ArticlePDF Available

Economic and Political Determinants of Tax Amnesties in the U.S. States

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

This paper revisits earlier studies on the determinants of tax amnesties. The novel findings are (i) amnesties are more likely to be declared during fiscal stress periods, and (ii) political factors significantly affect the introduction and timing of amnesties. In particular, the paper empirically disentangles opposite theoretical effects to show that governors perceive amnesties as another revenue source (rather than a tax increase alternative). Finally, supporting evidence shows that by breaking horizontal equity, amnesties might be perceived as unfair: a significant correlation exists between governors who lost their reelection bids and the introduction of a tax amnesty during their election years.
Content may be subject to copyright.
WP/06/222
Economic and Political Determinants of
Tax Amnesties in the U.S. States
Eric Le Borgne
© 2006 International Monetary Fund WP/06/222
IMF Working Paper
Fiscal Affairs Department
Economic and Political Determinants of Tax Amnesties in the U.S. States
Prepared by Eric Le Borgne
1
Authorized for distribution by Michael Keen
September 2006
Abstract
This Working Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the IMF. The views
expressed in this Working Paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those
of the IMF or IMF policy. Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are
published to elicit comments and to further debate.
This paper revisits earlier studies on the determinants of tax amnesties. The novel findings
are (i) amnesties are more likely to be declared during fiscal stress periods, and (ii) political
factors significantly affect the introduction and timing of amnesties. In particular, the paper
empirically disentangles opposite theoretical effects to show that governors perceive
amnesties as another revenue source (rather than a tax increase alternative). Finally,
supporting evidence shows that by breaking horizontal equity, amnesties might be perceived
as unfair: a significant correlation exists between governors who lost their reelection bids and
the introduction of a tax amnesty during their election years.
JEL Classification Numbers: H20, H26, H29
Keywords: Tax amnesty, Gubernatorial elections, Cox model
Author
s E-Mail Address: eleborgne@imf.org
1
I would like to thank Michael Keen and seminar participants at the 2005 National Tax Association conference for
valuable comments. A version of this paper is forthcoming in the National Tax Association Proceedings.
2
Contents
I. Introduction ............................................................................................................................3
II. Methodology: A Discrete-Time Duration Model..................................................................6
III. Data Description ..................................................................................................................6
IV. Empirical Results.................................................................................................................9
V. Conclusion ..........................................................................................................................10
References................................................................................................................................12
Tables
1. Definitions and Sources of Variables Used ...........................................................................7
2. Summary Statistics of Estimation Sample 1/.........................................................................7
3. Model for Time Waited Before Initiating a State Tax Amnesty .........................................10
Figures
1. U.S. States: Number of Tax Amnesties Per Year, 1982–2004 ..............................................4
3
I. INTRODUCTION
Almost all U.S. states have offered an amnesty program since 1980
2
; some have offered
several, often related to the same taxes.
3
These tax amnesties differ widely in terms of
coverage, tax types, and incentives offered. Tax amnesties have been designed to cover all
taxpayers, broad categories of taxpayers (e.g., small taxpayers, identified delinquent
taxpayers), or tax types (e.g., corporate income tax, sales tax). Amnesties differ with regard
to what is forgiven (e.g., interest, penalties, tax liabilities, criminal prosecution). In some
cases, only the penalty and interest components of the liability—which often account for the
bulk of the overall tax debt—may be forgiven, partially or fully. In other cases, the basic tax
liability itself may be reduced. Alternatively, the tax authority may establish a repayment
schedule under which interest and penalties stop accruing altogether, or interest may be
assessed at something less than market rates. Such a rescheduling is still an amnesty, as the
net present value of the debt is reduced.
While infrequent, state tax amnesty programs tend to be highly clustered over time. At the
level of the U.S. states from 1980 to 2004, the (unconditional) probability that a state will
introduce a tax amnesty program in a given year is 6.5 percent. However, as Figure 1
immediately reveals, tax amnesties are highly clustered in time. Following an initial wave in
the mid-1980s, they (timidly) reappeared some ten years later, and then became fairly
common at the turn of the century.
4
This paper analyzes the underlying determinants of state tax amnesty programs. The two
primary reasons for introducing tax amnesties
5
are (i) to raise revenue in the short-term,
and/or (ii) to increase compliance (e.g., by encouraging taxpayers to declare and pay
previously undeclared tax, file tax returns, or register to pay taxes, so as to increase revenue
and horizontal equity in the medium term). Within the revenue-raising motive, the
introduction of tax amnesties has also been strongly motivated by the desire of the tax
authorities to quickly obtain windfall revenue gains.
2
A tax amnesty can be defined as a program that provides for a reduction in real terms of taxpayers’ declared or
undeclared tax liabilities as established by law.
3
Forty-two states have offered tax amnesty programs. Those with multiple programs include Louisiana (four),
Arizona (three), Connecticut (three), Florida (three), Massachusetts (three), Missouri (three), New Jersey
(three), and New York (three). From 1980 to 2004, a total of 78 amnesty programs have been introduced by
U.S. states.
4
This time-clustering phenomenon is also present across countries. See Franzoni (1995) or Torger and
Schaltergger (2005) for a review of recent tax amnesties around the world.
5
The literature on tax amnesty extends the literature on tax compliance that started with Allingham and
Sandmo (1972). (See Andreoni, Erard, and Feinstein (1998) for a recent review of that literature.) Early
contributions to the tax amnesty literature include Alm and Beck (1990), Andreoni (1991), Malik and Schwab
(1991), Stella (1991), and Graetz and Wilde (1993).
4
Figure 1. U.S. States: Number of Tax Amnesties Per Year, 1982–2004
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
1
982
1
98
4
1
9
86
1
988
1
99
0
1
9
92
1
994
1
996
1
9
98
2
000
2
002
2
0
04
Although the reasons for “successful” (in terms of immediate gross revenue yield) tax
amnesties are well understood
6
in both the economic literature and by practitioners
(increasing revenues and compliance), the determinants of the introduction of a tax amnesty
program are far less so.
