ArticlePDF Available

Who you gonna call? oligarchic clans as a bottom-up force of neighborhood europeanization in Ukraine

Authors:
Inna Melnykovska, Rainer Schweickert
Who you gonna call?
Oligarchic Clans as a Bottom-up
Force of Neighborhood
Europeanization in Ukraine
67
/2008
A
RBEITSPAPIERE
DES
O
STEUROPA
-I
NSTITUTS DER
F
REIEN
U
NIVERSITÄT
B
ERLIN
ARBEITSSCHWERPUNKT POLITIK
Das Osteuropa-Institut der Freien Universität beschäftigt sich als multidisziplinäres regional-
wissenschaftliches Zentralinstitut in Forschung und Lehre mit den Räumen Ost-, Ostmittel-
und Südosteuropas.
Mit der Reihe „Arbeitspapiere des Osteuropa-Instituts stellt der Arbeitsschwerpunkt
Politik aktuelle Ergebnisse aus seiner Arbeit der Öffentlichkeit zur Verfügung.
Die Arbeitspapiere erscheinen in unregelmäßiger Folge. Einzelne Papiere können gegen
eine Schutzgebühr bezogen werden bei:
Osteuropa-Institut der Freien Universität Berlin
Garystr. 55
14195 Berlin
http://www.oei.fu-berlin.de/
Tel.: ++49 30 838 54058
52075
Fax: ++49 30 838 53616
Titelgrafik:
ImStall
2
http://www.imstall.com
Druck:
Copy-Repro-Center Berlin
Arbeitspapiere des Osteuropa-Instituts
der Freien Universität Berlin
Arbeitsschwerpunkt Politik
Inna Melnykovska,
Rainer Schweickert
Who you gonna call? –
Oligarchic Clans as a Bottom-up
Force of Neighborhood Europe-
anization in Ukraine
Heft 67/2008
©
2008 by Inna Melnykovska / Rainer Schweickert
Osteuropa-Institut der Freien Universität Berlin
Arbeitsbereich Politik und Gesellschaft
Herausgeber: Klaus Segbers
Redaktion: Julia Gerlach
ISSN 1434 – 419X
Table of content
1. Introduction ............................................................................................................................ 5
2. Oligarchic Structures as Domestic Forces behind Institution Building in Ukraine ........ 8
3. Transforming Oligarchic Clans into Global Players ........................................................ 13
4. Ukrainian Business Interests and EU Leverage for Better Institutions.......................... 17
5. Conclusions ........................................................................................................................... 24
References ................................................................................................................................. 25
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
5
Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a Bottom-up Force of
Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
Inna Melnykovska
1
and Rainer Schweickert
2
Abstract
3
This paper argues that, in the absence of a strong membership incentive within the European
Neighborhood Policy (ENP), a top-down institutional convergence of CIS countries towards
European standards i.e. democracy and market economy is unlikely to be successful.
However, due to enlargement fatigue within the EU, the membership incentive is off the
agenda for the CIS. Hence, the ENP has to initiate or to speed up a bottom-up institutional
convergence by identifying bottom-up domestic forces that are willing and able to drive the
convergence in a particular country. Ukraine, whose oligarchic clans are the main bottom-up
forces behind institution building, is a case in point. After having supported the first wave of
institutional reforms during the Orange Revolution, these bottom-up forces are facing great
difficulties in forming sustainable coalitions for further institutional reforms. The paper shows
that the EU could, by providing economic incentives rather than the membership incentive,
exploit the strong business interests of the oligarchic clans in the EU markets and EU
investment to motivate them to jointly drive institutional convergence from the bottom-up.
Key words: Europeanization, institutional convergence, institution building, Orange revolution,
oligarchic clans
JEL-Classification: B15, D02, D72, F15, F20, P33, P36
1
Inna Melnykovska, Otto-Suhr-Institut für Politikwissenschaft, FU Berlin/Kiel Institute for the World Economy;
melinna@gmx.de.
2
Rainer Schweickert, Kiel Institute for the World Economy; rainer.schweickert@ifw-kiel.de.
3
This paper is an output of the ENEPO project (EU Eastern Neighbourhood: Economic Potential and Future Development)
financed by the EU in the Sixth Framework Program. The authors thank the participants of the workshop entitled “Europe’s
Unfinished Political and Economic Transitions? The Convergence-Divergence Debate Revisited”, which was organised by the
European Studies Centre (ESC) at the University of Oxford and the South East European Studies at Oxford (SEESOX), and
supported by the Economic and Social Research Council in Oxford on January, 24 – 25, 2008, for helpful comments on an
earlier draft. We would like to thank Klaus Segbers, George Georgiadis, and Paul Kramer for comments and excellent editorial
support.
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
6
1. Introduction
Institutional convergence towards European standards/values, i.e. building EU-style
institutions, in any particular post-communist country can theoretically run two ways: bottom-
up and top-down. Democratic governments may implement institutional reforms in a top-down
way without wide domestic support in the population or the elite. A top-down convergence
would be less complex, as governments would not have to spend time and effort finding
domestic support. However, such convergence would be highly risky, especially if institution
building causes high social costs. Hence, top-down institution building might be easier if the
strong external incentive of EU membership were provided, which would make the bitter pill
of convergence easier to swallow for those who stand to loose by balancing social pressure
with other, e.g. geo-political, benefits. Alternatively, the wide support of some institutional
change by the population or by the elite can induce governments to achieve institutional
convergence in a bottom-up way. Such convergence would be more sustainable, as the
resulting European-style institutions would be home grown. Convergence in a bottom-up way
would proceed slowly, but could be speeded up by providing some external incentives for the
population or for the elite.
Indeed, the success of the Central and Eastern European countries (CEECs) in the top-
down building of European-style institutions is often attributed to EU membership incentive
these countries enjoyed. The concept of convergence
not only, but also of institutions
is
tightly integrated in the process of EU enlargement (Schweickert 2004). The institutional
convergence of the CEECs, often labeled “Enlargement Europeanization”, has resulted in the
most massive transfer of European institutions in recent history (Schimmelfennig and
Sedelmaier 2005; Pop-Eleches 2007).
1
When accepting ten CEECs as new members, the EU
established the Copenhagen Criteria for membership, including standards of criteria on
institutional quality, and provided financial and technical assistance to bring down the social
costs of institutional convergence towards these common standards (Gawrich and Schweickert
2004; Raik 2005; Roland 2005). To fulfill EU institutional standards, the candidate countries
must demonstrate political stability, including maintaining of human rights and protection of
minorities (political criteria); implement the aquis communautaire into national legislation and
adopt the goals of the political, economic and monetary union (legal criteria); and have a fully
functioning market economy (economic criteria). Truly, the EU has been successful until now
in its enlargement strategy, as there is a large consensus on the favorable role of the EU in
promoting democracy and economic development by fostering a top-down institution building
in most CEECs (Gawrich and Schweickert 2004; Raik 2005; Roland 2006).
In the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS), the top-down institutional
convergence towards European standards and values has lagged behind. Unlike in the CEECs,
comparable Europeanization mechanisms incentives, compensations, linkages, direct
financial support, etc. – to implement European institutions have not been available in the CIS..
The EU did not give these countries a membership incentive and concentrated more on
economic cooperation than on institutional convergence. Furthermore, the other international
organizations acting in the CIS targeted macroeconomic stability and expected institutions to
be built as by-product of the macroeconomic reforms. Only in the second half of the 1990s did
the disappointing outcomes of political reforms, as well as the economic stagnation and crises
in the CIS and in developing countries, give rise to a great number of studies on the reasons for
the mistakes made in the design of the reforms (Hellmann 1998; Unmüsig and Walther 1999;
Rodrik 2000, 2003, 2006; Schweickert und Thiele 2004).
2
These studies conclude that building
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
7
European-style institutions is crucial to successful political reforms and sustainable economic
growth in the CIS and lead international lending organizations, governments and investors to
rethink the importance of institutions.
It is obvious that the EU as one of the influential international actors in institution
building in the region would speed up top-down institutional convergence towards European
values and standards in the CIS by offering a membership perspective for the neighboring CIS
countries. However, after Eastern enlargement has been completed with the recent accession of
Bulgaria and Romania in 2007, the “carrot” of membership to push for institutional
development in transition countries is currently reserved for the Western Balkan states
exclusively. For the post-Soviet space as well as for Mediterranean countries, the EU has
created a new instrument, the European Neighborhood Policy (ENP).
The ENP clearly demonstrates the EU’s interest in “the ring of well-governed states”
3
that
would respect European democratic, market and legal institutions, but has limited potential to
push for institutional convergence towards European standards in a top-down way. In the
absence of a strong membership incentive, a top-down institutional convergence is unlikely to
be successful. “Neighborhood Europeanization” has to rely on the European Neighborhood
Policy Action Plans (ENP APs) together with financial assistance to cut the social costs of
institution building under the new European Neighborhood Policy Instrument (ENPI). As
argued in Gawrich et al. (2008), the incentives and compensations provided by the ENP are
well-suited to a top-down approach, but a top-down approach could only work in the CIS if the
membership incentive were provided, as it was to the CEECs, which have successfully
converged as a result.
In the absence a strong membership incentive, democratic institutions and a stable market
economy have to be bottom-up to survive changes in the political and economic sphere (Rumer
2005). The so-called color revolutions in Ukraine, Georgia and the Kyrgyz Republic
exemplified the potential of these countries to converge towards European standards in a
bottom-up way. The wide support for institutional convergence by the population and by the
elite has induced the government to introduce formal legislative standards and to narrow the
institutional gap between the EU and these countries. Such a bottom-up convergence proceeds
slowly, but could be speeded up by the EU.
This paper argues that, the EU’s external incentives for institutional development in the
CIS can only work if there is a net benefit for domestic forces to converge in a bottom-up way
towards EU standards. Hence, the ENP has to rely more on appropriate incentives and
mechanisms to push for a bottom-up convergence by identifying the domestic bottom-up forces
that are willing and able to drive institution building in a particular country. The EU should
design ENP incentives and mechanisms such that they exploit the political and economic
preferences of these domestic forces to bring about institutional convergence. Because the
strength of the EU is its position as a global economic player, economic incentives have to play
the most important role in this regard.
4
Ukraine, which has expressed a keen interest in becoming member of the EU, but which
is not being considered for membership by the EU, is a case in point. The Orange Revolution
clearly revealed Ukraine’s potential to adopt the fundamental European values of democracy,
market economy, human rights and the Acquis communautaire, a potential that can be
exploited by the ENP (Vinhas de Souza et al. 2006). However, the unified domestic forces that
ended Kuchma’s repressive regime failed to build any consistent coalition after the common
goal of overcoming reform gridlock and building minimal institutional standards was achieved
and the EU did not offer Ukraine the strong incentive of membership. As a consequence,
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
8
Ukraine’s reform capacity to converge in a top-down way that would go hand in hand with
enthusiastic expectations that EU membership would be granted in the aftermath of the Orange
Revolutions has decreased considerably (Fischer et al. 2008, White et al. 2008). However, the
EU still has the possibilities to push for a bottom-up institutional convergence in Ukraine. It
can use economic incentives to motivate the oligarchic clans that are the main bottom-up forces
behind institution building in Ukraine to jointly drive institutional convergence, since these
clans are strongly interested in EU markets and its investment.
We proceed by showing that the oligarchic clans have been and are still the main
(potential) internal drivers of a bottom-up institutional convergence in Ukraine (Section 2).
