ArticlePDF Available

The Fiscal Theory of Income Distribution in Action: South African Low-Income vs High-Income Earners Response to Fiscal Policy Shocks

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

ScannThis study seeks to test the fiscal theory of income distribution in action in South Africa using low- and high-income earners, covering the period 1979–2022, using the Bayesian Vector Autoregression (BVAR) model with hierarchical priors. This study examines the impact of fiscal policy on income distribution among low-income and high-income earners. The results are interesting as they show that the impact of the Fiscal Theory of Income Distribution depends on the level of income, as the finding shows that for low-income earners, an unexpected increase in government expenditure decreased income inequality, while for the high-income, it exacerbated income inequality. While on the side, taxation is found to play a significant role in reducing income inequality for the high-income earners model, while for the low-income earners it was found to contribute to income inequality.The lagged response suggests that expectations and market dynamics play a crucial role in reducing income inequality regardless of income level. This study suggests that South Africa should adopt a balanced tax policy by combining progressive income taxes with targeted regressive taxes, while offsetting the burden on low-income groups through rebates, credits, and social programs. This would ensure an equitable distribution of burdens across income levels, with revenue from progressive taxes used to fund social welfare programs, such as education, healthcare, and affordable housing. This approach could reduce the wealth gap, promote social mobility, and create a more just society, making it an effective solution for income inequality in the country.
Content may be subject to copyright.
The views expressed are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those of the funder, ERSA or the author’s affiliated
institution(s). ERSA shall not be liable to any person for inaccurate information or opinions contained herein.
The Fiscal Theory of Income Distribution
in Action: South African Low-Income vs
High-Income Earners Response to Fiscal
Policy Shocks
Lindokuhle Talent Zungu
ERSA working paper 898
January 2025
The Fiscal Theory of Income Distribution in Action: South African Low-
income vs. High-Income Earners Response to Fiscal Policy Shocks
Lindokuhle Talent Zungu1
Abstract
This study seeks to test the fiscal theory of income distribution in action in South Africa using
low- and high-income earners, covering the period 1979–2022, using the Bayesian Vector
Autoregression (BVAR) model with hierarchical priors. This study examines the impact of fiscal
policy on income distribution among low-income and high-income earners. The results are
interesting as they show that the impact of the Fiscal Theory of Income Distribution depends on
the level of income, as the finding shows that for low-income earners, an unexpected increase in
government expenditure decreased income inequality, while for the high-income, it exacerbated
income inequality. While on the side, taxation is found to play a significant role in reducing income
inequality for the high-income earners model, while for the low-income earners it was found to
contribute to income inequality.The lagged response suggests that expectations and market
dynamics play a crucial role in reducing income inequality regardless of income level. This study
suggests that South Africa should adopt a balanced tax policy by combining progressive income
taxes with targeted regressive taxes, while offsetting the burden on low-income groups through
rebates, credits, and social programs. This would ensure an equitable distribution of burdens across
income levels, with revenue from progressive taxes used to fund social welfare programs, such as
education, healthcare, and affordable housing. This approach could reduce the wealth gap, promote
social mobility, and create a more just society, making it an effective solution for income inequality
in the country.
Keywords: BVAR, Fiscal Theory of Income Distribution, Hierarchical priors, Monetary policy,
South African
1 Department of Economics, Faculty of Commerce, Administration and Law, University of Zululand,
Kwadlangezwa 3886, South Africa; zungut@unizulu.ac.za or zimiseleb@yahoo.com
1. Introduction
Undoubtedly, growing income inequality within and among countries has become a significant
