ArticlePDF Available

Japanese Lifetime Employment: A Century's Perspective

Authors:
  • Hitotsubashi University Business School

Abstract and Figures

This paper examines the origins and dynamic evolution of the lifetime employment system in Japan from the beginning of the 20th century to present. Based on the historical perspective developed in the paper, we derive implications to the future course of the Japanese employment system. In this paper, we view lifetime employment as an economic as well as social institution, characterized by an implicit contract and reciprocal exchange of trust, goodwill, and commitment between employers and workers. We argue that this institution emerged as an equilibrium outcome of the dynamic interactions among management, labor, and government and became an integral part of the nation's employment system over the past hundred years, reinforced by complementary institutions such as state welfare policies, labor laws, corporate governance, social norms, family values, and education system. Based on our long-run historical analysis, we reevaluate the cost and benefit both in terms of economic and social of the lifetime employment system and explore the factors that determine its efficiency and stability. We emphasize the importance of understanding labor market conditions, technology and the nature of human capital, interactions between social and economic aspects of employment relations, and the role of complementary institutions. The paper concludes by assessing changes in these factors in the post-bubble period, offering some insights to the future course of the Japanese employment system.
Content may be subject to copyright.
INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE IN JAPAN
JAPANESE LIFETIME EMPLOYMENT: A CENTURY'S
PERSPECTIVE
by
Chiaki Moriguchi and Hiroshi Ono
Working Paper 205
September 2004
Postal address: P.O. Box 6501, S-113 83 Stockholm, Sweden. Office address: Sveavägen 65
Telephone: +46 8 736 93 60 Telefax: +46 8 31 30 17 E-mail: japan@hhs.se Internet: http://www.hhs.se/eijs
1
1
Institutional Change in Japan
Japanese Lifetime Employment: A Century's Perspective
(Forthcoming in Institutional Change in Japan: Why It Happens, Why It Doesn’t.
Edited by Magnus Blomström and Sumner La Croix.)
Chiaki Moriguchi, Northwestern University and NBER
chiaki@northwestern.edu
Hiroshi Ono, Stockholm School of Economics
hiroshi.ono@hhs.se
Date of Revision: July 8, 2003
Abstract
The economic stagnation in the 1990s in Japan posed a serious challenge to the practice of
“lifetime employment.” Despite pessimistic predictions, however, empirical studies have found
no major changes to the practice pertaining to core employees. Why does lifetime employment
persist in Japan? This paper develops a conceptual framework motivated by personnel economics
and sociology and explores the persistence and stability of Japanese lifetime employment from a
historical perspective.
In this paper, we view lifetime employment as a set of interdependent human resource
management (HRM) practices surrounding an implicit and long-term employment contract. We
further examine these firm-level practices within the context of an employment system in which
micro-level practices interact with macro-level institutions. Using this framework, we study the
formation and transformation of lifetime employment, focusing on key historical events such as
the Great Depression, Postwar Occupation, High Growth, Oil Crisis, and the Post-Bubble
stagnation.
Our analysis shows that lifetime employment is a product of dynamic interactions among
labor, management, and government in response to changing environment. The practice evolved
gradually into a cluster of HRM policies, which was further reinforced by the endogenous
formation of labor laws, state welfare system, and social norms. As a result, today’s Japanese
lifetime employment is deeply embedded into complementary practices and institutions, resulting
in its resilience and stability. The paper concludes by offering some insights into the future
course of Japanese lifetime employment.
2
2
1. Introduction
Sociologists and economists have long recognized the employment security and corporate
loyalty shared by white-collar and blue-collar employees in large firms as a uniquely Japanese
institution (Abegglen 1958; Dore 1973; Shirai 1983; Koike 1988). At the same time, many
scholars have predicted the demise of so-called Japanese lifetime employment in the past.
Cole (1971) argued that it was not sustainable under high economic growth, as chronic labor
shortages would raise employees’ outside options who would then be tempted to move from
one job to another. Beck and Beck (1994) and others predicted that the economic slowdown
in the 1990s coupled by the globalization of financial markets would change managerial
incentives. Infusion of foreign capital and necessity of rationalization, they argued, would
promote American-style personnel practices, such as layoffs, performance pay, and mid-
career hiring, and undermine the precarious equilibrium between management and labor.
Contrary to the scholarly predictions and journalistic reports, empirical studies have so
far detected no major changes in the practice of lifetime employment pertaining to “core”
employees. Although quantifying the extent of lifetime employment has been difficult due
to the lack of a simple empirical definition, for one measure, the proportion of long-tenure
workers (ten years or longer) in Japan averaged 43 percent in the 1990s, while the same
proportion in the U.S. was 26 percent (Auer and Cazes 2000). Following up the study by
Hashimoto and Raisian (1985), Kato (2001) shows that ten-year job retention rates of core
male employees (age 30 to 44 with more than 5 years of tenure) changed little from the 1977-
87 period to 1987-97 period.1 Tsuru (2002) documents that the ratios of long-term male
employees to total workforce increased in the 1980s and remained stable throughout the
1990s at firms of all sizes.2 Labor turnover data confirm these observations. As Figure 1
shows, the establishment-level separation rates of manufacturing workers declined
1 A ten-year job retention rate is a ratio of workers employed by the same firm after ten years to an initial
number of workers.
2 See also Chuma (1998) and Rebick (2001) for similar empirical assessments.
3
3
considerably during the high growth period (1960-75) and remained low thereafter, with only
a mild upward trend since 1996. Note that the data cover smaller establishments (employing
30 or more workers) as well as female employees for which lifetime employment has been
less prevalent. Moreover, “separations” in the data include intra-firm transfers of employees
across establishments, a common employment adjustment method to avoid dismissals.
Why does lifetime employment persist in Japan? Why do we not observe a drastic
institutional change despite the more-than-a-decade-long economic stagnation? The first
objective of this paper is to introduce a conceptual framework motivated by personnel
economics and sociology to study the stability and persistence of Japanese lifetime
employment. In light of recent advances in personnel economics, we characterize today’s
lifetime employment as a cluster of human resource management (HRM) practices that
constitute a self-enforcing equilibrium. We also examine these practices within the context
of the Japanese economic system in which firm-level practices interact with macro-level legal,
political, and social institutions. The second objective of this paper is to apply this
framework to a historical analysis and investigate the formation and transformation of lifetime
employment over the last several decades.
What can history tell us? Our analysis delivers two main messages. First, Japanese
lifetime employment is a product of dynamic interactions among management, labor, and
government in response to changing environments. As such, the practice evolved into a set
of sophisticated and interdependent HRM practices. Second, the firm-level practices were
reinforced by the endogenous formation of macro-level institutions, such as labor laws, state
welfare policies, and social norms. As a consequence, today’s lifetime employment is
deeply embedded into complementary practices and institutions, resulting in its resilience and
stability.
4
4
The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 lays out a conceptual
framework. Section 3 presents a historical analysis, documenting the evolution of Japanese
lifetime employment. Section 4 speculates the future course of lifetime employment, and
the last section concludes.
2. Re-conceptualizing Lifetime Employment
Recent literature in personnel economics has emphasized a complementarity among HRM
practices, the property defined by the increasing marginal benefits of some practices in the
usage of others.3 Since the early 1980s, a number of American manufacturing firms
introduced aspects of Japanese-style HRM practices, such as small group activities and
flexible job assignments, to improve labor productivity. In many instances, their
experiments failed (Brown and Reich 1989; Osterman 1994). These and other observations
stimulated the theoretical literature that underscores the importance of adopting a set of HRM
practices at once as opposed to a piecemeal introduction of a few (e.g. Kanemoto and
MacLeod 1992; Kandel and Lazear 1992; Baker, Gibbons, and Murphy 1994; Milgrom and
Roberts 1995). Although empirical identification of complementarities proved to be difficult,
using micro survey data, a growing number of studies find evidence in support of the theory
(e.g. MacDuffie 1995; Ichniowski, Shaw, and Prennushi 1997; Kato and Morishima 2002).
In light of these advances, we re-conceptualize lifetime employment as a cluster of
complementary HRM practices.
Lifetime employment commonly refers to long-term employment contracts (i.e.,
indefinite contracts specifying no fixed duration) with an implicit handshake between
employers and regular employees. Since Japan’s statutory laws stipulate that either party
can terminate such contracts at any time with a short advance notice, the contracts have to be
3 See Ichniowski and Shaw (2003) for a comprehensive literature review.
5
5
internally enforced, that is, there must be an incentive for both management and workers to
conform to their promise.4 Observe, however, that long-term employment is intrinsically
fragile as any changes in product or labor market conditions would affect ex post incentive of
one of the two parties. For example, during economic prosperity workers have a greater
incentive to leave their firms, while during recessions employers have a stronger incentive to
renege on their promises. So what makes long-term employment contracts self-enforcing?
In practice, the following areas in HRM are found critical in supporting lifetime
employment in Japanese firms (Koike 1988; Shimada 1988; Sako and Sato 1997; Tachibanaki
and Noda 2000; Kato 2000): (1) human capital development that raises an employee’s
productivity over his tenure and provides managerial incentives to retain the employee, e.g.
corporate training, job rotations, small group activities such as quality circles; (2)
compensation system that provides incentives for employees to exert effort, acquire desirable
human capital, and remain with the firm, e.g. seniority-plus-merit wage, internal promotion,
bonuses, corporate pensions; (3) employment adjustment methods that protect the level of
employment, while providing management with alternative ways to reduce labor costs during
business downturns, e.g. hiring freeze, intra- and inter-firm transfers, voluntary retirement;
and (4) internal enforcement and coordination mechanisms that facilitate information sharing,
enable employees to monitor management, and encourage labor-management cooperation, e.g.
enterprise unions, join labor-management committees, workplace socialization. In short,
today’s lifetime employment consists of a set of sophisticated and interdependent HRM
practices that encompasses multiple aspects of work organization and labor-management
relations.