7
In an important early study, Dubin, Graetz, and Wilde (1992)
analyzed precisely this question. They investigated two potential rationales for introducing
tax amnesties: the first is the idea that a state would initiate a tax amnesty if it expects the
amnesty program to produce a significant (gross) revenue yield (the “yield” motive); and the
second is the idea that a state would introduce an amnesty in times of fiscal duress—that is,
an amnesty is one source (along with raising taxes) for increasing revenue collection during a
recessionary period (the “fiscal stress” motive). They find that the most important reason for
6
Allowing detected tax evaders (also known as accounts receivable) to participate in a tax amnesty is
by far the major determinant of the (gross) revenue yield of tax amnesties. (Of the $6.6 billion in total
gross amnesty revenue collected by the states during 1980–2004, 92 percent were from programs that
allowed taxpayers with accounts receivables to participate.) The other key determinant of (gross)
revenue yield is the coupling of a tax amnesty program with increased (and advertised) tax
administration detection and enforcement capacity (e.g., Alm, McKee, and Beck, 1990).
7
We should note, however, that immediate gross revenue yield—although often used as a benchmark
for evaluating the “success” of an amnesty—only captures one aspect (gross short-term gain) of what
would be a successful tax amnesty. (Net short-term gain, long-term compliance, and revenue effects
are not taken into account.) The empirical evidence on the long-run revenue effect from states’
amnesty cum increased enforcement strategy is inconclusive. Joulfaian (1988), studying
Massachusetts amnesty program, finds that chronic nonfilers as well as filers who underreport tax are
not attracted by tax amnesties. Alm, McKee, and Beck (1990), in an experimental study, find that
compliance decreases after amnesties (on their own), but rises if amnesties are combined with tighter
enforcement. Alm and Beck (1993) find that the 1985 Colorado tax amnesty had no long-run effect
on tax revenues (either their level or growth rate). Christian, Gupta, and Young (2002) find, using
data on subsequent filing from the Michigan income tax amnesty, that the additional revenue raised
from these taxpayers is marginal (around 0.1 percent of the state’s personal income tax revenues).
5
introducing a tax amnesty is its expected revenue yield, while a state’s “fiscal stress” is not a
significant factor. Earlier studies (e.g., Leonard and Zeckhauser (1987)) had found evidence
of a fiscal stress effect on a much more limited sample than Dubin, Graetz, and Wilde (1992)
(hereinafter referred to as DGW) did.
This paper revisits the same question as DGW: what are the causes of state tax amnesties?
Revisiting this question more than a decade later is desirable for the following reasons: first,
as described earlier, state tax amnesties tend to come in waves. DGW’s analysis was
concerned with the 1980s amnesty programs, and the reasons for introducing these might be
different from the reasons for the second and third waves of amnesties. Second, our sample is
much larger (about twice the size) than that used by DGW, which significantly improves the
statistical robustness of our results. (DGW’s sample contained 40 tax amnesties.) Third, our
econometric modeling of the probability of declaring an amnesty differs from theirs; DGW
rely on a parametric duration model which assumes normally distributed hazards—an
assumption that is rarely met in survival analysis problems. As Figure 1 earlier showed, state
tax amnesties tend to be clustered in time, which would indicate a multimodal, rather than a
normal, distribution, thereby violating the normally distributed hazards assumption and
significantly affecting the econometric results. Finally, we investigate the role that political
factors might have in the timing and introduction of tax amnesties—as opposed to the purely
economic factors considered in DGW.
8
Political factors are likely to influence the decision to introduce a tax amnesty through
several (sometimes conflicting) channels. A priori, the net effect of gubernatorial elections on
the decision to introduce a tax amnesty is ambiguous—an empirical analysis is therefore
warranted. On the one hand, since amnesties are a revenue source—as is raising taxes—they
might similarly be frowned upon by state governors ahead of elections.
9
On the other hand,
since tax amnesties can, at least in the short term, be an alternative to increasing taxes as a
revenue source, governors could be tempted to rely more often on amnesties during election
years.
8
Dubin, Graetz, and Wilde (1992) also investigate the effect, on the probability that a state declares an amnesty,
of the Internal Revenue Service’s (IRS’s) audit rate. They find that, had the IRS’s audit rate been constant rather
than declining sharply as it was (and it has mostly continued to fall since 1992), states would have initiated far
fewer amnesties. It is now recognized, however, that the sharp decline in IRS audit rates might only weakly be
correlated with the effective detection capacity of the IRS since the IRS now relies much more on
computerization which enables extensive cross checking and more targeted audits than was possible in the
1980s.
9
A large empirical political economy literature finds evidence that state governors running for re-election
engineer a political-budget cycle, i.e., they have a tendency to increase spending and cut taxes ahead of
elections, and reverse this behavior after elections (see Besley and Case, 2003, for recent evidence as well as a
survey of the empirical literature).
6
II. METHODOLOGY: A DISCRETE-TIME DURATION MODEL
The econometric model for modeling duration data we use is Cox. Cox’s (Cox, 1972) semi-
parametric proportional hazard model provides a reasonable compromise between a purely
empirical (i.e., non-parametric) approach to survival and hazard function estimation and the
tight structure required by parametric models.
Cox’s proportional hazards model is the following:
(
)
(
)
(
)
(
)
kjkjjj
xbxbxbbx
j
ethethxth
+++
==
..
00
2211
where
(
)
j
xth is the probability that a tax amnesty occurs in state j any given year,
conditional on the state not having introduced an amnesty before and on the control variables
x
j
,
()
th
0
is known as the baseline hazard, and
(
)
kjkjjj
xbxbxbbx
ee
+++
=
..
