ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

This paper analyzes the problem of designing mechanisms to implement efficient solutions in economies with externalities. We provide two simple mechanisms implementing the Pigouvian Social Choice Correspondence in environments in which coalitions can or cannot be formed. Copyright 1999 by Blackwell Publishing Inc.
Pigouvian Taxes: A Strategic Approach
JOSÊ ALCALDE
University of Alicante
LUIS C. CORCHÓN
University Carlos III, Madrid
BERNARDO MORENO
University of Málaga
Abstract
This paper analyzes the problem of designing mechanisms to imple-
ment efficient solutions in economies with externalities. We pro-
vide two simple mechanisms implementing the Pigouvian Social
Choice Correspondence in environments in which coalitions can
or cannot be formed.
1. Introduction
This paper studies the problem of implementing efficient allocations in
economies with externalities. In these environments, it is well known that
competitive equilibrium fails to be Pareto efficient. Pigou ~1920!pro-
posed solving this problem by establishing a tax system ~called Pigouvian
taxes!in such a way that when agents are price and tax takers a Pareto
efficient allocation is attained.
1
A classical criticism of Pigou’s approach is that the computation of
Pigouvian taxes requires precise knowledge of utility and production
José Alcalde, University of Alicante ~alcalde@merlin fae.ua.es!. Luis C. Corchón, University
Carlos III, Madrid, 126 28903 Getafe, Madrid, Spain ~lcorchon@eco.uc3m.es!. Bernardo
Moreno, University of Málaga.
We are grateful to Salvador Barberà, Carmen Beviá, Martin Peitz, William Thomson, two
anonymous referees, an associated editor, and participants in the Primer Congrès de la
Catalunya Central for very useful comments on a preliminary version of the paper. Alcalde’s
work is partially supported by DGCYT under project PB 94 –1504. Corchón acknowledges
financial support from DGC YT’s project PB 93–0940. The authors also acknowledge finan-
cial support from the Institut Valencià d’Investigacions Económiques.
Received 1 July 1997; Accepted 14 June 1998.
1
Other approaches dealing with the problem of externalities include the classical contribu-
tions by Coase ~1960!and Arrow ~1970!.
1
functions—information that is not in the hands of the regulator. This is
the typical problem dealt with in the Theory of Implementation. In this
framework Varian ~1994!presents a two-stage compensation mechanism imple-
menting in subgame perfect Nash equilibria ~SPE!the Pigouvian Social
Choice Correspondence ~PSCC!, that is, the mapping between the set of
admissible economies and the allocations that are a Pigouvian equilibrium
for the corresponding economy. Varian’s compensation mechanism for
the two-agent case is such that at the first stage each agent announces the
Pigouvian tax for the other agent. The agent generating the externality is
penalized whenever the sum of the Pigouvian taxes is not balanced. At the
second stage, this agent selects the output level.
The compensation mechanism provides a nice solution to the prob-
lem of implementing the PSCC when agents’ preferences are strictly con-
vex. However, this mechanism presents two difficulties. First, in economies
in which one agent has linear preferences, there are SPE of this mecha-
nism yielding allocations that are not Pareto efficient ~see Examples 2.8
and 2.9 below!. Second, and more important, the solution concept used
by Varian, namely SPE, cannot be easily extended to environments in
which coalitions can be formed. We believe that an extension to these
environments is crucial because of their relevance to potential applications.
2
In this paper we present two “simple” mechanisms that implement,
even for linear economies, the PSCC for different equilibrium concepts.
The first mechanism implements the PSCC in strong Nash equilibria.
An important difference between Varian’s mechanism and ours is that
output is not decided by a single individual. As we will see in Examples 2.8
and 2.9, the reason that Pareto inefficient allocations can be supported by
SPE in Varian’s compensation mechanism is that output is decided by a
single individual. In order to avoid this problem, our mechanism deter-
mines the output level through the interaction of all agents. In order to
interpret this procedure, let us think of the level of externality as pollu-
tion. The quantity of pollution must equal the quantity of pollution per-
mits, which are determined by the interaction of all agents. Assuming that
the quantity of pollution can be monitored without cost, and that pollu-
tion and output are in fixed proportions, it follows that output is ~indi-
rectly!determined by the quantity of pollution permits.
2
In the case considered in this paper, Pigouvian taxes can be interpreted as Lindahl prices
of the pollution. Therefore, a Pigouvian equilibrium can be seen as a Lindahl equilibrium.
Nakamura ~1988!presents a feasible and continuous mechanism ~at the cost of the simplicity
of the mechanism!implementing Pigouvian allocations in Nash equilibria but not in strong
equilibria. Walker ~1981!presents a mechanism implementing Lindahl allocations in Nash
equilibria but not in strong equilibria. Peleg ~1996!presents a mechanism implementing the
Lindahl correspondence in Nash and strong equilibria for the case in which all strategically
active agents have strictly increasing preferences in all goods. In our model, agent 0 has
strictly increasing preferences in the public good but preferences for the rest of the agents
are strictly decreasing in this good. Thus, Peleg’s mechanism cannot be directly applied to
our framework.
