ArticlePDF Available

Does a Lack of Health Insurance Elicit an Increase in the Rate of Voluntary Military Enlistment in the U.S.? The “Military Health Care Magnet Hypothesis,” 1974-2007

Canadian Center of Science and Education
International Business Research
Authors:

Abstract

This study addresses a question that has not been researched much previously, namely, does the unavailability of health insurance act as an incentive for persons to enlist in the military in the U.S.? This relationship is proffered as the “Military Health Care Magnet Hypothesis.” The present study endeavors to provide insight into this issue within a cost-benefit framework. The empirical analysis uses annual data for the years 1974 through 2007, the only years to date for which all of the variables in the model are dependable after the end of military conscription in the U.S. in 1973. Both OLS and 2SLS results demonstrate, among other things, that the greater the percentage of the civilian population without health insurance, the greater the rate of enlistment in the U.S. Army.
International Business Research January, 2010
13
Does a Lack of Health Insurance Elicit an Increase in the Rate
of Voluntary Military Enlistment in the U.S.?
The “Military Health Care Magnet Hypothesis,” 1974-2007
Richard J. Cebula (Corresponding Author)
Department of Economics
Armstrong Atlantic State University
Savannah, Georgia, U.S.A
E-mail: Richard.Cebula@armstrong.edu
Usha Nair-Reichert
Department of Economics
Georgia Institute of Technology
Atlanta, Georgia, U.S.A
E-mail: Usha.Nair@gatech.edu
Kyle Taylor
Department of Economics
Armstrong Atlantic State University
Savannah, Georgia, U.S.A
E-Mail: cebulari@mail.armstrong,edu
Abstract
This study addresses a question that has not been researched much previously, namely, does the unavailability of health
insurance act as an incentive for persons to enlist in the military in the U.S.? This relationship is proffered as the
“Military Health Care Magnet Hypothesis.” The present study endeavors to provide insight into this issue within a
cost-benefit framework. The empirical analysis uses annual data for the years 1974 through 2007, the only years to date
for which all of the variables in the model are dependable after the end of military conscription in the U.S. in 1973.
Both OLS and 2SLS results demonstrate, among other things, that the greater the percentage of the civilian population
without health insurance, the greater the rate of enlistment in the U.S. Army.
Keywords: Military enlistment, Health insurance unavailability, Cost-benefit model
1. Introduction
In recent years, various dimensions of the health care industry have attracted considerable attention. The topics debated
range from hospital costs, profitability, and efficiency issues to medical malpractice to physician staffing to the health
care inflation rate (Chirikos, 1998-99; Daniels and Gatsonis, 1999; Given, 1996; Glied, 2003; Goodman and Stano,
2000; Hart et al., 1997; Jordan, 2001; Karsten, 1995; Koch, 1992; Okunade, 2001, 2003; Olsen, 1996).One of the most
important and contentious issues in U.S. healthcare that has received the greatest increase in attention in recent years is
health insurance coverage (Bharmal and Thomas, 2005; Bundorf and Pauly, 2002; Cebula, 2006; Dushi and Honig,
2003; Frick and Bopp, 2005; Gruber, 2003; Harris and Keane, 1999; Holahan et al, 2003; Kronick and Gilmer, 2002;
Marstellar et al, 1998; de Meza, 1983; Newhouse, 1994; Nyman, 2003; Swartz, 2001; 2003).
This tremendous scrutiny and debate can be attributed to several reasons. Presumably, as argued in Dushi and Honig
(2003, p. 252), at least part of this increased attention can be attributed to the fact that there has been a noticeable
decline in health insurance coverage over the last two decades. Indeed, over a decade ago, Cutler (1994, p. 20) had
observed that “About 15 percent of the population…are uninsured.” More recently, for the year 2003, Bharmal and
Thomas (2005, p. 643) observe that the number of uninsured reached 43.6 million or 17.3 percent of persons under the
Vol. 3, No. 1 International Business Research
14
age of 65. Even more recently, Frick and Bopp (2005) also emphasize that 17 percent of this population is without
health insurance.
To provide perspective, “economic” concerns can in effect largely be categorized into those relating to efficiency issues
and those relating to equity issues. The topic of the percent of the population without health insurance effectively falls
into both of these categories. From a purely financial perspective, those persons without health insurance create an
efficiency problem in that the healthcare system must, in the final analysis, “balance its books,” i.e., payments for the
uninsured must somehow be made. At issue is the efficiency/equity question of having those with private insurance
and/or some other entity (be it government, taxpayers in general, or other source of funds) pay for the medical care of
those without health insurance. From the perspective of medical care per se, one provocative issue is whether or not
those without health insurance receive the same quality and quantity of medical care as those with health insurance. It
could be argued that those without health insurance should not receive the same level and quality of medical care
because their revealed preference/demand for health insurance is lower and therefore they value health care at a lower
level than the medically insured do. This argument might seem substantive if in fact not having health insurance merely
reflected health insurance preferences as opposed to limited purchasing power/income and/or other constraints to
obtaining health insurance. For whatever reason, the percent of the U.S. population without health insurance is an issue
of considerable political interest, as evidenced by the major health care reform pursued by the Obama administration in
2009.