2211
is the relative hazard.
kjkjjj
xbxbxbbx +++= ..
2211
is the log relative hazard (also known as the risk score).
The latter is assumed to be a function of the macroeconomic, fiscal, and political variables
(these are detailed in the next section).
One important advantage of the Cox model over parametric duration models is that it does
not assume any particular parameterization of the baseline hazard;
10
that is, the model does
not make any assumption about the shape of the hazard over time—it could be increasing,
decreasing, constant, increasing then decreasing, etc. The only assumption made is that,
whatever the shape of the hazard over time, it is the same for every U.S. state. Given the
relatively low number of tax amnesties in the U.S. states, the tests of the validity of
assumptions made on the shape of the hazard over time that are needed for parametric
estimations are expected to have low power.
11
III. DATA DESCRIPTION
The model measures the determinants of the time it takes for a state to declare its first tax
amnesty, with 1977 being the starting year. A total of 596 state-years are analyzed with
48 U.S. states, 36 tax amnesties, and a mean time until the first tax amnesty of 12.4 years
(with a minimum of 5 years and a maximum of 21 years). Once the first tax amnesty has
occurred (i.e., the first “failure”), subsequent state data and therefore tax amnesties are not
taken into consideration. The model does not therefore analyze the motives for repeated tax
amnesty programs.
10
Therefore, Cox’s model does not produce any estimate of the baseline hazard
(
)
th
0
.
11
However, should we know (or be able to test with sufficiently high power) the functional form of
(
)
th
0
, then
the semi-parametric Cox model would be less efficient.
7
The “escape/failure probability” (i.e., the probability of switching from having had no tax
amnesty to having one in the current year) is assumed to be a function of the following
macroeconomic and fiscal variables: the growth of a state’s growth state product (“Growth”),
total state taxes in millions of dollars (“Total taxes”), and the growth of a state’s indebtedness
(“Growth state debt”), and the following political variables: gubernatorial elections
(“Election”), and whether an incumbent governor unsuccessfully runs for another term
(“Governor defeated”). Detailed definitions and sources for these variables are in Table 1,
while Table 2 provides summary statistics of these variables.
Table 1. Definitions and Sources of Variables Used
Amnesty 1/ Binary dummy variable (equals one if there is a tax amnesty)
Total taxes 2/ Total state taxes collected (in millions of $US)
Growth 2/ Growth rate of per capita gross state product
Growth state debt 2/ Growth rate of total state debt
Election 3/
Gubernatorial elections binary dummy variable (equals one if there
is a gubernatorial election)
Governor defeated 3/
Incumbent state governor defeated in re-election bid. Binary
dummy variable (equals one if defeated)
1/ Source: The Federation of Tax Administrators.
2/ Source: U.S. Census Bureau, Statistical Abstract of the United States (various years).
3/ Source: The Book of the States, Council of State Governments (various years).
Table 2. Summary Statistics of Estimation Sample 1/
Variable Units Mean
Standard
Deviation Min. Max.
Total taxes Millions of U.S. dollars 629.7 158.3 231.1 1,070.3
Growth Percentage 6.9 4.0 -14.1 25.1
Growth state debt Percentage 14.8 26.1 -35.0 347.3
Election Binary dummy variable 0.29 0.46 0.0 1.0
Governor defeated Binary dummy variable 0.09 0.28 0.0 1.0
1/ Annual observations for 48 U.S. states starting in 1977. (Number of observations is 596.)
A state’s gross state product (GSP) growth rate (or alternatively, a state’s unemployment rate
as these are highly correlated) is expected to be negatively related to the introduction of a tax
amnesty program. Several channels are possible. First, because of the automatic fiscal
stabilizers, a state experiencing an economic slowdown, will, ceteris paribus, experience a
deterioration of its fiscal balance; this could increase the need for introducing a tax amnesty
in order to raise short-term revenue. Second, during a recession, as financial hardship
increases, noncompliance is also expected to increase (nonfiling, underreporting, etc.) which
could increase the need for an amnesty so as to increase the tax base going forward.
8
A state’s total tax collection is expected to be positively related to the introduction of a tax
amnesty program for several reasons. First, a large amount of tax collected—and its
corollary: a large state government—is indicative of a large need for revenue and a large
(in absolute amount) potential for evaded taxes. Second, a large state government has to be
financed by relying on a large revenue collection which, ceteris paribus, requires higher tax
rates than that of smaller governments. For a given detection probability and penalty
structure, higher tax rates are more likely to increase noncompliance than lower rates. As
absolute revenue and evaded taxes grow, at some point, a state might decide that the pool of
evaded taxes has become sufficiently large as to warrant the introduction of a tax amnesty
program so as to recapture some of the evaded money (the revenue yield motive).
The percentage change in a state’s total debt is expected to be positively correlated with the
introduction of a tax amnesty program. States that are experiencing a deterioration of their
fiscal balance (and a growing state debt) might consider the introduction of a state tax
amnesty as one way to increase revenue in the short-term and therefore limit the growth of
state debt (the fiscal stress motive).
Theoretically, gubernatorial elections have an ambiguous effect on the decision to introduce
a tax amnesty since several opposite channels are possible; the net effect, therefore, needs to
be determined empirically. On the one hand, a negative and significant effect would provide
evidence that state governors perceive taxes as another revenue source (akin to taxes): along
with the well documented political budget cycles among U.S. states showing that governors
do not introduce tax hikes during election years,
12
this would provide a first evidence that
they also shy away from amnesties during gubernatorial election years. Introducing a tax
amnesty program ahead of a gubernatorial election could be politically unwise since, should
the amnesty be successful, it would reveal to tax-abiding voters that they have been honestly
paying their taxes but that the state government has not been successful at enforcing a basic
taxation principle: that of horizontal equity. They could therefore blame the governor as
being incompetent and not reelect him/her. In the case where an amnesty is unsuccessful,
then the governor’s reputation could also be tarnished by having introduced an unsuccessful
program. On the other hand, a positive and significant effect would arise if governors think
of tax amnesties and tax increases as substitutes. A tax amnesty program is not a new tax but
an administrative scheme to collect past taxes. With tax increases ahead of elections being
politically difficult, a given need for short-term revenue could be accomplished by
introducing a tax amnesty program.