Combining the theories of Oleh Havrylyshyn (2006a) and Mancur Olson (2000), Section 3
takes a closer look at the political and economic preferences of the oligarchic clans and the way
they are changing under the influence of globalization. Section 4 concentrates on Ukraine’s
trade with and investment from the EU, thereby identifying the EU’s potential leverage to
exploit the changing preferences of the rent-seeking oligarchic clans in Ukraine and to
engender the bottom-up convergence of Ukraine’s institutions towards EU standards. Finally,
Section 5 summarizes and draws conclusions for “Neighborhood Europeanization” under ENP.
2. Oligarchic Structures as Domestic Forces behind Institution
Building in Ukraine
The population or the elite are the domestic forces that drive a bottom-up institutional
convergence. The population may participate in “intermediary” non-state organizations, such as
professional associations, religious groups, labor unions and citizen advocacy organizations to
articulate their preferences for better institutions and push democratic governments for
institutional convergence. A population organized in such a way is often referred to as a civil
society. In their turn, the elite in such a society may found lobby organizations or create
networks with politicians (often part of elite) to push for institution building. Theoretically,
civil society is assumed to be even more important for a bottom-up convergence than the elite.
Civil society, however, has not been the main bottom-up force in Ukraine.
Public choice
was neither a driving nor constraining force of institution building during the early transition
years (Howard 2002; McFaul 2002). CIS countries had the least participatory civil societies in
the world (Howard 2002; World Values Survey 2004) and their civil societies were regarded as
weak and passive (this was also true for Ukraine).
5
The studies on the civil society in Ukraine
define the mass demonstrations during the Orange Revolution in 2004-2005 as spontaneous
popular protests based upon social dissatisfaction with the incumbent political regime, but not
the activities of a developed and established civil society (Stepanenko 2006). While these
studies differ on the importance of the mass demonstrations for the outcome of the Orange
Revolution, they agree that the popular protests were “the birth” of a civil society that has now
undergone an elementary stage in its development, but is still nascent in nature (McFaul 2005;
Kudelia 2007; Gelman 2008). Ukraine’s civil society is, therefore, a weak bottom-up force.
Hence, the elite are the only domestic forces capable of building institutions in Ukraine.
Among the various elite groups, the oligarchic clans are the most powerful bottom-up forces,
“capturing” the state authorities and controlling the enforcement and implementation of
institutional reforms (Hellman 1998; Zimmer 2006; Pleines 2005, 2008). During the early
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
9
stages of transition, the oligarchic clans were responsible for the gridlock in institutional
convergence with the EU. By 2004, they had changed their political and economic preferences,
supported the Orange Revolution and the following bottom-up institutional convergence and
managed to maintain their immense influence in Ukraine’s politics and in its economy.
6
Thus,
we concentrate exclusively on oligarchic clans as the most powerful bottom-up force of
institutional change in Ukraine.
The oligarchic clans are a special hybrid of the political and business elite, which is a
major actor in both Ukraine’s politics and its economy. They are not groups of relatives or
systems of kinship, as are the classic European and Asian clans, but rather business entities.
7
Thus, they are mainly interested in accumulating wealth and capturing new markets. However,
the oligarchic clans also are different from a classic business entity in the way they use the
strategy “power-money-power” for wealth accumulation. Namely, access to state power
enables the oligarchic clans to secure their economic interests and make profits, which they use
to broaden their political power. A symbiosis of politics and business does not involve just a
simple patronage connection. Besides lobbying, networking and bribing to influence politics,
the oligarchic clans aim at assimilating the political elite. The assimilation of clan’s members
in politics and vice versa is a common phenomenon in Ukraine.
The Ukrainian clans exhibit hierarchical levels. The top position is held by a chieftain
who is surrounded by a core, i.e. the most trustworthy group of business partners, relatives and
friends. The chieftain and members of a core are often called oligarchs. Lower positions in a
clan’s hierarchy are held by professionals and ordinary employees who work in the enterprises
under the clan’s control. Agents of influence or patrons in politics hold a special position.
Officially, they are not members of a particular clan, but their mutual support and cooperation
are vital for the clan’s fortune.
8
State officials supply the clans with valuable information about
state policy plans and ensure them a privileged economic position and profits by providing
licenses, tax exemptions and subsidies.
In the political framework of Ukraine’s “defective democracy”
9
(Merkel et al. 2003),
oligarchic clans capture the state and directly access political power through the executive, the
legislative or judicial branches.
10
Yet, the value of having access to a particular state branch
varies over time. In the early 1990s, a direct connection to the president was of the highest
value.
11
Thus, the Ukrainian clans concentrated their attention on building up their connections
in the executive. They secured their enterprises through contacts to the president, the
presidential administration and the government in general. In the late 1990s, connections to
parliamentary representatives or - even better obtaining a personal mandate increasingly
gained more importance. Some oligarchs founded or captured political parties, or simply
bought slots on party lists. Others used one-man constituencies in Ukraine’s mixed majoritarian
and proportional representation system to become members of the Verkhovna Rada (the
Ukrainian parliament). The oligarchs became independent from national politics and
transformed themselves into state actors that translated their interests into public policy,
passing “made-for-oligarch” laws.
12
Such laws ensured, for instance, preferable trade
conditions or tax relief for specific economic sectors, regions or enterprises. In addition, the
oligarchs received full personal immunity for their term of office, which helped them to avoid
criminal responsibility. They could thus use their privileges secure their illegal wealth and
avoid persecution or punishment by the tax administration. As a result, oligarchic clans have
been able to expand their influence disproportionally and accumulate a great amount of wealth.
During the privatization of state enterprises, the oligarchic clans exploited their
connections in politics to acquire those state enterprises that promised the large profits.
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
10
Representatives of a particular oligarchic clan in politics provided reliable information on the
financial situation and production capacities of the state enterprises to be privatized, ensured
their clan a privileged position, and the possibility to buy the state enterprises at low prices
during the privatization auctions. As a result, oligarchic wealth became concentrated in the
most profitable sectors of Ukraine’s economy, such as gas and oil, metal, food-proceeding, and
machinery sectors.
Because oligarchic capital is spread across various sectors, it was difficult to say which
clan dominated which sector. The only exceptions were with the agrarian and coal mining
clans, who were interested in sectoral benefits (Kubicek 2000; Pleines 2005, 2008).
13
In the
early years of transition, clans mostly covered a region, but, with greater diversification and an
increasing number of clans, their regional dominance also became less clear-cut (Wittkowsky
2001; Kowall and Zimmer 2002; Zimmer 2006). Often, clans coming from the same region
rivaled each other in doing business or influencing politics.
14
Hence, a particular oligarchic
clan did not push for sectoral or regional preferences, but rather for preferences for particular
enterprises in which the clan was involved. The particularly low level of trust between the
oligarchic clans in Ukraine accelerated rivalry and made their collective actions difficult
(Aslund 2005). As they often conducted their day-to-day business in the same economic sectors
and in the same regions, the Ukrainian oligarchic clans were often rivals.
The rivalry between the oligarchic clans was reflected in the political regime of Ukraine,
which suffered from the syndrome of “feckless pluralism” (Carothers 2002). The clans used
their political connections to the state branches instrumentally and transmitted their conflicts
into politics, thereby making the political system highly competitive, its institutions inefficient,
and the political regime largely unstable. Ukraine’s state authorities represented the preferences
of the rival oligarchic clans and conflicted with each other, passing contradictory and opaque
laws. Moreover, president Leonid Kuchma’s “divide and rule” strategy even strengthened the
syndrome of “feckless pluralism”. He appointed representatives of rival oligarchic clans to
offices with similar levels of power,
15
in order to prevent the rise of possible internal rivals and
even reinforced the rivalry among the clans.
By the end of Kuchma’s second and last constitutionally possible term in office, it looked
like the Ukrainian clans had reached the equilibrium of institutional development and power
distribution. A particular clan was either satisfied with or did not have sufficient power to
change the status quo of Ukraine’s “defective democracy” with its partial reforms, in which
some democratic and market economy principles, e.g. elections and private property, were
implemented, but the rule of law and large-scale macroeconomic reforms failed (Hellmann
1998). This status quo was advantageous to accumulate wealth. However, it was
disadvantageous to ensure property rights and the security of the accumulated wealth. Due to
the large number of oligarchic clans, Kuchma’s “divide and rule” strategy also led to the
regular rotation of persons and also meant high instability and insecurity for those who had
already accumulated a great amount of wealth. Such a strategy also gave fewer incentives for
the oligarchic clans to invest in and to modernize their enterprises. New persons in office could
withdraw their beneficial budget compensations and privileges in Ukraine’s markets.
Furthermore, with a new person in office, previous office holders and their oligarchic clan with
illegally accumulated wealth ran the danger of being prosecuted by the state.
The president was the most powerful force in Ukraine’s political system. Thus, the
presidential election of 2004 was especially important for the security of illegally accumulated
wealth. By becoming the president, a representative of a particular clan could destroy the
financial imperia of the other clans. As a result, in the “defective democracy”, the presidential
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
11
election became an Achilles’ heel for the oligarchic clans (Hale 2005). Due to the lack of
transparency in and the frequent abuse of institutional mechanisms of election and consequent
power transfer, any clan powerful enough to manipulate election outcomes was able to push its
representative for the presidency. The uncertainty among the oligarchic clans about the fate of
their wealth, if a representative of a rival clan were to win the presidential elections, was high.
The designated successor of Kuchma, Viktor Yanukovych, had to admit his inability to unite
all the clans behind his candidature. Part of the reason for this was his support for one
particular clan (of the Doneck region) during his years as the prime minister before the election
in 2004. It was not credible that he could become a dominating arbiter, who could act in the
interest of all the clans. Despite the rivalry in their day-to-day business, the oligarchic clans
joined forces to secure their wealth in the run-up to the presidential elections in 2004. Because
Ukraine’s “defective” democracy did not provide an institutional framework for actors to settle
disputes and realize the potential gains, the various oligarchic clans built a coalition to confront
with the incumbent president and his designated successor (North 1990).
Hence, most oligarchs directly or indirectly supported the Orange Revolution of 2004 and
the subsequent institution building in the political and economic system of Ukraine
(Malynkovych 2006, Melnykovska 2008). They participated in the Orange Revolution
personally or provided media space for the “orange” candidate for the presidency, Viktor
Yushchenko, and for his proponents, to report about election fraud and to organize the mass
demonstrations (Mr. Yushchenko’s opponent was Yanukovych, the “white-and-blue”
candidate).
16
The uncertainty about their wealth security united all the clans under the common
goal of overthrowing the presidential regime and pushing for some minimal convergence
towards European standards. They eliminated the possibility that anyone oligarchic clan could
monopolize state authorities and they supported the new institutional framework of the political
system to ensure that a “pluralism” of the clans’ influence in the politics was established.