The present study seeks to provide at least preliminary insights into a very different dimension of the overall health
insurance issue. In particular, this study empirically investigates what is proffered here as the Military Health Care
Magnet Hypothesis.” In particular, this study hypothesizes that the greater the percentage of the civilian population that
is without health insurance, the greater the incentive at the margin for civilians to enlist in the U.S. military, ceteris
paribus. In the interest of relevance, the study period runs from 1974 through 2007, thereby beginning with the first full
year after the end of military conscription (the “draft”) in the U.S. and controls for the Gulf War of 1990 and the wars in
Iraq and Afghanistan. We adopt a cost-benefit framework to empirically test this hypothesis. We include as independent
variables factors such as the percent of the civilian population without health insurance, measures of real income growth
in the U.S., the percent of the population with a “veteran” status, the risks associated with military service during
ongoing military conflicts, and other factors that are relevant to the enlistment decision process. Both OLS and 2SLS
results provide considerable support for the central health care insurance/enlistment hypothesis.
2. Review of Related Literature
Before providing the framework and results of the present study, we review briefly some of the recent published
literature on health insurance coverage determinants on the one hand and on military enlistment determinants on the
other hand. Beginning with the former, the following observation by Swartz (2003) is relevant. In particular, Swartz
(2003, p. 283) makes the observation that, simply put, many of those who do not have health insurance “…simply
cannot afford to purchase it…” Swartz (2003, p. 283) proceeds to observe that many households “…cannot afford to
purchase health insurance unless it is heavily subsidized.” Swartz (2003, p. 283) also claims that most of those
households that “…do not have access to employer-sponsored coverage…must purchase…health insurance in the
non-group [individual] market…where insurance is typically twice as expensive [to the household] as employer-group
coverage…,” where the likelihood of purchasing health insurance is lower than otherwise (because of “the law of
demand”).
In the study by Dushi and Honig (2003), the focus involving healthcare insurance is rather different. In particular, in
Table 1 of their study, Dushi and Honig (2003, p. 253) provide evidence on gender differences in the propensity to
purchase group health insurance when the latter is available. Their data reveal that, overall, females in the labor force
tend to have a lower “take-up” rate than males in terms of health insurance plans: 73 percent of the time for females
versus 88 percent of the time for males. Dushi and Honig (2003) argue that some significant portion of this male-female
take-up disparity is attributable to married women opting to rely on a spouse’s health insurance plan. This male-female
take-up disparity notwithstanding, when a health insurance plan is available through the employer, nearly three-fourths
of the time women do take advantage of the option. Moreover, the presence of labor unions appears to increase health
insurance availability.
Newhouse (1994) approaches the question regarding the propensity of the elderly to purchase health insurance from a
different perspective. He observes that that most of the U.S. population age 65 and older are covered by Medicare. He
also stresses that as a person advances in years, so does the incidence of health problems. Given the limitations on
Medicare coverage, Newhouse (1994, p. 7) observes that many elderly persons regard Medicare coverage as insufficient
to meet their needs. Indeed, apparently because of the latter consideration, Newhouse (1994, p. 7) finds that “…over 80
percent of Medicare beneficiaries…had some form of supplemental health insurance, with a third having individually
purchased insurance.”
International Business Research January, 2010
15
The study by Frick and Bopp (2005) is concerned with the fact that between 15 and 20 percent of the U.S. population
do not have health insurance. Frick and Bopp (2005) observe that the classic utility-insurance model makes it patently
clear that having a very low income can seriously restrict the ability to purchase health insurance. The Frick and Bopp
(2005) study not only focuses on the effects of poverty on health insurance purchases but also on other factors. Frick
and Bopp (2005) deals with pooled cross-sectional/time series data, with the empirical estimation process revealing the
following: the percent of the population without health insurance is an increasing function of the percent of the
population whose income lies below the poverty level, the percent of the population that is female, and the percent of
the population with only a high school diploma, with the first of these three variables being the most dominant.
Finally, the study by Cebula (2006) uses an aggregate state-level cross-section data set to examine the percent of the
population without health insurance in the year 2000, and includes as an explanatory variable a measure of the effects
of being either self employed or an independent contractor. The most interesting finding is that the percent of the
population without health insurance is an increasing function of the percent of the population that is either self
employed or independent contractors. The study also concludes that the percent of the population without health
insurance is a decreasing function of median family income and the percent of the population age 65 and older and an
increasing function of the percent of the population that is Hispanic. Thus, a basic conclusion found in the Cebula (2006)
study involves the inability of people to afford health insurance, as found in Frick and Bopp (2005).
The political basis and economics of the military draft and the subsequent formation of the AVMF (all-volunteer
military force) are set forth in a series of insightful, original studies by Tollison (1970) and by Tollison, Amacher,
Miller, Pauly, and Willett (1973). Beyond the scope of these studies, Seeborg (1994) conducted a provocative study
based on data derived from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth, in which he concluded that the probability of
enlistment is directly related to minority and poverty status, while controlling for ability and a number of other
socioeconomic background variables. In addition, the Seeborg (1994) analysis of poverty “transitions” shows that a
very large percentage of enlistees in the early 1980s who were living in poverty at age 17 had escaped poverty by 1990,
i.e., that the military can serve as a mechanism for upward economic mobility for disadvantaged youth.
