ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

The Sarkozy Report is a study commissioned by the French President on better ways to measure the level and progress of societal well-being than conventional economic indicators such as GDP. Despite being prepared by prominent economists-the commission was led by Joseph Stiglitz, Amartya Sen, and Jean-Paul Fitoussi-the Report rejects reliance on "production-oriented" measures of progress in favor of a broader array of quality-of-life indicators, some of them subjective, and measures of the sustainability of well-being into the future. These multiple dimensions of well-being, it argues, should be used in policy decisions and welfare evaluations. The views expressed in the Report may portend a sea-change in the way economists think about the benefits of economic growth. Copyright (c) 2010 The Population Council, Inc..
WELL-BEING,FRONT AND
CENTER:A NOTE ON THE
SARKOZY REPORT
RICHARD A. EASTERLIN*
Introduction
As a result of French President Nicholas Sarkozy’s
dissatisfaction with current measures of well-being,
most notably GDP, in February 2008 he asked three
economists – Joseph Stiglitz, Amartya Sen (both
Nobel Prize winners), and Jean-Paul Fitoussi – to
create a commission to consider better ways of mea-
suring social progress. The resulting 25-member
group includes 22 scholars with advanced degrees in
economics. Of the other three, two are leading con-
tributors to behavioral economics, the third a pio-
neer in the study of social capital. Eight members
were born in the United States, six in France, and
three in Britain; four of the remainder are from
developing countries.Only two members are female.
The place-of-birth and sex distributions are probably
reasonably representative of the composition of the
economics profession at the time of the members’
professional training.
The resulting Report by the Commission on the
Measurement of Economic Performance and Social
Progress1is a landmark document, most notably in
its advocacy of the use of subjective measures of
well-being for designing policies and assessing so-
cial progress. The magnitude of this recommenda-
tion may not be fully appreciated by non-econo-
mists. For decades economists have prided them-
selves on being “behaviorists”, and they dismissed
self-reports, insisting, in the words of Victor Fuchs,
1995 president of the American Economic Associ-
ation, “that what people do is more relevant than
what they say” (Fuchs 1983, 14, italics in original).
Economic historian Deirdre McCloskey has char-
acterized the attitude of economists as follows:
Unlike other social scientists, economists are
extremely hostile toward questionnaires and
other self-descriptions. … One can literally get
an audience of economists to laugh out loud by
proposing ironically to send out a questionnaire
on some disputed economic point. Economists
… are unthinkingly committed to the notion
that only the externally observable behavior of
economic actors is admissible evidence in argu-
ments concerning economics (1983, 514).
That a group of distinguished economists, five of them
Nobel Prize winners, and most of them trained in the
economic era of behaviorism, would assert that in
measuring social progress serious attention should be
given to self-reports of subjective feelings comes close
to economic heresy. To be sure, the group does not
advocate exclusive use of subjective measures, but
even to admit such measures to the hallowed compa-
ny of so-called objective indicators like GDP or the
unemployment rate is a sharp break with a discipli-
nary paradigm that has dominated economists’ think-
ing for decades. It is,in my opinion, long overdue.
The Report itself comprises three main segments, enti-
tled “Classical GDP Issues”, “Quality of Life”, and
“Sustainable Development and Environment”. The
Commission was divided into subgroups,each working
on one of the three topics.Although the membership
of the subgroups is not stated, it can be fairly well sur-
mised from the references on each topic.
Readers are thoughtfully presented with three options,
each of which covers all three segments: the “Executive
Summary” (12 pages), a “Short Narrative on the
Content of the Report” (62 pages), and “Substantial
Arguments Presented in the Report” (207 pages). In
what follows I draw chiefly on the Executive Summary.
To make a long story short, the Report is built on a
conceptual distinction among four types of measures:
1) production (economic performance),
2) material living level (economic well-being),
CESifo DICE Report 4/2010 22
Forum
* Professor of Economics University of Southern California. This
article is a reprint from the Population and Development Review
36(1), 119–124 (March 2010).