We expect that governors who decide to introduce a tax amnesty during an election year have
a higher probability of being defeated than those who abstain from introducing an amnesty
(i.e., we expect a positive and significant correlation between a defeated incumbent governor
and a tax amnesty program). Tax amnesties may be perceived as unfair by law-abiding
12
U.S. state governors have a tendency to increase (discretionary and highly visible) expenditures ahead of
gubernatorial elections, and also to lower or not increase taxes ahead of elections (see Besley and Case (2003)
for a survey of the literature and further evidence).
9
taxpayers since tax evaders are being rewarded by financial incentives (e.g., a waiver of both
penalties and interests on the tax liability, which implies, in real terms, a lower tax bill for tax
evaders than for tax-abiding citizens). As a result, law-abiding taxpayers/voters might punish
electorally a governor who declares a tax amnesty.
IV. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
We now turn to our empirical results from our panel data analysis of the determinants of the
occurrence of tax amnesties in U.S. states from 1977 to 1998. Table 3 below shows the
results of our Cox model with different control variables (x
j
s)—the first column (Model 1),
for instance, only controls for total state taxes as a determinant of the decision to introduce a
tax amnesty, while the last column (Model 5) simultaneously controls for the effect of all the
variables described above. Each coefficient measures the effect of a one unit change of the
explanatory variable. A hazard ratio greater (lesser) than 1.0 indicates an increase (decrease)
in the probability of a tax amnesty occurring. The table reveals that, controlling for the level
of a state’s total tax revenue and the gross state product’s growth rate, a tax amnesty program
has:
a significantly higher probability of being declared in states where debt is increasing;
a significantly lower probability of being declared (by a state governor) during a year
when gubernatorial elections are held; and
a significantly higher probability of being declared when an incumbent governor was
allowed to run for re-election but lost the election.
These results hold in all our specifications, and the magnitude and significance of the
coefficients are, quite surprisingly so, stable across all our specifications. They extend and
confirm some of the earlier results on DGW (1992). As do DGW, we find supportive
evidence that states with high tax levels are slightly more likely to initiate a tax amnesty
(see Models 1 and 2 in Table 3); a one million dollar increase in total state taxes is found to
increase the hazard of a tax amnesty by 0.2 percent.
However, in contrast with DGW, we find that even controlling for the revenue yield effect
(and a state’s growth rate), tax amnesties are more likely to be declared when a state is
experiencing a growing budget deficit. A 1 percentage point increase in state debt increases
the hazard of a tax amnesty by about 2 percent (Model 3 in Table 3). Tax amnesties are
therefore viewed as a revenue-raising source.
An especially striking result is that we are able to resolve a theoretically ambiguous effect
regarding the effect of political considerations on the timing of tax. We find that
policymakers perceive tax amnesties as another form of revenue source (the election
variable as a negative and significant coefficient in Model 4 of Table 3) rather than as an
alternative to a tax increase. Similar to the well-known aversion to increase taxes ahead of
elections, state governors are far less likely to declare a tax amnesty during a gubernatorial
10
election year: we find that tax amnesties are about 50 percent less likely to occur in election
years.
We also find evidence supporting the view that tax amnesty programs are perceived by voters
as “unfair” to them since they reward tax evaders with a lower effective tax rate than that of
law-abiding tax payers (thereby breaking horizontal equity). Model 5 in Table 3 shows that
state governors who ran for another term but lost their reelection bids were more than twice
as likely to offer a tax amnesty during their election years.
Table 3. Model for Time Waited Before Initiating a State Tax Amnesty
Variables: Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5
Total state taxes 1.002
(0.001)*
1.002
(0.001)**
1.002
(0.001)**
1.002
(0.001)***
1.003
(0.001)***
Growth 0.909
(0.049)*
0.901
(0.052)*
0.891
(0.044)**
0.906
(0.046)*
Growth state debt 1.017
(0.007)***
1.017
(0.004)***
1.018
(0.005)***
Election 0.520
(0.181)*
0.530
(0.179)*
Governor defeated 2.50
(0.81)***
Log likelihood -121.3 -120.0 -117.7 -116.7 -115.1
Number of observations 596 596 596 596 596
Notes: Hazard ratio (standard errors). The hazard ratio measures the effect of a one unit change of the
explanatory variable. A hazard ratio greater (lesser) than 1.0 indicates an increase (decrease) in the probability
of a tax amnesty occurring.
* denotes statistical significance at 10 percent level; ** denotes statistical significance at 5 percent
level; and *** denotes statistical significance at 1 percent level.
V. CONCLUSION
In this paper, we have revisited some of the early results on the determinants of tax amnesty
programs in the U.S. states. Our aim was twofold: first, to assess whether those determinants
have been stable over time; and, second, building on the recent political economy literature,
we check whether political—rather than purely economic—factors have a bearing on the
introduction of tax amnesty programs.
Similar to earlier empirical studies (e.g., Dubin, Graetz, and Wilde, 1992), we find that states
with high tax levels are more likely to initiate a tax amnesty. In contrast to earlier studies,
however, we also find that in our broader sample, even controlling for the revenue-yield
effect (and a state’s growth rate), tax amnesties are more likely to be declared when a state’s
indebtedness is growing. Tax amnesties are, therefore, viewed as a revenue-raising source.