global issue that has been steadily increasing over the past few decades (United nation, 2020). This
global issue has become a defining challenge for the United Nations Sustainable Development
Goals. The gap between the wealthy elite and the rest of the population continues to widen, leading
to social unrest, economic instability, and overall dissatisfaction among the masses, which
subsequently undermines investment and life-improving public policy reforms (Jenkins, 2017;
Piketty and Saez, 2003). The World Inequality Report 2022 reveals that the wealthiest 10% of the
global population currently holds 52% of the global income, while the poorest half holds 8.5%
(Chancel et al., 2022, p. 10). South Africa is one of the most unequal societies with a Gini
coefficient of 0.67, which is one of the highest in the world (United nation, 2020). Historical
factors, such as apartheid and colonialism, are believed to exacerbate the divide between the rich
and the poor, where the top 1% of earners in the country control almost 20% of the nation's income,
while the bottom 60% struggle to make ends meet (Coady and Dizioli, 2018; Nolan et al., 2019).
Further support is shown in Figure 1, which shows the top 1%, top 10%, and top 50%.
Figure 1. Graphic analysis of the trend of pre-tax national income of Share top 1%, top 10% and
the top 50% respectively starting from 1980–2022.
Source: Author’s calculation based on wid world data (2024).
This extreme level of inequality has far-reaching consequences, including limited access to quality
education, healthcare, and economic opportunities for most of the population. Givin the
highlighted the inequality issue, and efforts to combat this issue of a high income gap between the
rich and the poor within and among countries have been considered through various structural and
policy-oriented changes; however, the issue seems to further undermine the policy effort.
Fiscal Theory of Income Distribution (FTID) is a key concept in economics, arguing that
fiscal policy decisions significantly impact income distribution within a society (Lerner, 1943;
Tobin, 1965; Diamond, 1971; Keynes, 1936; Lucas,1988). This theory is crucial, as nations
address economic growth, social equity, and fiscal sustainability, emphasizing the need to
understand how different population segments respond to fiscal policy shocks. This study explores
the fiscal policy transmission dynamics across income groups in South Africa, examining whether
policy shocks would have a beneficial effect on low-income and high-income earners in South
Africa. South Africa's fiscal policy and income distribution are influenced by historical
inequalities, with income inequality remaining high despite progress since the 1994 Democratic
transition (IMF, 2020). The key pillars of South Africa's redistributive agenda include progressive
income taxes, social grants, and public expenditures on education, healthcare, and social services.
Understanding these interactions can help in designing more effective policies for financial
stability and equal-income distribution.
The literature on this subject has revealed two strands of research in these subject
matter. The first strand, based on the fiscal theory of income distribution, argues that fiscal policy
through government expenditure is detrimental to income inequality (Moene and Wallerstein,
2003; Samanta & Cerf, 2009; Bhatti et al., 2015; Aye and Odhiambo. 2022; Abramovsky and
Selwaness, 2023; Gunasinghe et al., 2020; Smith, 2024; Kebalo & Zouri, 2024). The second strand
builds on taxation as a policy that promotes redistribution of income (Gupta et al., 2014; Cevik
and Correa-Caro, 2020; Gupta and Jalles, 2022; Malla and Pathranarakul, 2022; Wienk et al., 2022;
Brown et al., 2023; Carneiro, 2023; Laura Abramovsky and Selwaness, 2023). The heterogeneity
in results can be attributed to various issues such as the model specifications, data sets, and
estimating methodologies used in existing literature and crises, which has led to numerous studies
creating a paradox in the current subject matter empirical wise.
This study builds on the seminal work of numerous studies, such as the study by Gupta et
al. (2014), Cevik and Correa-Caro (2020), Malla and Pathranarakul (2022), and Aye and
Odhiambo (2022). However, the variables are adopted from the study by Aye and Odhiambo
(2022) using data from 2010 to 2018 in a middle-income country. Their study uses the Generalized