Given the very low trust between the Ukrainian clans, transforming Ukraine from a
presidential into a parliamentary republic, where no force was able to monopolize state power,
was the second best choice for all oligarchic clans. During round table negotiations in
November-December 2004, “orange” and “white-and-blue” leaders agreed on a package of
laws, known as the “package deal”. With the support of the Ukrainian oligarchic clans, this
package was approved by the Verkhovna Rada by an overwhelming vote of 402 to 21. It
changed the division of powers between the president and the parliament that was specified in
the constitution of 1996 and amended electoral law. The constitutional change transformed the
Ukrainian political system of a presidential republic by adopting a number of features
necessary to establish parliamentarianism. It reduced the presidential powers and strengthened
the powers of the parliament. The amendment of the electoral law guaranteed fair competition
in the run-off of the presidential election that had to be repeated in December 2004. To calm
mass demonstrations against election fraud, and taking reference to the newly amended
electoral law, the central electoral commission was reshuffled and the possibilities for fraud
stemming from home voting and absentee ballots were substantially reduced. The candidate of
the “orange” forces, Yushchenko, obtained the chance to win the repeated run-off of the
presidential election, but this time under fair competition. In return, the “orange” forces agreed
that the newly elected president would lose some of his powers in favor of the parliament. As a
result, Yushchenko won the election and became the president. Because the constitutional
change was not to enter into force until after the parliamentary election in 2006, he still enjoyed
the framework of the presidential republic and appointed the first “orange” government
(January-September 2005), headed by his ally Yulia Tymoshenko. However, a new equilibrium
of power distribution among the elite was not established.
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
12
In the following months after the Orange Revolution, the parliamentary elections
intensified the rivalry either between the politicians or between the clans and made establishing
a new equilibrium difficult. In the struggle for votes and seats in the future parliament, the
members of the “orange” coalition started to blame each other for the failures of the first
“orange” government.
17
The coalition fell apart, soon opening the door for a comeback of the
“white-and-blue” forces. As a result of the parliamentary election in 2006, the “white-and-
blue” coalition led by the Party of Regions came back to political power. Supported by the
Communist and the Socialist Parties, Viktor Yanukovych became prime minister again. The
struggle for political dominance and control over state authorities between the “orange”
presidency and the “white-and-blue” government and the legislative led to a deadlock in state
governance. As a consequence, the Ukrainian parliament was dissolved in September 2007 and
Ukraine held pre-term parliamentary elections. This time, the parliamentary elections resulted
in the resurrection of the “orange” coalition, headed again by Tymoshenko as prime minister.
However, recent political disputes about privatization, dismissal and appointment of heads of
regional, district, and local administrations, as well as control over the State Property Fund and
authorities of the National Security and Defense Council (Boltushkina et al. 2008) have raised
doubts about the sustainability of this second “orange” coalition.
Since 2006, the position of the parliament has strengthened and the number of powerful
veto-players in Ukraine’s politics has consequently increased. The president can no longer
dominate politics. In contrast, the elite (also the oligarchic clans), which are present in the
parliament, have gained more influence, but need to negotiate any political decision with each
other or with the president. The oligarchic clans, whose prosperity depends on having a stake
of their parties in the government, have become involved in the political struggles. The
oligarchic clans have got their representatives into the new parliament (which is more
influential than the old parliament) using the party lists. The day-to-day preferences of rival
business clans have prevailed over striving for political stability. After the Orange Revolution,
the “feckless pluralismof the political system has become even more pronounced and, until
now, prevented the establishment of a new equilibrium of power distribution.
However, the oligarchic clans may become the bottom-up force to consolidate the state
power. Basically, the political elite could not replace the oligarchic clans as a driver of
institutional reforms. The clans are present in all the major political parties and control the
executive and judicial branches. Moreover, they depend less on short-term electoral periods
and public opinion than the political elite. Thus, the oligarchic clans can pursue a goal of
institutional convergence with the EU which promises them long-term benefits of sustainable
growth, even if the achievement of this goal causes social costs in a short-term perspective.
However, unlike in Russia, the oligarchic clans find it difficult to conduct the “collective
actions”. “Collective actions” are difficult, because of their great number, sectoral and regional
diversification and the low level of trust between clans, but they are not impossible
(Melnykovska 2008). Attaining minimum institutional standards for their business has been an
incentive strong enough to make them join forces to push for institutional convergence, as was
exemplified by their successful negotiations with the WTO completed in 2008. Despite the
political crises, the “while-and-blue” and “orange” forces in the parliament passed the laws
necessary to complete the negotiations on WTO accession and the “orange” president did not
use his veto. Depending on the preferences of the Ukrainian oligarchic clans, the EU may
provide them well-targeted incentives other than a membership perspective to accelerate a
bottom-up institutional building. Therefore, the political and economic preferences of
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
13
Ukraine’s oligarchic clans, as well as the determinants that create and change these
preferences, are need to be identified.
3. Transforming Oligarchic Clans into Global Players
Two theoretical approaches to institutional change explain why oligarchic clans
supported by external incentives could change their political and economic preferences and
become the driving forces of a bottom-up institutional convergence in CIS countries. A
prominent theory on internal drivers of institutional change and the evolution of rent-seeking
societies is Olson’s theory (2000) of the evolution of state rulers and the exploitation of rents,
which either hinders or supports institution building.
18
Olson distinguishes between “roving”
and “stationary bandits”. Translated into a CIS framework, “roving” oligarchic clans
concentrate on exploiting short-term rents like those stemming from non-renewable resources.
After getting sufficiently rich and reaching the limits of wealth accumulation and control,
“roving” clans transform into “stationary” clans and begin to care about securing their wealth.
While “roving” clans can rely on informal institutions, “stationary” clans need and demand
formal institutions, which implies that they begin to support institutional development. In terms
of Olson’s theory it is important that clans become stationary in order to change their
preferences and demand better (formal) institutions.
While this process may be rather slow, or even painfully slow in resource dependent
economies, according to the other theory of institutional change in rent-seeking societies,
opening up a country to globalization,
19
i.e. to trade and investment flows, may work as a
catalyst for transforming the preferences of oligarchic clans (Havrylyshyn 2006a). With
hindsight, the popular debate about an appropriate sequencing of opening up and institution
building seems to be misleading. In the early 1990s, institutional reforms were a by-product of
other high priority policies on macroeconomic stabilization, trade liberalization and enterprise
restructuring (Hare 2001). Follow-up institutional reforms either did not take place or lacked
implementation effort. Arguably, structural policies like opening up a country to the world
market and institution building at home have to reinforce each other in order to be successful.
As argued by Havrylyshyn (2006a), the majority of CIS countries, which have been
closed economies, reformed and changed their institutions moderately. They have also
experienced the greatest social pain. Vested interests in these countries have been working
towards the creation of “capitalism for the few” and concentrating ownership in the hands of
the selected elite. He calls such states the “oligarchic societies”. By comparison, the CEECs
countries have been more successful at reforming their institutions because they have been
more open. The results of Havrylyshyn’s research suggest that openness ensures economic
recovery and democratic institutions. Thus, the establishment of an open market economy and
institution building complement rather than exclude each other. Replying to debates between
“shock therapy” supporters and gradualists, Havrylyshyn comes to the conclusion that a more
useful view of sequencing should begin with a basic and simplified legal-regulatory
institutional framework that is comprehensive but not deep, thereby opening up a country, and
should then follow-up with refinements of these institutions over time (Havrylyshyn 2006b).
This is exactly why oligarchic interests matter in the context of institution building in
transition countries like Ukraine. Opening up a country can work as a catalyst for otherwise
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
14
rather slow processes of changing the political and economic preferences of the oligarchic
clans, assuming that they have an interest in reaping the potential benefits from trade and
foreign investment. Clearly, the success of institution building depends on the interests of the
powerful elite in the first place (Keohane 1984). Therefore, the political and economic costs
and benefits to these elite are key to explaining the nature and scope of change (Feeny
1988:168). Opening up may well change the cost-benefit calculation of “roving” clans. While
the impact of legacies (resource endowment, access to power) is constant, openness is a
conditional variable which ensures that “changes in relative prices and therefore changes in
the cost-benefit calculations – are the most important source of institutional change” driven by
the bottom-up domestic elite (North 1990:84). It can be shown for the case of Ukraine that the
oligarchic clans actually have this kind of incentives to change their preferences and to demand
better institutions and institutional convergence towards European standards.
20
Combining the theories on rent-seeking limits and openness, rent-seekers should be
subject to limits when seeking to accumulate wealth with informal institutions in a closed
economy and should transform from domestic into global players that demand formal
institutions in order to reap the benefits of interacting with global markets. Changes in sources
of rents can result in such limits to rent-seeking. It is evident from Table 1 that the sources of
rents have changed over time and thereby increased competitive pressures for Ukraine’s
oligarchic clans. In the early 1990s, fuel and metal product exports were the most attractive
sources of rents. In addition, large-scale credits from government in combination with
hyperinflation resulted in huge subsidies for the clans (Prizel 2002). Finally, the oligarchic
clans benefited from exporting highly subsidized gas and oil imports from Russia. In the Soviet
era, Russia subsidized Ukraine by supplying around 50 million tons of oil and substantial
amounts of gas each year at prices at roughly 35-40% of world market prices. After the
collapse of the Soviet Union, Russia and other energy-rich CIS countries did not intend to
continue subsidization of the Ukrainian oligarchic clans. The prices for imported energy to
Ukraine increased continuously, but were still under world price level.
21
In the mid-1990s, rents stemming from hyperinflation disappeared, but the clans
continued to benefit from the political patronage that supplied them with indirect subsidies,
special treatment and tax incentives (Van Zon 2000). Until the financial crisis in 1998, the
international community was more concerned with the political stability of Ukraine, because it
possessed nuclear weapons, than with its progress on institutional reform. Hence, during the
initial transition years, the preferences of the oligarchic clans where dominated by domestic
developments.
Following the financial crisis, the most important source of economic rents in Ukraine
still stemmed from imports of gas and oil from Russia and other energy-rich CIS countries.
22
However, the limits of such economic rents became more and more evident. Finally, the
termination of possibilities to reap economic rents was marked by the latest developments in
the gas market. According to the agreements signed in the spring of 2004, Ukraine covered its
energy debts to Gazprom with Eurobonds and transit charges for Russian gas up to 2009. For
the Ukrainian oligarchic companies, it meant no gas for transit from 2005 on. At the same time,
Gazprom revealed its intent to raise the gas prices to the world levels (Stern 2006). After the
2006 crisis, Gazprom sold gas to Ukraine via the joint company RosUkrEnergo at a price of
$230/mcm (Gazprom Press Release 2006).
23
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
15
Table 1. The sources of oligarchic rents in Ukraine
D o m e s t i c
credits from state’s
bank with negative real
interest rates due to
inflation
arbitrage opportunities
market monopolies
indirect subsidies
tax incentives
separate treatments
shadow privatization
tax incentives
separate treatments
tax incentives
separate treatments
early 1990s middle 1990s late 1990s early 2000s
I n t e r n a t i o n a l
cheap fuel resources
from Russia
external demand for
Ukrainian metal and
chemical products
weak international
request for reforms
international focus on
political stability
soft financial aid
external demand for
Ukrainian metal and
chemical products
weak international
request for reforms
international focus on
political stability
soft financial aid
Russia’s toleration of
Ukrainian debts and
illegal siphoning of
gas
strong international
pressure for reforms
external demand for
Ukrainian metal and
chemical products
strong international
pressure for reforms
focus on corporate
governance
Source: Aslund (2005); Prizel (2002); Zimmer (2006); own illustration.
Generally, even before the Orange Revolution, the possibilities for oligarchic clans to
profit from cheap Russian energy imports had almost disappeared. In addition, the
requirements of good corporate governance and transparency became essential for Ukraine’s
oligarchic groups to do business in international markets. Indeed, Table 2 shows that oligarchic
clans in Ukraine have increased their wealth considerably and become more transparent during
recent years. Due to rapid economic growth since the end of 1990s, most oligarchs at least
doubled their wealth. The Wprost rating of the 100 richest Europeans for 2007 includes 24
Ukrainians, with fortunes as large as $18,700 million. For comparison, in 2002 only 3
Ukrainians were listed among the richest Europeans, with fortunes as large as $1,700 million.