11
A key novelty of this paper’s analysis is that (i) it shows not only that political factors
significantly affect the introduction and timing of tax amnesties, but also, and strikingly, that
(ii) the empirical results manage to clearly disentangle opposite theoretical political economy
effects. The results support the view that state governors perceive tax amnesties as another
form of revenue source (and not as an alternative to raising taxes). In particular, we find that
consistent with well-known aversion to increasing taxes ahead of elections, governors are
only half as likely to declare a tax amnesty during election years. This study also finds
supportive evidence that law-abiding taxpayers/voters might consider a tax amnesty as unfair
to them and would electorally punish governors who offered tax amnesties: governors who
run for another term but lost their reelection bids were more than twice as likely to have
offered a tax amnesty during their election years.
12
REFERENCES
Allingham, M.G., and A. Sandmo, 1972, “Income Tax Evasion: A Theoretical Analysis,”
Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 1, pp. 323–38.
Alm, J., and W. Beck, 1993, “Tax Amnesties and Compliance in the Long Run: A Time
Series Analysis,” National Tax Journal, Vol. 46, pp. 53–60.
Alm, J., M. McKee, and W. Beck, 1990, “Amazing Grace: Tax Amnesties and Compliance,”
National Tax Journal, Vol. 43, pp. 23–37.
Andreoni, J., 1991, “The Desirability of a Permanent Tax Amnesty,” Journal of Public
Economics, Vol. 45, pp. 143–59.
———, B. Erard, and J. Feinstein, 1998, “Tax Compliance,” Journal of Economic
Literature, Vol. 36, pp. 818–60.
Besley, T., and A. Case, 2003, “Political Institutions and Policy Choices: Evidence from the
United States,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 41(1), pp. 7–73.
Christian, C.W., S. Gupta, and J.C. Young, 2002, “Evidence on Subsequent Filing From the
State of Michigan’s Income Tax Amnesty, National Tax Journal, Vol. 55, pp. 703–21.
Cox, D., 1972, “Regression Models and Life Tables,” Journal of The Royal Statistical
Society, Series B, Vol. 34, pp. 187–220.
Dubin, J.A., M. Graetz, and L.L. Wilde, 1992, “State Income Tax Amnesties: Causes,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, pp. 271–83.
Franzoni, L.A., 1995, On the Economics of Tax Amnesties, D.Phil. Thesis, Nuffield College,
Oxford. [Chapter 2 is a detailed review of experiences of different countries.]
Graetz, M., and L. Wilde, 1993, “The Decision by Strategic Nonfilers to Participate in
Income Tax Amnesties,” International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 13,
pp. 271–83.
Joulfaian, D., 1988, “Participation in Tax Amnesties: Evidence from a State,” in Proceedings
of the Eighty-First Annual Conference on Taxation, National Tax Association,
Washington DC, pp. 128–32.
Leonard, H.B., and R. Zeckhauser, 1987, “Amnesty, Enforcement, and Tax Policy,” in Tax
Policy and the Economy, ed. by Lawrence Summers (Cambridge, Massachusetts:
MIT Press).
13
Malik, A.S., and R.M. Schwab, 1991, “The Economics of Tax Amnesties,” Journal of Public
Economics, Vol. 46, pp. 29–49.
Stella, P., 1991, “An Economic Analysis of Tax Amnesties,” Journal of Public Economics,
Vol. 46, pp. 383–400.
Torger, B., and C.A. Schaltergger, 2005, “Tax Amnesties in Switzerland and Around the
World,” Tax Notes International, June 27, pp. 1193–1203.
United States, Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, 1998, “Tax Amnesties,” January 30.
... In particular, Dubin et al. (1992), using amnesty data from US states between 1980 and 1988, found that states initiated amnesties mainly for revenue yield rather than fiscal stress motives. Luitel and Tosun (2014) shed doubt on this result showing that fiscal stress is a major driver of tax amnesties in US states, especially in the period 1989 to 2010 (see also Le Borgne (2006)). In contrast to these studies, our primary goal is to explain the occurrence of amnesties theoretically, leading to an empirical specification where fiscal requirements are not only captured by the revenue (as in the aforementioned papers) but also the expenditure side of a government's budget. ...
... 20 Notice that this constitutes a major difference to previous empirical research, only including the revenue side of public households. In particular, most of the existing empirical studies follow Dubin et al. (1992) focusing on two motives behind the initiation of tax amnesties (see Le Borgne (2006) or Luitel and Tosun (2014)). These are significant (short run) revenue gains (the "yield" motive), and to overcome periods where governments are short of funds (the "fiscal stress" motive). ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper presents a theoretical model and empirical evidence to explain the occurrence of tax amnesties. We treat amnesties as endogenous, resulting from a strategic game between many taxpayers discounting future payments from punishment and a government that balances costs and benefits of amnesty programs. From the model we derive hypotheses about the factors that should influence the occurrence of tax amnesties. To test these predictions empirically, we rely on amnesty information from US States between 1981 and 2011. In line with the theoretical model, our empirical findings suggest that the likelihood of amnesties is mainly driven by a government's fiscal requirements and the taxpayers' expectations on future amnesties. Crown
... Studies conducted by Borgne (2006); Martin & Camarda (2017) and Buckwalter et al. (2013) stated that one of the most important reasons for calling tax amnesty is that tax amnesties are seen as a source of increasing public revenue since tax amnesties are often applied when the government debt is likely to grow. Governments use amnesty as an incentive for citizens to return large amounts of money into the country. ...