In our framework, we further embed micro-level HRM practices within the broader
context of an employment system of the Japanese economy (Aoki 1990; Moriguchi 2000).
4 As we discuss in detail later, there has been a development of case law precedents that restrict employers’ right
of dismissal to a certain degree.
6
6
Following Coleman (1990), we conceptualize lifetime employment as an outcome of the
long-run interactions between micro- and macro-level institutions. At the macro-level, the
government designs labor market regulations, union laws, and social welfare policies that
impact incentives of labor and management.5 Although these macro-level institutions are
exogenous to individual employers and workers, in the long run, they are endogenously
shaped as they interact with micro-level institutions. For example, dominant HRM
practices influence government policies as they create or eliminate demand for particular laws
or regulations. Similarly, we claim that social norms – notably loyalty, trust, and
commitment that are often assumed to be fixed cultural traits – evolve endogenously as they
are nurtured by micro-level economic and social exchange relations. In general, the long-run
interactions between management, labor, and the government give rise to a stable
employment system, in which micro-level institutions and macro-level institutions are
complementary to one another.
In the following historical analysis, we focus on major historical events – the Great
Depression, the Postwar Occupational Reforms, the High Growth period, the Oil Shock, and
the Post-Bubble stagnation – and document how they shaped and transformed lifetime
employment in Japan.
3. The Creation and Transformation of Lifetime Employment
3.1 Corporate Welfarism and the Challenge of the Great Depression
Lifetime employment traced its origins to corporate welfarism that emerged during the
interwar period (Hyodo 1971; Hazama 1978; Gordon 1985; Moriguchi 2000). World War I
(1914-18) brought about a rapid growth of heavy industries and a shortage of skilled labor
force. Moreover, as mechanization advanced and firms grew larger, production technology
5 Although it is beyond the scope of this paper, other institutions, such as corporate governance and supplied
relations also affect the feasibility and effectiveness of HRM practices. See, for example, Aoki (1988) and
Nishiguchi (1994).
7
7
and work organization became increasingly firm-specific. To train and retain skilled
workers (jukuren-ko), who were well-known for their footlooseness and lack of corporate
loyalty, major employers began introducing a variety of HRM practices (Kyochokai 1924).
In particular, leading firms set up corporate apprenticeship schools rather than relying
on public vocational schools, and gradually reduced mid-career hiring in favor of workers
trained in-house. Initially, however, a majority of apprentices left their employers after, if not
during, a training period for better wage offers (Hyodo 1971, p.407; Hazama 1978, p.513).
To reduce labor turnover, which often exceeded an annual rate of 80 percent during the 1910s,
employers introduced pecuniary incentives, such as service bonuses, periodic pay raises, and
retirement allowances, which were previously offered only to white-collar employees, to
blue-collar workers. Management awarded pay raises to a fixed percentage of workers
based on their merit and length of service, and instituted retirement allowances whose amount
increased with the years of service. Compared to the postwar practices, however, the
amount and coverage of these benefits were small and their payments irregular (Showa
Dojinkai 1960, pp.265-80).
In response to the surge of the labor movement in the late 1910s, leading employers
also introduced plant-level employee representation or “factory councils” to facilitate labor-
management communication and preempt employee discontent (Kyochokai 1926). Unlike
enterprise unions in the postwar period, these councils consisted exclusively of blue-collar
employees, reflecting a sharp status distinction between blue-collar and white-collar
employees within an establishment during the prewar period. Moreover, in most cases,
management restricted the subjects of council meetings to issues such as health, safety,
recreation, and efficiency improvements, refusing to discuss wages, hours, and benefits.
Early corporate welfarism was confined to a minority of prosperous employers in the
economy – such as Mitsubishi Shipyards, Sumitomo Metals, Hitachi Engineering, Nippon
8
8
Electric, and Yahata Ironworks – consisting of no more than a few hundred large private and
state-owned establishments mostly in capital-intensive industries. The number of
establishments instituting factory councils, for example, was fewer than 200 throughout the
1920s (Kyochokai 1929, Chapter 9). Although the HRM practices became less erratic and
more systematized among these establishments during the interwar period, employers retained
full discretion over qualifying or disqualifying individual employees as well as modifying or
discontinuing the practices at will with legal impunity. In the word of a contemporary
government official, the vaunted corporate welfarism rested entirely on “the whims of
capitalists” (Garon 1988, p.172).
The Japanese economy was troubled by successive downturns in the interwar period,
including the 1921 post-WWI recession, the 1923 Kanto Great Earthquake, and the 1926
Financial Crisis. The largest shock was the Great Depression of 1929-31 during which time
the nation’s industrial production declined by 8 percent. Numerous firms, including largest
employers, reduced wages, cancelled benefits, and undertook large-scale layoffs. The level
of employment fell by more than 8 percent in 1929-31. In protest, workers organized strikes
and public demonstrations. In 1930 alone, more than eight hundred disputes broke out
involving 72,000 workers, and over one million working days were lost (see Figure 2). The
surge of labor disputes prompted the government to exhort business leaders not to dismiss
workers en masse for fear of widespread unemployment and social disorder. Workers’
protest and government pressure urged management to develop measures to avoid dismissals.
Two major methods of employment adjustment, which became common practices after WWII,
emerged during the interwar period.
First, when dismissals became inevitable, major employers solicited workers to accept
voluntary retirement (kibo taishoku) in exchange for augmented retirement allowance.
Although voluntary retirement was de facto dismissal, management consulted employees in
9
9
advance and the sum of retirement allowance received by the employees, which increased
with their length of tenure, was nontrivial (Shakaikyoku 1936).6 The practice of voluntary
retirement was often effective in moderating workers’ discontent and helped maintain
cooperative relations between management and remaining employees (Gordon 1985, p.201;
Nishinarita 1988, pp.183-92).
Second, large firms began to use temporary workers (rinji-ko) as a buffer to insulate
core employees from business fluctuations. Previously, temporary workers were commonly
promoted to regular worker status after a short probationary period. During the interwar
period, however, the status of temporary workers became fixed indefinitely. They were
hired under short-term renewable contracts and let go first when business conditions
deteriorated. As management disqualified temporary workers from retirement allowance
plans, the cost of dismissing them was significantly lower than dismissing regular workers
(Hyodo 1971, p.430; Hazama 1978, p.498).
To summarize, during the interwar period, leading employers introduced a set of HRM
practices, such as company training, incentive pay, plant-level employee representation, and
employment security, to foster core skilled workers. Workers’ protest against employment
reduction and the elimination of benefits, together with government intermediation during
labor disputes, gradually established an expectation that these benefits were part of the “just
reward” that could not be withdrawn at management’s will (Gordon 1985, pp.196-206). In
response, management developed methods of adjusting employment to mitigate the cost of
long-term commitment in business downturns. As Figure 1 shows, separation rates of
production workers declined from over 60% in the early 1920s to below 50% in the late 1930s,
part of which may be attributed to the spread of corporate welfarism. Although a vast
6 For instance, in 1932 a male employee in a large establishment with 10 years of tenure received the average
retirement allowance worth 150 days’ wages plus 30 days’ pay in case of voluntary retirement (Zensanren 1936a,
1932b; Moriguchi 2003).
10
10
majority of workers in the economy remained highly mobile, a set of stable and loyal workers
began to emerge in leading firms.
Reflecting the development in firm-level HRM practices, complementary labor laws
began to take shape during the 1930s (Moriguchi 2003, pp.31-33). First, prompted by rising
unemployment, the government proposed a national unemployment insurance bill in 1932.
In the legislative process, however, the bill was transformed into law that incorporated an
aspect of unemployment insurance into corporate welfare practices. The law mandated every
employer (with 30 or more workers) to establish a retirement allowance fund for an employee
and pay an allowance in case of separation. Affirming prevailing HRM practices, the law
permitted employers to vary an amount of the allowance depending on an employee’s length
of service and the reason for separation. After the enactment of the law in 1936, retirement
allowance plans diffused to smaller-sized establishments in the economy.
Second, despite repeated legislative attempts by progressive politicians and
government officials, trade union law never materialized in the prewar period. Business
leaders strongly opposed union legislation throughout the period, claiming that factory
councils provided employees with a form of employee representation that were more
conducive to “labor-capital cooperation (roshi kyocho)” than trade unions. Although factory
councils did not give independent voice to workers, evidence indicates that organized labor
failed to gain workers’ support in large firms that instituted corporate weflarism. As Figure
2 shows, the absence of legal protection notwithstanding, trade unions organized more than
900 establishments and 400,000 workers by the mid-1930s. All major firms, however,
remained nonunion. Trade unions were dissolved by the military government after the
Japanese invasion of China in 1937.7
7 For the evolution of corporate HRM practices during WWII and the impact of wartime labor regulations,
readers are referred to Okazaki (1993) and Moriguchi (2000).