1Available at www.stiglitz-sen-fitoussi.fr.
CESifo DICE Report 4/2010
23
Forum
3) overall (multi-dimensional) wellbeing, and
4) well-being of current versus future generations
(sustainability).
Substantively, item 1, “Production”, as captured in
measures of GNP or GDP, gets little more than a
handwave.The Report rehashes at some length long-
standing problems in the measurement of these con-
cepts: the need to take greater account of changes in
the quality of goods and to improve measures of ser-
vices such as those provided by retail trade and fi-
nancial intermediaries, and particularly of govern-
ment-provided services (health, education and the
like). Nothing new or startling is said here, and no
recommendations are forthcoming. In fairness, one
would hardly expect solutions to issues of output
measurement that have been debated since the
1930s (for example, in the series of volumes pub-
lished by the NBER’s Conference on Research in
Income and Wealth and by the International Associ-
ation for Research in Income and Wealth).
What is new, for economists at least, is the assertion
that GNP and GDP are seriously deficient as mea-
sures of well-being, whether or not modified to take
account of problems like those noted above. Instead,
“the report advocates a shift of emphasis from a ‘pro-
duction-oriented’ measurement system to one focused
on the well-being of current and future generations”
(p. 10), that is, a shift from item 1 in the list above to
items 3 and 4. The Commission’s rejection of GNP
and GDP as measures of well-being is forceful and
caustic: “To focus specifically on the enhancement of
inanimate objects of convenience (for example in the
GNP or GDP which have been the focus of a myriad
of economic studies of progress), could be ultimately
justified – to the extent it could be – only through
what these objects do to the human lives they can
directly or indirectly influence” (p. 8). Note, too, the
extent of the shift the Commission is advocating – it is
not just the addition of new statistics,but a shift in the
orientation of the entire “measurement system”.
As I noted, none of the Commission’s specific recom-
m
endations relates to item 1,“production”. Of the 12 re
-
commendations that are offered, all are concerned
with measuring well-being: five relate to item 2,five to
item 3 and two to item 4.
Those bearing on item 2 – economic well-being –
deal chiefly with ways in which the national econom-
ic accounts, on which GDP is based, might be modi-
fied and used “to shift emphasis from measuring eco-
nomic production to measuring people’s well-being”
(p. 12), specifically, material well-being. In this re-
gard, the main thrust of the recommendations is to
focus on measures of the income, consumption, and
wealth of households, both their per capita amounts
and their distribution. Of special note is the recom-
mendation of time-use studies as a way of obtaining
insight into goods produced and consumed at home.
The Commission’s heart,however, is not primarily in
better estimates of material well-being. Rather, it is
in broadening the measurement of wellbeing to
encompass multiple domains (item 3). To this end,
the Commission identifies eight “key dimensions” of
well-being that “in principle…should be considered
simultaneously” (p. 14):
i. material living standards (income, consump-
tion, and wealth),
ii. health,
iii. education,
iv. personal activities including work,
v. political voice and governance,
vi. social connections and relationships,
vii. environment (present and future conditions),
and
viii. insecurity, of an economic as well as a physical
nature.
In the Commission’s view, “All these dimensions
shape people’s well-being, and yet many of them are
missed by conventional income measures” (p. 15).
(This is a masterpiece of understatement; one may
well ask whether any of these dimensions are cap-
tured by “conventional” income measures.) To rem-
edy this situation the Commission offers a number of
recommendations. It is in this connection that the
Commission’s radical view (for economists) of sub-
jective measures comes to the fore.After advocating
the official collection of a variety of objective mea-
sures on each of the dimensions of well-being noted
above, the Commission states:
Research has shown that it is possible to col-
lect meaningful and reliable data on subjec-
tive as well as objective well-being. Subjective
well-being encompasses different aspects
(cognitive evaluations of one’s life, happiness,
satisfaction, positive emotions such as joy and
pride, and negative emotions such as pain and
worry): each of them should be measured sep-
arately to derive a more comprehensive ap-
preciation of people’s lives. … [T]he types of
question that have proved their value within
small-scale and unofficial surveys should be
included in larger-scale surveys undertaken
by official statistical offices (p. 16).