Segal, Bachman, and O’Malley (1999) study the differences in the propensity to enlist of various subgroups of potential
enlistees into the U.S Military. The analysis furthers the idea that black youth regard the military as a vehicle for
upward social and economic mobility. Hence black youth are more likely to enlist in the military compared to white
youth. Furthermore the presence of a military parent, military grandparent or a military sibling within the family
increases the propensity of a potential enlistee to enlist. This is consistent at least in principle with recent studies such as
Kleykamp (2006) and Cebula, Menon, and Menon (2008), that find the institutional and cultural presence of the
military within an area has a significant influence on enlistment decisions.
Warner, Simon, and Payne (2003) conclude that civilian job opportunities are the key consideration for high school
graduates when pondering the decision to enlist. Although post high school educational opportunities and access played
a role in such a decision, it was the overall economic opportunity available that was the most significant factor in an
enlistment decision, especially among rural youth.
A very relevant recent study by Kleykamp (2006) highlights three areas of influence on military enlistment: individual
educational goals; the institutional presence of the military in communities (as observed above); and race and
socioeconomic status. The study was conducted in the state of Texas and based on individual survey data. The study
analyses the relative risk ratios associated with each choice made by a potential enlistee.
Lastly, a study by Cebula, Menon, and Menon (2008) provides panel least squares (PLS) evidence at the state level for
factors influencing military enlistment. This study deals with data for the 2003 through 2005 period and finds that,
consistent with Kleykamp (2006) and Segal, Bachman, and O’Malley (1999), the stronger the institutional and cultural
presence of the military within an area, the greater the proportion of the age-eligible population that enlists in the
military. Furthermore, Cebula, Menon, and Menon (2008) also find that the greater the opportunity costs to military
enlistment, the lower the enlistment rate, a finding consistent with Warner, Simon, and Payne (2003), as well as
Seeborg (1994). Moreover, this study also finds a higher casualty rate as discouraging military enlistment.
Our review of the literature indicates that the lack of health care coverage reflects substantially the inability of the
people to afford healthcare costs. The military could serve as an avenue to improve one’s socio-economic status,
especially when the opportunity cost is low and alternate opportunities are scarce. One important way in which the
military could contribute to an individual’s well being is by providing health care. Hence the argument that in an era
of rising heath care costs access to health care through the military could provide an important incentive to enlist. The
flip side of this issue is also poses an interesting question: If our hypothesis were indeed to be true, how would
universal health care coverage impact military enlistment?
3. The Basic Framework
The basic framework adopted in this study focuses on the decision to enlist in the U.S military as a cost-benefit decision.
In particular, the decision to enlist in the military, Denlist, is predicated upon the expected net benefits of enlistment,
Vol. 3, No. 1 International Business Research
16
ENBenlist. The latter is treated as an increasing function of the expected gross benefits of enlistment, EGBenlist, and a
decreasing function of the expected gross costs of enlistment, EGCenlist, such that:
ENBenlist = f(EGBenlist, EGCenlist), DenlistEGBenlist > 0, DenlistEGCenlist < 0 (1)
Naturally, as evidenced in the studies referenced in the literature review above, there are a number of variables that
typically are expected to exercise an influence over enlistment rates. To begin addressing these, the first focus is on the
EGBenlist, where:
EGBenlist = g (economic benefits, Family/Cultural benefits) (2)
The central hypothesis being empirically tested in this study is that the greater the percentage of the population without
health insurance [UNINS], the greater the propensity to enlist [ENLIST] in the U.S. military, ceteris paribus. This
hypothesis, dubbed here as the Military Health Care Magnet Hypothesis, is based fundamentally on the fact that those
enlisted in the U.S. armed forces, along with their immediate families (spouse, children) receive free medical care
provided through the military. Given the increased proportion of the U.S. population without health insurance since
1974, free medical care provided by the armed forces should act as an attraction/incentive to potential enlistees, i.e.,
increase the EGBenlist. Alternatively stated, the expected economic benefits associated with enlistment are expected to be
greater the higher the percentage of the population without health insurance (UNINS), ceteris paribus. This is because
enlistment brings with it health care without any health insurance premiums. Thus, the higher the percentage of the
population without health insurance, the greater the EGBenlist level.
In addition, the “family/cultural benefits” of enlistment are expected to be greater in an environment which has a higher
presence of persons who are military veterans (Kleykamp, 2006; Segal, Bachman, and O’Malley, 1999; Cebula, Menon,
and Menon, 2008). This is because enlistment is viewed as a socially approved and admired behavior and presumably
receives positive psychological reinforcement, encouragement, and social approval in environments with a higher
percentage of the population being veterans (PVET). Thus, the family/cultural benefits from enlistment are an
increasing of PVET, ceteris paribus.
Hence, (2) initially becomes:
EGBenlist = g (UNINS, PVET), gUNINS > 0, gPVET > 0 (3)
The level of EGCenlist is expected to be an increasing function of opportunity costs of enlistment. These opportunity
costs can be measured by potential economic opportunities from non-enlistment sources, measured here in the broad
sense by the percentage growth rate of real GDP, GRRGDP. Accordingly, in principle paralleling Warner, Simon and
Payne (2003) and Cebula, Menon, and Menon (2008), based on opportunity-cost reasoning, it is hypothesized that
EGCenlist is an increasing function of GRRGDP, ceteris paribus.
