. D. Block, Neuroreport 11, 3261
(2000).
16. C. Iitaka, K. Miyazaki, T. Akaike, N. Ishida, J. Biol. Chem.
280, 29397 (2005).
17. P. S. Klein, D. A. Melton, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 93,
8455 (1996).
18. G. Adelmant, A. Begue, D. Stehelin, V. Laudet, Proc. Natl.
Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 93, 3553 (1996).
19. B. W. Doble, J. R. Woodgett, J. Cell Sci. 116, 1175
(2003).
20. A. Balsalobre, F. Damiola, U. Schibler, Cell 93, 929 (1998).
21. F. Zhang, C. J. Phiel, L. Spece, N. Gurvich, P. S. Klein,
J. Biol. Chem. 278, 33067 (2003).
22. A. J. Gelenberg et al., J. Med. 321, 1489 (1989).
23. J. A. Ripperger, L. P. Shearman, S. M. Reppert,
U. Schibler, Genes Dev. 14, 679 (2000).
24. E. Iwahana et al., Eur. J. Neurosci. 19, 2281 (2004).
25. F. Benedetti et al., Neurosci. Lett. 368, 123 (2004).
26. R. H. Lenox, T. D. Gould, H. K. Manji, Am. J. Med. Genet.
114, 391 (2002).
27. M. Gottlicher et al. , EMBO J. 20, 6969 (2001).
28. C. J. Phiel et al., J. Biol. Chem. 276, 36734 (2001).
29. M. E. Dokucu, L. Yu, P. H. Taghert, Neuropsychopharma-
cology 30, 2216 (2005).
30. We thank the University of Pennsylvania Diabetes and
Endocrinology Research Center Vector Core (NIH DK
19525) and M. J. Birnbaum for GSK3b adenoviruses,
and J. D. Alvarez and A. Sehgal for helpful discussions.
Supported by NIH DK45586 (to M.A.L.) and NIH
MH058324 (to P.S.K.).
Supporting Online Material
www.sciencemag.org/cgi/content/full/311/5763/1002/DC1
Materials and Methods
Figs. S1 to S7
20 October 2005; accepted 14 January 2006
10.1126/science.1121613
On Making the Right Choice: The
Deliberation-Without-Attention Effect
Ap Dijksterhuis,
*
Maarten W. Bos, Loran F. Nordgren, Rick B. van Baaren
Contrary to conventional wisdom, it is not always advantageous to engage in thorough conscious
deliberation before choosing. On the basis of recent insights into the characteristics of conscious
and unconscious thought, we tested the hypothesis that simple choices (such as between different
towels or different sets of oven mitts) indeed produce better results after conscious thought, but
that choices in complex matters (such as between different houses or different cars) should be left
to unconscious thought. Named the ‘deliberation-without-attention’ hypothesis, it was confirmed
in four studies on consumer choice, both in the laboratory as well as among actual shoppers, that
purchases of complex products were viewed more favorably when decisions had been made in the
absence of attentive deliberation.
C
ommon knowledge holds that thor-
ough conscious thought leads to good
decisions and satisfactory choices.
Whether purchasing a new car, a desktop com-
puter, or a pair of shoes, people generally
believe that serious conscious deliberation in-
creases the probability that they will make the
Bright[ choice. This idea applies especially to
choices between products that are complex,
multifaceted, and expensive. Whereas most
people are willing to buy a new set of towels
without much thought, they are unlikely to buy
a new car or outfit a new kitchen without
deliberation.
A second pervasive idea is that the quality
of a choice benefits from Bsleeping on it.[
Rather than (or in addition to) thinking con-
sciously, people usually feel that Bunconscious
thought[ is useful for making sound decisions.
Whereas conscious thought refers to thought or
deliberation while conscious attention is di-
rected at the problem at hand, unconscious
thought can be defined as thought or delibera-
tion in the absence of conscious attention di-
rected at the problem (1). An example of
unconscious thought is the following: One
compares two holiday destinations (say the
Costa Brava and T uscany) and does not know
what to decide. One puts the problem aside and
after 48 hours of not thinking about it con-
sciously, suddenly the thought BIt_s going to be
Tuscany![ pops into consciou sness. This thou ght
itself is conscious, but the transition from
indecision to a preference 2 days later is the
result of unconscious thought, or of deliberation
without attention.