Article
This research presents the reasons for tax amnesty, and the positive and negative opinions towards tax amnesty from the perspective of taxpayers based on a comprehensive survey conducted with participants in the Republic of Kosovo. Significant differences among survey results are evaluated by gender, age, education, and duration as taxpayer. Hypotheses are tested with the Independent-Sample t-test, One Way ANOVA, and Tukey Post Hock LSD tests. According to results from hypothesis testing, the main reasons for tax amnesty includes (i) reducing the workload of tax administration and judiciary, (ii) short-term public revenue growth, (iii) a new beginning for taxpayers who have shown discrepancies in tax compliance, and (iv) the use of tax amnesty as a tool for the programs political programs. Öz Bu çalışmada, Kosova Cumhuriyeti'ndeki uygulanan vergi aflarının nedenleri ve vergi aflarına karşı mükelleflerin olumlu ve olumsuz görüşlerini tespitine yönelik yapılan araştırma sonuçlarına yer verilmiştir. Bununla birlikte, araştırma verileri ile ankete katılan mükelleflerin, vergi aflarının nedenleri ve vergi afları ile ilgili oluşturulan olumlu ve olumsuz görüşlere katılma düzeyleri arasında; cinsiyetlerine, yaşlarına, eğitim durumlarına ve mükellefiyet sürelerine göre bir farklılığın olup olmadığı tespit edilmeye çalışılmıştır. Araştırma ile ilgili oluşturulan hipotezlerin testinde ise Bağımsız-Örneklem T-testi, Tek Yönlü Anova ve Tukey Post Hock LSD testleri kullanılmıştır. Çalışma, vergi aflarının temel nedenlerini tanımlamaktadır. Hipotez sonuçları, vergi affının temel nedenlerini ve gerekçelerini ortaya çıkarır; bunlar vergi idaresi ve yargı iş yükünün azaltılması, kısa vadeli kamu geliri artışı, vergiye uyum konusunda tutarsızlıklar gösteren ve sosyal ve politik programların uygulanmasında bir araç olarak affı kullanan vergi mükellefleri için yeni bir başlangıçtır.
... Studies conducted by Borgne (2006); Martin & Camarda (2017) and Buckwalter et al. (2013) stated that one of the most important reasons for calling tax amnesty is that tax amnesties are seen as a source of increasing public revenue since tax amnesties are often applied when the government debt is likely to grow. Governments use amnesty as an incentive for citizens to return large amounts of money into the country. ...
... Research Alm et al. (2009) show that tax amnesty conducted by Russia in the 1990s had little impact on long and short term tax revenues. Tax amnesty in the United States is part of the political business cycle (Le Borgne, 2006). Boniello et al. (2003) identified that countries that had successfully implemented tax amnesty were Italy, India, and South Africa. ...
... Vergi aflarının vergi adaletini bozduğu ve vergi mükelleflerinin vergi ödeme istekleri üzerinde olumsuz etkiler yarattığından söz edilmektedir. IMF tarafından 2006'da yayımlanan bir çalışmada, vergi afları nedeni ile oluşan kayıpların, kazanımlarından daha fazla olduğu belirtilmektedir (Borgne, 2006). Sıkça uygulanan vergi afları mükelleflerin vergi kaçırmanın meşru olduğu algısına kapılmalarına zemin hazırlayabilir. ...
Article
Full-text available
Vergi kavramı mükellefler üzerinde olumlu veya olumsuz düşünceleri çağrıştırabilir. Mükelleflerin bazıları vergiyi sosyal bir sorumluluk olarak görürken, bazıları ise vergiye karşı olumsuz düşüncelere sahip olabilmektedir. Bu araştırma Tekirdağ ilindeki gelir vergisi mükelleflerini kapsamaktadır. Araştırmada gelir vergisi mükelleflerinin vergi afları karşısında tutum ve davranışlarının ortaya çıkarılması amaçlanmıştır. Tekirdağ ilinde bir saha araştırması yapılmış ve elde edilen veriler SPSS 22.0 paket programı yardımı ile “TTesti”, “ANOVA Testi” ve “Korelasyon Analizi” gibi bir dizi istatiksel sınamaya tabi tutulmuştur. Araştırmada mükelleflerinin, vergi aflarına karşı aşırı bir tepki göstermedikleri ve bazı dönemlerde vergi aflarını kurtarıcı olarak görüldükleri sonucu elde edilmiştir. Vergi afların ekonomide durgunluk yaşanan dönemlerde ve daralma yaşanan sektörleri kapsayan biçimde uygulanması başarısını etkileyecektir.
... Le Borgne (2006Borgne ( , ss . 9-10) 1977Borgne ( -1998 (2017) Türkiye'de yapılan vergi affı çalışmalarının ampirik (anket) sonuçlarını meta veri analiziyle değerlendirmiştir. ...