Method of Moments (GMM) to analyze two fiscal policy measures: government expenses and
taxes on income, profits, and capital gains. This study contributes to the existing literature by
investigating the fiscal theory of income distribution in action for the South African low-income
and high-income earners. The idea is to trace how inequality for low-income earners and high
earners will respond to fiscal policy shocks. The study seeks to further compute two variables for
fiscal consolidation: time-varying Cyclically Adjusted Primary Balance (CAPB) for government
expenditure and total government revenue, adopting the similar method adopted by Buthelezi and
Nyatanga (2023). The main aim of comparing the two income earners is to trace the income group
that benefits the most from the fiscal policy shock. Therefore, this study used Bayesian Vector
Autoregression (BVAR) with hierarchical priors, covering the period 1979–2022 due to data
availability. The BVAR is constructed with hierarchical priors in response to two measurable
defects: when the data quality is uncertain, and when it is frequently short (ie, observation less
than 30). Thus, prior selection in a BVAR can help adjust for these flaws. Furthermore, the impulse
response function is more accurate when the present matter is estimated using Bayesian
approaches. Banbura et al. (2010) argue that Bayesian vector autoregression (BVAR) is a useful
tool for large dynamic models because of its credibility, structural analysis, dynamic relationships,
uncertainty accounting, modeling interdependencies, time-series analysis, and flexibility.
Therefore, as in the current study, we address the dynamic impact of socioeconomic issues. The
researcher believes that these kinds of issues have structural characteristics, which is why we find
the BVAR suitable for this study. BVAR allows for simultaneous estimation, which is useful in
dealing with uncertainty in parameter estimation and further constructing the impulse response.
This model tests the following hypotheses: (i) the fiscal theory of income distribution does not
hold for the South African economy, (ii) income tax creates more inequality than tax on goods and
services, (iii) the theory of income distribution is more beneficial to high-income earners than to
low-income earners, and (iv) fiscal consolidation variables are more beneficial to low-income
earners.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 provides a brief overview of the
literature on the subject, and Section 3 provides a summary of our model. Section 4 explores the
BVAR results, and Section 5 concludes and discusses policy implications.
2. Literature review
2.1.Fiscal theory of income distribution
Fiscal Theory of Income Distribution (FTID) is a framework that examines how government fiscal
policies impact income distribution within a society. This concept was developed by economists
over time with early proponents such as Lerner (1943). Modern formulations have been attributed
to Tobin (1965), Diamond (1971), Keynes (1936), and Lucas (1988). Their research and theoretical
frameworks have deepened our understanding of how fiscal policies influence income distribution
and contribute to the evolution of FTID as a field of study within economics. Despite not having
a single individual credited with its creation, FTID remains a significant area of research. FTID
suggests that fiscal policies, including taxation, government spending, and public debt
management, shape the distribution of income among individuals and households. Tax policies
can redistribute income by imposing higher taxes on higher-income individuals, while providing
tax breaks or credits to lower-income groups. Government spending programs such as welfare,
healthcare, and education can directly affect income distribution by providing assistance to those
in need. The FTID also emphasizes the role of public debt in the dynamics of income distribution.
Governments often finance spending through borrowing, which can have redistributive effects
(Lerner, 1943; Tobin, 1965; Diamond, 1971; Keynes, 1936; Lucas,1988). For example, if a
government borrows to finance social welfare programs, it effectively redistributes income from
future taxpayers to current beneficiaries of government spending (Keynes, 1936). Financial
policies are not neutral in their distributional effects, as they can either exacerbate or mitigate
income inequality (Gupta and Jalles, 2022). For instance, tax cuts that disproportionately benefit