We have here, potentially, an analog to the great
breakthrough of the 1930s when the immense re-
sources of government took over from individual
scholars the measurement of national income.
The Commission does not dodge the thorny issue of
the desirability of a single summary measure of
well-being, recognizing the “strong demands” for
such a measure. Although not going so far as to
endorse any one measure, it notes that several sum-
mary measures “are already being used, such as
average levels of life-satisfaction for a country as a
whole [a subjective measure], or composite indices
that aggregate averages across objective domains,
such as the Human Development Index”, and that,
with new statistical efforts “[o]thers could be imple-
mented” (p. 16). In addition, the Commission rec-
ommends that attention be given to distributional
aspects of overall well-being and its various
domains,as well as to interrelations among domains.
The issue of interrelations is illustrated by the state-
ment that “the consequences for subjective well-
being of being both poor and sick far exceed the
sum of the two effects” (p. 206, cf. also pp. 16, 55).
What is especially telling about this statement is the
(perhaps unwitting) primacy given to subjective
well-being as the criterion of overall well-being.
The analysis of and recommendations for measures
of current wellbeing, item 3,are carefully separated
from item 4, “sustainability,” that is, whether the
current level of well-being can be maintained for
future generations.And for good
reason: “It is no longer a ques-
tion of measuring the pre
sent,
but of predicting the future, and
this prospective di
mension mul-
tiplies the difficulties already en-
countered” in the discussion of
items 1–3 (p. 61). After an excel-
lent survey and evaluation of the
bewildering array of concepts and
measures of sustainability, the Re-
port ventures two fairly muted re-
commendations, opting for mul-
tiple economic and environmental
indicators and largely rejecting
both aggregative indexes of sus-
tainability and attempts to synthe-
size
the measurement of sustainability with that of
current welfare. In the end it is the measurement of
current welfare – item 3 – that is clearly the Re-
port’s central focus and contribution.
Given the wide-ranging scope of the Sarkozy Re-
port, it is not hard to find specific points with which
one may take issue. But such disagreements are, at
best, secondary to the general message that is con-
veyed – that the commonly accepted standard of
social progress,GDP,is seriously deficient. Instead of
GDP, measures relating to the multiple dimensions
of well-being, not just material gains, should be used
in policy decisions and welfare evaluations.
The significance of this message cannot be exagger-
ated. Consider two examples. The World Bank’s
World Development Report (WDR) 2009 acclaims
the benefits of urbanization, devoting three chapters
to policy proposals to promote urbanization in de-
veloping countries. The benefits identified in WDR
2009 are first and foremost income gains, as workers
shift from lower-paying rural work to higher-paying
urban jobs. Under the heading “What this Report is
not about” (World Bank 2009, 34), WDR 2009 ex-
plicitly sets aside consideration of the social and
environmental effects of urbanization, effects that
might well be negative. If the Sarkozy Commission
were to have its way, then these effects would re-
quire at least equal attention along with income
gains, and the result might well be a quite different
set of policy proposals.
Or consider a 2008 World Bank report that hails as
“success stories” and a model for the developing
world the exceptional growth rates of GDP per capi-
CESifo DICE Report 4/2010 24
Forum
0
2
4
6
8
10
1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006
0
20
40
60
80
100
Sources: Mean satisfaction from World Values Survey (2005); percent satisfaction from Kahneman and
Krueger (2006,16).
L
IFE
S
ATISFACTION,
C
HINA,
1990
2004
Mean life satisfaction
Percent satisfied
Figure
CESifo DICE Report 4/2010
25
Forum
ta achieved in recent decades by countries such as
China and South Korea (Commission on Growth
and Development 2008, 19–20). Since 1990 China
has had perhaps the highest rate of economic growth
ever recorded. With incomes more than tripling in a
fraction of a lifetime, one might have expected the
population to be fabulously overjoyed. During this
period, however, satisfaction with life has not im-
proved at all (see the Figure).