The scientific literature has emphasized the
benefits of conscious deliberation in decision
making for hundreds of years (2, 3). The idea
that conscious deliberation is the ideal (if not
always attainable) way to approach a d ecision
forms the backbone of classic (4, 5)aswellas
contemporary perspectives on decision making
(6, 7) and attitude formation (8, 9). In contrast,
the notion that unconscious thought is fruitful
hardly developed beyond the status of Bfolk
wisdom.[ It has been postulated or investigated
by scientists infrequently Ebut see (10–13)^.The
question addressed here is whether this view is
justified. We hypothesize that it is not.
First, conscious thought does not always
lead to sound choices. For example, participants
who chose their favorite p oster among a set of
five after thorough contemplation showed less
postchoice satisfaction than participants who
only looked at them briefly (14, 15). Further-
more, conscious deliberation can make multiple
evaluations of the same object less consistent
over time (16). Two reasons why conscious
deliberation sometimes leads to poor judgments
have been identified. First, consciousness has
a low capacity (17, 18), causing choosers to take
into account only a subset of the relevant
informationwhentheydecide(13, 19). Second,
conscious thought can lead to suboptimal weight-
ing of the importance of attributes (13–16):
We tend to inflate the importance of s ome at-
tributes at the expense of others, leading to
worse choices.
Conversely, unconscious thought, or thought
without attention, can lead to good choices
(13, 14). In a recent experiment, participants
read information about four apartments of dif-
ferent desirability (20). They were either asked
to choose their favorite immediately, or given
the opportunity to choose after a period of
conscious thought, or distracted for some time
Department of Psychology, University of Amsterdam,
Roetersstraat 15, 1018 WB, Amsterdam, the Netherlands.
*To whom correspondence should be addressed. E-mail:
a.j.dijksterhuis@uva.nl
Fig. 1. Percentage of participants who chose the
most desirable car as a function of complexity of
decision and of mode of thought (n 0 18 to 22 in
each condition). Error bars represent the stan-
dard error .
Fig. 2. Difference in attitude (on a scale of –25 to
þ25) toward the desirable and undesirable car as a
function of complexity of decision and of mode of
thought (n 0 12 to 14 in each condition). Error
bars represen t the standard error.
REPORTS
1005
www.sciencemag.org SCIENCE VOL 311 17 FEBRUARY 2006
before they chose. In the third of these con-
ditions, participants could only engage in
unconscious deliberation: They knew they
would have to choo se later, but the distraction
task prevented them from devoting conscious
attention to the choice. Interestingly, un-
conscious thinkers made better decisions than
conscious thinkers or than immediate choosers
(13, 14).
Recently, we formulated the Unconscious
Thought Theory (UTT) (21) about the strengths
and weaknesses of conscious thought and un-
conscious thought, that is, of deliberation with
and without attention. Two characteristics of
conscious and unconscious thought are impor-
tant in the current context. First, conscious
thought is rule-based and very precise (22, 23).
Unconscious thought can conform to rules in
that it detects recurring patterns, as the literature
on implicit learning shows (24). However, in
order to actively follow strict rules, conscious
attention is necessary. For example, one cannot
do arithmetic without conscious attention. This
capacity to follow rules makes conscious thought
more precise in decision making, because it
can strictly follow self-generated rules such as
not exceeding a maximum price. Second, as
alluded to earlier, conscious thought suffers
from the low capacity of consciousness, mak-
ing it less suitable for very complex issues.
Unconscious thought does not suffer from low
capacity. Indeed, it has been shown that during
unconscious thought, large amounts of infor-
mation can be integrated into an evaluative
summary judgment (13).
These characteristics of conscious and un-
conscious thought led us to postulate the
Bdeliberation-without-attention[ hypothesis, on
the relation between mode of thought or
deliberation (conscious versus unconscious)
and the complexity and quality of choice.