the wealthy can widen income disparities, whereas targeted spending on education or healthcare
can help reduce inequality by improving opportunities for lower-income individuals. Critics argue
that FTID oversimplifies the complex interactions between fiscal policies and income distribution,
ignoring other factors, such as technological change, globalization, and labor market dynamics.
However, FTID provides valuable insights into the relationship between government fiscal
policies and income distribution, guiding policymakers in designing more equitable economic
policies (Diamond, 1971; Keynes, 1936; Lucas,1988).
2.2.Empirical studies on Fiscal Theory of Income Distribution (FTID) and income inequality
Fiscal policy, which includes taxation and government expenditure, plays a crucial role in shaping
income distribution and reducing income inequality within society, as explained by FTID (Cevik
and Correa-Caro, 2020; Aye and Odhiambo, 2022; Gupta and Jalles, 2022;Aye and Odhiambo,
2022; Brown et al., 2023; Carneiro 2023). Progressive taxation policies can redistribute wealth,
whereas regressive policies can exacerbate inequality. Government spending on social welfare
programs, education, and healthcare can also help reduce income inequality by providing resources
and opportunities to those in lower-income brackets. Overall, fiscal policy plays a significant role
in shaping the income distribution within a society. Studies on the impact of fiscal policy on
income inequality have been based on the two stands that build on taxation policy as a means of
reducing income redistribution (Muinelo-Gallo and Roca-Sagalés, 2013; Gupta et al., 2014; Cevik
and Correa-Caro, 2020; Aye and Odhiambo, 2022; Gupta and Jalles, 2022; Malla and
Pathranarakul, 2022; Wienk et al., 2022; Aye and Odhiambo, 2022; Brown et al., 2023; Carneiro
2023; Abramovsky and Selwaness, 2023); The second strand are those studies that believe in
redistribution policy (Moene and Wallerstein, 2003; Samanta & Cerf, 2009; Bhatti et al., 2015;
Heshmati, and Kim. 2014; Aye and Odhiambo., 2022; Abramovsky and Selwaness, 2023;
Gunasinghe et al., 2020; Smith, 2024; Kebalo & Zouri, 2024).
These studies suggests that progressive taxation can reduce income inequality, especially
when combined with redistribution policies (i.e government expenditure) (Odhiambo, 2022; Gupta
and Jalles, 2022; Malla and Pathranarakul, 2022; and Wienk et al., 2022). This is because high-
income earners often have lower marginal propensities to consume, which can be reduced by
lowering their disposable income, according to studies by Aye and Odhiambo (2022), Gupta and
Jalles (2022), Malla and Pathranarakul (2022), and Wienk et al. (2022). Progressive taxation when
it accompanied by other distributive measures can reduce income inequality by raising the
purchasing power of those with lower incomes and boosting economic activity by reducing wealth
concentration (Muinelo-Gallo and Roca-Sagalés 2013; Carneiro 2023). However, some studies
claim that goods and service taxes do not reduce income inequality; only income taxes do (Malla
and Pathranarakul, 2022). Debates exist over the ideal progressivity of tax structures and the
possible compromises between promoting economic expansion and mitigating inequality.
Emerging economies are affected by this issue (Dotti 2020, Muinelo-Gallo, and Lescano 2022).
According to Dix-Carneiro et al. (2022), high tax rates can hinder economic expansion and job
creation by deterring investment, entrepreneurship, and hard labor.
The balance between improving economic efficiency and decreasing inequality is an
ongoing topic of discussion. Social spending programmes and redistributive payments can address
income inequality by supporting low-income households. Social assistance, unemployment
insurance, and welfare programs can help reduce poverty and economic inequality. Research
shows a connection between social spending and economic equality, with more spending in Latin
American countries leading to reduced economic disparities (Cimoli et al., 2017). Incorporating
education into social expenditure plans can have a negative and significant impact (Celikay and
Gumus, 2017; Gründler and Scheuermeyer, 2018).
Income distribution is influenced by income replacement programs, such as disability,
sickness pay, unemployment insurance, and occupational illness (Moene and Wallerstein, 2003;
Gunasinghe et al., 2020). Social expenditure on education and human capital development predicts