2
The second mechanism doubly implements the PSCC in Nash and
strong Nash equilibria. This mechanism is more complicated than the
first one but it has the additional advantage that implementation occurs
in both Nash and strong Nash equilibria. Therefore, the implementation
of the desired result does not depend on the possibilities of coalition
formation.
The two mechanisms are simple. Agents announce allocations and
prices, and the mechanisms mimic the role of competitive markets. The
first mechanism is continuous but there are Nash equilibria yielding allo-
cations that are not Pareto efficient. The second mechanism is discontin-
uous but it can be made continuous at the cost of complicating the
mechanism. Thus, the trade-off between the two mechanisms is that of
simplicity versus robustness of the equilibrium concept.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the
model. Implementation of Pigouvian SCC in strong Nash equilibria using
a continuous mechanism is reported in Section 3. Section 4 presents a
mechanism that doubly implements the Pigouvian SCC in Nash and strong
Nash equilibria.
2. The Model
Let us consider the following externality problem involving n11 agents.
Let I5$0,1,...,n%be the set of agents. Agent 0 consumes qunits of a
good generating an external effect on the other agents. Agents’ prefer-
ences are representable by a utility function, u
i
, which depends on two
variables. The first one, T
i
[R, plays the role of ~a transfer of!numér-
aire,
3
whereas the second, q[R
1
, measures the consumption of the good
that generates the externality. For simplicity, we assume that each u
i
is
quasilinear, but all of our results are still valid in the case of nonquasilin-
ear utility functions. Thus, agent i’s utility function can be expressed as
u
i
~T
i
,q!5T
i
1v
i
~q!,
where v
i
is concave, strictly increasing for agent 0, and strictly decreasing
for the other agents.
4
Alternatively, for interpretative convenience, we
3
In order to simplify the presentation, we assume that agents can incur unbounded debts.
An alternative assumption is that T
i
is nonnegative and agents prefer any feasible allocation
to any unfeasible allocation. In any case, the mechanisms presented in this paper can be
made feasible at the cost of some extra complications.
4
As was pointed out by Starrett ~1972!, externalities introduce nonconvexities that may
preclude the existence of a Pigouvian equilibrium. In our case, for qlarge enough, agents
1,...,nwould suffer a damage larger than any possible payoff they could obtain. In such a
case these agents would like to shut down business ~or move to a different location!and buy
an infinite amount of pollution permits. The existence of a Pigouvian equilibrium can be
restored if pollution cannot exceed a suitably chosen upper bound for which agents 1,...,n
wish to remain active. See Boyd and Conley ~1997!for an alternative interpretation of this
issue.
3
may write T
i
5t
i
q. In such a case, t
i
is interpreted as a per-unit tax. An
economy is a list e5~u
0
,u
1
,..,u
n
!. Let Edenote the set of all admissible
economies. Given an economy e, we say that an allocation z 5~T
0
,T
1
,...,T
n
,q!
is feasible for eif q[R
1
and (
i[I
T
i
50. Let Zdenote the set of all
feasible allocations. In order to simplify notation, we extend preferences
~and utility functions!over allocations in the following way. We say that
agent iweakly prefers allocation z5~T
0
,...,T
n
,q!to z
'
5~T
0
'
,...,T
n
'
,q
'
!
iff u
i
~T
i
,q!u
i
~T
i
'
,q
'
!. In this case, we will also write u
i
~z!u
i
~z
'
!.
The properties we introduce next are minimal conditions that should
be satisfied by any solution to be considered satisfactory. The minimal
requirements for an allocation are
1. Pareto efficiency. Given an economy e, we say that a feasible alloca-
tion zis efficient if there is no feasible allocation z
'
that is weakly
preferred to zby all the individuals, and strictly preferred by at
least one of the agents. That is, z[Zis Pareto efficient if there is
no z
'
[Zsuch that, u
i
~z
'
!u
i
~z!for all i[I, and u
j
~z
'
!.u
j
~z!
for some j[I.
2. Individual rationality. Given an economy e, we say that a feasible
allocation zis individually rational if it yields no fewer payoffs to all
agents than the allocation where neither exchange nor production
occurs. An allocation z[Zis individually rational whenever u
i
~z!
u
i
~0,0!for all i[I.
We are interested in social choice correspondences satisfying these two
minimal conditions. It is well known that, in a competitive equilibrium,
the level of output chosen by agent 0 fails to be Pareto efficient and
individually rational. Pigou ~1920!pointed out a solution to this problem—
intervention by a regulator who imposes a tax system. The idea of estab-
lishing a tax system to solve the problem of externalities is credited to
Pigou; however, he did not address the problem of distributing the income
generated by these taxes.
DEFINITION 2.1: The Pigouvian Social Choice Correspondence (PSCC),f
p
:Er
R
n
3R
1
,associates to each economy, e 5~u
0
,u
1
,..,u
n
![E, a tax0transfer
system, ~t
i
*
!
i[I
[R
n
, and an output q
*
[R
1
such that both of the following
hold:
1. q
*
maximizes u
i
~T
i
,q!5u
i
~t
i
*
q,q!5t
i
*
q1v
i
~q!for all i [I
2. (
i[I
t
i
*
50.