Complexity is defined as the amount of in-
formation a choice involves. A choice between
objects for which one or two attributes are
important (such as oven mitts or toothpaste) is
simple, whereas a choice between objects for
which many attributes are important (cars or
houses) is complex. Conscious thought is hy-
pothesized, due to its precision, to lead to good
choices in simple matters. However, because of
its low capacity, conscious thought leads to
progressively worse choices with more com-
plex issues. Unconscious th ought (i.e., deliber-
ation without attention) is expected, because of
its relative lack of precision, to lead to choices
of lower quality. However, the quality of choice
does not deteriorate with increased complexity,
allowing unconscious thought to lead to better
choices than conscious thought under com-
plex circumstances, this latter idea being the
kernel of the deliberation-without-attention
hypothesis. Quality of choice was operation-
alized both normatively (studies 1 and 2) as
well as subjectively (as postchoice satisfaction,
in studies 3 and 4).
Study 1. Participants were subjected to a 2
(mode of thought: conscious versus uncon-
scious) 2 (complexity of choice problem: sim-
ple versus complex) factorial design (25). All
participants read information about four hypo-
thetical cars. Depending on the condition, each
car was characterized by 4 attributes (simple) or
by 12 attributes (complex). The attributes were
either positive or negative. One car was char-
acterized by 75% positive attributes, two by
50% p ositive attributes, and one by 2 5% posi-
tive attributes (supporting online text). After
reading the information about the four cars,
participants were assigned either to a conscious
thought condition or to an unconscious thought
condition. In the conscious thought condition,
participants were asked to think about the cars
for 4 min before they chose their favorite car.
In the unconscious thought condition, partic-
ipants were distracted for 4 min (they solved
anagrams) and were told that after the period of
distraction they would be asked to choose the
best car.
The percentages of participants who chose
the best car are shown in Fig. 1. The crucial two-
way interaction supporting the deliberation-
without-attention hypothesis was significant
EF(1,76) 0 4.85, P G 0.04^. Unconscious think-
ers fared relatively well and showed no differ-
ences between conditions (F G 1, not significant).
Conscious thinkers generally made the proper
choice under simple conditions, but performed
poorly under complex circumstances EF(1,40) 0
4.95, P G 0.04^.
Study 2. For the second study we made one
change (25). Rather than asking for a choice,
we asked participants about their attitudes
toward each of the four cars. As the dependent
variable, we used the difference in attitude
toward the best car and the worst car. Again,
conscious thinkers were better able to differen-
tiate the quality of the cars under simple
conditions, whereas unconscious thinkers were
better able to differentiate the quality of the cars
under complex conditions E F(1,47) 0 5.63, P G
0.03^. The means are shown in Fig. 2.
Study 3. In a pilot study, undergraduate
students were asked how many aspects of a
product they would take into account in the
purchase of 40 different products. In this way,
we obtained an average Bcomplexity score[
for 40 different products (supporting online
text).
For the actual study, other students were
presented with this list of 40 products. From the
list, they were asked to choose a product that
they had recently purchased and were asked the
following questions: Which product did you
purchase? Did you know the product before
you went on the shopping trip? How much did
you think about the product between seeing it
for the first time and b uying it? How satisfied
are you with the product?
To test our hypothesis, we distinguished
participants who thought (either consciously or
unconsciously) about their purchase from im-
pulse buyers who did not think much at all.
Hence, participa nts who indicated that they
bought a product they had never come across
before the shopping trip were not included,
leaving only participants who knew the product
beforehand (n 0 49).
It is impossible to know whether people are
engaged in unconscious thought by asking
them, so strictly speaking, we can only test
the relationship between conscious thought,
Fig. 3. The relation between mode of
thought and postchoice satisfaction
(on a scale of 1 to 7) for the six
products most frequently chosen in
study 3. Higher bars indicate more
satisfaction. The more complex the
product (on a scale of 1 to 5), the fur-
ther to the right it is shown. The
complexity score is given in parenthe-
ses. Participants were divided into
conscious and unconscious thinkers
on the basis of a median-split for
each product individually. Each bar
repres ents between two and five
participants.
Fig. 4. Postchoice satisfaction of IKEA (n 0 27)
and Bijenkorf (n 0 27) shoppers as a function
of mode of thought. Error bars represent the
standard error.