income disparity. Fiscal policies supporting access to high-quality education and skill development
can increase human capital development, labor market results, and income inequality. According
to Moyo et al. (2022), educational attainment plays a significant role in wealth distribution, and
reducing economic disparity requires equitable access to education and addressing the skill gaps.
Artige and Cavenaile (2023) argued that equitable public education can significantly reduce wealth
disparity across different national categories.
Macroeconomic policies, economic growth, and income inequality are interconnected.
Fiscal measures, such as infrastructure and R&D, can improve income distribution, but factors
such as labor market structures, skill-biased technological advancement, and development
methods also influence economic growth distribution (Rezk et al., 2022). Fiscal policy design
significantly affects income inequality, particularly in foreign direct investment. Financial
development moderately influences money distribution, making foreign direct investment less
effective as a nation reaches certain growth levels (Lee and Wang, 2022; Ofori et al., 2023). The
impact of fiscal policies on income inequality is influenced by the political economy and
institutional issues. Inclusive political institutions, strong institutions, effective tax administration,
and transparency can reduce income inequality (Zuazu, 2022). Improved democratic institutions,
removal of bureaucratic barriers, high-quality legal and regulatory systems, control of corruption,
and governance can also reduce income disparity. Political polarization can negatively impact
income distribution (Kouadio and Gakpa, 2022). Fiscal policy and income disparity are influenced
by tax laws, social spending, human capital investments, macrofiscal policies, and institutional
variables. Investments in education, social spending, and progressive taxation can help reduce
economic disparities (Gu and Wang, 2022).
3. Methodology and data used for the study.
3.1.Justification of variables
This study uses data from the to 1979-2022 time series to test the validity of the Fiscal Theory of
Income Distribution in the South African economy using the BVAR model with hierarchical
priors, following the works of Ebalo and Zouri (2024), Malla and Pathranarakul (2022), Cevik and
Correa-Caro (2020), and Gupta et al. (2014). Economic variables in this paper are reflected in
Table 1, where two indexes of the Gini coefficient have been adopted to capture income inequality:
the top 1% of pre-tax national income and the top 50% of pre-tax national income. A measure of
income inequality that captures income before tax is preferable for this study for various reasons.
i) It helps to capture the role of fiscal policy in reducing income inequality, and ii) disposable
income significantly influences individual borrowing decisions, investments, and
consumption. These two variables are the central economic variables of interest when investigating
the fiscal theory of income distribution in action on the South African low- and high-income
earners. It serves as the anchor for understanding how fiscal policy impacts income inequality for
both low- and high income earners in South Africa. These two income indices are adopted to
compare how low- and high-income earners respond to the Fiscal Theory of Income
Distribution. For fiscal policy, the study adopted distributional and taxation variables accounting
for both progressive and regressive taxes. For distributional variables, this study adopted
government expenditure captured by total government expenditure (% GDP) (Malla and
Pathranarakul, 2022), and government health expenditure captured by total expenditure on health
(% GDP) (Zungu, 2024). According to the results documented by Zungu (2024), using machine
learning through the random forest algorithm, governmental health expenditure was found to be a
strong determinant of income inequality. All these variables reflect how government spending
decisions directly impact the economy; this would help analyze how income inequality responds
to fiscal policy changes, particularly on the redistribution side. The study utilized both progressive
and regressive taxation strategies; however, with regressive tax, policy adjustments take time.
Table 1. Variables employe for hypothesis testing
Theoretical framework variables
Variable(s) code
Description
Variable for income inequality used to capture low and high income earners