These numbers show not only a rising accumulation of wealth due to increased business
activities, but also show that there were transfers of wealth from the shadow into the official
economy. By 2007, several of the major oligarchs had become fully legal and legitimate, were
paying taxes, had declared their ownership and were spending substantial amounts for charity.
The case studies on the Ukrainian energy, metal and chemical sectors confirm the ongoing
implementation of corporate governance norms. In these sectors, the business and ownership
structure became more transparent, international bookkeeping norms were launched, and
companies and corporations began to develop long-term strategies (Heinrich 2004; Zheka
2006; Pleines 2008). Making one’s business transparent under informal institutions is highly
risky and therefore makes better formal institutions necessary. Transparency and good
corporate governance also meant that illegal “shadow” resources used to ensure wealth and
market benefits by means of state capture or corruption were scaled back.
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
16
Table 2. The wealth of Ukrainian oligarchs, 2002-2007
Wprost Ukraine
Year Total number Total number max Wealth, in million $US
2002 25 3 1 700
2003 50 6 1 900
2004 50 5 3 500
2005 100 7 2 800
2006 100 15 7 200
2007 100 24 18 700
Source: Lista 100 Najbogatszych Europy, Wprost; own calculations.
Obtaining investment for modernization has also become a big challenge for Ukraine.
Current growth has an extensive character, based on the old capital stock with exports of
intermediary, semi-finished and low-quality goods. The efficiency of the basic exporting
sectors e.g. the metal sector is low, while the energy wastage is high. At the same time,
Ukraine’s exporting sectors are aging.
24
Thus, the modernization i.e. replacement of the old
capital stock and increase of their efficiency that is needed to make economic growth
sustainable has become the priority of the Ukrainian oligarchic clans whose assets are
concentrated mostly in the exporting sectors. In addition, the clans have improved their access
to international capital markets and increased the capitalization and diversification of their
assets, which has led to more financial openness, the disappearance of transfer pricing, the
transparency of taxable profits and demand for better institutions.
Overall, after the financial crisis in 1998, the sources of economic rents for the Ukrainian
clans have either disappeared or became more limited. The oligarchic clans, whose business
became more and more internationalized, were forced to implement international standards of
transparency and corporate governance. In addition, to be competitive in international markets,
they needed and still need to modernize their energy-intensive companies, especially in the
energy, metal, and chemical sectors. The modernization, however, requires large financial
investment, which in turn depends on political stability and quality of institutions. Hence,
increasing trade and investment relations can be treated as an exogenous force, limiting the
sources of rents and challenging oligarchic clans in Ukraine to improve institutions and
converge with the EU standards.
Initially, the political system in Ukraine did not react to the changing political and
economic preferences of the oligarchic clans. As can be seen in Figure 1, there was no clear
trend in institution building after the 1998 crisis. Only after the Orange Revolution the impact
of institutional reforms leads to the progress in building institutions as measured by the World
Bank Governance Indicators (WBGI) (Figure 1). Quite unusually, the progress in building
economic-administrative and legal institutions is even stronger than the progress in building
political institutions. The usual pattern of institution building in CIS countries is rather that
follow-up economic-administrative and legal reforms are more difficult to implement than
political reforms (Hammermann et al. 2005). Given the political turmoil following the Orange
Revolution, it is far from clear whether or not this progress in building institutions implying an
increased convergence of Ukraine towards European institutional standards can be sustained.
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
17
Figure 1 shows a slight slow-down in the development of economic –administrative and legal
institutions in 2006-2007, but strong improvement in building political institutions. Further
steps towards the integration of Ukraine into the EU would be clearly in the interest of Ukraine
oligarchic clans because this would imply that trade and investment relations could be
expanded.
-1,2
-1,0
-0,8
-0,6
-0,4
-0,2
0,0
0,2
1996 1998 2000 2002 20 03 2004 2005 2006 2 007
political economic-administrative legal overall
Figure 1. Progress in institution building in Ukraine, 1996-2004
Source: World Bank Governance Indicators; own calculations.
4. Ukrainian Business Interests and EU Leverage for Better
Institutions
Trade and foreign direct investment (FDI) figures reveal that Ukraine’s regional and
global integration is on the rise. Its level of trade openness has increased considerably. Imports
and exports are equivalent to 90% of GDP and are now comparable to other countries in the
region. As has been argued above, Ukrainian oligarchic clans have become increasingly export-
oriented and have profited from external trade, but they urgently need new technologies and
investment to become more competitive on EU and global markets.
The importance of the EU as Ukraine’s main trading partner and investor is increasing.
The EU has even become more important than CIS countries, although energy imports from the
latter region still figure prominently (Figure 2). In 2006, EU-Ukraine trade surpassed €27
billion due to a strong increase in imports, but was on a steady rise even before (Table 3).
Despite this significant reorientation of exports toward the EU, the extent of Ukraine’s trade
with the EU is still lagging behind that of new EU members. To some extent, Ukraine’s trade
pattern reflects the trade policies of the past and Ukraine’s difficulty in deciding on priorities
for international integration. Being sandwiched between Russia and the EU, Ukraine has tried
to integrate in both directions (Vinhas de Souza et al. 2006). As a consequence, Ukraine
depends on Russian fuels and EU machinery and equipment. Its dependency on Russian fuels
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
18
is a carryover/legacy from the Soviet era, which left it with an extremely inefficient energy
sector. It is now not only a net importer of gas and oil, but is also the economy in the region
that consumes the most energy. Prices for the Russian gas and oil have increased, leading to the
introduction of energy-saving technologies and the diversification of energy suppliers and the
types of energy used. Thus, it is to be expected Ukraine will reduce its dependence upon
Russia.
0
5000
10000
15000
20000
25000
30000
35000
40000
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006
EXPORTS TO CIS
IMPORTS FROM CIS
CIS Balance
0
5000
10000
15000
20000
25000
30000
35000
40000
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006
EXPORTS TO EU27
IMPORTS FROM EU27
EU 27 Balance
Figure 2. Ukraine’s trade with EU and CIS, 2001-2005 ($ million)
Source: Direction of Trade Statistics, International Monetary Fund.
Table 3. Ukraine’s trade with the EU 2002-2006
Year
Imports,
€ million
Yearly %
change
EU
Share of
total
imports
Exports,
€ million
Yearly %
change
EU
Share of
total
exports
Balance,
€ million
Imports+
Exports,
€ million
2002 5.729
31,97
6.105
32,60
376 11.835
2003 6.859
19,7 32,27
6.972
14,2 32,70
112 13.831
2004 7.536
9,9 32,40
7.876
13,0 30,22
340 15.412
2005 9.543
26,6 32,93
7.400
-6,0 27,21
-2.143 16.943
2006 19.605
105,4 42,65
8.007
8,2 25,57
-11.597 27.612
Average
annual
growth,
%
36,0
7,0
23,6
Source: EU EUROSTAT, External Trade Statistics.
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
19
Up to now, however, the structure of Ukraine’s trade with the EU and Russia still
reveal the traditional pattern, with the westward movement of raw materials and semi-
processed goods, and the eastward (opposite) movement of final products, primarily
investment goods. Looking at trade with the EU, Figure 3 reveals that, although total trade
figures increased especially for EU trade, the structure of Ukraine exports and imports
remained rather stable. Iron and steel clearly dominate Ukrainian exports. In 2005, they had a
share of 24% in Ukraine’s total exports to the EU-27. Other exports to the EU mainly consisted
of primary products which made up for about 35% of total exports. This picture clearly reveals
the high dependence of Ukraine exports on a few commodities and products. So far, the
international business cycle and China’s new role in the world market have provided favorable
conditions for Ukraine’s exports and its economic recovery. At the same time, Ukraine exports
are highly dependent on these developments and diversification is needed in order to provide a
broader basis for export expansion (World Bank 2004). Thus, diversification is of high priority
for Ukraine’s oligarchic clans, who are trying to secure and expand their position in the
society.
Figure 3. Ukraine‘s trade with the EU by product, 2006 (€ million)
Source: EU EUROSTAT, External Trade Statistics.
Besides being an important trade partner, the EU is also an important investor in
Ukraine’s economy. Although Ukraine initially failed to attract a significant amount of capital
from abroad and from the EU in particular, FDI inflows to Ukraine increased considerably
from $3,8 billion in 2004 to almost $16 billion in 2007. Considering the origin of foreign
investors present in Ukraine, the EU is by far the largest investor. The share of EU FDI in total
FDI jumped from 56% in 2004 to 75% in 2007.
25
It is followed by the United States, a set of
so-called “offshore zones” and CIS countries, mainly Russia.
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
20
However, capital coming to Ukraine from the west and from the east differs not only by
volumes, but also by investment motives and distribution of funds across economic sectors.
Recipients of investment from Europe are mostly companies operating in the food, chemical
and machine building sectors (Emerson et al. 2006). The wholesale and retail trade sectors have
also received a significant amount of investment from the EU. At the same time, Russian
investment is concentrated in the fuel and energy sector. Russian oil companies have acquired
almost all Ukrainian oil-refineries, which in Soviet Union times were constructed specifically
for processing Russian oil. Another object of interest for investors from the “northern
neighbour” was healthcare complexes in the region of Crimea.
More generally, however, FDI in Ukraine seems to follow Ukraine’s trade patterns and
reflect its production links. While stronger production links between Ukrainian and Russian
enterprises in certain sectors would be beneficial for both countries, capital from the more
advanced economies of the EU could bring benefits such as generating new production,
management, and marketing technologies, better labor skills, improvement in risk management
that are more relevant for the long-run growth and development of the Ukrainian economy.
Another important benefit is that western companies also tend to “export” to Ukraine European
institutional standards.
In its turn, institutional development, especially the absence of corruption and
improvement in the business environment, attracts FDI. According to survey results, the main
motive for western companies operating in Ukraine was the possibility to access a large
domestic market (International Centre for Policy Studies 2000). Indeed, with its 48 million
inhabitants, Ukraine represents one of the biggest national markets in Europe, which, in
addition, has a good potential for growth in terms of purchasing power. Relatively low labor
costs are also reported as one of the motives for investment; however, this advantage is dimin-
ished by low productivity. At the same time, the poor quality of the business environment and
institutions is often quoted as a reason why Ukraine has attracted only small amounts of FDI,
though it has considerable comparative advantages over CEECs (Mayhew 2006).
While Ukraine’s problems are home-made to a large extent, the Ukrainian business
interests of the oligarchic clans also have to overcome substantial obstacles when trying to
enter foreign markets which are closely related to institutional convergence. At the same time,
the incentives provided by market access have already helped institutional convergence. Again,
this is an example of how the interests of the clans have been united and succeeded in pushing
reforms in a considerably short time. The Ukrainian oligarchic clans strived for better access to
the European Market as long as their commodities were hampered by the antidumping
measures that the EU applies to third countries. On the European steel market, Ukrainian
oligarchic clans exporting metal products competed against Russian and Rumanian steel
producers which benefited from the status of a full-fledged market of their economies and, at
the same time, provided the yardstick for evaluating Ukrainian exports. Furthermore, Ukrainian
metal sector has attracted less foreign direct investment (FDI) than the Russian metal sector, as
Ukraine’s metal exports have permanently been under EU antidumping investigations and
subject to EU antidumping penalties (Eremenko and Lisenkova 2004).