REPORTS
17 FEBRUARY 2006 VOL 311 SCIENCE www.sciencemag.org
1006
complexity, and quality. However, it follows
from our definition of conscious and uncon-
scious thought (according to which attention
to the problem at hand is the crucial distin-
guishing factor) that they are at least partly
dependent. At any one point in time, attention
is either directed at the decision under con-
sideration, or it is not; that is, at any partic-
ular point in time, either you are attending to
buying a car, or you are not. The more you
think about a decision consciously (that is,
with attention), the less time remains to think
about the same decision unconsciously (that
is, without attention).
We regressed the amount of thought and the
average number of aspects on postchoice satis-
faction. As expected, thinking does not make
people more satisfied, nor does complexity
(t_s G 1). However, the interaction of the two
parameters significantly predicted postchoice
satisfaction Et(48) 0 2.13, P G 0.04^.Correla-
tions were calculated between amount of
thought and postchoice satisfaction for three
categories of products: complex, medium, and
simple. For products of medium complexity, no
correlation was found Er(18) 0 –0.03^;for
simple products, a positive correlation was
found Er(15) 0 0.57, P G 0.03^; and for complex
products, a negative correlation was found
Er(16) 0 –0.56, P G 0.03^. As expected, the
more people thought consciously about simple
products, the more satisfied they were with
their purchase. Conversely, the more people
thought consciously about complex products,
the less satisfied they were with their purchase.
Figure 3 depicts satisfaction as a function of
mode of thought for the six most frequently
chosen products (26).
Study 4. On the basis of the pilot study to
study 3, two shops were selected: one where
people generally buy complex products (IKEA,
which sells mainly furniture) and one where
people generally buy simple products (Bijenkorf,
a department store like Macy_s that sells
clothes, clothing accessories, and kitchen ac-
cessories). At the exit, shoppers were asked the
following questions: What did you buy? How
expensive was it? Did you know the product
before you went on the shopping trip? and
How much did you think about the product
between seeing it for the first time and buying
it? A few weeks later, the shoppers were asked
(over the phone) how satisfied they were with
their purchases. As in study 3, participants who
indicated that they bought a product they had
never come across before the shopping trip
were not included.
We divided participants (Bthinkers[)onthe
basis of a median-split procedure into those
who engaged in much conscious thought
(conscious thinkers) and those who engaged
in little conscious thought (unconscious think-
ers). As expected, conscious thinkers reported
more p ostchoice satisfaction than uncon-
scious thinkers for Bijenkorf products (simple
products) EF(1,25) 0 6.52, P G 0.02^. The oppo-
site was true for the IKEA customers (complex
products), in which case unconscious thinkers
showed more postchoice satisfaction than con-
scious thinkers EF(1,25) 0 6.12, P G 0.02^
(Fig. 4).
In sum, in four studies we demonstrated the
deliberation-without-attention effect. Conscious
thinkers were better able to make the best
choice among simple products, whereas un-
conscious thinkers were better able to make the
best choice among complex products. Among
people who knew the product they purchased
before they went on a shopping trip, the amount
of conscious thought was positively related to
postchoice satisfaction for simple products and
negatively related to postchoice satisfaction for
complex products.
Our aim was to test the Bdeliberation-
without-attention[ hypothesis both in the labo-
ratory and among shoppers. In that sense, it is
important to view our set of studies as a whole
rather than as a series of individual studies.
Study 4 has unavoidable disadvantages such as
that the IKEA and Bijenkorf samples may have
differed (after all, different shops attract a
different clientele), which naturally opens the
potential for alternative explanations. There-
fore, study 3 was done in order to Bbridge[ the
laboratory studies with study 4. It has many of
the assets of study 4 (real choices between real
products with satisfaction as the dependent
variable), except that all participants were
students.
Although we investigated choices among
consumer products in our studies, there is no a
priori reason to assume that the deliberation-
without-attention effect does not generalize to
other types of choices—political, managerial,
or otherwise. In such cases, it should benefit
the individual to think consciously about
simple matters and to delegate thinking about
more complex matters to the unconscious.