Furthermore, it is also expected that risk-averse behavior would treat a greater degree of risk in the form of the greater
probability of being seriously wounded or a fatality under wartime conditions, namely, in the Gulf War of 1990, the
War in Afghanistan, and in Operation Iraqi Freedom, WARRISK, as elevating EGCenlist, ceteris paribus (Cebula,
Menon, and Menon, 2008). Hence, the EGCenlist is initially expressed as:
EGCenlist = h (GRRGDP, WARRISK), hGRRGDP > 0, hWARRISK >0 (4)
Substituting from (3) and (4) into (1) yields the following:
ENBenlist = f (UNINS, PVET, GRRGDP, WARRISK),
fUNINS > 0, fPVET > 0, fGRRGDP < 0, fWARRISK < 0 (5)
4. The Empirical Analysis
Based on the model expressed in (5), the following model is to be estimated initially:
ARMYRECRt = a0 + a1 UNINSt-1 + a2 PVETt-1 + a3 GRRGDPt-1 + a4 WARRISKt + μ (6)
where (data sources in parentheses):
ARMYRECRt = the number of army recruits in year t, as a percentage of the U.S. population in year t (National
Priorities Project Database, 2008);
a0 = constant;
UNINSt-1 = percentage of the civilian U.S. population without health insurance coverage in year t-1 (U.S. Census
Bureau, 1976; 1978; 1980; 1984; 1987; 1990; 1994; 1996; 1998; 2001; 2003; 2004; 2005; 2006; 2008; 2009);
PVETt-1 = the percentage of the U.S. population who have served in the U.S. military as of year t-1 (Congressional
Research Service, 2008; Council of Economic Advisors, 2009, Table B-34);
GRRGDPt-1 = the percentage growth rate of real GDP (expressed in year 2000 dollars) over year t-1 (Council of
Economics Advisors, 2009, Table B-4);
International Business Research January, 2010
17
WARRISKt = a binary dummy variable =1 for the year 1990 (first Gulf War) and the years of the Wars in Afghanistan
and Iraq; and
μ = stochastic error term.
The study period runs from 1974 through 2007. Basic descriptive statistics are provided in Table 1. The ADF and PP
unit roots tests reveal that three of the variables in this initial specification are not stationary in levels: one
(ARMYRECR) is stationary only in first differences; one (UNINS) is stationary in only second differences; and one
(PVET) is stationary in levels but with a trend variable. The variable GRRGDP is stationary in levels. The ADF and PP
results are provided in Table 2. Accordingly, in the estimate of equation (6), ARMYRECR is expressed in first
differences, UNINS is expressed in second differences, and a TREND variable is included. The data deals with total
annual number of army recruits in the US, hence it is not possible to distinguish by gender or race at the aggregate level.
Table 3, column (a) provides the results for our baseline model. We find that all four of the estimated coefficients
exhibit the hypothesized signs, with three statistically significant at the one percent level and one statistically significant
at five percent level. In addition, the TREND variable is statistically significant at the one percent level. The estimated
coefficient on the ΔPVET variable is positive (as expected) and statistically significant at the three percent level,
implying that an environment where there is a greater concentration of veterans is conducive to a greater propensity to
enlist in the U.S. Army (Segal, Bachman, and O’Malley, 1999; Kleykamp, 2006; Cebula, Menon, and Menon, 2008).
Consistent in principle with Seeborg (1999) Warner, Simon, and Payne (2003), and Cebula, Menon, and Menon (2008),
the estimated coefficient on the GRRGDP variable is negative and statistically significant at the one percent level. This
finding implies that the stronger the growth rate of the economy, the higher the opportunity costs of enlistment and the
lower the net benefits thereof and hence the lower the rate of enlistment. Next, the coefficient on the WARRISK
variable is negative and statistically significant at the one percent level. The latter finding implies that volunteers for
U.S. Army duty are deterred from enlisting during actual war-time conditions, presumably because of the perceived
higher risks of being either seriously wounded or killed in military engagements (Cebula, Menon, and Menon, 2008).
Finally, there is the finding for the key health care variable. The estimated coefficient on the variable UNINS is positive
and statistically significant at the one percent level, implying that the greater the percent of the civilian population
without health insurance, the greater the propensity for eligible young men and women to enlist in the U.S. Army. Thus,
this result provides strong empirical support for the “Military Health Care Magnet Hypothesis.”
We test for the robustness of our baseline model with three alternate specifications, the results of which are reported in
columns (b), (c) and (d) of Table 3. We include the following additional variables in these specifications (data source in
parentheses):
POPPRESt-1 = the Presidential job approval rating in year t-1, an index that ranges from
0 to 100 (Gallup Poll, 2008);
TERRORt = a binary variable for the terrorist attach of September 11th: TERRORt = 1 for the year 2001 and = 0
otherwise;
COLLEGEt-1 = percentage of the adult population age 25 and older with at least a bachelors degree in year t-1 (U.S.
Census Bureau, 1976; 1978; 1980; 1984; 1987; 1990; 1994; 1996; 1998; 2001; 2003; 2004; 2005; 2006; 2008; 2009).