11
11
3.2 Postwar Occupational Reforms and the Turbulent Years
Immediately after Japan's surrender in 1945, the nation was placed under the indirect
governance of the Supreme Commander for the Allied Powers (SCAP). Even before the
enactment of the Trade Union Law, which recognized workers’ right to bargain collectively
for the first time, there was an explosion of the labor movement led by Japanese workers
under the slogan of “democratization of management.” Union density (the percentage of
union membership in the total labor force) rose to 41 percent by 1946, compared to the
prewar peak of 8 percent (see Figure 2). In many cases, workers spontaneously formed
what they called “employee unions (jugyoin kumiai)” that consisted of white-collar and blue-
collar employees within an establishment or a company. In contrast to the prewar industrial
relations, newly established unions forcefully demanded the equal treatment of all employees,
contractual employment guarantee, and direct participation in management in order to
improve their status, welfare, and bargaining power. The labor movement quickly
radicalized under the leadership of the Congress of Industrial Unions, often resorting to
collective violence against managers during labor disputes.
While management was paralyzed by economic disorder and political turmoil, many
employee unions won extremely favorable contracts during 1945-49 that stipulated generous
wage increases, a variety of welfare benefits, and employment security (Gordon 1985, p.345).
By 1950, a large majority of large firms (with 500 or more employees) instituted major
corporate welfare programs (see Table 1). Many unions also won a “union shop” provision
that required every regular employee of a company to be a union member, and in exchange,
management won a clause requiring every union member to be an employee of the company.
This exclusive employee membership later became a hallmark of enterprise unionism. As a
dramatic symbol of labor victory, major unions also won pure “seniority wages” in which
wages were determined based on employees’ age, tenure, and family conditions, rejecting any
12
12
merit-based components insisted by employers.8 Labor's initial victory, however, was soon
challenged by management's counteroffensive.
In 1949, the SCAP implemented a drastic deflationary policy to bring the Japanese
economy under free market mechanisms, plunging it into a sharp recession. As generous
government subsidies suddenly disappeared, many companies faced a choice between drastic
rationalization and bankruptcy. The 1949-50 recession thus posed a serious challenge to
long-term employment. Unions fiercely opposed rationalization plans, demanding complete
withdrawal of proposed mass dismissals (Gordon 1985, pp.388-90). A sense of mutual
mistrust between labor and management grew. The most violent labor disputes in Japanese
history took place between 1949 and 1954, involving major companies, such as Toshiba,
Hitachi, Toyota, and Nissan. As Figure 2 shows, the working days lost in 1952 reached
unprecedented 15 million days involving 1.6 million workers.
In almost all major strikes, management eventually prevailed (Yamamoto 1991).
During prolonged disputes, radical union leaders typically lost support from core employees
of the company who instead formed or joined the “second union (daini kumiai).”
Management concluded an agreement with the second union, expelled the radical leaders, and
undertook dismissals by a familiar method of voluntary retirement and augmented dismissal
compensation. During the process, unions learned a hard lesson that their unrestrained
demands might be unsustainable in the face of economic reality. Employers also learned
that rationalization measures could provoke costly labor disputes. The second unions
became the foundation for enterprise unionism characterized by labor-management
cooperation in pursuit of corporate goals that took roots in most large Japanese firms in the
following decade (Shirai 1992).
8 In the 1960s, however, employers promoted ability-based wages to provide work incentives. By the early
1970s, a majority of firms adopted hybrid wages or “seniority-plus-merit” pay that combined seniority with a
prominent merit component based on performance evaluation by supervisors (Tsutsui 1998, p.174).
13
13
Contrary to popular belief, there was no statutory law that guaranteed lifetime
employment in Japan. The Japanese Civil Code stipulated that, under an employment
contract with no fixed duration, either party can terminate the contract at any time with a two-
week advance notice (Article 627(1)). The Labor Standard Law of 1947 obligated
employers to pay the equivalent of thirty days' wages when dismissing an employee (Article
20). Except for those restrictions, the legal codes supported the employers’ right to dismiss
employees. As Table 2 documents, by the early 1960s, however, it was common for
Japanese employers to circumvent dismissals by using other means, such as reduction of
working hours, relocation of regular employees, separation of non-regular employees, and the
suspension of hiring new workers. In the absence of statutory laws, what compelled
management to protect employment of their workers in the face of declining sales and profits?
The role of enterprise unions and the formation of case law provide key answers to this
question.
In exchange for their cooperation with management in rationalization and productivity
improvements, enterprise unions demanded employment security of their members, i.e., all
regular employees, as their first priority. No explicit contractual guarantee of employment
security, however, was found in union contracts. Instead the contracts established a clause
that required the employer’s prior consultation with a union in employment adjustment
among other personnel issues. Importantly, joint labor-management committees (roshi keiei
kyogikai), which were widely introduced during the 1950s and 1960s, played a critical role in
facilitating information sharing and joint consultation and establishing mutual trust between
labor and management. During business downturns, unions monitored managerial behavior
and cooperated in transferring employees and soliciting early retirement. Enterprise
unionism thus became a central internal enforcement mechanism for the emerging lifetime
employment practice in large firms.
14
14
In a parallel development, starting in 1948 the Japanese courts began to rule
increasingly in favor of employees in cases of dismissal (Sugeno 1992, pp.395-412; Tackney
1995, pp.420-27). Over the next three decades, the accumulation of judicial decisions
gradually restricted the employer’s right to dismiss employees at will.9 In particular, when
the dismissals due to business conditions became a major issue during the Oil Crisis in the
1970s, judicial decisions established minimum criteria that employers had to satisfy before
resorting to dismissals, citing the “accepted idea of lifetime employment” and “existing ways
of employment adjustment” (Sugeno 1992, p.408).10 In other words, the interpretations of
the law evolved endogenously to incorporate prevailing HRM practices and social
expectations. In turn, the accumulation of case law precedents reinforced the HRM practices
and transformed expectations into social norms. Since the late 1970s, the courts thus
provided legal enforcement for lifetime employment to a certain degree, extending the
practice to nonunion employers and smaller firms in the economy.
3.3 The High-Growth Period
The 1960s and the early half of 1970s are known as the “high-growth period.” The period
kickstarted from the “Income Doubling Plan” announced by the Ikeda cabinet in 1960, under
which economic goals were set to more than double Japan’s GNP in the course of the next
decade. Actual results exceeded this as it took less than seven years to double personal
incomes. The real GDP growth rate during 1960-1973 averaged 10 percent, and this
unprecedented achievement propelled Japan into the ranks of industrially advanced countries.
9 The 1975 Supreme Court decision established a principle that an exercise of the right of dismissal must be
based on “reasonable grounds” to receive general social approval (Nihon Shokuen Seizo, April 25, 1975, 29 Civ.
Cases 456).
10 The 1979 court decision specified that employers had to (1) exhibit a high degree of business difficulties; (2)
make effort to take other measures, such as transfers and voluntary retirement, before resorting to adjustment
dismissals; (3) use objective and fair standards in selecting workers to be dismissed; and (4) engage in prior
discussion with workers in good faith even if no such provision existed in union contracts (Sugeno 1992, pp.408-
9).
15
15
Corporate profits soared under continuous periods of double-digit growth. Rapid
business expansion depleted the supply of labor available in urban centers, and large
corporations aggressively recruited workers from rural areas. These companies constructed
dormitories and various housing facilities to accommodate the influx of the new workforce.
Their employees began to develop the mentality that their jobs would be secure and their
earnings would automatically increase with the length of service. These expectations were
fulfilled. The main managerial concern was recruiting and preserving the workforce.
Dismissal became a remote concept. The practice flourished among large firms in the 1960s,
and among smaller establishments in the 1970s. Accordingly, turnover rates of
manufacturing workers declined considerably (see Figure 1).
Lifetime employment came into fruition under the favorable economic conditions of
the high-growth period (Shimada 1994). Sustained periods of economic growth allowed
companies to project longer time horizons as economic conditions became more predictable.
For employers, stable employment relationships enhanced the concept of investments in
human capital, i.e., the recognition that workers are an important asset, or an investment with
real returns.
Companies started to provide considerable education and training to their workers, and
developed sophisticated human resource management systems for evaluation, promotion, and
compensation. For example, Koike (1997) documents how on-the-job training (OJT)
became common practice among manufacturing firms in the late 1950s and 1960s. A long-
term perspective shared by both labor and management was crucial for on-the-job training to
be successful, because skill formation will be interrupted if the workers would move. The
bonus payment system, which covered white-collar and blue-collar employees in all job
16
16
categories, also spread during the same period, primarily as an instrument to adjust wage
levels in response to labor market and firm-specific conditions (Ohashi 1989).11
Labor-management relations also stabilized during the high-growth period as firms
started to realize the gains from the human capital investment. The annual private sector pay
negotiations known as the Spring Offensive (shunto) was introduced in 1955. The Spring
Offensive suffered from low membership, and thus little bargaining power over management
in its initial stages. However, sizable wage increases determined by the negotiations during
the high-growth period led to larger membership, both with respect to the number of firms
and workers.12 An important outcome of the Spring Offensive was the standardization of
wage increase demands and settlements. In a remarkable display of consensus building,
member companies exchanged information to minimize wage dispersion, believing that
harmonious labor relations was beneficial for labor and management. Differences in wage
increase settlements across firms and industries were common in the formative years of the
Spring Offensive, but “virtually disappeared” during the mature period in the mid 1960s
(Koshiro 2000).13
As expectations of employment security became reality, long-term employment
became the norm governing the employment relationship in subsequent periods. Regular
workers in large firms were increasingly attracted to the economic benefits of the renewed
system – mainly “automatic” wage growth – which enabled them to smooth out their
consumption and savings over a longer-time horizon.14 They also enjoyed social benefits
such as the status accorded to joining prestigious corporations. Vogel (1963)’s reference to
11 The bonus system dates back to the prewar period, but its beneficiaries were mostly high ranking white-collar
workers (Jones and Kato 1995). By 1985, 97 percent of firms that have 30 employees or more paid semiannual
bonuses to their employees (Ministry of Labour statistics cited in Ohashi 1989).