26
The penalties for
Ukraine’s metal exports ranged from 24% to 64%, raised the price and reduced the
competitiveness of the Ukrainian goods. These penalties depend on whether, according to EU
calculations, a particular export product is sold at dumping prices. While calculating dumping
prices, the EU takes into account the economic status that the EU grants a country of origin.
Exports from a country without the status of a full-fledged market economy are more
vulnerable to antidumping penalties, than a country enjoying this status.
27
Thus, institutional
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
21
building is very important, as the EU uses the level of institutional quality in a particular
country as the main criteria to grant the status of a full-fledged market economy to a particular
country. Thus, to escape high antidumping penalties, the Ukrainian oligarchic clans have
strived for this status for their individual enterprises as well as for Ukraine’s economy in
general and have pushed for the improvement of Ukraine’s poor institutional quality.
The negotiations with the EU about obtaining the status of a full-fledged market economy
started in 2000. However, the European Union Council of Ministers initially granted Ukraine
only the status of a transitional quasi-market economy, but did offer the status of a full-fledged
market economy to certain Ukrainian companies. By 2005, two Ukrainian companies - Azot
and Gorlovka Stirol - obtained this status. However, given the lack of institutional reforms that
could provide safeguards by implementing formal rules, the political risks of expropriation for
Ukrainian producers when making their business more transparent were very high. Therefore,
the Ukrainian oligarchic clans used their political influence to implement the institutional
reforms required for achieving the status of a full-fledged market economy for the whole
country and to accelerate negotiations with the EU (Honcharuk 2006). Finally, in the aftermath
of the Orange Revolution (in 2005) and due to the progress in building institutions, Ukraine
obtained the status of a full-fledged market economy.
Generally, Ukraine when trying to penetrate foreign markets and to attract foreign
investment faces by far more problems at home than abroad. The greatest internal barriers to
international trade in the country, as perceived by traders, are the following: the general
complexity of regulations and their unfair enforcement, including a multitude o f pre-customs
permits, registrations, licenses, technical regulations, and, related to this, corruption, delays,
and high compliance costs, the slow and costly process of VAT reimbursements to exporters,
which continues to receive highly negative grades in business surveys, and the unpredictability
of and corruption in customs (World Bank 2004). Hence, some of the main limitations to
expanding trade and investment relations are domestic and relate to institutional development.
Convergence with the EU (import of EU company legislation, EU rules on standardization and
certification, EU competition rules, EU customs procedures, etc.) would not only help
eliminate these internal barriers but would also strongly support Ukraine’s integration with the
EU (Vinhas de Souza et al. 2006).
WTO membership is an imperfect substitute for EU integration as regards finding who
might support Ukraine in becoming a competitive market economy with democratic
structures.
28
An assumption present in some studies is that the process of obtaining WTO
membership Ukraine announced its intention to join the WTO as early as 1993 can be a
stepping-stone for EU membership given that some of the requirements are similar for both
processes (Blue Ribbon Commission for Ukraine 2004; World Bank 2004) and that WTO
membership should, therefore, precede EU membership. Although it is true in the sense that no
country has ever entered the EU without having first entered the WTO, the connection between
these two “options” is not very strong. As the experience of the last enlargement round shows,
most of the applications for EU membership preceded WTO membership, and frequently by
several years.
29
The Baltic countries, whose economic problems most resemble the sort of
problems faced by Ukraine, did join the WTO until as late as 1999. For most of the former EU
candidate countries, the causality was actually the reverse: the fulfillment of WTO membership
conditions came about as a by-product of the EU Accession process. Additionally, the
assumption that the WTO is an effective framework provider that will enhance domestic
reforms especially on the scale necessary for EU Accession seems to overestimate the
“minimum common denominator” negotiation process that actually leads to WTO membership
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
22
(which, among other things, is responsible for the usually disappointing trade increases a
country experiences after joining the WTO).
30
EU accession and, to a lesser extent, cooperation would clearly be a great deal more
effective to Ukraine in exporting a much more robust and comprehensive regulatory framework
than WTO membership. If one assumes EU accession is the main objective, the EU integration
process includes all the necessary reforms for WTO entry. This is especially true within the
framework of pre-accession free trade agreements, as was the case in the last round of
enlargement. For Ukraine, which is far from EU accession and free deep trade agreements with
the EU, it implies that membership in the WTO may provide some intermediate target with,
however, limited additional impact on the willingness of Ukrainian oligarchic clans to support
further institutional convergence.
Accordingly, the second government of Tymoshenko (since December 2007) made
Europeanization an explicit goal of domestic reforms rather than treating it as a foreign policy
goal. Tymoshenko declared that Europeanization is one of her government’s priorities. The
negotiations on a free trade area, simplification of the visa requirements, participation in EU
programs and agencies and development of energy cooperation are the main tasks on her
government’s agenda. Furthermore, Tymoshenko has supported her political declaration by
implementing wide-ranging reform programs. Launching the government program “Ukrainian
breakthrough: not for politicians, but for the people”, Tymoshenko stressed that her
Transparency Initiative is based on understanding of the necessity for changes and reforms in
Ukraine that are in accordance with key European values and the demands of Ukrainian civil
society.
31
However, the political declarations are difficult to implement without bottom-up support.
According to Razumkov Zentrum (Razumkov Center 2008), 224 of 227 governments’ reforms
(both of Yanukovych and of Tymoshenko) were in line with the AP priorities for 2007.
32
Only
one third of the government reforms, however, were fully implemented. Almost 40% of the
implemented reforms dealt with AP priorities regarding economic and regulatory policy, trade
and the new perspective of economic cooperation with the EU. The political crises were the
main obstacle to better implementation. Similarly, the effectiveness of current government
activities is rather low due to the ongoing struggles for power between the government, the
parliament, the president, and the oligarchic clans (Boltushkina et al. 2008).
However, there is no deep commitment on the part of the EU for any deep free trade
agreement (FTA+). Already the Partnership and Cooperation Agreement (PCA), the bilateral
agreement which governed EU-Ukraine relations until 2008, was more a declaration of
intentions to cooperate in different areas (political cultural, scientific cooperation, trade,
investment, etc.) than anything else. It does not offer any specified mechanisms or benefits for
achieving cooperation. The new ENP framework is not very different (Afanasyeva et al. 2008).
There is still no specified mechanisms that provides a roadmap as well as benefits, and, in
addition, it is based on the intention of the EU to prolong top-down “Enlargement
Europeanization” as “Neighborhood Europeanization”, i.e. it details what the EU wants without
offering a reasonable “carrot” as an incentive for domestic forces like the oligarchic clans to
support necessary reforms.
Ukraine entered the ENP framework in 2004. The first EU-Ukraine AP was drafted in
late 2004 before the Orange Revolution and was signed with slight changes in February 2005
after the new Ukrainian government protested about some of its draft’s provisions. It defined
the priorities of cooperation in different policy areas and the mechanism of their
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
23
implementation for three years. Further, it targeted the following: promotion of Ukraine’s
accession to the WTO, removal of non-tariff barriers, improvement of the investment climate
and tax reform and approximation of legislation to EU standards. In December 2005 and March
2008, the European Commission evaluated the implementation of the AP positively (Joint
Report 2005; 2008). Nevertheless, the mode of operation of the AP is not too distinct from the
former PCA. The institutional framework and tools used in the relationships between Ukraine
and the EU remain the same.
33
What the EU could do to offer a reasonable incentive for countries that are not on the
list of potential accession countries is clearly to provide a FTA+, which could be expected to
boost trade and investment relations through substantial trade liberalization and regulatory
harmonization (Emerson et al. 2006). In order to achieve this, the FTA+ would have to build
on the liberalization undertaken as part of WTO membership and work towards “deep
convergence” not just cutting tariffs but addressing red tape for exporters by aiming for
similar regulatory standards and norms in both economies. The significance of such an FTA+
would, however, depend on the range of products covered by the agreement. The major
Ukrainian trade items, such as heavy industry products and agricultural products, belong to the
“sensitive” sector for the EU and are, therefore, not included in agreements with the EU.
Furthermore, a large range of Ukrainian products fails to fulfill European standards and is,
therefore, barred from EU markets by using non-tariff barriers. Nevertheless, a kind of FTA+
as a kind of operation scheme with neighboring countries and offering a reasonable incentive
for cooperation in exchange for the creation of a ring of well-governed countries at the
periphery of the EU, as is the intention of the EU, should be a realistic target for European
politics.
A further step, i.e. offering a stake in the Common Market, would of course be more of
an incentive for Ukraine’s oligarchic clans to push for further institutional convergence with
the EU in all the parties but, at the same time, is currently less realistic. It would involve
participation in the areas of free movement of goods, services, and factors of production. A
stake in the Common Market has not been offered to non-accession countries but is mentioned
in the ENP APs for Ukraine and for Moldova.
34
While this is clearly expected to have high
benefits in terms of growth (Brenton and Manchin 2003) and FDI inflows that promote
technological transfer and efficiency improvements (Levine 1997; Francois and Schuknecht
1999), the ENP APs are rather wake at this point. Even if it were to become reality, important
topics for Ukraine, like agriculture and steel markets, could still be excluded from negotiations
(Milcher and Slay 2005).
All in all, the stylized facts about trade and FDI as well as the policy discussion should
have made clear that tying up with the EU is of clear advantage for the oligarchic clans in
Ukraine. Doing business with the EU could constitute a common denominator that they might
otherwise lack in order to unite the Ukrainian elite under the goal of improving institutions and
governance. EU markets, being the largest neighbour markets both in terms of population and
GDP, are the most attractive market for the Ukrainian oligarchic clans and provide the relevant
yardstick for meeting high institutional standards. The FTA+ should provide significant
incentives for re-kindling bottom-up demand for institutional reforms in Ukraine. However,
given the present design of ENP AP for Ukraine, in which the FTA+ is defined vaguely, one
can not be overly optimistic.
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
24
5. Conclusions
The preceding has shown that Ukraine provides a case in point supporting the argument
that opening it up and integrating it internationally may speed up the change in political and
economic preferences of the oligarchic clans in favor of formal institutions that otherwise
might be established only very slowly. In the absence of strong incentives of EU membership
to initiate top-down institution building, the oligarchic clans that are the most influential part of
the domestic elite and therefore also the most important bottom-up force to drive the
institutional convergence of Ukraine towards European standards. The oligarchic clans have
changed their political and economic preferences from wealth accumulation toward its security
and a consolidation of their position by means of establishing formal institutional safeguards.
They needed a minimum of formal institutions in order to meet international standards of doing
business, and these institutions had not been provided by Kuchma’s regime. Hence, most of the
oligarchic clans directly or indirectly supported the Orange Revolution of 2004 and the
consequent institutional change in the political and economic system of Ukraine.