If a given U.S. President is very popular, his policies, including actual or potential military policies, may attract
enlistees who “believe” in his cause. Alternatively, under certain conditions, even if temporary, there may be expected
benefits from enlistment if a potential enlistee experiences or expects to experience greater self esteem from serving
his/her country. For example, after the terrorist attacks on U.S. soil on September 11th of 2001, a surge of patriotism
seemingly swept across the nation and at some level united Americans. Thus, the experience of terrorism on September
11th of 2001 (TERROR) and the manifestation of a popular President (POPPRES) each may act to increase the expected
benefits of enlistment, ceteris paribus. Finally, the greater one’s educational attainment, the greater one’s labor force
options. Hence, the greater proportion of the population with a college degree, the less appealing military enlistment
will be (Seeborg, 1999: Warner, Simon, and Payne, 2003), ceteris paribus.
In Table 3, column (b), the variable POPPRES is included in the model; in column (c), the variables POPPRES and
TERROR are included in the model; finally, in column (d), all three of the additional variables [POPPRES, TERROR,
and COLLEGE] are included the model. In all three columns, the estimated coefficients on these additional variables
fail to be statistically significant at even the ten percent level. On the other hand, the estimated coefficients on the four
basic explanatory variables, UNINS, PVET, GRRGDP, and WARRISK continue to exhibit their expected signs;
furthermore, nine of these 12 coefficients are statistically significant at the one percent level, one is statistically
significant at the five percent level, and the remaining two are statistically significant at approximately the six percent
level. Thus, there appears to be strong evidence that the Army recruitment rate is an increasing function of the PVET
variable and a decreasing function of the GRRGDP and WARRISK variables. This conclusion is strengthened by the
Vol. 3, No. 1 International Business Research
18
fact that the coefficient on the UNINS variable is positive and statistically significant at the one percent level in all three
estimates.
As an additional robustness check, we also consider the possibility that there is no reason to expect that there exists a
significant time lag between the influence of either (a) the presence a military parent, military grandparent, and/or a
military sibling or (b) a stronger institutional and cultural presence of the military on the one hand and the decision to
enlist in the Army on the other hand (Segal, Bachman, and O’Malley, 1999; Kleykamp, 2006; Cebula, Menon, and
Menon, 2008). Thus, the analysis now investigates the Military Health Care Magnet Hypothesis under the condition that
ARMYRECR and PVET are contemporaneous.
Given that ARMYRECR and PVET are being treated as contemporaneous, the possibility of simultaneity bias arises.
Accordingly, the analysis undertakes a 2SLS (two-stage least squares) estimation, with the instrumental variable being
the two-year lag of the unemployment rate of the civilian labor force, URt-2 (Council of Economic Advisors, 2009,
Table B-42). This variable was the instrument of choice because (a) URt-2 is highly correlated with PVETt and (b) URt-2
is also not correlated with the error terms in the system.
The following equation is now estimated by 2SLS with the Newey-West (1987) heteroskedasticity correction:
ARMYRECRt = b0 + b1 UNINSt-1 + b2 PVETt + b3 GRRGDPt-1 + b4 WARRISKt +μ (8)
The results are presented in Table 3, column (e); all four of the estimated coefficients exhibit the expected signs and are
statistically significant at the one percent level. The DW and Rho statistics imply the absence of any serious
autocorrelation problems. Finally, the F-statistic is statistically significant at the one percent level, attesting to the
overall strength of the model.
Thus, it can be reasonably inferred that the U.S. Army enlistment rate is positively impacted by a stronger institutional
and cultural presence of the military (Segal, Bachman, and O’Malley, 1999; Kleykamp, 2006; Cebula, Menon, and
Menon, 2008). In addition, the greater the growth rate of real GDP, the lower the enlistment rate (Seeborg, 1999;
Warner, Simon, and Payne, 2003; and Cebula, Menon, and Menon (2008). Furthermore, it can be inferred that wartime
conditions and the associated greater expected risk of being seriously wounded or killed create a disincentive to enlist
(Cebula, Menon, and Menon, 2008). Finally, the coefficient on the health insurance variable is positive and highly
statistically significant, implying strong support for the “Military Health Care Magnet Hypothesis.” Clearly, these 2SLS
findings are all consistent with the OLS findings.
5. Conclusion
This study addresses the following question: “Does the unavailability of health insurance act as a incentive for persons
to enlist in the military?” Within a cost-benefit framework, the present study endeavors to provide insight into this issue,
referred to here as the “Military Health Care Magnet Hypothesis”. The OLS and 2SLS results provide substantial
evidence that the greater the percentage of the civilian population without health insurance, the greater the rate of
enlistment in the U.S. Army. Voluntary enlistment in the U.S. Army also is positively impacted by a greater presence of
military veterans (which “promotes” enlistment). Furthermore, it is negatively impacted by a more rapidly growing
economy (a proxy for higher opportunity costs) and military conflicts/wars (risk-averse behavior with military conflict
being a risk factor that elevates the expected probability of being wounded or killed). Thus, the AVMF (all-voluntary
military force) market appears to function as the free enterprise system would expect.