12 Membership increased from 730,000 in 1955 to 5.6 million in 1965 (Ministry of Labor statistics, cited in
Takanashi 2002).
13 For example, the coefficient of dispersion for wage increases was 0.29 in 1956 but fell below 0.1 in the 1960s
(Ministry of Labor statistics, cited in Takanashi 2002).
14 Inoki (2000) writes that by 1965, more than 95 percent of total households owned black-and-white television
sets, and by 1970, 90 percent of households owned washing machines and refrigerators.
17
17
Japan’s “new middle class” points precisely at this time period when the job of the salaryman
characterized by security and prestige became a desirable status among the majority of the
Japanese.
Lifetime employment, however, also entailed the social costs. Sanctions for
deviating from the norm were met with certain penalties. The stigma attached to job changers
hampered their chances of reemployment and resulted in their wage loss.15 Job separations
signaled a “lack of sincerity” much like a divorce (Dore 1983). As commitment to the
employer became customary, workers became reluctant to accept as social equals those
individuals hired with prior job experience (Cole 1971b). Large companies respected the
implicit agreement and their employees were seldom dismissed. However, as Crawcour
(1978) explains, “when dismissal did occur it was an industrial death sentence with
consequences far more severe than they would be in many other industrial societies” (p.240).
Social pressures to conform to the norm thus functioned as a powerful enforcement
mechanism for long-term employment.
3.4 The Oil Crisis
The stability of the employment relationship was seriously challenged with the First Oil
Shock in 1973, followed by the Second Oil Shock in 1979. Real GNP growth averaged 4.7
percent between 1975 and 1980, and 3.7 percent between 1980 and 1985. Employers initially
responded to the shock by upholding their renewed commitment to employment stability.
Much like the methods used to adjust employment levels in the Occupation period (see Table
2), dismissal was the last resort. Instead, large and medium-sized firms made concerted
efforts to reduce overtime, transfer workers within the firm, reduce new recruits, sell
15 Empirical studies of the Japanese labor market have found a negative correlation between the number of job
changes and earnings. See for example, Kato and Rockel (1992) and Ono (2004).
18
18
corporate assets, cut executive bonuses and salaries, and cut dividends (Shimada 1979).16 In
spite of these efforts, the shocks proved to be overburdening even for largest firms, forcing
them ultimately to adjust their regular workforce mainly in the form of voluntary retirement
and permanent transfers. During December 1973 and February 1978, more than one million
regular employees lost their jobs (Koshiro 1983).17
In response, there was an initial surge of labor disputes in 1974-75 involving more
than 5.3 million workers (see Figure 2). Several cases of dismissals were brought before the
court, leading to the judiciary decisions that restricted the right of dismissals due to business
conditions as discussed earlier. Most enterprise unions, however, eventually approved
employment adjustment plans and cooperated with management to carry them out. Prior
consultations at joint labor-management committees were particularly useful in facilitating
labor-management cooperation during the crisis. Furthermore, in 1975 the labor movement
adopted a voluntary wage restraint policy intended to promote macroeconomic stability
(Takanashi 2000). In a move that reflected the high priority accorded to employment
security, organized labor accepted a substantial reduction in real wages in the Spring
Offensive of 1980 immediately following the Second Oil Shock (Shimada 1992).
It is against this backdrop that the government launched the Employment Stability
Project in 1977. The Ministry of Labor and the Ministry of Trade and Industry were both
determined to preserve employment security because they and the business community
believed it was the key to industrial and social harmony (Cole 1979). The objectives of the
Project were twofold. The first aim was to stabilize employment by transferring workers
from declining industries to new more profitable lines of business. Employers who were
forced to temporarily lay off workers due to business fluctuations were offered rebates to
16 See Brunello (1988) for a detailed analysis concerning how employers used employee transfers during the
First Oil Shock.
17 However, the impact of the oil shock on employment adjustment was considerably smaller in Japan than in
the U.S..: a comparative study revealed that the manpower reduction measured by the number of employees
involved in Japan was only one third of that in the U.S. (Shinozuka 1978).
19
19
transfer workers, often into newly established affiliates.18 Second, the Project provided
incentives for employers to keep their workers employed by subsidizing the costs involved
with re-training workers in the skills necessary for new lines of business. Subsidies were also
provided in circumstances where employers wished to implement short-time schedules,
including those who were working zero hours or temporarily staying at home (Genda and
Rebick 2000). Hashimoto (1993) finds that the government-led employment stabilization
movement reduced employment sensitivity to the business cycle, i.e., firms responded to
business fluctuations mainly through adjustment of work hours rather than employment.
It is often argued that Japan survived the Oil Crisis much better than their Western
counterparts. Such views should not overlook the considerable measures undertaken by
government, management, and labor to minimize the extent of the external shocks triggered
by the oil crisis. As Shimada (1992) argues, the priority on employment stability established
during the 1970s formed a backbone of the Japanese employment system in the subsequent
decades.
3.5 The Bubble Economy and Its Aftermath
The conclusion of the Plaza Accords in September 1985 triggered a sharp appreciation of the
yen relative to the dollar. During the next ten months, the value of the yen jumped from 240
to 150 yen per dollar. The enormous price disadvantage of Japanese imports consequently led
to a decline in product demand, and lifetime employment was once again tested as employers
faced pressures to let workers go. However, the downturn was short-lived; the economy
bottomed out by the end of 1986 and managed a quick recovery. The low-interest rate policy
intended to stabilize macroeconomic performance soon led to aggressive corporate
investments. Asset inflation, mainly through the appreciation of land and stock prices,
18 For example, the major shipbuilding firm, Ishikawajima Harima Heavy Industries, established an affiliated
firm specializing in designing sound reduction construction machinery. Other manufacturing firms also ventured
into real estate and other service sector industries (Cole 1979).
20
20
encouraged further investments. This upward spiral led to the so-called bubble economy
(Noguchi 1994).
The wealth effect stimulated consumer demand, and corporations responded by
expanding their productive capacity. Employers hoarded labor at unprecedented levels. In
previous episodes of expansion, employers exercised caution in hiring and recruiting, and
adjusted to upward swings through overtime work. However, corporate confidence was high
and the forecast so positive during the bubble years that corporations recruited as much labor
as possible. The result was a complete turnaround, from a buyer’s market to a seller’s market.
Labor shortage problems became pervasive especially among large firms who continued to
hoard workers at an aggressive rate. The demand for college graduates was greater because
firms desired a higher quality labor force, and because they were able to pay higher salaries.
In the peak year of 1991, large firms with more than 1000 employees hired 145,600 new
college graduates, or 64.7 percent of the total pool of college graduates, which represented a
60 percent increase compared to the mid-1980s (Ariga, Brunello and Ohkusa 2000).
The prolonged period of asset inflation showed initial signs of collapse in 1991. By
October, stock prices had fallen 50 percent from their 1989 peak. In December, the
Economic Planning Agency acknowledged that the economy had entered a slump. To deal
with the recession, employers once again resorted to the conventional methods of adjustment,
by reducing overtime work, reducing new hiring, transferring workers to subsidiaries, and
encouraging early or voluntary retirement. Employee dismissal remained the last resort, but
became inevitable. Chuma (1994) claims that reductions in the core workforce started as
early as the spring of 1993.
The aftermath of the bubble economy dragged on as firms were confronted with not
only a mountain of bad loans, but a mass of surplus labor. Despite increasing pressures to
let workers go, management continued to uphold the lifetime employment practice throughout
21
21
the 1990s (Genda and Rebick 2000; Rebick 2001; Kato 2001). Job retention rates and
employment durations remained virtually unchanged in comparison to the 1980s.
Management kept core employees employed by resorting to transfers, whether they be intra-
firm or to subsidiaries within a corporate group (Sako and Sato 1997; Kato 2001).
Enterprise unions mainly negotiated wage increases that were in line with productivity gains,
and their willingness to accept virtually no wage growth kept unemployment rates low in the
1990s (Genda and Rebick 2000). No major outbreak of labor disputes has been observed
since the mid-1970s (see Figure 2). On the other hand, repeated concessions signaled the
union’s lack of bargaining power, leading many workers to see their unions as “powerless”
(Kawakita 1997).
Two forms of government intervention in the 1990s also contributed to the
maintenance of employment security. First, a new system was established in 1997 to
provide special subsidies for job creation and skill formation in fifteen new growth areas,
such as information technology and social welfare. Second, the government paid employers
direct subsidies to retain or employ older workers (Genda and Rebick 2000). The system of
deferred compensation implies that employees closer to a firm’s mandatory retirement age are
paid more than their marginal product, which makes them more vulnerable to dismissals than
younger workers. Government subsidies were therefore targeted specifically to protect older
workers during the economic downturn.