If overall life satisfaction is taken as an indicator of
well-being (though not necessarily the only one), as
the Sarkozy Commission recommends, one might
have second thoughts about this “success story” as a
model for other developing counties.At a minimum,
the life satisfaction measure might lead one to won-
der whether other dimensions of well-being, not
reflected in the trend of GDP per capita, need to be
examined. The pattern for China is no exception. A
study of 37 countries worldwide – 17 developed, nine
developing, and 11 in transition – reveals no signifi-
cant relationship between the improvement in hap-
piness and the long-term rate of growth of GDP per
capita (Easterlin and Angelescu 2009). This is true
for the three groups of countries taken separately
and for all 37 countries combined.
Heretofore, social science disciplines other than eco-
nomics have been less enthusiastic about the benefits
of economic growth, but it is economists that have
had the policymaker’s ear.With the Sarkozy Report,
a sea change is perhaps in the making.
References
Commission on Growth and Development (2008), The Growth
Report: Strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive Develop-
ment, World Bank,Washington DC.
Easterlin, R. A. and L. Angelescu (2009), “Happiness and Growth
the World over: Time Series Evidence on the Happiness–income
Paradox”, IZA Discussion Paper No. 4060; in revised form in R.A.
Easterlin, Happiness, Growth, and the Life Cycle, Oxford Univer-
sity Press, New York, in press.
Fuchs, V. (1983), How We Live, Harvard University Press, Cam-
bridge, Mass.
Kahneman, D. and A. B. Krueger (2006), “Developments in the
Measurement of Subjective Well-being”, Journal of Economic Per-
spectives 20(1), 3–24.
McCloskey, D. N. (1983),“The Rhetoric of Economics”, Journal of
Economic Literature 21(2), 481–517.
World Bank (2009), World Development Report 2009: Reshaping
Economic Geography, Washington, DC.
World Values Survey (2005), Official Data File, v. 20081015, 2008,
http://www.worldvaluessurvey.org/.
... 07. Although the GDP indicator is often subjected to generally fair criticism (see Costanza et al., 2014;Easterlin, 2010;Goldsmith, 2019;Kapoor & Debroy, 2019;McElwee & Daly, 2014), in this case the criticism is intended to hide the fact that the potential of developed countries has weakened, as well as to cast doubt on the need for economic growth in general; however, the rejection of growth as a goal objectively leads to the stagnation of society (for details see Grinin & Grinin, 2021). 08. ...
Chapter
In this Conclusion, Grinin et al. undertake two tasks simultaneously: (1) to summarize a large part of the ideas and forecasts which have been presented in this monograph and (2) to develop a portrait of the new cybernetic society, in which most of the processes analyzed in this book will take on new qualities. The authors call this new unprecedented type of society “cybernetic”, because its formation will be inextricably linked to the completion of the Cybernetic Revolution. The authors forecast that it will be a society, which will be very different from all previous societies. Why? On the one hand, it will be closely connected to very profound technological changes in the management and regulation of our life at all levels. On the other hand, it is inextricably linked to the process of global aging; moreover, aging becomes an integral part of society. Cybernetic society must go through a difficult path of social frictions, conflicts, and optimizations before many things become institutionalized. The horizon of forecasts is sometimes very long—up to the first third of the twenty-second century. The authors describe changes awaiting humanity that are very serious and uncertain, but at the same time hopeful.