Note that the quantity qmay be interpreted as a public good produced by
a firm ~agent 0!and paid by all agents. The only difference with the
standard public good case is that utility functions of agents 1 to nare
decreasing on q. In such a case, given an economy e5~u
0
,u
1
,..,u
n
![E,t
i
is agent i’s individualized price of the public good, and condition 2 in
Definition 2.1 represents the usual way of defining the price at which the
firm sells the public good.
4
The PSCC has good properties. For instance, it is Pareto efficient and
individually rational. However, in many cases the regulator does not have
access to the information needed to compute the Pigouvian taxes. This is
where implementation theory comes into the picture. The following con-
cepts are standard in the literature.
DEFINITION 2.2: A mechanism G, is a list of strategy spaces, M 5~M
i
!
i[I
, and
an outcome function, f :3
i[I
M
i
rR
n
3R
1
.
Given e5~u
0
,u
1
,..,u
n
![E, let ~G,e!denote a normal form game. Let xbe
an equilibrium concept ~i.e., Nash equilibrium, etc.!and x~G,e!be the set
of x-equilibria of the game ~G,e!. In this paper we focus our attention on
Nash and strong Nash equilibria.
DEFINITION 2.3: A profile of messages m 5~m
0
,m
1
,...,m
n
![M is a Nash
equilibrium of the game ~G,e!if for all i [I and for all m
i
'
[M
i
, we have
that u
i
~f~m
i
,m
2i
!! u
i
~f~m
i
'
,m
2i
!!.Let N~G,e!be the set of Nash equi-
libria of the game ~G,e!.
DEFINITION 2.4: A profile of messages m 5~m
0
,m
1
,...,m
n
![M is a strong
Nash equilibrium of the game ~G,e!if there is no S #I and m
S
'
[3
i[S
M
i
,
satisfying u
i
~f~m
S
'
,m
2S
!!.u
i
~f~m
S
,m
2S
!! for all i [S.Let S ~G,e!be the
set of strong Nash equilibria of the game ~G,e!.
DEFINITION 2.5: The mechanism Gimplements the PSCC f
P
:ErR
n
3R
1
in
x-equilibrium if for all e [Ewith x~G,e!ÞB,f~x~G,e!! 5f
P
~e!.
Let xand x
'
be two concepts of equilibrium, and x~G,e!~respectively,
x
'
~G,e!! be the set of x-equilibria ~respectively, x
'
-equilibria!of the game
~G,e!.
DEFINITION 2.6: The mechanism Gdoubly implements the PSCC f
P
:ErR
n
3
R
1
in x-equilibrium and x
'
-equilibrium if for all e [Ewith x~G,e!ÞB,
and x
'
~G,e!ÞB,f~x~G,e!! 5f~x
'
~G,e!! 5f
P
~e!.
Let us introduce Varian’s ~1994!compensation mechanism for the two
agents case.
DEFINITION 2.7 ~The Compensation Mechanism; Varian 1994!:
Announcement stage: Agents 0 and 1 simultaneously announce the mag-
nitude of the appropriate Pigouvian per-unit tax; denote the announcement
offirm0bym
0
and the announcement of agent 1 by m
1
.
Choice stage: The regulator makes side payments to the agents so that they
face the following payoff functions:
u
0
~q,m
0
,m
1
!5m
1
q1v
0
~q!2a~m
0
1m
1
!
2
u
1
~q,m
0
,m
1
!5m
0
q1v
1
~q!.
The parameter a.0is of arbitrary magnitude. Agent 0 selects the level of
output q.
5
Thus, both individuals simultaneously select Pigouvian taxes at the
first stage and agent 0 selects the output level at the second stage. Varian
~1994!shows that this mechanism implements in SPE the Pigouvian Social
Choice Correspondence when agents’ preferences are strictly convex. How-
ever, we provide two examples which show that Varian’s results are only
valid when preferences are convex but not strictly convex.
Example 2.8: Agent 0 has linear preferences ~constant returns to scale!.
Consider the following profit functions
v
0
~q!5pq 2cq,p.c.0
v
1
~q!52
d
2q
2
d.0.
The Pigouvian allocation is q
*
5~p2c!0d,t
0
*
5c2p,t
1
*
5p2c. Note
that q
*
5~p2c!0d,m
0
5t
1
*
,m
1
5t
0
*
is an SPE of Varian’s compen-
sation mechanism yielding the Pigouvian allocation. However, setting
[q50, [m
0
5p2c,[m
1
5c2pis a subgame perfect equilibrium because
agent 0’s payoff is identically zero in the second stage.
Example 2.9 ~Linear externality!:
Consider the following functions
v
0
~q!5pq 2Aq
c
,c.1, p,A.0
v
1
~q!52dq,d.0
The Pigouvian allocation is q
*
5@~ p1d!0cA#
10~c21!
,t
0
*
52t
1
*
52d.
Then agent 1’s payoff is zero. Note that q
*
,m
0
5t
1
*
,m
1
5t
0
*
is an SPE
of Varian’s compensation mechanism yielding the Pigouvian alloca-
tion. However, there are SPE where agent 1 chooses any arbitrary m
1
~which yields an undesirable outcome in the second stage!because
agent 1 makes zero payoff in the second stage.