References and Notes
1. It is important to note that attention to the problem at
hand is the crucial distinction in our definitions of conscious
and unconscious thought. Thinking about buying a new
car while attention is directed at possible new cars is
conscious thought. Thinking about buying a new car
while attention is temporarily directed elsewhere is
unconscious thought. This distinction does not mean that
conscious thought only comprises conscious processes.
One can compare it to speech. Speech is a conscious
process (i.e., attention is directed at it while one speaks),
but it is in part dependent on accompanying unconscious
processes (such as processes responsible for syntax or
word choice).
2. R. Descartes, The Philosophical Writings of Descartes
(Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge, 1984).
3. J. Locke, An Essay Concerning Human Understanding
(Penguin, London, 1689/1997).
4. I. L. Janis, L. Mann, Decision Making: A Psychological
Analysis of Conflict, Choice, and Commitment (Free
Press, New York, 1977).
5. H. A. Simon, Q. J. Econ. 69, 99 (1955).
6. J. R. Bettman, M. F. Luce, J. W. Payne, J. Consum. Res. 25,
187 (1998).
7. D. Kahneman, Am. Psychol. 58, 697 (2003).
8. S. Chaiken, J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 39, 752 (1980).
9. R. E. Petty, J. T. Cacioppo, in Advances in Experimental
Social Psychology, L. Berkowitz, Ed. (Academic Press,
New York, 1986), vol. 19, pp. 123–205.
10. As far as we know, the possibility of unconscious thought
(as well as the term ‘unconscious thought’’) was explicitly
used for the first time by Schopenhauer, who remarked
that ‘One might almost believe that half of our thinking
takes place unconsciously’ (27).
11. G. Claxton, Hare Brain, Tortoise Mind: How Intelligence
Increases When You Think Less (Harper Collins, New York,
1997).
12. The idea of unconscious thought was also studied by
various researchers interested in incubation processes in
creativity. An example is K. S. Bowers et al.(28).
13. A. Dijksterhuis, J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 87, 586 (2004).
14. A. Dijksterhuis, Z. van Olden, J. Exp. Soc. Psychol.,
in press.
15. T. D. Wilson et al., Pers. Soc. Psychol. Bull. 19, 331
(1993).
16. G. M. Levine, J. B. Halberstadt, R. L. Goldstone, J. Pers.
Soc. Psychol. 70, 230 (1996).
17. G. A. Miller, Psych. Rev. 63, 81 (1956).
18. T. Nørretranders, The User Illusion: Cutting Consciousness
Down to Size (Viking, New York, 1998).
19. T. D. Wilson, J. W. Schooler, J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 60, 181
(1991).
20. Quality of decision was operationalized from a
normative perspective. One of the choice options was
made more desirable than the others because it
had been assigned more positive aspects than the
other apartments.
21. A. Dijksterhuis, L. F. Nordgren, Persp. Psychol. Sci.,
in press.
22. The important distinction between following rules and
merely conforming to them (and the need for conscious
attention in the former) was made by S. A. Sloman
(29).
23. E. R. Smith, J. DeCoster, Dual-Process Theories in
Social Psychology, S. Chaiken, Y. Trope, Eds. (Guilford,
New York, 1999), pp. 323–336.
24. Unconscious thought is reminiscent of implicit learning,
but there is an important difference. Implicit learning
refers to aspects of a task that are learned while
working on the task (and that are inaccessible to
consciousness). Unconscious thought refers to thought
processes that take place after the encoding of relevant
information. A good example of this definition of
unconscious thought is the groundbreaking work by
Stickgold and colleagues on learning during sleep.
See, e.g., (30, 31).
25. Materials and methods are available as supporting
material on Science Online.
26. We found a correlation between number of aspects and
amount of thought (r 0 0.54, P G 0.001): The more
complex a product is, the more people think consciously
when deciding to purchase it. Understandable as this
may be, our analysis suggests that people should do the
opposite, i.e., think unconsciously when deciding to
purchase a complex product. The correlation between
number of aspects and price was also significant
(r 0 0.45, P G 0.001): Expensive products were more
complex than inexpensive ones.
27. A. Schopenhauer, in Essays and Aphorisms (Penguin,
London, 1851/1970), p. 123.