Top 1% of pre-tax national income

Top 50% of pre-tax national income
Variable for fiscal policy fiscal theory of income distribution

Government expenditure on health

Total government expenditure

Income tax
ts
Taxes on goods and services

National government revenue as % of GDP
Economic variables that proxy fiscal consolidation used a discretion of fiscal authorities

Time-varying CAPB for government expenditure

Time-varying CAPB for total government
revenue
Other control variables in the model
em
Real balance
gd
GDP per capita
inf
Inflation
gf
Government effectiveness
cc
Corruption control
Therefore, income tax is captured by the total income tax revenues (% GDP) to control for
progressive tax, while taxes on goods and services are captured using the total revenue raised from
taxes imposed on the consumption of goods and services (% GDP) to control for regressive tax.
The study further adopted two variables for fiscal consolidation: time-varying CAPB for
government expenditure and time-varying CAPB for total government revenue (Buthelezi and
Nyatanga, 2023). This variable provides a detailed analysis of government fiscal policy by
analyzing the cyclically adjusted primary balance for government expenditure, taking into account
economic fluctuations. The tvp variable provides insights into the cyclically adjusted primary
balance for total government revenue, allowing the evaluation of the evolution of fiscal
sustainability and budget constraints over time and their impact on income inequality. While the
study controls for government effectiveness, corruption, National government revenue as % of
GDP (PPR), and the overall level of economic development captured using GDP per capita
(constant 2010 US$). The variables were chosen following the theoretical foundations and
empirical literature that underpin the relationship under investigation.
2 World inequality Database
3 World Development Indicators
3.2.Model specification.
The Bayesian VAR (BVAR) model adopted in the paper is reflected in equation 1.
=++++,
󰇡0, 󰇢 (1)
In the model we have a column vector consisting of 13 endogenous variables, denoted as
,  , ,,, , ,,, ,  and cc. There is 13 × 1 vector represented by ,
which serves as the intercept. On the other hand, we have a 13 ×13 matrix (= 1, , ) that
contains autoregressive coefficients for the regressors, where is the order the BVAR. Finally,
is a 13 × 1 vector comprising Gaussian exogenous shocks characterized by a zero mean and a
variance-covariance matrix denoted as . The total number of coefficients to be estimated in this
model is 13+13
, and this number increases quadratically with the number of included variables
and linearly with the lag order.
The Bayesian methodology employed for the estimation of VAR (Vector Autoregressive)
models effectively addresses a notable constraint by introducing an augmented structural
framework. This augmentation entails the incorporation of prior information, a strategic choice
that has garnered empirical validation in alleviating the curse of dimensionality. Evidenced by the
empirical studies of (Marta et al., 2010), this approach enables the estimation of expansive models.
The utilization of informative priors serves to guide model parameters towards a more
parsimonious reference point, yielding a reduction in estimation errors and a consequent
improvement in out-of-sample projection accuracy, as expounded upon by Koop (2013). Notably,
this process of "shrinkage" bears resemblance to prevalent frequentist regularization techniques,
as delineated in the research of De Mol et al. (2008).
3.3. Selection of hierarchical priors and specification
Informing prior beliefs effectively is crucial, with flat priors often yielding suboptimal results
(Marta et al., 2010). Del Negro and Schorfheide (2004) favored values optimizing data density,
and Marta et al. (2010) addressed overfitting. Giannone et al. (2015) introduced data-driven
hyperparameters in a Bayes' Law as reflected in equation 2 to 3.
(|)(|,)(|)
(2)
(|)(|,)(|) (3)
The equation =+ 1 , defines VAR parameters and hyperparameters . Equation 1
marginalizes Equation 2, yielding a data density function (|) and the marginal likelihood
(ML). ML depends on and informs hyperparameter choice. Giannone et al. (2015) advocate this
empirical Bayes approach, as it robustly explores the hyperparameter space while acknowledging
uncertainty, yielding theoretically sound results when efficiently implemented. In the selected
Normal-inverse-Wishart (NIW) framework we approach the model in Equation 1 by letting =
,,…, and =vec(), then the conjugate prior setup as reflected in equation 4 to 5.
|~󰇡,󰇢 (4)
~(,) (5)
Where , and , , and are all dependent on a lower-dimensional vector of hyperparameters
denoted as . Giannone et al. (2015) considered three priors in their study, which were called the
sum-of-coefficients prior, the single unit-root prior, and the Minnesota (Litterman) prior that is
used as a baseline. The prior is characterized in question 6 to 7.
()|=
1,  =,= 1
0,  
(6)
()()|=󰇱
1

/(1),  =  =
0,  
(7)
Where controls prior influence, with 0 enforcing strict priors and approximating
ordinary least squares. The manages prior standard deviation on variable lags. The Minnesota
prior reduces the deterministic component, while the sum-of- coefficients prior assumes no change
initially, using dummy observations (Giannone et al., 2015). It is implemented via the Theil mixed
estimation by adding artificial dummy observations to the data matrix, which are reflected in
equation 9.
=
+
(1 + )
=[0, ,….,] (9)
In equation 9 is a 13×13 vector of variable averages over the initial observations. Variance is
controlled by , and makes the prior uninformative, as well as 0 leads to unit roots
with no co-integration. The single unit-root (SUR) prior by Sims and Zha (1998) allows co-
integration relations and influences variables accordingly. These kinds of priors, associated with
dummy observations in equation 10.