Chapter
It is quite natural that in the current global transition from the “era of growth” to the “era of stability,” the importance of qualitative changes in all spheres of life is increasing. It is indicators of the quality of life in different countries of the world that play an important role among the indicators characterizing these changes. Quality of life depends on both material, social, and psychological factors. Taking into account the existing approaches to determining the quality of life, Malkov et al. make an attempt to create an integrated index that considers both subjective (psychological) and objective aspects of its assessment. The notion that the higher the quality of life, the more basic material, social, and spiritual needs are met, is used as a methodological basis for the construction of the index. When constructing the index, Malkov et al use Maslow’s theory of the “pyramid” of needs (the first, basic, hierarchical level within the “pyramid” is physiological needs, the last level is the need for self-actualization). For each type of needs, indicators characterizing the degree of their satisfaction (or, on the contrary, dissatisfaction) have been selected. The chapter contains a description of the methodology used and some calculation results.
Chapter
The chapter discusses the necessity of choosing different strategies for different groups of countries for a successful movement to the recognized worldwide goals. In this respect, strategies as well as policies depend on different causes and conditions, including demographics, natural resources, historical traditions, etc., but especially on levels of development of countries which are very uneven. The most important and deep gap is the one between the income levels of high-income and low-income countries. However, it happens quite often when high-income countries as well as their (or world) organizations impose on low-income countries strict and almost single-type programs for economic and social reforming, transforming of agricultural or energetic spheres, and so on for achievement of approved world goals (as democracy, carbon neutrality, sustainable development, decrease of inequality and injustice, increase in state efficiency, rates of economic growth, consumptions optimizing, etc.). These programs are worked out on the basis of high-income countries’ experience and they are often not suitable for many low-income countries. Grinin et al. maintain that there should not be single-type recommendations, programs, etc. for all countries for their taking part in the world-wide movement toward common goals. There are common world goals, but for their achievement different countries would need strategies, policies, programs, and measures of different types, which would take into consideration specifics of different societies. Though there still is a great gap between high-income and low-income countries, Grinin & Korotayev note that the process of “Great Divergence” (when the abovementioned gap had been increasing since the early nineteenth century) in the recent decades was replaced by the “Great Convergence,” when this difference in development is reduced by increasing the level of development in less prosperous states. This convergence is characterized by heterogeneity—different rates of development of certain states, on the basis of which fast-growing states and less high-income states (mainly the countries of Tropical Africa) are distinguished. This feature requires different approaches in solving global problems common to all countries of the world. In view of this, Grinin et al. draw attention to the need to form global strategies for moving toward sustainable development, taking into account differences in development and available opportunities. In some countries, the level of development of capitalism has reached a level at which it is already exhausting itself and transformations are required, while there are countries in which full-fledged market relations have not yet been formed. Grinin et al. maintain that in the coming decades, the world will experience a complex continuum of types, transitions, combinations, and forms of economic structures. The authors analyze two main types. The high-income countries will experience a shift toward the strengthening of distributive institutions. The low-income countries that continue the processes of economic and socio-political modernization, in their turn, will proceed toward the strengthening of capitalist market institutions though with some important restrictions preventing exploitation and environmental degradation. All this will take place during the final phase of the Cybernetic Revolution, with the development of the process of internationalization of the labor force (through the development of remote employment) along with the internationalization of capital. Thus, the most important task in the coming decades is to increase the flexibility of the socioeconomic development of all countries of the world. Grinin & Korotayev believe that it is necessary to find ways to combine all the best features of capitalism in order to provide the necessary dynamism and innovativeness of development, at the same time softening all the distortions that have formed as a result of the development of capitalism over the past twenty years, bearing in mind that not so much industrial capitalism as financial and global financial capitalism is responsible for it.
Article
Full-text available
O artigo investiga a distribuição do bem-estar subjetivo (BES) nas favelas brasileiras, destacada como uma entre tantas dimensões das desigualdades de condições sociais e modalidades de estratificação persistentes no contexto brasileiro. Para tanto, foram utilizados dados de um survey domiciliar recente, aplicado a uma amostra representativa da população adulta residente no Conjunto de 16 favelas da Maré, região do subúrbio do município do Rio de Janeiro. O bem-estar subjetivo foi captado com perguntas sobre a satisfação das pessoas em relação a diferentes domínios da vida cotidiana, coletadas segundo um protocolo chamado Mansa (Manchester short assessment of quality of life). Foram descritos padrões de desigualdade e diferenças nos níveis de bem-estar subjetivo segundo características da população da Maré. Gênero e renda, condições de saúde, relações afetivas, exposição à violência armada e medo da violência foram alguns dos fatores relevantes associados a tais padrões.