28. K. S. Bowers, G. Regehr, C. Balthazard, K. Parker,
Cogn. Psychol. 22, 72 (1990).
29. S. A. Sloman, Psychol. Bull. 119, 3 (1996).
30. R. Stickgold, M. Walker, Trends Cogn. Sci. 8, 191 (2004).
31. R. Stickgold et al., Science 294, 1052 (2001).
32. We thank E. Neimeijer, L. Schreers, and R. Wassenberg
for help with conducting study 4. This research was
supported by a grant from Nederlandse Organisatie voor
Wetenschappelijk Onderzoek (016.025.030).
Supporting Online Material
www.sciencemag.org/cgi/content/full/311/5763/1005/DC1
Materials and Methods
20 October 2005; accepted 9 January 2006
10.1126/science.1121629
REPORTS
1007
www.sciencemag.org SCIENCE VOL 311 17 FEBRUARY 2006
... 2. Decision-making assumption. Individuals make decisions both slowly and deliberately and quickly and automatically, with these two general cognitive processes often interacting to produce action (Dijksterhuis et al., 2006;Evans, 2008;Gilovich & Griffin, 2010;Lizardo et al., 2016). 6 Deception and other forms of concealment appear to be "slow" ways of thinking (Gombos, 2006). ...
... As the ego has honed their ability to judge and execute concealment, the decision to conceal may become more associative and automatic. In such cases, given that automatic decision-making produces results similar to deliberative decision making (Dijksterhuis et al., 2006), I do not expect the predictions of my overall model to change. ...
... Rather, when people think fast, they can be engaging in several different cognitive processes, such as associative processes or habit-like processes that were once deliberative but have become automatic over time(Gilovich and Griffin 2010;Kahneman, 2011). Similarly, automatic and unconscious processes can also be deliberative and slow(Dijksterhuis 2006). Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. ...
Article
Full-text available
Concealment, or the deliberate withholding of information from others, is of fundamental sociological interest. Yet, a general theoretical framework of concealment is missing from the sociological canon. This paper specifies a model that builds on and goes beyond existing accounts of concealment by emphasizing the desire for autonomy. I propose that the desire for autonomy, and the subjective assessment of concealment as the best route to achieve autonomy, lead individuals to attempt concealment. After specifying a dyadic model based on the concealer (ego) and the target of concealment (alter), I incorporate ego-alter power differentials, network dynamics, and norms about privacy and concealment into a multilevel model of how concealment is initiated and maintained.
... The accepted wisdom is that thorough conscious thought leads to the best decisions. However, research investigating the role of unconscious information in decision-making has suggested that unconscious thought can improve such decisions (Dijksterhuis et al., 2006). This was a surprising result but several subsequent studies failed to find evidence that unconscious information can influence decision-making (Acker, 2008;Rey et al., 2009;Newell & Rakow, 2011), leading to considerable controversy. ...
Article
Contrary to the widespread belief that careful conscious thought leads to good decisions, recent psychophysical studies have argued that unconscious information can improve conscious decisions. However, these studies likely failed to manipulate conscious awareness in their experiments. To address this issue, we used a new technique called continuous flash suppression (CFS), which provides a powerful method to reliably manipulate conscious awareness in visual perception. This technique was combined with a simple perceptual decision paradigm in the same experimental protocol as the recent psychophysical studies. This protocol enabled us to investigate whether unconscious information can alter conscious perceptual decisions. Participants were asked to decide the direction of a coherent random-dot motion stimulus and then to rate the confidence of the random-dot motion direction judgments. We found that unconscious motion information was not integrated with conscious decision-related motion information to increase both decision accuracy and confidence when the motion stimuli were presented for the first few hundred milliseconds with strong perceptual suppression induced by the CFS stimuli. These results suggest that unconscious information does not improve conscious decisions.
... A further issue with self-evaluations of thinking style is that individuals can report only awareness. Some aspects of processing are automatic and not available to consciousness [63,64]. These factors explain why studies often report that the relationship between subjective ratings and actual performance is often weak [65,66]. ...