We have seen that the compensation mechanism, in the case of econ-
omies in which exactly one agent has linear preferences, does not solve
the problem of finding a mechanism that implements the Pigouvian SCC.
More seriously, coalition formation cannot be considered because an exten-
sion of SPE to deal with this possibility does not exist. Thus, we look for
new mechanisms in which the problem of coalition formation can be
dealt with.
3. A Continuous Mechanism Implementing the Pigouvian
Correspondence in Strong Nash Equilibria
This section presents a simple and continuous mechanism that imple-
ments, in strong Nash equilibria, the Pigouvian Social Choice Correspon-
dence. For the sake of concreteness, think of the classical example of the
6
papermill ~agent 0!and the fishermen ~agents 1,...,n!. In this context, it
is reasonable to assume that agents know the damages and profits caused
by the papermill output and that they can meet together and discuss the
quantity of pollution permits. Let us introduce the mechanism G
S
that
formalizes the rules under which discussions are organized. Let M
i
5R
2
be the strategy space for each i[I. A strategy for agent i[Iis a pair
m
i
5~m
i
1
,m
i
2
![R
2
. The first component is interpreted as her proposed
Pigouvian tax, m
i
1
. The second component, m
i
2
, is interpreted as the
incremental level of pollution permits. A profile of strategies is a list m5
~m
0
,m
1
,...,m
n
![R
2~n11!
. The outcome function is
f~m
0
,m
1
,...,m
n
!5~t
0
~m!,...,t
n
~m!,q~m!!,~3.1!
where q~m!5max$0, (
i50
n
m
i
2
%and, for each iin I,t
i
~m!5
min$m
i
1
,2(
jÞi
m
j
1
%.
In this mechanism each agent i[Ireceives a compensation ~or pays
a tax!of T
i
~m!5t
i
~m!q~m!. Her payoff is t
i
~m!q~m!1v
i
~q~m!!. Thus, in
mechanism G
S
the quantity of pollution permits is unanimously decided
by all agents and each agent’s tax is given by the taxes announced by the
others, except when she states a “high” tax ~or a “low” subsidy!for herself.
A strong Nash equilibrium of the game formed by this mechanism and
the payoff functions of each agent yields a self-enforcing agreement that
no group of agents would like to renegotiate.
5
We first state a result connecting strong Nash and Nash equilibria for
this mechanism.
LEMMA 3.1: [m5~[m
0
,[m
1
,..., [m
n
!is a strong Nash equilibrium of the above
mechanism if and only if ~i![m is a Nash equilibrium and ~ii!(
i50
n
[m
i
1
50.
Proof: To prove the necessary condition, let [m5~[m
0
,[m
1
,..., [m
n
!be a
strong Nash equilibrium of G
S
which does not satisfy condition ~ii!.
First, consider the case where q~[m!.0. Then consider the case where
each agent plays the strategy Km
i
5~[m
i
1
2(
i[I
@t
i
~[m!0~n11!# ,[m
i
2
!. Since
the transfer received by each agent is larger than before and the level
of qis unchanged, all agents will benefit from this deviation. Notice
that, when condition ~ii!is not satisfied, (
i[I
t
i
~[m!is negative. Second,
suppose that q~[m!50. Consider the following agents’ strategies. For
agent 0, Km
0
5~2(
i51
n
t
i
,q!and for each i51,...,n,Km
i
5~(
jÞi
t
j
,0!,
where qand t
i
,i51,...,n, are positive real numbers satisfying
q(
i51
n
t
i
,v
0
~q!2v
0
~0!. Notice that, by construction, all agents prefer
the outcome associated with these strategies rather that the equilib-
rium outcome. A contradiction.
In order to prove the sufficient condition, let [mbe a Nash equi-
librium satisfying condition ~ii!in Lemma 3.1. Suppose this is not a
strong Nash equilibrium, so there is a coalition S#Nand strategies
5
Notice that we do not assume the outcome of the meeting can be written in the form of a
contract that can be enforced by courts, as in the famous Coase Theorem.
7
8
formation possibilities. Thus we need a mechanism that copes with cases
in which coalitions can or cannot be formed.
To simplify the presentation we introduce a mechanism that is discon-
tinuous. Nevertheless, the mechanism can be made continuous by making
the proper modifications ~see Corchón and Wilkie 1996!. Thus the trade-
off between the mechanism presented in Section 3 and the one in this
section is that of simplicity versus a more robust concept of implementation.
We introduce the mechanism G
H
. Let M
i
5R
2
be the strategy space
for each i[I. A strategy for agent i[Iis a pair m
i
5~m
i
1
,m
i
2
![R
2
. For
each i[I,m
i
1
is the tax ~or subsidy!she proposes for herself, and m
i
2
is an
incremental quantity on the production level. A profile of strategies is
written as Km5~Km
0
,Km
1
,..., Km
n
![R
2~n11!