The piecemeal adjustment to protect older workers had the undesirable consequence
of depressing youth labor markets. Kato (2001) finds that employment remained stable for
core workers in the 1990s as reviewed previously, but less so for younger workers and
middle-aged workers with short tenure. The primary cause of the problem was that employers,
faced with the post-bubble surplus of labor, dramatically reduced their intakes of new hires
(Rebick 1998). Furthermore, labor hoarding during the bubble years left a diamond-shaped
22
22
age composition of the workforce, with an overstock of workers in their thirties. This
imbalanced age composition misaligned the system of internal promotion. Eventually, the
bulk of the bubble-cohort must be promoted, or it will demoralize subsequent cohorts.
However, management faces a dilemma because the average quality of the bubble-cohort is
likely to be lower than that of the subsequent cohorts due to the lower recruiting standards
used during the period (Ariga, Brunello and Ohkusa 2000). The lack of organizational
restructuring has therefore worsened the labor market conditions for younger employees.
Their promotion rates have slowed down, and their training opportunities within firms have
been depressed (Genda 2000).
4. The Future of the Lifetime Employment System
In the midst of the longest economic stagnation in the nation’s history, doubts about
the future of lifetime employment have surfaced once again and continue to captivate the
public’s attention. A February 2002 survey by Nikkei Research reported that over half of 800
firms surveyed “could no longer sustain” permanent employment practices.19 In the
business community, Matsushita’s announcement of 8,000 job cuts through voluntary layoffs
during fiscal year 2002 was received as a turning point in Japanese industrial relations.20
Matsushita, in both its organization and history, represents a microcosm of the Japanese firm,
often credited as the first to effectively implement lifetime employment. Its announcement
was an impetus for change, as it triggered an avalanche of corporate downsizing plans among
other Japanese companies. As of November 2001, 82 firms had announced plans to
discharge a total of 120,000 workers by fiscal year 2004.21 Is this the end of Japanese
19 A survey of 805 firms listed in the Tokyo Stock Exchange and JASDAQ reported in Nihon Keizai Shimbun,
February 26, 2002.
20 This view has been popularized in the media. See for example, a Nihon Keizai Shimbun article entitled “Can
Matsushita Come Back?” (August 4, 2001).
21 Nihon Keizai Shimbun (European Edition), November 18, 2001.
23
23
lifetime employment? Or will the practice maintain its resilience and resurge once economic
conditions recover?
There is some evidence suggesting that employment adjustments in the 2000s may be
tougher than in the previous decades. Conventional measures of employment adjustment are
becoming more difficult to implement. Reassigning or transferring workers to other parts of
the business may no longer be a viable solution. Smaller firms that serve on the receiving
end of surplus workers from large companies are getting saturated with workers; moreover,
they face hardship themselves, and can no longer absorb such “redundancies from above”
(Ono 2002). Early or voluntary retirement risks adverse selection, i.e. management may lose
high-ability workers instead of the targeted low-ability workers. Further, early retirement is
likely a bad deal for the average worker. Studies have shown that, in many cases, the lump-
sum compensation offered through these plans would not compensate for the loss in earnings
when viewed over a lifetime (Ichinose 2001).
Despite increasing pressures to reduce redundant labor, recent survey results confirm
that dismissal of regular employees continues to be the last resort among Japanese firms (see
Table 3). The Japan Institute of Labor (2001b) reports that preferences for employment
adjustments among Japanese employers have changed little. Maintaining a reserve of excess
labor under economic duress, however, is not without its costs. Ono and Rebick (2003)
estimate that the quantity of surplus labor retained among Japanese employers is around 5
percent of total employment, or about the same as the unemployment rate in 2002. The
impact of this efficiency loss on labor productivity is certainly not negligible. Further, as
discussed previously, the burden of protecting the core workforce falls disproportionately on
younger workers. In March 2002, the unemployment rate among workers between the ages of
15 to 29 recorded 9.6 percent, in comparison to the nation’s average of 5.2 percent.
24
24
One obvious prescription is a more flexible labor market. But the Japanese labor
market that matured under the premise of lifetime employment has yet to develop an
infrastructure that facilitates an efficient reallocation of workers across corporate boundaries.
Table 4 shows the top five reasons why workers do not, or cannot change jobs. The reasons
accentuate the sentiments of many Japanese workers who feel “stuck” with their current
employers. The internal labor markets that presume entry from below impedes the mobility
of workers who are separated from their firms in mid-career (Ono and Rebick 2003; Recruit
Works Institute 2001). Older workers are more likely to be endowed with higher levels of
firm-specific skills, and by definition, this makes it more difficult to transfer their skills to
other firms. The seniority-plus-merit pay makes it even harder for workers to leave their
employers because it likely results in wage loss. Hence, it is an equilibrium for mid-career
workers to remain with their current employers; they don’t want to quit their firms and other
firms don’t want to hire them.
A notable example of employers’ aversion to older workers is found in job postings
where employers explicitly impose age restrictions on their new hires. In 1999, over 90
percent of Japanese firms were found to impose age limits – generally 35 to 40 – on their job
openings (Japan Institute of Labor 2001c). This so-called “age limit” problem continues to
be the most common reason for workers not changing jobs in the Japanese labor market (see
Table 4). Under pressure for reform, the government introduced guidelines to abolish age
limits in recruiting and hiring in October 2001 as part of the revised Employment Measures
Law. However, the guidelines specify ten exceptions where age restrictions are acceptable.
One of the exceptions is phrased almost specifically to prevent disruptions in the seniority
system.22 As it stands, the guidelines are mainly viewed as a cosmetic gesture, and their
22 Exception 4 in the guideline reads: “Cases where recruiting or hiring is intended for workers under a certain
age in situations where, in order to make wage payments regardless of age to new employees, companies will be
required to revise present regulations determining wages mainly in accordance with age” (Japan Institute of
Labor (2001a)).
25
25
immediate impact on job mobility remains questionable. In short, a labor market for job
changers has not yet developed in Japan, without which the worker with general human
capital will suffer severe penalties from job separations.
Finally, the long-term threat which not only may undermine the employment system
but economic growth itself is Japan’s aging population. The rate of aging in Japan is the
fastest in the world, compounded by longer life expectancy and lower fertility. The
implications for the economy are ominous. The aging population will eventually lead to an
inverted pyramid shaped age composition of the workforce and increase the burden for the
active labor force to support the private and public pension system. To summarize, the
Japanese labor market faces a labor surplus problem in the short-run, and a labor shortage
problem in the long-run. These problems are yet to find solutions.
5. Conclusion
This paper examined the historical process in which Japanese lifetime employment was
shaped and became institutionalized over the past century as a result of the dynamic
interactions among labor, management, and government. Pioneered by leading firms during
the interwar period, the lifetime employment practice matured into a cluster of HRM policies,
diffused to a wider set of firms, became more deeply institutionalized, and was increasingly
socially-embedded at each historical event examined in our paper. In particular, we
documented the endogenous formation of macro-level institutions that reinforced the lifetime
employment practice. The development of state welfare policies, enterprise unions, case
laws, government subsidies, and social norms are primary examples of such institutions. We
argued that the practice’s remarkable stability and resilience to economic shocks cannot be
explained without the existence of these complementary institutions.
What does the history tell us about the future of Japanese lifetime employment? So
far the system has emerged from each economic shock by consolidating itself more firmly
26
26
with necessary adjustments and innovations. As long as the complementary institutions
continue to support it, lifetime employment will likely persist. But should it change?
According to our analysis, the shift from spot labor markets to long-term employment
was initially driven by efficiency considerations. By achieving greater productivity through
higher human capital, it produced benefits to both management and labor in the form of
higher profit and greater employment security. The government endorsed the corporate
practices as it brought about economic development and industrial peace at a relatively low
social welfare cost to the state. However, the efficiency of lifetime employment is by no
means guaranteed: it depends on several key parameters, most importantly, the growth rate of
the firm, the nature of human capital, and labor market conditions. In particular, during the
high-growth period and again in the bubble economy, under the economic conditions
favorable to management, the lifetime employment practice was extended to a much wider
segment of the economy with perhaps little gain in long-run economic efficiency. Once
extended, labor’s oppositions, government regulatory support, and court decisions tended to
make it difficult to reverse the practice. Even for elite corporations, core proponents and
traditional mainstay of lifetime employment, an increasing importance of professional
occupations with general human capital may limit the returns from lifetime employment. In
general, in evaluating the future economic implications of the system, one must discern long-
run trends in the key parameters.
Furthermore, after several decades since its inception, lifetime employment has
become deeply embedded in the society, inseparably integrated into political, legal, and social
institutions. As such, the continuation of the system is no longer dictated by its firm-level
efficiency concerns. For example, as employment security became a norm and a
fundamental premise upon which the society is built, the social benefits of employment
security are far greater than its direct economic benefits. The system, however, also created
27
27
social costs that were originally unforeseen. For instance, lifetime employment produced a
stark status difference between regular and non-regular workers, promoted occupational
segregation by gender between career and non-career jobs, and brought about high
unemployment for the young and the old during recessions. In other words, it is important
also to evaluate the social implications of lifetime employment which go far beyond the
original efficiency implications.
To give careful assessment of the social and economic implications of Japanese
lifetime employment is beyond the scope of this paper. By providing a historical perspective,
however, this paper underscores the importance of understanding the dynamic process that
shaped the practice and the complementarity between the corporate HRM practices and
macro-level institutions in carrying out such assessment.
28
28
REFERENCES
Abegglen, James. 1958. The Japanese Factory. New York: Free Press.