Article
Full-text available
The Inventory of Personality Organization-Reality Testing Subscale (IPO-RT) and Belief in Science Scale (BIS) represent indirect, proxy measures of intuitive-experiential and analytical-rational thinking. However, a limited appraisal of factorial structure exists, and assessment of person-item functioning has not occurred. This study assessed the IPO-RT and BIS using confirmatory factor analysis (CFA) and Rasch analysis with a sample of 1030 participants (465 males, 565 females). Correlation analysis revealed a negative, moderate relationship between the measures. CFA supported a bifactorial model of the IPO-RT with four bifactors (Auditory and Visual Hallucinations, Delusional Thinking, Social Deficits, and Confusion). A one-factor model best fitted the BIS. Satisfactory item/person reliability and unidimensionality was observed for both measures using Rasch analysis, and items generally exhibited gender invariance. However, IPO-RT items were challenging, whereas BIS items were relatively easy to endorse. Overall, results indicated that the IPO-RT and BIS are conceptually sound, indirect indices of intuitive-experiential and analytical-rational thinking. Acknowledging the breadth of these thinking styles, a useful future research focus includes evaluating the performance of IPO-RT and BIS alongside objective tests.
... Although Dijksterhuis et al. (2006) asserted in "Science" that IDM systems outperformed ADM systems, this assertion was not corroborated by the present study. Similarly, D, another performance metric, indicated that ADM outperformed IDM situations and was influenced by the level of refereeing. ...
Article
Full-text available
This study aimed to examine how soccer referees make decisions about issuing yellow cards for fouls. The research involved 60 male participants, divided into expert (n=30) and novice (n=30) groups based on their experience and qualifications as referees. They took part in a 2×2×2 mixed-design experiment. The study looked at Decision-Making Style (DMS: Analytical Decision-Making [ADM] vs. Intuitive Decision-Making [IDM]), Video Type (yellow card foul vs. non-yellow card foul), and Referee Level (expert vs. novice) as independent variables. The dependent variables were accuracy rate (ACC), discrimination index (D), self-confidence index (C), and overconfidence index (OC). The findings showed that Analytical Decision-Making (ADM) led to higher accuracy compared to Intuitive Decision-Making (IDM). Expert referees demonstrated better accuracy than novice referees. There was also an interaction between Decision-Making Style and Referee Level, showing differences in the effectiveness of ADM and IDM between expert and novice referees. Additionally, the study revealed that both expert and novice referees showed overconfidence, with experts demonstrating significantly higher overconfidence, particularly during IDM. In conclusion, the research highlighted the complexity of referees’ decision-making in high-pressure situations and emphasized the potential benefits of employing Analytical Decision-Making strategies. The study contributed to understanding cognitive biases in sports officiating and suggested the need for targeted training programs to help referees improve their performance and reduce overconfidence in challenging situations.
... If we take the time to listen to and value our youth, young adults, and adults, we may not only keep them from fooling us, but also offer them the confidence and encouragement they need to succeed in life. Dijksterhuis et al. (2006) found that rapid decisions generally resulted in favorable ones since people weren't distracted by various options or overthinking. Facione and Gittens (2016) emphasized that two systems influence human decision-making. ...
Article
Full-text available
Human beings are born free. They feel more relax and can perform efficiently if they live upto their choice. Every kind of transgression consequences in unwanted ending results. Depriving an individual of free will and choice is like robbing a person of his status of humanity. This research paper is going to examine the impacts of transgression of discretion on individuals when they are imposed. The paper also demonstrates the impacts of transgressing an individual's life and career. This transgressing refers to the rejection of someone's own decisions or their ability of decision-making and free choice. Liberal humanism, Free Choice Theory is taken as the conceptual framework of the paper. The first hand data is obtained from Paulo Coelho's (1999) novel, Veronika Decides to Die, while secondary data is collected from books, library, journals and other internet sources. The study uses the approach of qualitative research. Selected data from the novel by Paulo Coelho is examined through the lens of close reading. This research paper also illustrates how different characters of the novel recognize the meaning of their present life/status after having got the freedom of choice and the right of making their own decisions.