. The outcome function is given
by
f~Km!5~T
0
~Km!,...,T
n
~Km!,q~Km!! ~4.1!
with q~Km!5max$0, (
i50
n
m
i
2
%if (
j[I
m
j
1
50 and q~Km!50 in any other case,
and T
i
~Km!5m
i
1
q~Km!if (
j[I
m
j
1
50 and 2g6(
i50
n
m
i
1
6otherwise, where the
parameter g.0 can be chosen to be arbitrarily small.
A natural interpretation can be provided for this mechanism. Each
agent announces her proposed Pigouvian tax, m
i
1
. The second component
for each agent’s strategy, m
i
2
, is the incremental level of pollution permits.
The output level is q~Km!and she receives a compensation ~or pays a tax!
of T
i
~Km!. So her payoff will be T
i
~Km!1v
i
~q~Km!!. This compensation depends
on two factors. First, if the announced taxes balance the sum of transfers
among agents, each agent’s compensation is q~Km!times the tax she
announced. Second, if such a balance does not hold, no output is pro-
duced and each agent is penalized.
We next introduce our main result of this section.
THEOREM 4.1: The mechanism G
H
doubly implements in Nash and strong Nash
equilibria the Pigouvian Social Choice Correspondence.
Proof: Let e5~u
0
,u
1
,..,u
n
![Ebe an economy. We will first prove that
every Pigouvian equilibrium can be supported by a strong Nash equi-
librium of the game ~G
H
,e!.
Let ~T
0
*
,...,T
n
*
,q
*
![R
n
3R
1
be a Pigouvian allocation for e.We
show that the strategy profile Um, where Um
i
5~t
i
*
,@q
*
0~n11!# ! and t
i
*
5
~T
i
*
0q
*
!for each i[I, is a strong Nash equilibrium of ~G
H
,e!yielding
such an allocation.
First, it is clear that such strategies yield the desired outcome.
Now we show that Um[S~G
H
,e!. Consider a coalition S#Iand a
deviation [m
S
of agents in this coalition. If Um
i
1
5[m
i
1
for all i[S, any
agent in Scan get any q
'
[R
1
at a price t
i
*
. By definition of a
Pigouvian allocation the agents cannot improve payoffs with any q
'
Þ
q
*
.If Um
i
1
Þ[m
i
1
for some i[S, we should consider two cases.
9
~i!If (
i[S
[m
i
1
1(
j[I\S
Um
j
1
Þ0, then q~[m
S
,Um
2S
!50. Suppose that
agents in Sobtain a higher payoff. But then for all i[S
v
i
~0!.2g
*
(
i[S
[m
i
1
1(
j[I\S
Um
j
1
*
1v
i
~0!.t
i
*
q
*
1v
i
~q
*
!,
contradicting that ~T
0
*
,...,T
n
*
,q
*
!is a Pigouvian allocation for e.
~ii!If (
i[S
[m
i
1
1(
j[I\S
Um
j
1
50, then (
i[S
[m
i
1
5(
i[S
Um
i
1
. In this case,
there should be an agent i[Ssuch that [m
i
1
,Um
i
1
. Suppose that
igets a higher payoff. Since [m
i
1
,Um
i
1
, we have that
u
i
~Um
i
1
q~[m
S
,Um
2S
!,q~[m
S
,Um
2S
!! u
i
~[m
i
1
q~[m
S
,Um
2S
!,q~[m
S
,Um
2S
!!
.u
i
~Um
i
1
q~Um!,q~Um!!,
which contradicts that ~T
0
*
,...,T
n
*
,q
*
!is a Pigouvian allocation for
e. Thus, Umis a strong Nash equilibrium and hence a Nash equi-
librium.
On the other hand, let [m5~[m
0
,[m
1
,..., [m
n
![N~G
H
,e!.We
show that this yields a Pigouvian allocation for e. Consider two
cases.
Case A: (
i[I
[m
i
1
Þ0. In such a case, for each agent there is a strategy,
namely Um
i
5~2(
jÞi
[m
j
1
,2(
jÞi
[m
j
2
!yielding q~Um
i
,[m
2i
!5
T
i
~Um
i
,[m
2i
!50, a contradiction.
Case B: (
i[I
[m
i
1
50. But then, given [m
2i
, each agent is a price-taker
so the outcome associated with the Nash equilibrium is a Pigou-
vian allocation for e.
To conclude the proof, let [m5~[m
0
,[m
1
,..., [m
n
![S~G
H
,e!. Since
S~G
H
,e!#N~G
H
,e!,[mis a Nash equilibrium of this game. Therefore,
its outcome is a Pigouvian allocation for e.n
References
ARROW, KENNETH J. ~1970!The organization of economic activity: Issues
pertinent to the choice of market versus non-market allocation; in Public
Expenditures and Policy Analysis, R. H. HAVEMAN and J. MARGOLIS, eds.
Chicago: Markhamm, pp. 59–73.
BOYD, JOHN H. III, and JOHN P. CONLEY ~1997!Fundamental nonconvexities
in Arrovian markets and a Coasian solution to the problem of externalities,
Journal of Economic Theory 72, 388–407.
COASE, RONALD ~1960!The problem of social cost, Journal of Law and Econom-
ics 3, 1–44.