Aoki, Masahiko. 1988. Information, Incentives, and Bargaining in the Japanese Economy. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Ariga, Kenn, Giorgio Brunello, and Yasushi Ohkusa. 2000. Internal Labor Markets in Japan. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Auer, Peter and Sandrine Cazes. 2000. "The Resilience of Long-term Employment Relationship: Evidence
from the Industrialized Countries." International Labour Review 139: 379-408.
Baker, George, Robert Gibbons, and Kevin J. Murphy. 1994. "Subjective performance measures in optimal
incentive contracts." Quarterly Journal of Economics 109:1125-1156.
Beck, J. C. and M. N. Beck. 1994. The Change of a Lifetime Employment Patterns among Japan's Managerial
Elite. Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press.
Brown and Reich. 1989. "When does union-management cooperation work? A look at NUMMI and GM-Van
Nuys." California Management Review: 26-44.
Brunello, Giorgio. 1988. "Transfers of employees between Japanese manufacturing enterprises: Some results
from an enquiry on a small sample of large firms." British Journal of Industrial Relations 26, 119–132.
Chuma, Hiroyuki. 1994. Kensho: Nihongata Koyo Chosei (Examining Japanese Employment Adjustment).
Tokyo: Shueisha.
Cole, Robert E. 1971a. Japanese Blue Collar-The Changing Tradition. Berkeley: University of California Press.
—. 1971b. "The Theory of Institutionalization: Permanent Employment and Tradition in Japan." Economic
Development and Cultural Change 20: 47-70.
Cole, Robert E. 1979. Work, Mobility and Participation: A Comparative Study of American and Japanese
Industry. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Coleman, J. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Dore, Ronald. 1973. British Factory-Japanese Factory. Oxford: Alden Press.
—. 1983. "Goodwill and the Spirit of Market Capitalism." British Journal of Sociology 34: 459-482.
Garon, Sheldon. 1988. The State and Labor in Modern Japan. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Genda, Yuji. 2000. "Youth employment and parasite singles." Japan Labor Bulletin 39, 5–12.
Genda, Yuji and Marcus E. Rebick. 2000. "Japanese Labour in the 1990s: Stability and Stagnation." Oxford
Review of Economic Policy 16: 85-102.
Gordon, Andrew. 1985. The Evolution of Labor Relations in Japan: Heavy industry 1853-1955. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press.
Hashimoto, Masanori. 1993. "Aspects of Labor Market Adjustments in Japan." Journal of Labor Economics 11:
136-161.
Hashimoto, Masanori and John Raisian. 1985. "Employment Tenure and Earnings Profiles in Japan and the
United States." American Economic Review 75: 721-735.
Hazama, Hiroshi. 1978. Nihon Romu Kanrishi Kenkyu (Historical Studies of Japanese Labor Management).
Tokyo: Ochanomizu Shobo.
Higuchi, Yoshio. 1999. "Rodo shijo no ryudoka wa naze susumanainoka? (Why doesn’t labor market flexibility
progress?) Jurist 1149, 10–14.
Hyodo, Tsutomu. 1971. Nihon ni okeru Roshi Kankei no Tenkai (The Evolution of Labor-Capital Relations in
Japan). Tokyo: Tokyo Daigaku Shuppankai.
Ichinose, T. 2001. "Tenshoku ni yoru sh¯ogai chingin no gensho to soki taishoku yugu seido" (Early retirement
plans and the decline in lifetime income resulting from job changes). Rosei Jiho 3484, 27-34.
Ichniowski, Casey and Kathryn Shaw. 2003. "Beyond incentive pay: Insiders' estimates of the value of
complementary human resource management practices." Journal of Economic Perspectives 17:155-180.
Ichniowski, Casey, Kathryn Shaw, and Giovanna Prennushi. 1997. "The effects of human resource management
practices on productivity: A study of steel finishing lines." American Economic Review 87:291-313.
Japan Institute of Labor. 2001a. Guidelines to Abolish Age Limits in the Revised Employment Measures Law.
Japan Institute of Labour Report.
—. 2001b. Reorganization of Businesses and Employment Adjustment Aimed at Middle-aged and Older
Workers. Japan Institute of Labour Report.
—. 2001c. Shitsugyo Kozo no Kenkyu (Structure of Unemployment). Japan Institute of Labour Report 142.
Jones, Derek C. and Takao Kato. 1995. "The Productivity Effects of Employee Stock-Ownership Plans and
Bonuses: Evidence from Japanese Panel Data." American Economic Review 85: 391-414.
Kandel, Eugene and Edward Lazear. 1992. "Peer pressure and partnership." Journal of Political Economy
100:801-817.
29
29
Kanemoto, Yoshitsugu and Bentley MacLeod. 1992. "Reputation and self-enforcing labor contract." Journal of
The Japanese and International Economics 6:144-162.
Kato, Takao. 2000. "The recent transformation of participatory employment practices in Japan." NBER Working
Paper No. 7965, Cambridge, MA.
—. 2001. The End of Lifetime Employment in Japan? Evidence from National Surveys and Field Research."
Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 15:489-514.
Kato, Takao and Motohiro Morishima. 2002. "The Productivity Effects of Participatory Employment Practices:
Evidence from New Japanese Panel Data." Industrial Relations 41:487-520.
Kato, Takao and Mark Rockel. 1992. “Experiences, Credentials, and Compensation in the Japanese and U.S.
Managerial Labor Markets: Evidence from New Micro Data.” Journal of the Japanese and
International Economies 6 (March): 30-51.
Kawakita, Takashi. 1997. "The Mid-career Unemployed in Japan." Japan Labor Bulletin 36: 5-8.
Koike, Kazuo. 1988. Understanding Industrial Relations in Modern Japan. London: MacMillan Press.
—. 1991. Shigoto no Keizaigaku (Economics of Job). Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shimposha.
—. 1997. Human Resource Development. Tokyo: Japan Institute of Labor.
Koshiro, Kazutoshi. 1983. "Development of Collective Bargaining in Postwar Japan." pp. 205-257 in
Contemporary Industrial Relations in Japan, edited by T. Shirai. Madison: University of Wisconsin
Press.
—. 2000. A Fifty Year History of Industry and Labor in Postwar Japan. Tokyo: Japan Institute of Labor.
Kyochokai. 1924. Hompo Sangyo Fukuri Shisetsu Gaiyo (Overview of Industrial Welfare Facilities in Japan).
Tokyo: Kyochokai.
—. 1926. Wagakuni ni Okeru Rodo Iinkai Seido (Labor Committees in Japan). Tokyo: Kyochokai.
—. 1929. Saikin no Shakai Undo (Recent Social Movements). Tokyo: Kyochokai.
Milgrom, Paul and John Roberts. 1995. "Complementarities and Fit: Strategy, structure, and organizational
change in manufacturing." Journal of Accounting and Economics 19:179-208.
Moriguchi, Chiaki. 2000. "The evolution of employment relations in U.S. and Japanese manufacturing firms,
1900-1960: A comparative historical and institutional analysis." NBER Working Paper No.7939,
Cambridge, MA.
—. 2003. "Implicit contracts, the Great Depression, and institutional change: A comparative study of U.S. and
Japanese employment relations." Journal of Economic History 63: 625-665.
Nishiguchi, Toshihiro. 1994. Strategic Industrial Sourcing: The Japanese Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Nishinarita, Yutaka. 1988. Kindai Nihon Roshi Kankei-shi no Kenkyu (Historical Study of the Modern Japanese
Labor-Capital Relations). Tokyo: Tokyo Daigaku Shuppankai.
Noguchi, Yukio. .1994. Bubble no Keizaigaku (Economics of the Bubble). Tokyo: Nihon Keizai Shimbunsha.
Ohashi, Isao. 1989. "On the Determinants of Bonuses and Basic Wages in Large Japanese Firms." Journal of the
Japanese and International Economies 3: 451-479.
Okazaki, Tetsuji. 1993. "The Japanese firm under the wartime planned economy." Journal of the Japanese and
International Economies 7: 175-203.
Ono, Hiroshi. 2002. "Japanese labor market reform: Why is it so difficult?" In Fixing Japan’s Economy:
Proceedings of the Japan Information Access Project Symposium. Washington D.C., April 2002.
—. 2004. "College Quality and Earnings in the Japanese Labor Market." Industrial Relations 43: 595-617.
Ono, Hiroshi and Marcus E. Rebick. 2003. "Constraints on the Level and Efficient Use of Labor." In Structural
Impediments to Japan's Economic Growth. Edited by Magnus Blomström, Jennifer Corbett, Fumio
Hayashi and Anil Kashyap. Pp. 225-257. Chicago: NBER and University of Chicago Press.
Osterman, Paul. 1994. "How common is workplace transformation and who adopts it?" Industrial and Labor
Relations Review 53:173-187.
Rebick, Marcus E. 2001. "Japanese Labor Markets: Can We Expect Significant Change?" pp. 120-141 in Japan's
New Economy: Continuity and Change in the Twenty-First Century, edited by M. Blomstrom, B.
Gangnes, and S. La Croix. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Recruit Works Institute. 2001. Working Persons Chosa 2000: Shutoken (Working Persons Survey 2000: The
Greater Tokyo Area). Tokyo: Recruit.
Sako, Mari and Hiroki Sato. 1997. Japanese Labour and Management in Transition: Diversity, Flexibility and
Participation. London and New York: Routledge.
Shakaikyoku. 1936. Taishoku Tsumitatekin oyobi Taishoku Teate Hoan Yoko oyobi Shiryo (Summary and
Documents of the Retirement Allowance Fund Law). Tokyo: Naimusho Shakaikyoku.