Article
Full-text available
Bu çalışma, 2010 sonrasında Türkiye’de çıkarılan vergi af kanunlarının vergi gelirleri üzerindeki etkisini, aylık tahsil/tahakkuk verilerini kullanarak, olay analiziyle (event study) değerlendirmeyi amaçlamaktadır. Türkiye, tasarruf yetersizliği ve ekonomik ve politik maliyetlerinin düşük olmasından dolayı sıklıkla vergi aflarına başvurmaktadır ve vergi afları vergi politikasının bir aracı haline gelmiştir. Türkiye, 1980 sonrasında çıkarılan vergi aflarının bir kısmından kısa zamanda yüksek gelirler elde etmesine karşın 2003 sonrasında çıkarılan vergi aflarından istediği geliri elde edememiştir. Bu dönemde vergi tahsil/tahakkuk oranlarında da ciddi bir düşüş yaşanmaktadır. Tahsil/tahakkuk oranı 2006 yılında yüzde 92.2 iken, 2018 yılında yüzde 81.4 olarak gerçekleşmiştir. Bu çalışma, Türkiye’de 2010 yılından sonra çıkarılan vergi aflarının vergi gelirleri üzerindeki etkisini, aylık tahsil/tahakkuk oranları temel alınarak 6 ve 12 aylık etkileri itibariyle olay analiziyle (bağımlı örneklem t testi) incelemektedir. Bu bağlamda, çalışma ampirik olarak alandaki önemli bir boşluğu doldurduğu gibi finans alanında kullanılan bir yöntem maliye alanına da kazandırılmış olmaktadır. 2010 sonrasında çıkarılan vergi afları, 6 ve 12 aylık etkileri dikkate alındığında, vergi gelirleri üzerinde istatistiksel olarak anlamlı bir etkiye sahip olmadığı görülmektedir. Vergi aflarının başarılı olabilmesi için affın bir vergi reformunun parçası olarak ortaya çıkması, vergi aflarına sıklıkla başvurulmaması ve vergi aflarına ekonomik kriz veya doğal afetler gibi olaylardan sonra başvurulması gerekmektedir. (This paper is to evaluate the effect of tax amnesty laws which enacted in Turkey after 2010 on tax receipts by means of event study by employing monthly tax collection/tax accrual ratios. Turkey often introduces the tax amnesty laws because of lack of savings and tax amnesties become the basic policy instrument of tax policy. Turkey hasn’t received expected amount of tax revenues from tax amnesties since 2003 even though it got great amount of tax revenues from some of these amnesties in the short term after 1980. In this period, the ratio of tax collection/tax acrual has seriously declined from 92.2 percent in 2006 to 81.4 percent in 2018. It’s observed that tax amnesties enacted after 2010 have statistically no effect on tax receipts when considering the 6 and 12 months impacts. Tax amnesties should be appeared as a part of tax reforms, introduced after economic crisis and natural disasters and shouldn’t be frequently applied for the achievement of these programmes)
... An honest taxpayer will not make an intentional decision to default in his tax payment but may be caught off guard if indicted for a false filed tax return Thus, for the honest taxpayer, the amnesty is a previously inaccessible platform to lessen punishments meted out, or expected to be enforced as a result of tax default (Mello e Souza, 2006). Borgne (2006) also discovered that tax amnesties are instituted more in countries with increasing debts. Tax amnesties are, therefore, viewed as a source of generating funds or revenue by the government. ...
Article
Full-text available
Penelitian ini bertujuan untuk menganalisis pengaruh tax amnesty dan sanksi pajak terhadap kepatuhan wajib pajak di Kantor Pelayanan Pajak Makassar Selatan Variabel independen dalam penelitian ini yaitu tax amnesty dan sanksi pajak, sedangkan variabel dependen yaitu kepatuhan wajib pajak. Populasi dalam penelitian ini adalah seluruh wajib pajak orang pribadi yang wajib lapor SPT di Kantor Pelayanan Pajak Kratama Makassar Selatan. Data yang digunakan dalam penelitian ini adalah kuesioner dengan menggunakan skala likert 1 sampai 5. Pengambilan sampel yang digunakan dalam penelitian ini menggunakan metode purposive sampling. Jumlah sampel dalam penelitian ini sebanyak 100 responden. Metode analisis data yang digunakan dalam penelitian ini adalah analisis regresi linear berganda meggunakan program SPSS. Berdasarkan hasil analisis dalam penelitian ini menunjukkan bahwa tax amnesty tidak berpengaruh terhadap kepatuhan wajib pajak. Tidak berpengaruhnya tax amnesty terhadap kepatuhan wajib pajak diakibatkan kurangnya sosialisasi yang sehingga banyak wajib pajak yang tidak mengetahui adanya program tax amnesty ini sehingga kurangnya partisipasi dari wajib pajak orang pribadi. Sedangkan sanksi pajak berpengaruh terhadap kepatuhan wajib pajak. Sanksi pajak yang semakin tinggi akan meningkatkan kepatuhan wajib pajak di masa mendatang.
Article
Full-text available
The purpose of the paper is to take an incisive glimpse into Pakistan’s political economy through the lens of a tax policy abnorm i.e. the tax amnesty scheme, 2018. The paper is theoretically anchored in the elitist framework which arguably best explains structural composition of the economy. The paper refines the elitist framework, accentuates its significance, and innovates on it to induct the competing Freudian concepts of “pleasure principle” and “reality principle” to sharpen our understanding of Pakistan’s political economy. It is argued that impending inflows of offshore bank and financial account information of Pakistan resident persons under the OECD’s Multilateral Convention was the main dynamic of the amnestization initiative in which the Supreme Court of Pakistan played the role of the agent provocateur. The empirical results obtained help conclude that the amnestization initiatives have helped proliferate underground economy, and enhance the elitist economic status quo in Pakistan.
Article
Full-text available
Tax amnesties; for economic, financial, social and political reasons, the state will give up some of the tax receivable. The general purpose of the government to give up the receivable is to ensure the transfer of the receivables to the treasury that will not be transferred to the treasury at all. The purpose of the study; the reasons for applying tax amnesties are theoretically and the reasons for economic reasons and political reasons are more effective in determining tax amnesty, Probit analysis was made. Besides, the frequent removal of tax amnesties as a short-term solution in recent years also reveals the necessity of the study and the necessity of making it.
Article
Full-text available
a one-time amnesty may increase future Does a tax amnesty raise or lower com- compliance if it is accompanied by greater pliance over time? This paper uses experi- expenditures for enforcement and stronger mental methods to analyze the long run penalties for evaders. Critics contend that impact of an amnesty. The results indicate the long run consequences of an amnesty that the average level of compliance falls are more likely to lead to a significant after an amnesty. However, a well-de- negative impact on voluntary compliance. signed amnesty may be able to overcome They present several arguments to bol- this decline. If post-amnesty enforcement ster their case. First, honest taxpayers may efforts increase, then aggregate comp,ii- perceive the amnesty as special treat- ance actually increases. In fact, post-am- ment for tax cheats. If the honest taxpay- nesty compliance is higher when an am- ers resent the tax break given to evaders nesty is accompanied by increased and conclude that the amnesty is unfair enforcement efforts than when enforce- to them, then their compliance may de- ment increases without an amnesty. An cline. Second, individuals may not believe amnesty may therefore be an effective tool that the amnesty is a one-time opportu- for easing the transition to a tougher tax nity to repay taxes. If they anticipate fu- regime. ture amnesties, then compliance may again decline. No work to date has been able to re-
Article
Full-text available
This paper discusses time series methods that can be used to examine the long run effects of a tax amnesty, and ap- plies these methods to the 1985 Colorado amnesty. Several time series models are estimated: simple ordinary least squares time trend mode/s, univariate time series models, and multivariate intervention models. The empirical results from all models strongly indicate that the Colo- rado amnesty had no long run impact on either the level or the trend of tax collec- tions. This result suggests that a typical amnesty seems unlikely to generate sig- nificant new revenues, but also seems un- likely to compromise voluntary compli- ance.