Article
WHAT IS THE PROBLEM? It is well understood that ensuring the health and wellbeing of the population and the planet requires action on a wide range of social, economic, cultural and environmental determinants. Current economic policies typically pay insufficient heed to these determinants compromising the future health of the planet and inadequately considering the impact of intergenerational transfer of wealth and resources. We now have a critical opportunity to pivot economic policy towards a wellbeing economy. WHAT IS THE SOLUTION? As far back as Confucius, philosophers and leaders across political spectra have identified the benefits of societal wellbeing, though often using different terminology. Over the 20th century, however, economic policy is typically focussed on income, outputs, spending and economic prosperity as key measures of progress with less attention being paid to wellbeing measures such as equity, health, environment and culture. The notion of the ‘wellbeing economy’ is gaining traction as an approach to building sustainable and resilient ecosystems and wellbeing in the community. A wellbeing economy is one that is both prosperous and delivers equitable distribution of wealth, health and wellbeing, while protecting the planet’s resources for future generations and other species. It positions the economy as an enabler of societal outcomes, shifting the drivers of government decision-making away from economic growth for its own sake to an economy that is equitable, restorative and regenerative by design (Hough-Stewart et al., 2019).
Article
Full-text available
In the article, the authors pose and consider in detail the extremely topical question of whether capitalism has a future or will it be replaced by some new system. And if there is a future, then what kind of future is it? These are not new questions, but in the last few years they have acquired exceptional importance, since not only the left, but also representatives of the largest financial capital have started talking about the end of capitalism. The article deals with the following questions: what is capitalism as a way of life and as a system; what was the evolution of capitalism; what are his potentialities. In addition, various scenarios are considered and forecasts are given for the next 50–100 years. It is assumed that in the next few decades the development of capitalism may proceed differently in developed and developing countries, resulting in a complex continuum of types, transitions, combinations and forms of capitalism. The authors believe that capitalism will be inevitably transformed to one degree or another, but the degree of such transformation can vary greatly. Various scenarios for the future of capitalism are considered: from maintaining its leading role to reducing capitalism to one of a few socio-economic subsystems.
Chapter
We extend the Easterlin Paradox (EP) literature in two key respects. First, we test whether income comparisons matter for subjective wellbeing both when own incomes are compared with others within the country (intra-national) and with incomes across countries (inter-national). Second, we test whether these effects differ by settlement-type (rural through to large cities) and by country-type (developed and transitional). We confirm the intra-national EP prediction that subjective wellbeing is unchanged by an equi-proportionate rise in intra-country incomes across all developed country settlement-types. This is also the case for rural areas in transitional countries but not for larger settlements in those countries. Inter-national income comparisons are important for people’s subjective wellbeing across all country-settlement-types. Policy-makers must therefore consider their citizens’ incomes in an international context and cannot restrict attention solely to the intra-national income distribution.
Book
The second in a series of books published with the IZA, this volume presents Richard Easterlin's outstanding research on the analysis of subjective well-being, and on the relationship between demographic developments and economic outcomes. In both fields, his work has laid the foundations for enlarging the scope of traditional economic analysis and has increased our understanding of behaviour in several important domains, such as fertility choices, labour market behaviour, and the determinants of individual well-being. In various seminal contributions, Easterlin has demonstrated the importance of material aspirations and relative economic status for human behaviour. This book is a collection of 11 of his key papers, revised and edited to make a cohesive book. New material includes an Introduction from the editors, two section Introductions from Easterlin, and an Epilogue from Easterlin.