Shimada, Haruo. 1988. Humanware no Keizaigaku (Economics of "Humanware"): Iwanami Shoten.
—. 1979. "The Japanese Labor Market after the Oil Crisis: A Factual Report." In Structural Determinants of
Employment and Unemployment, Vol.2. Paris: OECD.
30
30
—. 1992. "Japan’s Industrial Culture and Labor-Management Relations." In S. Kumon and H. Rosovsky, eds.
The Political Economy of Japan, Vol.3: Cultural and Social Dynamics. Stanford: Stanford University
Press.
—. 1994. Nihon no Koyo (Japanese Employment). Tokyo: Chikuma Shobo.
Shinozuka, Eiko. 1978. "Koyo chosei no mondaiten" (Problematic points concerning employment adjustment).
ESP 72 (April).
Shirai, Taishiro. 1983. Contemporary Industrial Relations in Japan. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.
—. 1992. Gendai Nihon no Romu Kanri (Labor Management in Modern Japan). Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shimposha.
Showa Dojinkai. 1960. Wagakuni Chingin Kozo no Shiteki Kosatsu (Historical Survey of Japanese Wage
Structure). Tokyo: Shiseido.
Sugeno, Kazuo. 1992. Japanese Labor Law. Seattle: University of Washington Press.
Tachibanaki, Toshiaki and Tomohiko Noda. 2000. The Economic Effects of Trade Unions in Japan. London:
MacMillan Press.
Tackney, Charles. 1995. "Institutionalization of the lifetime employment system: a case study of changing
employment practices in a Japanese factory." Ph.D. Dissertation, Industrial Relations, University of
Wisconsin-Madison.
Takanashi, Atsushi. 2002. Shunto Wage Offensive. Tokyo: Japan Institute of Labor.
Tsuru, Tsuyoshi. 2002. Roshi Kankei no Nonyunion-ka (Nonunionization of Labor-Management Relations).
Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shimpo.
Tsutsui, William. 1998. Manufacturing Ideology: Scientific Management in Twentieth-century Japan: Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Vogel, Ezra. 1963. Japan’s New Middle Class: The Salary Man and His Family in a Tokyo Suburb. Berkeley:
University of California Press.
Yamamoto, Kiyoshi. 1991. Nihon no Rodo Sogi (Labor Disputes in Japan), 1945-1980. Tokyo: Tokyo Daigaku
Shuppankai.
Zensanren. 1932a. Wagakuni ni okeru Kaiko Teate Seido no Genjo (Current Conditions of Dismissal Allowance
Plans in Japan). Tokyo: Zenkoku Sangyo Dantai Rengo.
—. 1932b. Wagakuni ni okeru Romusha Taishoku Teate Seido no Genjo (Current Conditions of Retirement
Allowance Plans in Japan). Tokyo: Zenkoku Sangyo Dantai Rengo.
31
31
Figure 1. Separation Rates of Manufacturing Workers, 1923-200
1
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
1923 1929 1935 1941 1947 1953 1959 1965 1971 1977 1983 1989 1995 2001
Sources: (a) 1923-1936: Nihon Rodo Undo Shiryo Iinkai (1959), Nihon Rodo Undo Shiryo (Historical
Data of Japanese Labor Movement), vol.10; (b) 1937-40: Ohara Shakai Mondai Kenkyusho (1964),
Taiheiyo Sensoka no Rodosha Jotai (Labor Conditions during the Pacific War); (c) 1948-2002:
Rodosho, Maitsuki Kinro Tokei Chosa (Monthly Labor Survey).
Notes:
1) Separation rates (%) are annualized. Monthly separation rate is defined by the number of
employees separated from an establishment (voluntary quits, layoffs, and discharges) within a month
divided by the number of employees at the end of the previous month.
2) In (a), the surveys covered production workers in manufacturing establishments employing 50 or
more regular production workers. In (c), the surveys covered regular employees (blue-collar and
white-collar employees) in manufacturing establishments with 30 or more regular employees.
32
32
Figure 2. Union Membership, Density, and Working Days Lost, 1921-2001
0
2,000
4,000
6,000
8,000
10,000
12,000
14,000
1921 1926 1931 1936 1941 1946 1951 1956 1961 1966 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 199 6 2001
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
Union membership (1,000)
Working days lost (1,000)
Union density (%)
Sources: (a) 1921-1946: Nihon Rodo Undo Shiryo Iinkai (1959), Nihon Rodo Undo Shiryo (Historical
Data of Japanese Labor Movement), vol.10; (b) 1947-2001: Rodosho, Rodo Kumiai Kihon Chosa
(Labor Union Basic Survey) and Rodo Sogi Tokei Chosa (Labor Disputes Statistics), various years.
Notes:
1) Trade union membership as of the end of June each year is reported.
2) Union density (%) is the union membership divided by the total number of employees in June each
year reported in Rodoryoku Chosa (Labor Force Survey) by the Bureau of Statistics.
3) Working days lost is defined by the number of working days lost due to labor disputes accompanied
by strikes and lockouts that lasted longer than half a day.
33
33
Table 1. Corporate Welfare Programs in 1949
Welfare Program All Firms 500 or more
workers 100-499
workers 30-99
workers
Company Housing 58.7 96.3 82.4 54.8
Dining Facilities 21.5 72.2 37.6 14.7
Company Loan 9.4 31.9 14.6 6.8
Medical Clinic 18.4 96.6 43.5 7.6
Health & Safety 50.1 94.6 75.4 41.0
Recreation Programs 26.4 77.4 50.4 17.3
Athletic Facilities 22.0 87.7 46.9 11.8
Source: Rodosho (1960), Rodo Gyoseishi (History of Labor Administration), Vol.2, p.1540.
Note: Percentage of firms adopting each program is reported.
Table 2. Employment Adjustments during Business Downturns
in 1954-55 and 1962-63
Method of Employment Adjustment 1954-55 1962-63
Reduction of Working Hours 48 51
Relocation of Regular Workers 25 31
No Contract Renewals of Temporary Workers 19 13
Reduction of Outside Workers 3 14
No Hiring of New Workers 10 23
Dismissal or Voluntary Retirement of Regular
Workers 17 8
Source: Tsuda, Masumi (1968), Nenkoteki Roshi Kankei-ron (Seniority-based Labor-Management
Relations), p.174.
Notes: Percentage of firms using each method is reported. One firm may use more than one method.
The survey covered firms with 30 or more regular workers in mining, manufacturing and
transportation.
34
34
Table 3. Methods of Employment Adjustment in 2000
Adjustment Method %
Restricting overtime work 11
Reassigning workers to other parts of the business 7
Temporary transfer (shukko) 5
Reducing (or stopping) mid-year intakes of new employees 4
Increasing holiday leave and days-off 2
Dismissing part-time and temporary workers 2
Dismissing or calling for the voluntary retirement of regular employees 2
Source: Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare (2000), Survey on Labour Economy Trend.
Table 4. Top Five Reasons Why Workers Don’t Change Jobs in 2001
Reason %
I exceed the age limit of the job postings 40.8
My work experience is not transferable to the general society 23.4
Returns to seniority will be lost and I will suffer wage loss 21.8
I do not know how to look for jobs 19.1
I will lose personal contacts established through my work 14.1
Source: Recruit Works Institute (2001) Working Persons Chosa 2000: Shutoken (Working
Persons Survey 2000: The Greater Tokyo Area).
... For instance, stereotypes about age could lead voters to believe that younger or older candidates will be more likely to prioritize specific policy issues, adopt particular governance styles, or win an actual election, which may affect their ultimate vote choice. 1 To examine age biases and stereotypes among voters, we conducted two novel survey experiments in Japan, a country where young people are significantly underrepresented in political institutions. Japan is known for its strong age norms, especially regarding respect for elders and clearly defined roles for younger and older citizens (Moriguchi & Ono, 2006;Nakane, 1972;Sung, 2001). These norms could contribute to age biases against young candidates seeking public office, suggesting Japan may provide a relatively easy case to find evidence of youth discrimination, if it exists. ...
... This age-based hierarchy pervades nearly every aspect of Japanese life, from expressions of filial piety within families (Sung, 2001) to the senpai-kouhai (senior-junior) relationships present in organizations, businesses, and schools (Nakane, 1972). Many institutions, including political ones, operate under strict seniority systems, bestowing individuals with increased power and status as they gain experience with age (Moriguchi & Ono, 2006;Pekkanen et al., 2006). Consequently, it is relatively uncommon for younger individuals to hold positions of authority over their older counterparts, which may reinforce biases against young candidates aiming to represent an older voting population. ...
Article
Full-text available
Why do elected officials tend to be much older than most of their constituents? To understand the mechanisms behind the underrepresentation of young people in public office, we conducted two novel survey experiments in Japan. We asked voters in these experiments to evaluate the photos of hypothetical candidates while altering candidates’ faces using age regression and progression software. Contrary to the observed age demographics of politicians, the voters in our experiments strongly disliked older candidates but viewed younger and middle-aged candidates as equally favorable. Voters saw young candidates as less experienced but also more likely to focus on many policy issues over a longer period, including education, childcare, climate change, anti-corruption measures, and multiculturalism. Young voters especially liked young candidates, suggesting that greater youth turnout could increase youth representation. Conversely, elderly candidates were universally panned, seen as the least competent, least likely to focus on most policy issues, and least electable. Voter biases thus do not seem to be a driving factor behind the shortage of young politicians. To the contrary, voters appear perfectly willing to cast their ballots for young candidates.