CORCHÓN, LUIS C., and SIMON WILKIE ~1996!Double implementation of
the ratio correspondence by a market mechanism, Economic Design 2,
325–337.
10
NAKAMURA, S. ~1988!Feasible Nash implementation of competitive equilibria
in an economy with externalities, Discussion paper no. 248, University of
Minnesota.
PELEG, B. ~1996!Double implementation of the Lindahl equilibrium by a con-
tinuous mechanism, Economic Design 2, 311–324.
PIGOU, A. C. ~1920!The Economics of Welfare. London: Macmillan.
STARRETT, D. ~1972!Fundamental non-convexities in the theory of externali-
ties, Journal of Economic Theory 4, 180–199.
VARIAN, HAL R. ~1994!A solution to the problem of externalities when agents
are well-informed, The American Economic Review 84, 1278–1293.
WALKER, MARK ~1981!A simple incentive compatible scheme for attaining
Lindahl allocations, Econometrica 49, 65–71.
Pigouvian Taxes 281
11
... 3. How should a monopoly be regulated when regulators do not know the cost function or the demand function of the monopolist? 4. How should it be determined whether or not a public facility -a road, a bridge, a stadium-should be constructed and who should pay for it? ...
... They are also doubly implementable by abstract mechanisms, Schmeidler (1980). Double implementation also occurs with several solutions to the problem of the commons, Shin and Suh (1997) and Pigouvian Taxes, Alcalde, Corchón and Moreno (1999). Yamato (1993) Summing up, it is now clear that implementing mechanisms can not be just "anything". ...
... These points were worked out by subsequent contributions from Baron and Myerson, Lewis and Sappington, Sibley and others. 4. By now the reader should know the di¢ culties of implementing e¢ cient public decisions. ...
Chapter
Full-text available
... 3. How should a monopoly be regulated when regulators do not know the cost function or the demand function of the monopolist? 4. How should it be determined whether or not a public facility -a road, a bridge, a stadium-should be constructed and who should pay for it? ...
... They are also doubly implementable by abstract mechanisms, Schmeidler (1980). Double implementation also occurs with several solutions to the problem of the commons, Shin and Suh (1997) and Pigouvian Taxes, Alcalde, Corchón and Moreno (1999). Yamato (1993) Summing up, it is now clear that implementing mechanisms can not be just "anything". ...
... These points were worked out by subsequent contributions from Baron and Myerson, Lewis and Sappington, Sibley and others. 4. By now the reader should know the di¢ culties of implementing e¢ cient public decisions. ...
Chapter
Full-text available
... 3. How should a monopoly be regulated when regulators do not know the cost function or the demand function of the monopolist? 4. How should it be determined whether or not a public facility -a road, a bridge, a stadium-should be constructed and who should pay for it? ...
... They are also doubly implementable by abstract mechanisms, Schmeidler (1980). Double implementation also occurs with several solutions to the problem of the commons, Shin and Suh (1997) and Pigouvian Taxes, Alcalde, Corchón and Moreno (1999). Yamato (1993) Summing up, it is now clear that implementing mechanisms can not be just "anything". ...
... These points were worked out by subsequent contributions from Baron and Myerson, Lewis and Sappington, Sibley and others. 4. By now the reader should know the di¢ culties of implementing e¢ cient public decisions. ...
Article
Full-text available
Glossary Definition of the Subject Introduction Brief History of Implementation Theory The Main Concepts The Main Insights Unsolved Issues and Further Research Answers to the Questions Acknowledgments Bibliography
... 3. How should a monopoly be regulated when regulators do not know the cost function or the demand function of the monopolist? 4. How should it be determined whether or not a public facility -a road, a bridge, a stadium-should be constructed and who should pay for it? ...
... They are also doubly implementable by abstract mechanisms, Schmeidler (1980). Double implementation also occurs with several solutions to the problem of the commons, Shin and Suh (1997) and Pigouvian Taxes, Alcalde, Corchón and Moreno (1999). Yamato (1993) Summing up, it is now clear that implementing mechanisms can not be just "anything". ...
... These points were worked out by subsequent contributions from Baron and Myerson, Lewis and Sappington, Sibley and others. 4. By now the reader should know the di¢ culties of implementing e¢ cient public decisions. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper constructs a two-country (Home and Foreign) general equilibrium model of Schumpeterian growth without scale effects. The scale effects property is removed by introducing two distinct specifications in the knowledge production function: the permanent effect on growth (PEG) specification, which allows policy effects on long-run growth; and the temporary effects on growth (TEG) specification, which generates semi-endogenous long-run economic growth. In the present model, the direction of the effect of the size of innovations on the pattern of trade and Home’s relative wage depends on the way in which the scale effects property is removed. Under the PEG specification, changes in the size of innovations increase Home’s comparative advantage and its relative wage, while under the TEG specification, an increase in the size of innovations increases Home’s relative wage but with an ambiguous effect on its comparative advantage.