In the course of the Orange Revolution, Ukraine was transformed into a parliamentary-
presidential republic. Thereby, the probability that any domestic force can monopolize state
authorities has been diminished, but the number of veto-players in Ukraine’s politics has
increased. The political crises that have occurred since the end of the Orange Revolutions in
2005 demonstrate that post-revolutionary institutional reform is a tricky business in Ukraine’s
political system of “feckless pluralism”. The first Orange coalition, consisting of Our Ukraine
Party, Bloc Yulia Tymoshenko, and the Socialist Party was dissolved after having lost the sight
of their common goal of overturning Kuchma’s regime. The Party of Regions won the
parliamentary election of 2006 and created a wide parliamentary majority with the Communist
and the Socialist Parties. Having returned to power, the Party of Regions attempted to regain its
old influence in the new more democratic regime. Obviously, the new democracy passed its
first test because these attempts failed. However, this led to a political deadlock. The results of
the recent pre-term parliamentary election of 2007 gave the “orange” forces a new chance to
promote democratic and market-oriented reforms in Ukraine. However, there seems to be no
end to Ukraine’s political instability in sight. The second Orange coalition has been short-lived;
the new parliamentary elections are on horizon. And the situation is worsened by the fact that
the oligarchic clans, who ensure their wealth through their connections to politics, are also
involved in the political struggles between the executive and the legislative.
This implies that there would be an important role to play for the EU as an external driver
for institution building in Ukraine. Trade and investment flows have increased in recent years,
providing the EU with the leverage to support bottom-up demand for further reforms in
Ukraine. With civil society still in its early stage of establishment, such demand has to be based
on business interests. As shown in the paper, the oligarchic clans found it hard to form a
coalition for the day-to-day business. An important reason for this is that, contrary to the
situation in Russia, oligarchic clans are sectoral and regional rivals. Access to EU markets is
likely to promote further convergence of Ukraine’s legislation with EU standards by providing
significant external incentives, like a free trade agreement or a stake in the Common Market, to
the Ukrainian oligarchic clans to push for further institutional convergence. Taking into
account the presence of the oligarchic clans in the parliament and the executive, these
economic incentives could be very effective
However, the ENP framework does not provide a firm commitment on the part of the EU,
and the AP provides possibilities rather than concrete mechanisms and benefits. It is unlikely
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
25
that this will be sufficient to create a momentum for institutional convergence with the EU, as
was the case with “Enlargement Europeanization”. External incentives supporting the domestic
drivers of institutional reforms would be highly welcome in the present situation in Ukraine.
While it is doubtful whether or not stable political conditions favoring reforms may be
established in Ukraine by Tymoshenko’s government, a new enhanced agreement to replace
the expiring PCA and new ENP AP are to be negotiated. Moreover, Ukraine has not only
successfully completed the negotiations on WTO membership, it has begun negotiations with
the EU on the FTA+. The challenge in these negotiations is that the incentives the EU provides
are rather small compared to the accession process and thus have to be well targeted in order to
be effective and generate some optimism that the bottom-up forces for institutional reform in
Ukraine will be strengthened and that the current stalemate can be overcome.
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
26
References
Acemoglu, D., and S. Johnson. 2003. Unbunding institutions. NBER Working Paper 9934,
National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge.
Afanasyeva, E., F. Hammermann, and R. Schweickert. 2008. From a Soviet Past to a European
Future. International Journal of Economics (forthcoming).
Aslund, Anders. 2005. Comparative Oligarchy: Russia, Ukraine and the United States. Paper
presented at CASE Conference ‘Europe after the Enlargement’, 8-9 April, in Warsaw, Poland.
Blue Ribbon Commission for Ukraine. 2004. Proposals for the President: A New Wave of
Reform, Kyiv, http://www.carnegieendowment.org/files/BRCReport121204Eng2.pdf (accessed
October 23, 2008).
Brenton, P. and M. Manchin. 2003. Making EU Trade Agreements Work: The Role of Rules of
Origin. The World Economy, 26 (5): 755-769.
Boltushkina, Olena, Inna Vedernikova, Yulia Mostovaya, Serhii Rakhmanin, Yuriy Skolotiany,
and Nataliya Yatsenko. 2008. 100 Head-Off Steps. Zerkalo Nedeli, 29 March-5 April, 12 (691),
http://www.zn.ua/1000/1550/62561/ (accessed October 23, 2008).
Carothers, T. 2002. The End of the Transition Paradigm. Journal of Democracy 13 (1): 5-21.
Chhibber, A., R. K. Peters, and B. J. Yale. 2006. Reform and growth: Evaluating the World
Bank Experience. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.
Drautzburg, T., I. Melnykovska, and R. Schweickert. 2008. Determinants of Institutional
Change in Transition Countries – Does Membership in International Institutions Matter? Kieler
Working Papers 1421, Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Kiel.
Emerson, M., T. H. Edwards, I. Gazizullin, M. Lücke, D. Müller-Jentsch, V. Nanivska, V.
Pyanytskiy, A. Schneider, R. Schweickert, O. Shevtsov, and O. Shumylo. 2006. The prospects
of deep free trade between the European Union and Ukraine. Brussels: Centre for European
Policy Studies.
Eremenko, I., and K. Lisenkova. 2004. The impact on Ukraine of joining the WTO: Subsidies
vs. antidumping in ferrous metallurgy. CERT Discussion Paper 11, Centre for Economic
Reform and Transformation, School of Management and Languages, Heriot-Watt University,
Edinburgh.
Feeny, David. 1988. The demand for and supply of institutional arrangements. In Rethinking
institutional analysis and development, edited by V. Ostrom, D. Feeny, and H. Picht. San
Francisco: International Centre for Economic Growth, Chap. 6: 159-209.
Fischer, S., R. Puglisi, K. Wolczuk, and P. Wolowski. 2008. Ukraine: Quo Vadis? EU-ISS
Chaillot Paper 108, Paris.
Francois, J.F. and L.Schuknecht. 1999. International trade in financial services, competition,
and growth performance. Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) Discussion Paper
2144, London.
Gawrich, A., and R. Schweickert. 2004. Institutionelle Entwicklung in Europa - Wie weit sind
die südosteuropäischen Länder? Die Weltwirtschaft 2: 153-186.
Gawrich, A., I. Melnykovska, and R. Schweickert. 2008. Neighborhood Europeanization
through ENP - The. Case of Ukraine. Mimeo.
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
27
Gazprom and Turkmenistan update Turkmen gas supply conditions for 2006. 2006. Gazprom
Press Release, 29 December.
Gelman, V. 2008. Out of the frying pan into the fire? Post-Soviet regime changes in
comparative perspective. International Political Science Review 29 (2): 157-180.
Hale, H. E. 2005. Regime Cycles: Democracy, Autocracy, and Revolution in Post-Soviet
Eurasia, World Politics 58 (1): 133-65.
Hammermann, F., Hansen, M. and R. Schweickert 2005. Institutional Development and EU-
Integration – the Case of the Baltic Countries. Baltic Economic Trends 3: 7-14.
Hare, P. G. 2001. Institutional Change and Economic Performance in the Transition
Economies. Working Paper presented in the UNECE Spring Seminar, May 7, Geneva.
Havrylyshyn, O. 2006a. Divergent paths in post-communist transformation - Capitalism for all
or capitalism for the few? Basingstoke, UK, and New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Havrylyshyn, O. 2006b. Growth and institutions in the transition: How do Belarus, Russia and
Ukraine compare to others. Tiger Working Paper Series 97, Centrum Badawcze Transformacji,
Integracji I Globalizacji, Warsaw.
Heinrich, A. 2004. Globalisierung und Corporate Governance. Russlands Erdöl- und
Erdgassektor. Osteuropa 54 (9-10): 355-365.
Hellman, Joel S. 1998. Winners take all: The politics of partial reform in post-communist
transitions. World Politics 50 (1): 203-234.
Honcharuk, A. 2006. Ukraine for Europe: politics, pipe, economics... Zerkalo Nedeli, 24 June,
24 (603), http://www.zn.ua/2000/2675/53750/ (accessed October 23, 2008).
Howard, M. 2002. The Weakness of Postcommunist Civil Society, Journal of Democracy 13
(1): 157-169.
International Centre for Policy Studies. 2000. Foreign Direct Investment in Ukraine. Policy
Studies 11, Kiev; http://www.icps.com.ua/doc/ps_eng_200006_11.pdf (accessed October 23,
2008).
Joint Evaluation Report EU-Ukraine Action Plan. 2005 December, Brussel/Kyiv.
Joint Evaluation Report EU-Ukraine Action Plan. 2008 March, Brussel/Kyiv.
Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay and M. Mastruzzi. 2005. Governance Matters IV: Governance
Indicators for 1996-2004. World Bank, Washington D.C.
Keohane R. O. 1984. After hegemony: cooperation and discord in the world political economy.
Princenton: Princeton Press.
Kowall T., und K. Zimmer. 2002. Der politische Einfluss von Wirtschaftseliten in der Ukraine,
Arbeitspapiere der Forschungsstelle Osteuropa 42, Bremen.
Kubicek, P. 2000. Unbroken Ties: The State, Interest Associations, and Corporatism in Post-
Soviet Ukraine. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Kudelia, S. 2007. Revolutionary Bargain: The Unmaking of Ukraine’s Autocracy through
Pacting. Journal of Communist Studies and Transition Politics 23 (1): 77-100.
Levine, R. 1997. Financial Development and Economie Growth: Views and Agenda. Journal
of Economic Literature 35 (2): 688-726.
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
28
Malynkovych, V. 2006. Ukrainskaya Perspektiva. Polititicheskiy klas 13 (1),
http://www.igpi.ru/info/people/malink/1139380574.html
Mayhew, A. 2006. Foreign Direct Investment and the Modernisation of Ukraine, SEI Seminar
Series 1: 67-81.
McFaul, M. 2002. The fourth wave of Democracy and Dictatorship: Non-Cooperative
Transition in the Post-Communist World. World Politics 54 (2): 212-224.
McFaul, M. 2005. Transition from Postcommunism. Journal of Democracy 16 (3): 5-19.
Melnykovska, I. 2008. Towards New Horizons through Different Paths: Colour Revolution or
Soft Authoritarianism? Mimeo.
Merkel, W., H.-J. Puhle, and A. Croissant, ed. 2003. Defekte Demokratien. Band 1: Theorien
und Probleme. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.
Milcher, S., and B. Slay. 2005. The Economics of the “European Neighbourhood Policy”: An
Initial Assessment’. Paper presented at the conference “Europe after the Enlargement”, Case
Foundation, Warsaw, April 8-9.
North, C. D. 1990. Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Olcott, M. B., and M. Ottaway. 1999. The Challenge of Semi-Authoritarianism. Working Paper
7, Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, Washington DC.
Olson, M. 2000. Power and Prosperity: Outgrowing Communist and Capitalist Dictatorship.
New York: Basic Books.
Pleines, H. 2005. Ukrainische Seilschaften. Münster: LIT-Verlag.
Pleines, H. 2008. Reformblockaden in der Wirtschaftspolitik. Eine vergleichende Analyse der
Rolle von Wirtschaftsakteuren in Polen, Russland und der Ukraine. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag.
Pop-Eleches, G. 2007. Between Historical Legacies and the Promise of Western Integration:
Democratic Conditionality after Communism, East European Politics and Societies 21(1):
142–161.
Prizel, I. 2002. Ukraine's Hollow Decade. East European Politics and Societies 16, no.2:
363-385.
Raik, Kristi. 2005. “Democracy and civil society in the new Eastern neighbours of the EU:
foreign aid and local needs. In The new Eastern neighbours of the European Union on the way
to democracy: How to support civil society”. Available from:
http://www.oef.org.ee/_repository/Document/Idanaabrite_uuring%20eng.pdf; Internet.