... The government paid employers direct subsidies specifically for the purpose of retaining and employing older workers. While the elderly workforce may have benefited from this labour market intervention, it also had the undesirable consequence of depressing youth labour market (Moriguchi and Ono, 2006). ...
... But after 1990, this trend reversed and life satisfaction increased in absolute and relative terms (compared with young people). This reversal is consistent with the expected consequences of the policy reforms targeting elderly people, and with government's intervention to protect the employment of older workers (which came at the expense of depressing labour market conditions for younger adults) (Moriguchi and Ono, 2006). This may explain, at least in part, the bifurcation in life satisfaction between the older and younger people in the 1990s. ...
Article
Whether economic growth improves the human lot is a matter of conditions. We focus on Japan, a country which shifted in the 1990s from a pattern of rampant economic growth and stagnant well-being, to one of modest growth and increasing well-being. We discuss concurrent policy reforms and analyse the changes in well-being. In particular, we assess whether the correlates of the increase in well-being are consistent with those expected from the reforms. We apply Blinder–Oaxaca decomposition to World Values Survey data. Results show that improved conditions for the elderly, parents and women, that is the primary groups targeted by the reforms, correlate with well-being increases. This evidence is consistent with the hypothesis that social safety nets can make economic growth compatible with sustained increases in well-being.
... Japan is an indicator of the last point, in which less than a seventh of its employment has been in hyper-efficient industrial groups, with commitment to the kaizen of continuous improvement in methods of work organisation to raise productivity (Colenso, 2000). The rest of the economy has low productivity in both agriculture and services, yet is socially efficient in the sense of assuring employment, income and a high degree of social cohesion (Dore, 1986, Moriguchi & Ono, 2004. ...
Article
Full-text available
One of the premises of rising neoliberalism from the 1980s had been the claim of Ronald Reagan that government is the problem not the solution, readily endorsed, in parallel, by Margaret Thatcher on coming into government. Drawing on a range of international examples this paper shows that this was utterly uninformed, that deregulation of finance in the US led to the worst financial crisis in 2008 since 1929 and that Thatcher's scrapping of the 1970s Labour governments' industrial policy instruments led to major de-industrialisation in the UK which influenced the 'No' vote in the 2016 referendum on whether Britain should remain in the European Union. While the US nonetheless pursued an industrial policy by stealth which promoted a range of advanced technology corporations and that Germany, embodying liberal market principles after WW2, recently has endorsed the case for not only a German but also European industrial policy and led in advocating a European Green New Deal modelled on the Roosevelt New Deal which recovered the US from The Depression of the early 1930s and convinced Truman to support the Marshall Aid programme that also recovered Western Europe after the cataclysm of WW2.
... Efficient and active rental market (in addition to the housing market itself) is important for the growth of the sharing economy (Barron et al. 2018). This is vital for Japan because of its unique corporate loyalty and employment security, also known as lifetime employment practice (Moriguchi and Ono 2006;Kambayashi and Kato 2009). Young and middle-aged workers prefer to rent rather than purchase a house because of corporate subsidies and the high probability of being transferred by the employer to branches across different cities. ...
Article
Full-text available
We introduce a new type of automated valuation model (AVM) for residential rental markets employing the ordinary kriging method. Using nearly 300, 000 coordinates of individual properties and a proprietary dataset of asking rental prices, we form a unique micro-level housing rental dataset for five major metropolitan areas in Tokyo, Japan, and estimate the rental AVM with kriging, utilising only latitude and longitude. From our training and test datasets, we find that the accuracy of the ordinary kriging method is comparable to the traditional hedonic pricing approach, which requires substantial property information. Our finding suggests that the efficiency of the ordinary kriging approach for rental AVM is comparable to the hedonic pricing approach. For robustness, we investigate the roles of spatial variables based on our baseline hedonic regression models. Spatial variables—latitudes, longitudes, and distance to Tokyo Station—are significant in determining housing rents in the Tokyo residential market. By providing an open-source AVM for the residential rental market, we alleviate the information asymmetry between the tenants-to-be and property owners and increase the efficiency of housing markets.
... Por esto, se les asignan actividades mayormente de apoyo dentro de las corporaciones. Algunas empresas han ido abriendo puestos de empleo regular -seishain-para ellas, pero, a diferencia de los hombres que pueden ser contratados sobre la base de permanencia desde un inicio, las mujeres deben cumplir un determinado número de años en la empresa, hacer una solicitud explícita y pasar un examen (Asao, 2011;Moriguchi y Ono, 2004;Takahashi, 2018). Aunque el gobierno ha estado tratando de motivar a que las corporaciones incorporen a más mujeres en puestos directivos, la respuesta ha sido prácticamente nula (Song, 2015; The Government of Japan, 2018). ...
Article
Full-text available
A partir de una revisión documental y desde un enfoque cultural, este artículo revisita, luego de cuatro décadas de su popularización, los elementos principales del modelo de cultura corporativa japonesa, analizando la relación entre las prácticas organizacionales y la cultura laboral con elementos específicos de la cultura de aquella sociedad. Asimismo, desde una perspectiva cualitativa y partiendo del análisis de la política exterior, se revisarán las características de la inversión japonesa en América Latina a fin de destacar la importancia de una mutua comprensión cultural entre Japón y América Latina.
Article
Guided by an institutionally embedded resource-based view, this paper addresses two under-researched questions. First, what effects do flexible strategies for labor-cost retrenchment (e.g., wage-based and functional flexibility) have on market value as compared with rigid strategies (such as pure downsizing)? Second, what effects do flexible strategies have, compared to rigid strategies, when firm have a high level of knowledge assets? We answer these questions by focusing on firms in the research context of a stakeholder-capitalism environment. The dearth of studies on flexible strategies is surprising when one considers that firms in many advanced economies deploy them widely to reduce labor costs during times of crisis. We address this research gap with a novel data set of 220 retrenchment announcements by Japanese firms. We find that announcing the adoption of flexible strategies is significantly and positively associated with a greater likelihood of the firm’s market value increasing. Further, flexible strategies are evaluated more positively if they protect knowledge assets. We attribute these effects to flexible strategies being perceived not only as a capability but also as a signal of legitimacy – that is, as an effort to maintain capabilities in an environment characterized by long-term in-house employment and to align with the norms of a broader institutional landscape.
Article
Full-text available
The article examines the experience of value-based work motivation in modernized East Asian societies and economies of the Confucian tradition. The author considers the ontological, anthropological, civilization-cultural, socio-psychological, political-economic and applied (on the cases of Japan and China) aspects of the above mentioned problem. Performed an interdisciplinary analysis of the worldview and value-based foundations of work motivation, and various characteristic features of the labor and corporate ethics of the Confucian-tradition countries, which contributed to the phenomenal success of their post-war reconstruction, and economic and social modernization. Applied the fractal-synergistic method developed by the author, along with various tools of social philosophy, political economy, psychology, and modernization theory. The author shows that the present mode of thinking (and the corresponding value-based motivation) of a typical Western person, based on the dichotomy of the individual “I” and the outside world, turns out to be significantly more conservative and resistant to the Fourth Industrial Revolution, associated with the widespread introduction of artificial intelligence and the blurring of boundaries between inorganic, living and digital realities, than the traditionally holistic consciousness of China and the “Confucian tigers”, which perceives nature, society and human in an organic unity. This phenomenon is in sharp contrast to the eras of the first three industrial revolutions, when the West, primarily the Protestant West was the undisputed global leader in technological progress, the introduction of innovations, and the intensive growth of labor productivity. It is proved that in the newly industrialized countries of East Asia, the reformed and modernized Confucianism actually acts as a consolidating positive civil religion and a value-motivational driver of dynamic socio-economic development. The author evaluates the relevance of the East Asian experience of the value-based work motivation in the context of the transformation of societal values in Ukraine and the imperatives of the post-war reconstruction of this country’s economy. It is concluded that the communitarian-solidarist system of labor ethics inherent in East Asian countries has a significant potential for its implementation in Ukraine.
Article
The author, using data on 694 U.S. manufacturing establishments from a 1992 survey, examines the incidence of innovative work practices (teams, job rotation, quality circles, and Total Quality Management) and investigates what variables, including human resource practices, are associated with the adoption of these practices. He finds that about 35% of private sector establishments with 50 or more employees made substantial use of flexible work organization in 1992. Some factors associated with an establishment's adoption of these practices are being in an internationally competitive product market, having a technology that requires high levels of skill, following a “high road†strategy that emphasizes variety, service, and quality rather than low cost, and using such human resource practices as high levels of training and innovative pay systems.
Article
Spurred by the Japanese model, the U.S. automobile industry has been restructuring its industrial relations practices along lines that aim to build upon union-management cooperation. This new organization of work changes local work rules by replacing numerous detailed job classifications with only one to three broad classifications. Team work, job rotation, and continuous improvement programs are introduced to replace direct supervision as the mechanism for obtaining high productivity and quality. Greater employee involvement in decision making is supposed to improve worker satisfaction and increase productivity. This article examines the advantages and problems of implementing union-management cooperation by comparing the experiences of the NUMMI (Toyota-General Motors joint venture) automobile assembly plant in Fremont, CA, with that of the GM plant in Van Nuys, CA. The article identifies the factors that facilitated cooperation in one case (NUMMI) and that seemed to block it in the other (GM-Van Nuys) and discusses the policy instruments that might enhance coooperative outcomes.