Finally, it may be worthy of note that if the “Military Health Care Magnet Hypothesis” is valid, then it logically follows
that if a system of de facto universal health care is in fact instituted in the U.S., there may be unforeseen externalities
from a military recruitment perspective. In particular, implementation of universal health care would naturally result in
a decline in the expected gross benefits of enlistment. This is because would-be enlistees will factor the same into their
cost-benefit analysis of whether to enlist. Clearly, as the AVMF market factors the availability of universal health care
outside the confines of the military into its marginal enlistment decision calculus, for many the expected net benefits (of
enlisting) will decline sufficiently as to create a no-enlist decision. In turn, it follows that some form of additional
incentives will be needed in order to induce sufficient recruitment/enlistment. We contribute to the debate on universal
health care coverage by pointing out the possibility for an unintended consequence, namely a decline in military
enlistment. Thus if universal health care is instituted, it could increase the cost of military recruitment in the future.
References
Bharmal, M. and Thomas, J. III. (2005). “Health insurance coverage and health-related quality of life: analysis of 2000
Medical Expenditure Panel Survey Data,” Journal of Health Care for the Poor and Underserved, 16 (4), pp. 643-654.
International Business Research January, 2010
19
Bundorf, M.K. and Pauly, M. (2002). “Is health insurance affordable to the uninsured?” Working Paper 9281,
Cambridge, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research, October.
Cebula, R.J. (2006). “A further analysis of determinants of health insurance coverage,” International Advances in
Economic Research, 12 (3), pp. 1-8.
Cebula, R.J., Menon, S and Menon, M. (2008). “Military enlistment: a preliminary panel data set analysis, 2003-2005,”
Review of Business Research, 7 (3), pp. 9-16.
Chirikos, T.N. (1998-99). “Further evidence that hospital production is inefficient,” Inquiry, 35 (4), pp. 408-416.
Council of Economic Advisors. (2009). Economic report of the President, 2009.
Washington, D.C., U.S. Government Printing Office.
Congressional Research Service. (2008) Report for Congress: instances of use of United States armed forces abroad,
1798-2007.
Cutler, D.M. (1994). “A guide to health care reform,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8 (3), pp. 13-29.
Daniels, M.J. and Gatsonis, C. (1999). “Hierarchical generalized linear models in the analysis of variations in health
care utilization,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 94 (445), pp. 29-42.
Dushi, I. and Honig, M. (2003). “Price and spouse’s coverage in employee demand for health insurance, “ American
Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 93 (2), pp. 252-256.
Frick, K. and Bopp, A. (2005). “Poverty, insurance theory and the medically uninsured,” Atlantic Economic Journal, 33
(4), pp. 515-523.
Gallup Poll. (2008). Presidential Job Approval: at
http://www.gallup.com/poll/1723/Presidential-Job_Approcal-Depth.aspx (accessed May 30, 2009).
Given, R.S. (1996). “Economies of scale and scope as an explanation of merger and output diversification in the health
maintenance organization industry,” Journal of Health Economics, 15 (4), pp. 685-713.
Glied, S. (2003). “Health care costs: on the rise again,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17 (2), pp. 125-148.
Goodman, A.C. and Stano, M. (2000). “HMOs and health externalities: a local public good perspective,” Public
Finance Review, 28 (3), pp. 247-269.
Gruber, J. (2003). “Evaluating alternative approaches to incremental health-insurance expansion,” American Economic
Review Papers and Proceedings, 93(2), pp. 271-276.
Harris, K.M. and Keane, M.P. (1999). “A model of health plan choice: inferring preferences and perceptions from a
combination of revealed preference and attitudinal Data,” Journal of Econometrics, 89 (1-2), pp. 131-157.
Hart, L., Wagner, E., Pirzada, S, Nelson, A.F. and Rosenblatt, R. (1997). “Physician staffing ratios in staff-model
HMOs: a cautionary tale,” Health Affairs, 21 (1), pp. 55-70.
Holahan, J., Nichols, L.M., Blumberg, L.J. and Shen, Y.-C. (2003). “A new approach to risk-spreading via
coverage-expansion subsidies,” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 69(2), pp. 277-282.
Iraq Coalition Casualties Count Database. (2008). Fatalities data: at http://icasualties.org/oif/ (accessed May 29, 2009).
Jordan, W.J. (2001). “An early view of the impact of deregulation and managed care on hospital profitability and net
worth,” Journal of Healthcare Management, 46 (1), pp. 161-71.
Karsten, S.G. (1995). “Health care: private good vs. public good,” The American Journal of Economics and Sociology,
54 (2), pp. 129-144.
Kleykamp, M. A. (2006). “College, jobs, or the military? Enlistment during a time of war,” Social Science Quarterly,
87 (2), pp. 272-290.
Koch, J.V. (1992). “A note on smoking health costs and public policy,” The American Journal of Economics and
Sociology, 51 (2), pp. 159-60.
Kronick, R. and Gilmer, T. (2002). “Insuring low-income adults: does public coverage crowd out private?” Health
Affairs, 21 (1), pp. 225-239.
Marstellar, J.A., Nichols, L.M.; Badawi, A., Kessler, B.,Rajan, S. and Zuckerman, S. (1998). “Variations in the
uninsured: state and county analyses.” Research Report, Washington, D.C., The Urban Institute.
deMeza, D. (1983). “Health insurance and the demand for medical care,” Journal of Health Economics, 2 (1), pp.