Article
Existing research applying the Personal Wellbeing Index (PWI) in China is restricted to urban and rural samples. There are no studies for Chinese off-farm migrants. The specific aims of this study are (a) ascertain whether Chinese off-farm are satisfied with their lives; (b) investigate the equivalence of the PWI in terms of its psychometric properties; and (c) examine whether the responses to the PWI from participants falls within the narrow range predicted by the 'Theory of Subjective Wellbeing Homeostasis???. The PWI demonstrated good psychometric performance in terms of its reliability, validity and sensibility and was consistent with previous studies for Western and non-Western samples. The data revealed a moderate level of subjective well-being (PWI score = 62.6). While Chinese off-farm migrants lead hard lives, the PWI was within the normative range predicted for Chinese societies by the 'Theory of Subjective Wellbeing Homeostasis'. A likely explanation for this finding rests with the circular nature of migration in China. When China's offfarm migrants find it too difficult to cope in the cities, most have the fallback position that they can return to their homes in the countryside. This option provides an external buffer to minimize the inherent challenges of life which would otherwise impinge on the life satisfaction of China's off-farm migrants.
Article
A classic in its field, this pathbreaking book humanized the scientific rhetoric of economics to reveal its literary soul. In this completely revised second edition, Deirdre N. McCloskey demonstrates how economic discourse employs metaphor, authority, symmetry, and other rhetorical means of persuasion. The Rhetoric of Economics shows economists to be human persuaders, poets of the marketplace, even in their most technical and mathematical moods.
Article
The World Bank Annual Report 2009, Year in Review, explores the impact of the global financial and economic crisis in developing countries, and fast-track funding and programs that can help member countries withstand the debacle. In addition, new and ongoing programs and projects in health, climate change, infrastructure, and several other areas are highlighted. A new feature this year is personal-impact stories for each region, relaying the positive effects of World Bank assistance on individuals.
Article
Direct reports of subjective well-being may have a useful role in the measurement of consumer preferences and social welfare, if they can be done in a credible way. Can well-being be measured by a subjective survey, even approximately? In this paper, we discuss research on how individuals' responses to subjective well-being questions vary with their circumstances and other factors. We will argue that it is fruitful to distinguish among different conceptions of utility rather than presume to measure a single, unifying concept that motivates all human choices and registers all relevant feelings and experiences. While various measures of well being are useful for some purposes, it is important to recognize that subjective well-being measures features of individuals' perceptions of their experiences, not their utility as economists typically conceive of it. Those perceptions are a more accurate gauge of actual feelings if they are reported closer to the time of, and in direct reference to, the actual experience. We conclude by proposing the U- index, a misery index of sorts, which measures the proportion of time that people spend in an unpleasant state, and has the virtue of not requiring a cardinal conception of individuals' feelings.
Article
Deirdre N. McCloskey (1942–) was educated at Harvard University, taught for many years at the University of Chicago and the University of Iowa, and is currently a UIC Distinguished Professor of Economics, History, English, and Communication at the University of Illinois at Chicago. McCloskey was Donald until 1995. She describes her transition in Crossing: A Memoir. In addition to her long-standing research interests in economic history, in the 1980s McCloskey became interested in the ways in which economists persuade one another, and her work on the rhetoric of economics poses a serious challenge to traditional views of economic methodology. The author of twenty books and three hundred articles, McCloskey has been an extremely influential figure. In the opening scene of the movie The Graduate a Mr. McGuire puts an avuncular arm around the Dustin Hoffman character and says, “I just want to say one word to you. Just one word.” Yes, sir? “Are you listening?” Yes, I am. “Plastics.” [Pause] Exactly how do you mean it? “There's a great future in plastics. Think about it. Will you think about it?” Yes, I will. “Enough said: that's a deal.” So nowadays the avuncular word to the wise is “rhetoric.” There's a great future in rhetoric. Furthermore, unlike plastics, rhetoric has also had a great past, the twenty centuries during which it was the educator of the young and the theory of speech in the West – as the classicist Werner Jaeger called it, “the first humanism,” the “rhetorical paideia.”