... However, the framework related non-financial information, to support has little to say about appropriate revenue use, management within a company or business as it leaves aside other sources of distortion in (Bartolomeo et al., 2000). EMA integrates the economy so there is no scope for corporate environmental and business policies efficiency-enhancing revenue recycling and thereby provides guidance on building a (Alcalde, Corchon& Moreno, 1998). sustainable business. ...
... operating expenses, for pollution control According to the European Environment equipment, and environmental taxes. Tijani Agency (1996), "bringing externalities into and Hamadi (2013) prices"isthe major reasons for environmental environmental tax that bespeaks inherent tax: The main economic reason for using taxes challenges such as:The increased demand to in environmental policy is to bring the costs of grow internally generated revenue, which has pollution and other costs of using the led to the exercise of the power of taxation to environment called "externalities" into the the detriment of the tax payers who suffer prices of the goods and services produced by multiple taxations and bear higher tax burden economic activity. Internalizing external than anticipated; Insufficient information environmental costs is the main reason for available to tax payer on tax compliance using environmental taxes instead of requirement which create uncertainty and regulations. ...
Article
Full-text available
Environmental problems in Nigeria are somewhat caused by industries in Nigeria, while Nigerians are putting pressure on governments to find ways of reducing environmental damages while minimizing harm to economic growth. This study examined challenges of environmental taxation and accounting in Nigeria. A descriptive survey design was adopted. The population of this study is the entire relevant tax authorities in SouthWest Zone of Nigeria and the data for this research were collected from a sample of 250 respondents randomly selected. Data used were sourced primarily using a self-administered, closed-ended questionnaire, designed in Likert scale format. The instrument was validated by experts in taxation and accountancy. Cronbach Alpha was used to determine the reliability index at .05 significance level and the reliability index for the instrument ranges from 0.79-0.84. Meanwhile, mean and standard deviation were used in answering research questions. It was revealed that environmental taxation is significantly coterminous with improved environmental quality in Nigeria, as its existence and administration have the tendency to ensure, restore, and maintain environmental quality in the country. Environmental taxation and accounting have not reduced environmental problems. The study thus, recommended that government should ensure that the structure and administration of environmental related tax premised on sound accounting system in the country should be void of loopholes and provisions that can permit evasion and that proceeds from environmental taxation should be channeled towards the development of infrastructural facilities in Nigeria to ensuring an improved standard of living in the country while companies are also advised to environmental accounting record that depict relevant financial transaction of the companies.
... Resolving neighbor conflicts with the use of Pigou's taxation of the entity creating negative externalities is not applied in practice. Despite attempts to further develop Pigou's theory (Alcalde, Corchón & Moreno, 1999) it is considered as impossible to implement due to the amount of information required (McDonald & McMillen, 2012, pp. 446-447). ...
Article
Full-text available
Purpose-The aim of the paper is to present and compare the rules of resolving a neighbor conflict created by airport noise in the context of Dutch and Polish experiences. Design/methodology/approach-We consider formally similar situations, because both countries utilize public intervention in an attempt to solve the conflict, however differences are visible at the level of its scope, implementation and performance. Research is focused on analyzing the structure of the considered public intervention in both countries in order to establish salient similarities and differences existent in the jurisdictions under comparison. Findings-Descriptive studies are supplemented by particular examples of residential property markets near the largest airport in each country, namely Schiphol Airport in Amsterdam and Chopin Airport in Warsaw. Conducted studies include an assessment of the manner in which public intervention is factually implemented, which allows to formulate initial normative conclusions as to the achieved economic and environmental effects. These are different in both jurisdictions as they depend on the adopted legal solutions and the actual implementation of law. Research limitations and research implications-We analyze compensating loss in the form of residential property value diminution as opposed to analyzing market prices in areas surrounding airports.
... According to the traditional Pigouvian framework, environmental taxes should equal marginal damages and be levied directly on the source of emissions. However, the framework has little to say about appropriate revenue use, as it leaves aside other sources of distortion in the economy so there is no scope for efficiency-enhancing revenue recycling ((Alcalde, Corchon & Moreno, 1998). On a general note, the main theory of environmental tax is based on the fact that " The polluters should pay " in the sense that the source of the pollution is where the tax is imposed. ...
Article
Full-text available
Cities in Nigeria are generally characterized by poor drainage and are therefore subject to flooding. Particularly affected are cities like Lagos, Ibadan, Aba, Calabar, Yenagoa, etc. An estimated 25 million people or 28% of Nigeria’s population live in the coastal area and are at risk from flooding. To this end, environmental taxes have been proposed to address a wide range of issues including waste disposal, water pollution and air emissions. This study looked at environmental tax, and how it can be used as a tool for flood reduction in Nigeria. The research covers the local governments which are majorly affected by flood in Lagos state and copies of questionnaire were administered to the selected samples who are residents. The Spearman Rank Order Correlation which is a non-parametric test was used to measure the degree of association between the dependent and the independent variables. The findings revealed that there is a moderate positive correlation (Rs=.398, p<.005) between the imposition of environmental tax on nylon packages and the reduction of flood and it is significant at 0.01. The study concludes that the implementation of environmental taxes on nylon packaging companies will lead to a reduction in the use of nylon as the major packaging system in Nigeria. The study therefore recommends that there should be a change in the packaging system in Nigeria as most of our products are made by nylon. The adoption of paper bags or cloth bag which has been adopted in developed countries especially in England should be emphasized.