Article
Full-text available
This article aims to explore how the decision-makers cognition affects the earliness and post-internationalization speed. Managerial cognition is evaluated through the lens of the dual-process theory, which assumes that human information processing is made by two cognitive systems: the intuitive System X and the analytical System C. This is a multiple case study framed in a small and open context such as the Portuguese footwear industry. The results suggest that, when deciding the first international entry, the decision-makers of the firms internationalizing earlier mostly relied on the intuitive cognitive system, while the decision-makers of the firm delaying the first entry showed a predominance of the analytical cognitive system. However, regardless of being early or later entrants, the sampled firms combine intuition with analysis to make the final decision about further involvement with foreign markets, resulting in a gradual and slower post-internationalization. Our in-depth analysis suggests that the Uppsala model could be questioned because the speed of the internationalization process seems to be governed by how decision-makers perceive a given reality based on its cognition.
Article
Full-text available
This chapter outlines the two basic routes to persuasion. One route is based on the thoughtful consideration of arguments central to the issue, whereas the other is based on the affective associations or simple inferences tied to peripheral cues in the persuasion context. This chapter discusses a wide variety of variables that proved instrumental in affecting the elaboration likelihood, and thus the route to persuasion. One of the basic postulates of the Elaboration Likelihood Model—that variables may affect persuasion by increasing or decreasing scrutiny of message arguments—has been highly useful in accounting for the effects of a seemingly diverse list of variables. The reviewers of the attitude change literature have been disappointed with the many conflicting effects observed, even for ostensibly simple variables. The Elaboration Likelihood Model (ELM) attempts to place these many conflicting results and theories under one conceptual umbrella by specifying the major processes underlying persuasion and indicating the way many of the traditionally studied variables and theories relate to these basic processes. The ELM may prove useful in providing a guiding set of postulates from which to interpret previous work and in suggesting new hypotheses to be explored in future research. Copyright © 1986 Academic Press Inc. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
Article
Full-text available
This study tested the prediction that introspecting about the reasons for one's preferences would reduce satisfaction with a consumer choice. Subjects evaluated two types of posters and then chose one to take home. Those instructed to think about their reasons chose a different type of poster than control subjects and, when contacted 3 weeks later, were less satisfied with their choice. When people think about reasons, they appear to focus on attributes of the stimulus that are easy to verbalize and seem like plausible reasons but may not be important causes of their initial evaluations. When these attributes imply a new evaluation of the stimulus, people change their attitudes and base their choices on these new attitudes. Over time, however, people's initial evaluation of the stimulus seems to return, and they come to regret choices based on the new attitudes.
Article
Full-text available
Two experiments examined processes by which analyzing reasons may influence attitude judgments. Participants made multiple liking judgments on sets of stimuli that varied along 6 a priori dimensions. In Study 1, the stimulus set consisted of 64 cartoon faces with 6 binary-valued attributes (e.g., a straight vs a crooked nose). In Study 2, the stimuli were 60 digitized photographs from a college yearbook that varied along 6 dimensions uncovered through multidimensional scaling. In each experiment, half of the participants were instructed to think about the reasons why they liked each face before making their liking rating. Participants' multiple liking ratings were then regressed on the dimension values to determine how they weighted each dimension in their liking judgments. The results support a process whereby reasoning leads to increased variability and inconsistency in the weighting of stimulus information. Wilson's model of the disruptive effects of reasoning on attitude judgments ( e.g., T. D. Wilson, D. S. Dunn, D. Kraft, & D. J. Lisle, 1989 ) is discussed. (PsycINFO Database Record (c) 2012 APA, all rights reserved)
Article
Introduction, 99. — I. Some general features of rational choice, 100.— II. The essential simplifications, 103. — III. Existence and uniqueness of solutions, 111. — IV. Further comments on dynamics, 113. — V. Conclusion, 114. — Appendix, 115.
Article
Presents a general descriptive theory of decision making under stress, which includes a typology of 5 distinctive patterns of coping behavior, including vigilance, hypervigilance, and defensive avoidance. The theory is illustrated with discussions of laboratory experiments, field studies, autobiographical and biographical material, and analyses of managerial and foreign policy decisions. Two analytical models, a schema for decision-making stages and a decisional "balance sheet," are also presented to clarify the theory. (28 p ref) (PsycINFO Database Record (c) 2012 APA, all rights reserved)