47-54.
National Priorities Project Database. (2008). Recruiting data: at http://nationalpriorities.org/ (accessed June 2, 2009).
Vol. 3, No. 1 International Business Research
20
Newey, W. and West, K. (1987). “A simple positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent
covariance matrix,” Econometrica, 55 (3): 703-708.
Newhouse, J.P. (1994). “Symposium on health care reform,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8 (3), pp. 3-11.
Nyman, J. (2003). The theory of demand for health insurance. Stanford, CA, Stanford University Press.
Okunade, A. A. (2003). “Are factor substitutions in HMO industry operations cost saving?” Southern Economic Journal,
69 (4), pp. 800-821.
Okunade, A.A. (2001). “Cost-output relation, technological progress, and clinical activity mix of U.S. hospital
pharmacies,” Journal of Productivity Analysis, 16 (1), pp. 167-193.
Olsen, R.N. (1996). “The reform of medical malpractice law: historical perspectives,” The American Journal of
Economics and Sociology, 55 (3), pp. 257-275.
Seeborg, M. C. (1994). “Race, poverty and enlistment: some evidence from the National Longitudinal Survey of
Youth,” The Journal of Economics, 1 (1), pp. 15-24
Segal, D. R., Bachman, J.G., Freedman-Doan, P. and O’Malley, P. (1999). “Propensity to serve in the U.S military:
secular trends and sub-group differences,” Armed Forces and Society, 25 (3), pp. 407-427.
Swartz, K. (2001). “Markets for individual health insurance: can we make them work with incentives to purchase
insurance?” Inquiry, 38 (2), pp. 133-145.
Swartz, K. (2003). “Reinsuring risk to increase access to health insurance,” American Economic Review Papers and
Proceedings, 69 (2), pp. 283-287.
Tollison, R. (1970). “The political economy of the military draft,” Public Choice,10 (1), pp. 67-78.
Tollison, R., Amacher, R., Miller, J., Pauly, M. and Willett, T. (1973). The Economics of the MilitaryDraft. Morristown,
NJ, General Learning Press.
U.S. Census Bureau. (1976). Statistical Abstract of the United States, various issues 1976 to 2009, Washington, D.C.,
U.S. Government Printing Office.
Warner, J. T., Simon, C. J. and Payne, D.M. (2003). “The military recruiting productivity slowdown: the roles of
resources, opportunity cost, and the tastes of Youth.” Defense and Peace Economics, 14 (4), pp. 329-342
White, H. (1980). “A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity,”
Econometrica, 48 (3), pp. 817-838.
White House. (2008). Past Presidents: at http://www.whitrhouse.gov/history/presidents/ (accessed June 3, 2009).
Table 1. Basic Descriptive Statistics
Table 2. ADF and PP Unit Root Test Results
*Critical value for rejection of null hypothesis at 95 percent confidence level = -2.89.
International Business Research January, 2010
21
Table 3. Estimation Results for ΔARMYRECR
Terms in parentheses are t-values. Δ is the first differences operator;
ΔΔ is the second differences operator.
***indicates statistically significant at one percent level.
**indicates statistically significant at five percent level.
*indicates statistically significant at ten percent level.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
This article introduces a health maintenance organization (HMO) model that characterizes HMO decisions on enrollment, utilization levels, and quality. Facing global budgets dependent on revenue raising capacity, HMOs must determine standards of care and the corresponding premiums to cover costs. Revenues are allocated among HMO providers by gatekeepers who are often subject to strict utilization controls. The authors' model identifies various uncompensated health and pecuniary externalities that may result from patient disenrollments, thereby affecting treatment costs. As a result of these externalities, HMOs may provide less than socially efficient levels of care, and they may also enroll less than socially efficient numbers of members. The model also predicts that HMOs may promote socially cost-inefficient treatment options for conditions in which multiple options are available.
Article
Full-text available
The fairly recent discovery and growing use of costly, revolutionary biotechnology drugs (e.g., GM-CSFs) in hospitals represent a major technical innovation in clinical pharmacy intervention. This paper models the translog production cost impacts of ten distinct clinical pharmacy tasks including pharmacokinetics, consultations with MDs, monitoring drug interactions,..., and presents results on decomposed technical change, economies of scope, scale economies, total factor productivity, and the alternatively defined pairwise factor substitution possibilities. The model was fitted to 1981–1990 time-series/cross-sectional data of US hospital pharmacies (source: Eli-Lilly Co.). Zellner's ISURE (Iterative Seemingly Unrelated Regression Equations) system estimates reveal a non-homothetic underlying technology with biased and pure technical change effects dominating scale-augmentation. Certain clinical tasks increase costs but are cost-saving if jointly produced with selective others. One of the largest and statistically significant economies of scope estimates is between monitoring drug interactions and consultations with MDs. Cost implications of findings are given in light of the recent trends in hospital pharmacy clinical activities, related professional health manpower, and piecemeal health policy reforms.
Article
With rare exceptions the provision of actuarially fair health insurance tends to substantially increase the demand for medical care by redistributing income from the healthy to the sick. This suggests that previous studies which attribute all the extra demand for medical care to moral hazard effects may overestimate the efficiency costs of health insurance.