... Benford (1998) deals with a similar problem. His approach consists of an extension to a dynamic setting of aKwerel scheme (1977). 2 See, for instance,Alcalde et al. (1999),Peleg (1996), or Walker (1981. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper deals with the dynamics of the regulation of a persistent pollutant. We show that the equilibrium taxes announced in a series of Varian-type “compensation” mechanisms Varian (Am. Econ. Rev. 85:1278–1293, 1994) do not coincide (in general) with the optimal Pigouvian taxes. This result emerges from the combination of pollution persitence and limited information on the part of the regulatory agency. We also find that equilibrium taxes may fall in response to an increase in the degree of pollution persistence.
Article
Full-text available
This paper constructs a two-country (Home and Foreign) general equilibrium model of Schumpeterian growth without scale effects. The scale effects property is removed by introducing two distinct specifications in the knowledge production function: the permanent effect on growth (PEG) specification, which allows policy effects on long-run growth; and the temporary effects on growth (TEG) specification, which generates semi-endogenous long-run economic growth. In the present model, the direction of the effect of the size of innovations on the pattern of trade and Home’s relative wage depends on the way in which the scale effects property is removed. Under the PEG specification, changes in the size of innovations increase Home’s comparative advantage and its relative wage, while under the TEG specification, an increase in the size of innovations increases Home’s relative wage but with an ambiguous effect on its comparative advantage.
Article
Full-text available
D. Starrett [J. Econ. Theory4(1972), 180–199] argues that the presence of externalities implies fundamental nonconvexities which cause Arrow markets to fail. While this is true, we argue this failure is due to the structure of the Arrovian markets that Starrett uses, and not to the presence of externalities as such. We provide an extension of a general equilibrium public goods model in which property rights are explicitly treated. Nonconvexities are not fundamental in this framework. We define a notion of Coasian equilibrium for this economy, and show first and second welfare theorems. In this context, the first welfare theorem is a type of Coase theorem.Journal of Economic LiteratureClassification Numbers: D62, H41.
Article
Also, there is considerable ambiguity in the purpose of the analysis of externalities. The best developed part of the theory relates to only a single, question: the statement of a set of conditions, as weak as possible, which insure that a competitive equilibrium exists and is Pareto efficient. Then the denial of any of these hypotheses is presumably a sufficient condition for considering resort to non-market channels of resource allocation-usually thought of as Government expenditures, taxes, and subsidies. At a second level the analysis of externalities should lead to criteria for non-market allocation. We are tempted to set forth these criteria in terms analogous to the profit-and-loss statements of private business; in this form, we are led to benefit-cost analysis. There are, moreover, two possible aims for benefit-cost analysis; one, more ambitious but theoretically simpler, is specification of the non-market actions which will restore Pareto efficiency; the second involves the recognition that the instruments available to the Government or other non-market forces are scarce resources for one reason or another, so that all that can b achieved is a "second-best." Other concepts at seem to cluster closely to the-concept of public goods are those of "increasing returns" -and-" market failure.'' These are related to Pareto inefficiency on the one hand and to the existence and optimality of competitive equilibrium on the other; sometimes the, discussions in the literature do not adequately distinguish these two aspects. I contend that market failure is a more general category than externality; and both differ from increasing returns in a basic sense, since market failures in general and externalities in particular are relative to the mode of economic organization, while increasing returns are essentially a technological phenomenon. Current writing has helped bring out the point that market failure is not absolute; it is better to consider a broader category that of transaction costs, which in general impede and in particular cases completely block the formation of markets. It is usually though not always emphasized that transaction costs are costs of running the economic system. An incentive for vertical integration is replacement of the costs of buying and selling on the market by the costs of intra-firm transfers; the existence of vertical integration may suggest that the costs of operating competitive markets are not zero, as is usually assumed in our theoretical analysis. Monetary theory, unlike value theory, is heavily dependent on the assumption of positive transaction costs; the recurrent complaint about the difficulty of integrating these two branches of theory is
Chapter
The Problem to be ExaminedThe Reciprocal Nature of the ProblemThe Pricing System with Liability for DamageThe Pricing System with No Liability for DamageThe Problem Illustrated AnewThe Cost of Market Transactions Taken into AccountThe Legal Delimitation of Rights and the Economic Problem
Article
This paper constructs a two-country (Home and Foreign) general equilibrium model of Schumpeterian growth without scale effects. The scale effects property is removed by introducing two distinct specifications in the knowledge production function: the permanent effect on growth (PEG) specification, which allows policy effects on long-run growth; and the temporary effects on growth (TEG) specification, which generates semi-endogenous long-run economic growth. In the present model, the direction of the effect of the size of innovations on the pattern of trade and Home’s relative wage depends on the way in which the scale effects property is removed. Under the PEG specification, changes in the size of innovations increase Home’s comparative advantage and its relative wage, while under the TEG specification, an increase in the size of innovations increases Home’s relative wage but with an ambiguous effect on its comparative advantage.