Razumkov Center. 2008. Public Watch over Action Plan EU-Ukraine: Achievements and
Perspectives. National Security and Defence 6: 2-6.
Rodrik, D. 2000. Saving transitions. The World Bank Economic Review 14 (3): 481–508.
Rodrik, D. 2003. The primacy of institutions (and what this does and does not mean). Finance
and Development 40 (2): 31-34.
Rodrik, D. 2006. Goodbye Washington consensus, hello Washington confusion? A review of
the World Bank’s economic growth in the 1990s: Learning from a decade of reform. Journal of
Economic Literature 44 (4): 973-987.
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
29
Roland, G. 2005. After Enlargement: Institutional Achievements and Prospects in the New
Member States. In The New Member States Convergence and Stability, edited by C. Detken, V.
Gaspar, and G. Noblet. European Central Bank, Frankfurt a.M.: 35-58.
Rose A. K. 2004. Do WTO members have more liberal trade policy? NBER Working Paper
9347, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge.
Rumer, B. 2005. Central Asia: At the End of Transition. In Central Asia at the End of the
Transition, edited by B. Rumer
.
New York, London: M.E. Sharpe: 27-31.
Schimmelfennig, F., and U. Sedelmeier, eds. and comps. 2005. The Europeanization of Central
and Eastern Europe. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Schweickert, R. (2004). How Far Away is Europe? Institutional Development in Europe’s
Balkan and Black Sea Neighbours. Intereconomics 39 (6): 305–309.
Schweickert, R., and R. Thiele. 2004. From Washington to Post-Washington? Consensus
Policies and Divergent Developments in Latin America and Asia. Kiel Discussion Papers, Kiel
Institute for the World Economy, Kiel.
Stepanenko, V. 2006. Civil Society in Post-Soviet Ukraine: Civic Ethos in the Framework of
Corrupted Sociality? East European Politics and Societies 20: 571-597.
Stern, J. 2006. Natural Gas Security Problems in Europe: The Russian-Ukrainian Crisis of
2006. Asia-Pacific Review 13: 32-59.
Unmüßig, B., and M. Walther. 1999. Strukturanpassung in Afrika: Warten auf den Post-
Washington Konsensus. Entwicklung & Zusammenarbeit 40 (9): 247–250.
Van Zon, H. 2000. The Political Economy of Independent Ukraine: Captured by the Past.
Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Vinhas de Souza, Lucio, Rainer Schweickert, Veronica Movchan, Oksana Bilan, and Ihor
Burskovskyj. 2006. Now so Near, and Yet Still do Far: Relations between Ukraine and the
European Union. In Return to Growth in CIS countries, edited by O. Havrylyshyn, and L.
Vinhas de Souza. Berlin: Springer, Chap.7: 144-190.
White, S., J. Korosteleva, and I. McAllister. 2008. A wider Europe? The view from Russia,
Belarus and Ukraine. Journal of Common Market Studies 46 (2): 219-241.
Wittkowsky, Andreas. 2001. Regional, Sectoral, and State Actors in Ukraine: The Struggle
Against Hard Budget Constraints. In Explaining Post-Soviet Patchworks, vol. 3: The Political
Economy of Regions, Regimes and Republics, edited by K. Segbers, Aldershot: Ashgate: 246-
264.
World Bank. 2004. Ukraine Trade Policy Study. Report 29684. Washington D.C.
World Value Survey. 2004. Database, www.worldvaluessurvey.org (accessed October 23,
2008).
Zheka, V. 2006. Corporate Governance and Firm performance in Ukraine. CERT Discussion
Paper 5, Centre for Economic Reform and Transformation,
Edinburg.
Zimmer, K. 2006. Machteliten im Ukrainischen Donbass. Berlin: LIT-Verlag.
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
30
1
Europeanization is “a process in which states adopts EU rules” (Schimmelfennig and Sedelmaier 2005).
2
A growing empirical literature stresses that “institutions matter” for sustainable economic growth (Rodrik 2003;
Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi 2005; Chhibber et al. 2006; Acemoglu and Johnson 2003).
3
Solana, Javier: A secure Europe in a better world. European Security Strategy, Brussels 2003, p.14.
4
Apart from economic incentives, regional security may be an additional or even increasingly important incentive
for institutional building. Thus, NATO membership also provides incentives. Empirical results confirm that apart
from EU incentives, NATO membership has a positive impact on institution building in transition countries
(Drautzburg, Melnykovska and Schweickert 2008).
5
Although it is difficult to measure the extent to which a civil society exists, the number of registered
organizations and associations, and the percentage of citizens who are members of voluntary organizations and
associations, are commonly used as a yardstick.
6
The rankings of the most influential persons in Ukraine’s politics and economy are periodically published by a
few national journals and newspapers. Representatives of business groups have held the leading position in these
ratings since before the Orange Revolution. See,
Ranking of The Most Influential People of the Country. Hvardiya,
Halytski Kontrakty,
2002-2005; Rating of the 200 Most Influential Ukrainians 2007, in: Focus 51(64), 21
December 2007.
7
Relatives could be included in a clan, but relative relationships play a secondary role.
8
The patronage relationship between Pavlo Lazarenko, the former prime minister of Ukraine, and Yulia
Tymoshenko, the former president of the United Energy Systems of Ukraine (UESU), ensured the monopoly
position of this company on Ukraine’s gas market.
9
Defective democracies are political regimes, also categorized as “semi-authoritarian regimes” or “electoral
authoritarian regimes” (Olcott and Ottaway 1999), in which limited forms of pluralism (i.e. elections, civil
society) exist, but in which the other elements of democracy (i.e. accountability, checks and balances between
state branches) do not function properly.
10
The judicial branch can not be considered an independent branch of state power because it is strongly influenced
by the executive.
11
In Ukraine, the position of presidential advisor was held for a long time by oligarchs Vadym Volkov and
Oleksandr Rabynovich. Businessman Andriy Derkach is also an example. In 1996, he was appointed presidential
advisor on foreign trade and two years later he became the manager of Kuchma’s election team.
12
According to Kerstin Zimmer (2006), in the late 1990s, Ukrainian enterprises bought legislative laws (44
percent of total), presidential decrees (37 percent of total), credits and preferences of the National Bank (approx.
37 percent of total) and adjudications (21-26 percent of total).
13
The agrarian oligarchic clans had already existed in Soviet times and still influenced Ukraine’s politics through
its own ‘Agrarian Party’ (
Selyanska Partiya Ukrainy
). The coal mining oligarchic clans obtained subsidies and
blocked restructuring reforms of the mining sector by means of networking with the executive. In the 1990s, the
coal ministry and government were strongholds of the Donbas-based oligarchic clan. Its position was supported by
the miners’ strikes and by the coal enterprise directors and the Donbas regional elites. However, the influence of
the agrarian and coal mining clans began to diminish already in Kuchma’s era. Cross-sector oligarchic clans took
over the agrarian and coal clans’ influence in politics.
14
Such inner regional rivalry is exemplified by the rise and fall of the United Energy Systems of Ukraine (UESU),
Tymoshenko’s clan stemming from the Dnipropetrovsk region. Flourishing during the period that Lazarenko was
the prime minister, the company lost its monopoly in the Ukrainian gas market and its wealth after a new prime
minister, Valeriy Pustovoitenko, a representative of another oligarchic clan that also came from the
Dnipropetrovsk region, was appointed in 1997. The same regional origin of Pystovoitenko’s and Tymoshenko’s
clans did not secure the financial imperia of UESU. Tymoshenko and the members of the executive board were
accused of smuggling currency and natural gas, bribing, and the large-scale misappropriation of state property.
15
Coming to power in 1994, president Kuchma awarded the presidential administration with governmental
powers. Correspondently, the value of the position in this state body increased for the oligarchic clans radically.
The positions in the presidential administration (as well as in the government) offered opportunities to obtain
information about privatization plans, to negotiate subsidies for enterprises and to obtain credits and licenses. The
presidential administration, or “shadow government” as it was since then called, had wide executive powers and
competed with the government. The offices of the head of the presidential administration and prime minister were
objects to exchange between the Kyiv, the Kharkov, the Doneck and the Dnipropetrovsk clans. During Kuchma’s
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
31
presidency the governmental positions were filled by the representatives of the Dnipropetrovsk and the Doneck
clans. The chieftains of the Kharkov (Jevheniy Kusnaryov) and the Kyiv (Viktor Medvedchuk) clans often became
the heads of the presidential administration.
16
The “5 channel” and “Era” the broadcasting companies - loyal to the Orange forces media - were owned by the
Ukrainian oligarchs.
17
The first “orange” coalition was created in the aftermath of the Orange Revolution in 2005 and consisted of Our
Ukraine Party, Bloc Yulia Tymoshenko and the Socialist Party. The first “orange” government of Tymoshenko
was blamed for corruption and dissolved in the autumn of 2005.
18
Institutional convergence can be considered an institutional change to adjust institutions to certain institutional
standards.
19
By globalization we mean trade in goods, financial flows, and global harmonization of rules and norms.
20
The type of rent might be another conditional variable. Connecting the ideas of Olson and Havrylyshyn implies
that opening up a country may have different implications for rent seekers depending on the types of rents. Unlike
non-renewable resources in isolated mining sectors, opening up has a direct impact on rents to be extracted from
monopoly situations in the case of renewable resources or production sectors in general. The scarcity and
worldwide demand for non-renewable resources limit the positive effects of globalization by pushing domestic
rent-seekers to support institutional convergence towards global standards. In trade with non-renewable resources,
openness has lost its power.
21
The end prices were also lower than the world prices because compensation for transit charges was included in
the payment for energy resources.
22
The financial crisis in 1998 also marked the end of IMF “soft” credits. At the request of the IMF and because
the Ukrainian government wanted to avoid financial full-fledge default, it undertook some market reforms and
cancelled “soft budget constrains”. Thus, the most conservative part of the Ukrainian elite
the “red directors”
-
lost its rents in terms of subsidies and donations, and subsequently left the stage of the politics. “Red directors”
were the former Communist party apparatchiks or directors of the Soviet state enterprises who actually ran state
enterprises on a day-to-day basis. As products of the old system, these individuals kept control over their
enterprises in the years of transition and were likely to attempt to frustrate any reform effort that limited their
power. The external shock following the crisis of 1998 transmitted into successful economic and political reforms
that squeezed their rent-seeking possibilities.
23
The importance of two pipelines going through Ukraine as a “high-value card” in the bargaining position of
Ukraine vis-à-vis Russia diminished. In 1999, the Yamal-pipeline began to transport the Russian gas across
Belarus and Poland, circumventing Ukraine. By 2010, Ukraine’s loss of geopolitical advantage in the transit of
energy will be intensified by the completion of a pipeline running through the Baltic Sea and connecting Russia
directly with Germany.
24
In 2004, Ukraine’s steel sector reached its highest level of capacity utilization: 95.4%, up from 52.1% in 1998.
25
The figure for FDI flows from the EU-27 includes one very large off-shore zone, Cyprus, which accounts for a
substantial part of FDI into Ukraine.
26
From 1993 until 200, the EU lodged 43 anti-dumping cases against Ukrainian steel traders.
27
The decision whether the Ukrainian steel prices were “dumping” prices or not was defined by comparing
Ukrainian steel prices to the calculated unit production costs and steel prices in a third country ”surrogate” that
had the status of a full-fledged market economy. The calculated costs and prices were typically higher than
Ukrainian ones. Thus, the EU introduced antidumping customs duty equal to the difference between the
production costs of the third country and the production costs of the Ukrainian producers.