Article
In recent years many studies have reported large differences in the use of medical treatments and procedures across geographic regions, hospitals, and individual health care providers. Beyond reporting on the extent of observed variations, these studies examine the role of contributing factors including patient, regional, and provider characteristics. In addition, they may assess the relation between health care processes and outcomes, such as patient mortality, morbidity, and functioning. Studies of variations in health care utilization and outcomes involve the analysis of multilevel clustered data; for example, data on patients clustered by hospital and/or geographic region. The goals of the analysis include the estimation of cluster-specific adjusted responses, covariate effects, and components of variance. The analytic strategy needs to account for correlations induced by clustering and to handle the presence of large variations in cluster size. In this article we formulate a broad class of hierarchical generalized linear models (HGLMs) and discuss their applications to the analysis of health care utilization data. The models can incorporate covariates at each level of the hierarchical data structure, can account for greater variation than what is allowed by the variance in a one-parameter exponential family, and permit the use of heavy-tailed distributions for the random effects. We develop a Bayesian approach to fitting HGLMs using Markov chain Monte Carlo methods and discuss several methods for model checking. The HGLM analysis is presented in the context of two examples of applications to the study of variations in the utilization of medical procedures for elderly Medicare beneficiaries who sustained a heart attack. The first example involves the analysis of clustered longitudinal data with binomial responses and examines geographic and temporal trends in the utilization of coronary angiography across the United States during the 4-year period 1987–1990. The second example involves the analysis of multilevel, clustered data with Poisson responses and examines hospital variations in the utilization of coronary artery bypass graft surgery in 1990. The HGLM analysis incorporates state-level and hospital-level covariates and makes it possible to estimate covariate effects and cluster-specific rates of utilization for both hospitals and states.
Article
Economists have given considerable attention to the allocative and distributive effects of the military draft) The common trademark of these studies is the acceptance of the draft as a given political institution which has a predictable opportunity cost impact on the individual and when aggregated on society. This approach is methodologically analogous to the neo-classical treatment of tax institutions which was characterized by the lack of expenditure considerations and more generally by the lack of consideration of the political origin of fiscal institutions 2 Modern public finance scholarship has abandoned this asymmetrical and simplified methodology. The theoretical integration of tax and expenditure processes and the political origin of fiscal institutions are now problems of the first order of concern. The object of this paper is to analyze the military draft using this more modern methodology. Particular emphasis will be placed on the development of a model which explains in a very simplistic way the political origin and stability of a military draft in a democratic setting. The paper is divided into four parts. Section I presents an individualistic choice model of the draft in a referendum-type democracy. Section II relaxes the assumptions of the model to show how the introduction of more realistic collective conditions tends to reinforce the choice process depicted in the model. Section III discusses the distributional implications of eliminating the draft and what these implications in turn imply for the political adjustment process required to abolish the draft. Section IV concludes with mention of other implications of the model. I. THE MODEL The immediate task is to set forth the assumptions of the analysis which serve to simplify the collective environment of the model to manageable proportions. As will be noted, however, the divergencies between the individualistic model and the world are not large. The model should possess explanatory power. First, a referendum-type democracy where each issue must be considered by the voters is assumed. Individuals in the model base their voting behavior on how they expect the draft issue to affect their present wealth positions. Second,
Article
I am pleased to report that the American economy today is strong. We are enjoying the longest economic expansion ever recorded, with more than 22 million new jobs since 1993, the lowest unemployment rate in 30 years, the lowest female unemployment rate in 40 years, the lowest Hispanic and African-American unemployment rates ever recorded, and the highest home ownership rate on record. This economic expansion has been not only unusually long, but also broad and deep. For the first time in decades, wages are rising at all income levels. We have the lowest child poverty in 20 years and the lowest poverty rate for single mothers ever recorded. Since 1993 the median family income has gone up more than 6,000,andforAfricanAmericanfamiliesithasrisenevenmore.Thenumberoffamilieswhoownstockhasgrownby40percent.Ourcurrenteconomicstrengthistheresultnotofchance,butofachoicetheAmericanpeoplemade8yearsago.Atthattime,10millionofourfellowcitizenswereoutofwork.Interestrateswerehigh.TheFederalbudgetdeficitwas6,000, and for African-American families it has risen even more. The number of families who own stock has grown by 40 percent. Our current economic strength is the result not of chance, but of a choice the American people made 8 years ago. At that time, 10 million of our fellow citizens were out of work. Interest rates were high. The Federal budget deficit was 290 billion and rising. And the Federal debt had quadrupled in the previous 12 years, imposing a crushing burden on our economy and on our children.
Article
A bstract The major stimulus for the extensive, state level, reform of medical malpractice during the past two decades was the widespread belief in a malpractice crisis. The perception of a crisis arose in the 1960s largely because of what was viewed as sudden and dramatic increases in the malpractice liability of physicians. However, historical data demonstrate that the common perception that physician liability increased suddenly and dramatically beginning in the 1960s Is incorrect. Since malpractice reform has been based upon the false premise that the medical malpractice liability system, previously working smoothly, was in disarray, the soundness of much of the malpractice reform which has occurred in the past two decades is questioned.