Article
Full-text available
Based on individual taxpayer-level data from Michigan, this study provides first-time empirical evidence on the subsequent filing compliance of state income tax amnesty participants. We find that about two-thirds of new filers and nine-tenths of previous filers who filed amended returns under amnesty, subsequently filed income tax returns. These results hold after controlling for observable differences between new and amending filers. Although in aggregate an estimated 5,500 taxpayers were added to Michigan's tax rolls, the additional revenue raised from these taxpayers appears marginal, at about 0.1 percent of the state's personal income tax revenues.
Article
Full-text available
There are two main concerns about tax amnesty. First, if it is anticipated it may increase cheating and reduce the efficiency of the tax system. Second, amnesty may be inequitable by letting cheaters ‘off the hook’. However, several federal governments currently hold a policy of long-term, or permanent, tax amnesty, in apparent defiance of these concerns. This paper examines fully anticipated tax amnesty and finds that it is possible for a permanent tax amnesty to actually increase, rather than decrease, the efficiency and equity of the tax system.
Article
Full-text available
This paper analyzes empirically for the years 1980-1988 the factors that led states with state income taxes to run tax amnesty programs. We find that the potential yield from an amnesty is more important than the fiscal status of a state. Furthermore, we estimate that if the 1RS audit rate had remained constant during the 1980–1988 period (instead of falling by almost one half), then the cumulative probability that an average state would have had a tax amnesty by 1988 would have fallen by just over 25 percent.
Article
The analysis of censored failure times is considered. It is assumed that on each individual are available values of one or more explanatory variables. The hazard function (age-specific failure rate) is taken to be a function of the explanatory variables and unknown regression coefficients multiplied by an arbitrary and unknown function of time. A conditional likelihood is obtained, leading to inferences about the unknown regression coefficients. Some generalizations are outlined. LIFEtables are one of the oldest statistical techniques and are extensively used by medical statisticians and by actuaries. Yet relatively little has been written about their more formal statistical theory. Kaplan and Meier (1958) gave a comprehensive review of earlier work and many new results. Chiang in a series of papers has, in particular, explored the connection with birth-death processes; see, for example, Chiang (1968). The present paper is largely concerned with the extension of the results of Kaplan and Meier to the comparison of life tables and more generally to the incorporation of regression-like arguments into life-table analysis. The arguments are asymptotic but are relevant to situations where the sampling fluctuations are large enough to be of practical importance. In other words, the applications are more likely to be in industrial reliability studies and in medical statistics than in actuarial science. The procedures proposed are, especially for the two-sample problem, closely related to procedures for combining contingency tables; see Mantel and Haenzel (1959), Mantel (1963) and, especially for the application to life tables, Mantel (1966). There is also a strong connection with a paper read recently to the Society by R. and J. Peto (1972). We consider a population of individuals; for each individual we observe either the time to "failure" or the time to ccloss" or censoring. That is, for the censored individuals we know only that the time to failure is greater than the censoring time. Denote by T a random variable representing failure time; it may be discrete or continuous. Let F(t) be the survivor function, %(t) = pr (T2 t)
Article
The analysis of censored failure times is considered. It is assumed that on each individual are available values of one or more explanatory variables. The hazard function (age‐specific failure rate) is taken to be a function of the explanatory variables and unknown regression coefficients multiplied by an arbitrary and unknown function of time. A conditional likelihood is obtained, leading to inferences about the unknown regression coefficients. Some generalizations are outlined.
Article
Tax amnesties have frequently been justified as politically popular ways to generate increases in government revenue. This paper examines the circumstances under which amnesties are likely to have a beneficial impact on revenue collections. It concludes that, while in general it may be correct to impose a reduced penalty on individuals who voluntarily disclose tax evasion, shortlived amnesties of the type most frequently observed in practice are unlikely to generate genuinely additional revenue, particularly when judged against the potential danger of reducing future tax compliance.
Article
Amnesties are widely used in society to rehabilitate past sinners, to collect resources, such as library books, that would otherwise be unrecoverable, and to make enforcement easier by reducing the ranks of delinquents. Over the past four years, tax amnesties have emerged as a major instrument of state revenue policy. Twenty states conducted amnesties. Record collections were made by New York ($360 million) and Illinois (income tax amnesty dollars 3.4% of collections). Amnesties took in dollars that would probably have escaped otherwise, and tax rolls were bolstered. Tax amnesties also have costs, however. They may anger honest taxpayers, diminish the legitimacy of the tax system by pardoning past evasion, and decrease compliance by making future amnesties seem more likely. Shou1.d the federal government, aswirl in tax reform and suffering from an estimated $100 billion tax evasion problem, now offer an amnesty of its own? What type of federal program would most likely be offered? What would it be likely to accomplish? State tax amnesties have generally bean coupled with enhanced enforcement efforts, a feature intended to preserve the legitimacy of the tan system. The amnesty/enforcement combination twists the penalty schedule, lowering it non raising it later, in that way encouraging prompt payment. With no past sins to hide, future compliance also becomes less costly, hence more probable. Any federal amnesty, we predict, would be accompanied by a strengthening of enforcement. After reviewing the state experience, we speculatively estimate that a federal amnesty/enforcement to annual revenues on the order of $10 billion.