28
The creation of any deep regional integration with Russia is both rather unlikely to occur and unlikely to be of
great help. Ukraine’s trade regime is determined by both CIS-wide arrangements and bilateral agreements.
Numerous CIS-wide agreements (like the CIS Economic Union, CIS Free Trade Zone, CIS Common Agricultural
Market, etc.) have failed to be fully implemented. After Ukraine joins the WTO, it seems that the feasibility of
CIS agreements is rather low and likely any activities related to these agreements will be limited to an attempt to
create a free trade area between CIS countries. In addition, Russia’s markets are still relevant for Ukraine, but, as
the trade regime of the EU towards Russia is rather liberal, there is no contradiction between bilateral Ukraine-
Russian trade and EU integration.
29
The same does not apply to achieving some sort of FTA with the EU: FTAs with the EU usually preceded both
WTO entry and the official EU application membership by several years.
Inna Melnykovska and Rainer Schweickert: Who you gonna call? – Oligarchic Clans as a
Bottom-up Force of Neighborhood Europeanization in Ukraine
32
30
Andrew Rose (2004) estimated that WTO Accession has non-significant trade-creating effects, contrary to
regional FTAs, which have strong significantly positive trade creating effects. That is probably the case due to the
“lowest common denominator” constraints of the WTO Accession negotiation process, as opposed to
regional/bilateral FTAs that usually go much deeper towards liberalization amongst their members. The EU is
perhaps the most obvious example of the latter case. Igor Eremenko and Ekaterina Lisenkova (2004) share the
same conclusion for Ukraine.
31
Press release. 2007. Press office of the Cabinet of Ministers of Ukraine (CMU).
32
The calculations take into account all governmental measures in 2007. During this period, Ukraine has too
governments: one of Yanukovych (September 2006-December 2007) and the other of Tymoshenko (since
December 2007). Thus, these achievements could not be endowed to Tymoshenko’s government only.
33
The ENP tools to enhance reforms stemmed from the PCA and were sporadically complemented with
Enlargement tools. Despite regime changes and transformation of Ukraine into a parliamentary-presidential
republic, the EU institutional linkages are almost the presidency- and executive-oriented (Gawrich et al. 2008).
34
The same unique character has the FTA incentive.
... Third, the prevalence of patron-clientelism impacts levels of systemness. In the FSU republics, a variety of the clientelist modelclan politicshas been used to explain the social organisation linking political and business elites (Wedel 2003;Sidikov 2004;Kuzio 2005;Way 2005;Melnykovska and Schweickert 2008). The concentration of resources in the hands of just a few after the fall of the USSR created oligarchic societies in Eastern Europe, and oligarchic clans have a large stake in political and economic change. ...
... The concentration of resources in the hands of just a few after the fall of the USSR created oligarchic societies in Eastern Europe, and oligarchic clans have a large stake in political and economic change. These clans, therefore, play an integral role in institution building and party politics (Melnykovska and Schweickert 2008). Important changes in power came with the Orange Revolution in Ukraine, notably the decrease in executive power and an increase in legislative power. ...
Article
After 15 years of political stagnation, the colour revolutions in Ukraine and Georgia ushered in hopes of democratic progress. However, the failure of political parties to institutionalise and party systems to facilitate legitimate, political competition has stalled democratisation. Fatherland in Ukraine and United National Movement in Georgia rose to political prominence with democratic promises, but poor party infrastructure, unclear ideological foundations, political agendas driven by personal interest, and lack of reification resulted in weak party institutionalisation. Weak party institutionalisation is mediated by under-/over-institutionalised party systems which have led to substantial democratic deficits in both countries almost a decade later.
... Entering the 21st century, the alliance between Ukrainian oligarchs and political elites became more entrenched, exhibiting an intertwined and symbiotic relationship. In the 2002 parliamentary elections, oligarchs like Akhmetov and Kolomoisky provided funding to help several pro-oligarch parties become the largest parliamentary faction [2]. In return, they gained the privilege of appointing loyalists in the government and state-owned enterprises, further expanding their power. ...
Article
This article investigates the role of Ukrainian oligarchs in shaping the country’s foreign policy decision-making process. The study examines the emergence and consolidation of the oligarch class following Ukraine's independence and the privatization reforms of the 1990s. Using a historical and political analysis approach, the article explores how oligarchs have built their economic and political networks, which allowed them to influence Ukraine's external relations through lobbying, media manipulation, and international business expansion. The results highlight that, while oligarchs have shaped foreign policy, their actions often prioritized personal or group interests over national objectives, complicating policy coherence. In the context of de-oligarchization reforms and the Russia-Ukraine conflict post-2014, the article finds that, although their influence has been constrained, oligarchs continue to play a significant role in foreign affairs. The article concludes by offering insights into the persistent and evolving influence of oligarchs on Ukraine’s foreign policy, emphasizing the complexity of their involvement within a shifting political landscape.
... In Ukraine, where the major media owners are business people who draw most of their profits from other industries, the government offers similar benefits for media loyalty (excluding state advertising) but tailors them to the owners' main businesses-metals, gas, banking, and so on. 18 Thus Ukrainian oligarchs who own media outlets exchange information support for the government for privileges given to their key businesses (Mediasapiens 2012 For all these reasons, big media owners often cooperate with the state in preventing the media from holding the authorities accountable. This phenomenon usually results in what Richter (2008) called "in-house censorship"-obstruction of the publication or transmission of journalistic output that the powers that be will not like. ...
Article
Full-text available
Despite relatively progressive laws on the books, Ukrainian media have been "captured" by the state and by private business owners who use their outlets in pursuit of political ends.
Chapter
The preceding chapters have already told a self-contained story, in an essentially chronological way, of economic developments in Ukraine since independence. Part III of the book will retell this story from a thematic perspective, analysing five key issues and challenges faced. The challenges are not simply individual stories, but are closely interrelated; indeed, the sequence is itself important. This chapter begins by asking what were the consequences of reforms being delayed for three years until the autumn of 1994.
Book
Heiko Pleines untersucht im Rahmen einer Analyse der Politikfelder Agrarpolitik, Kohlerestrukturierung und Privatisierung den Einfluss von Wirtschaftslobbies auf die Politik vergleichend für Polen, Russland und die Ukraine. Der Schwerpunkt der Analyse liegt dabei auf Reformblockaden, d.h. es wird untersucht, unter welchen Bedingungen die Einflussnahme nichtstaatlicher Akteure eine politische Entscheidungsfindung verhindert. Ein besseres Verständnis der Ursachen und Formen von Reformblockaden stellt einen wesentlichen Beitrag zur Erklärung politischer Entscheidungsprozesse dar.
Article
The transition from communism in Europe and the former Soviet Union has only sometimes led to democracy. Since the crumbling of the Berlin Wall in 1989 and the collapse of the Soviet Union in 1991, twenty-eight mostly new states have abandoned communism. But only eight - the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Slovenia, and just last year, Croatia - have entered the ranks of liberal democracies. The remaining majority of new postcommunist states are various shades of dictatorships or unconsolidated “transitional” regimes. Why? Why did some states abandon communism for democracy, while others for authoritarian rule? Why are some states stuck in between? The answers to these questions should be easy for political science. Simultaneous regime change in two dozen countries - all beginning from roughly similar places, but moving along very different trajectories over ten years - provides the perfect parameters to test extant theories and develop new hypotheses about regime change. Clear variation on the dependent variable with a finite set of independent variables offered up a unique laboratory to isolate causal patterns. A decade since the collapse of European communism, however, theory development regarding regime change has advanced only slightly. At the beginning of the decade, Adam Przeworski pointed to the inability to predict communism’s collapse as a “dismal failure of political science.” Yet, the paucity of plausible explanations for regime patterns in the postcommunist world ten years later stands as an even greater indictment.
Article
Explaining the huge difference in average incomes between the world's richest and poorest nations is one of the most fundamental issues in development economics. How did this vast gulf emerge, and can anything be done to reduce it? To answer these questions, we can seek guidance from three strands of thought. First, there is a long and distinguished line of theorizing that assigns a preeminent role to geography. Geography is the key determinant of climate and of natural resource endowments, and it can also play a fundamental role in the disease burden, transport costs, and extent of diffusion of technology from more advanced areas that societies experience. It therefore exerts a strong influence on agricultural productivity and the quality of human resources. Recent writings by Jared Diamond and Jeffrey Sachs are among the more notable works in this tradition. A second view emphasizes the role of international trade as a driver of productivity change and income growth. We call this the integration view because it gives participation in the larger global economy-and impediments to participation-a starring role in fostering economic convergence between rich and poor regions of the world. The globalization debate, of course, is to a large extent about the merits of this integration view. Finally, a third view centers on institutions-in particular, the role of property rights and the rule of law. In this view, what matters are the rules of the game in a society, as defined by prevailing explicit and implicit behavioral norms and their ability to create appropriate incentives for desirable economic behavior.
Article
Early growth theory from the time of the Solow model focused on factors of production and their productivity, and led to econometric estimates of the sources of growth measuring just these factors. Revived interest in growth as exemplified by Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995) attempted to inquire about a much wider range of conditions which contribute to greater factor accumulation and productivity. Johnson and Subramanian (2005) note that to answer this question "attention has turned increasingly to institutions"; their paper provides a useful recent survey of the links between growth and institutions. This link has also received considerable attention in the transition literature starting with the ex ante debates between gradualists and big-bang proponents , which may be most usefully seen as a debate on the on the sequencing of stabilization, liberalization and institution building. This vast literature is reviewed in Kolodko, 2004. So far only a small number of empirical studies of this link have been done and generally at a fairly broad level. (Moers 1999, Havrylyshyn and van Rooden 2002, Beck and Laeven 2005).This paper builds on the latter addressing three aims: describing the path of institutional development followed in three transition countries, Belarus, Russia and Ukraine; situating their achievements in comparison to other transition economies in the region; and providing a tentative assessment of the role that institutions have played in the CIS growth recovery. The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 reviews the empirical literature on determinants of recovery in transition, including in particular macrostabilization, liberalization, and institutional development. Section 3 provides some measures of institutional progress in the three countries and compares them to trends in other groups of transition economies, while Section 4 addresses the relationship between growth on the one hand and the three key determinants noted. The issue of the post-2000 surge of growth in the CIS is discussed here as well. Finally Section 5 summarizes what is known and what remains unclear on the institutions-growth link for transition economies.
Article
Post-communist democracy promotion has been most important in “borderline” countries, which had less favorable structural conditions than the East-Central European frontrunners, but where a domestic democratic constituency nevertheless existed and could benefit from Western support. External democracy promotion efforts have ranged from “soft” diplomatic pressure to economic and military sanctions and have acted through a variety of channels: (1) promotion of democratic attitudes among citizens yearning for Western integration, (2) political incentives for elites (in government and in the opposition), (3) domestic power balance shifts in favor of democratic politicians, and (4) promotion of better democratic governance through incentives for public administration reform. The most effective approach to democracy promotion thus far, however, has been the combination of political conditionality with significant political/economic incentives, best exemplified by the European integration process. Furthermore, the success of any strategy hinges on its fit with the geopolitical and domestic environment of the country in question. In particular, external actors must be more sensitive to the national sovereignty implications of such interventions, which can be easily exploited by domestic antidemocratic actors to undermine democracy promotion efforts.