1
=
+

1(1 + )
=
,, . ,  (10)
where is again distinct, as above, likewise, is the key parameter, governing the tightness of the
SUR prior. Numerous heuristics for determining hyperparameters associated with prior
distributions have been explored in the literature, with notable contributions by Doan et al. (1984)
and Marta et al. (2010). The estimation of these hyperparameters, achieved through the
maximization of the marginal likelihood (ML), embodies an empirical Bayes methodology, as
elucidated by Giannone et al. (2015), offering a distinct interpretation from the frequentist
perspective within the realm of economic analysis.
4. Empirical analysis and interpretation results
This study uses the Bayesian VAR model to examine the response of income inequality to Fiscal
Theory of Income Distribution (FTID) in South Africa from to 1979-2022, utilizing Bayesian
GMM for robustness. Following what has been done in the BVAR literature for model estimation,
the current study follows the transformation of variables following the function documented by
Kuschnig and Vashold (2019). This function deals with numerous transformations within the
system, including stationarity. Furthermore, dealing with fiscal policy analysis, considering the
number of variables used to capture for fiscal policy, it is very difficult to choose the appropriate
variable to capture for fiscal policy, for instance, the total government expenditure (% GDP), the
total expenditure on education (% GDP), and the total expenditure on health (% GDP). Therefore,
following the approach adopted in the literature, this study adopted the results reported by Zungu
(2024), who used machine learning (ML) through the random forest (RF) algorithm (Breiman,
2001) to determine the fiscal policy variable that significantly contributes to income
inequality. The study found that government expenditure on health, total government expenditure,
and education expenditure are significant determinants of income inequality. ML using the RF
format was used to model the study, revealing that the model specification would be in the
following format: gi, gh, tg, ts, tx, itx, tvp, em, gd, inf, gf, cc.
4.1. Data transformation and stationarity
When estimating any model, it is important to ensure that the data are compatible with a
rectangular numeric matrix with no missing data points, as this is a requirement for the BVAR
model. As noted in the methodology, this is a 13 ×13 matrix, considering =,,
,,,, , ,,, , ,. Only gd per capita (gd) is provided in billions
of dollars, with the exception of variables in rates; gi is an index. The study uses Kuschning and
Vashold (2019) and McCracken and Ng (2016) to transform gd to the log level by applying code
44, creating a new variable with the definition of gd. The remaining variables were coded as 1
without transformation. This study uses the Augmented Dickey-Fuller test (ADF) and Phillips-
Perron test (PP) to test for the stationarity of variables, which are crucial for accurate predictive
models in economics, finance, and other fields. The results show that all variables are non-
stationary in levels and stationary after the initial differencing; please see Appendix 1A for more
information on the stationarity requirements. To address this, code 25 with the transformation
function is initiated to transform all variables into first differences, allowing for ADF and PP
results of nonstationarity data in levels. Considering that the study used a yearly time interval, and
in accordance with the Akaike criterion (AIC) and Schwarz (BIC), the research adopted 2 as the
number of lag length for this study.
4.2.The prior setup and configuration
The recent VAR econometric paradigm emphasizes the importance of prior setups in addressing
missing data points and questionable data quality. Traditional maximum likelihood VARs are
overparameterized, leading to a loss of degrees of freedom. Therefore, BVAR was used to address
these limitations. The model setup follows Kuschnig and Vashold's prior setting function
(Kuschnig and Vashold's, 2019), which includes arguments for Minnesota and dummy-
observation priors and hierarchical handling of their hyperparameters. The prior hyperparameter
4 Code 4 is used in the BVAR code to transform the data to stationary 1 is for those variables that do not require
transformation.
5 Code 2 is used in the BVAR code to transform all variables into first differences in accordance with the results of
the ADF and PP results of nonstationarity.
is given lower and upper restrictions for its Gaussian proposal distribution and gamma hyperprior,
but is not treated hierarchically. Following Kuschnig and Vashold's prior setting function, it allows
the outhor to set Ψ to the square root of the innovation variance after fitting the AR(p) models to
each variable. We add a sum-of-coefficients prior to a single unit-root prior, pre-constructing three
dummy observation priors. Essential parameter hyperpriors are allocated gamma distributions
similar to λ. This version of the BVAR provides a character vector.
4.3.Estimation of the model and identification via sign restrictions
The BVAR model requires data preparation and transformation with the order of p as an argument.
Customization settings are required for this function. The initial iterations, burns, and draws are
defined as 1500 000 and 500 000 respectively to allow for model accuracy. The author then set
verbose true, as recommended by Kuschnig and Vashold (2019), as the function shows a progress
bar during the Markov chain Monte Carlo stage (MCMC). Table 2 shows the posterior marginal
likelihood results.
Table 2. Posterior marginal likelihood
Bayesian VAR With no sign restrictions
Bayesian VAR With sign restrictions
Optimisation concluded.
Posterior marginal likelihood: -783.693
Hyperparameters: lambda = 0.43265
|==========================| 100%
Finished MCMC after 10.85 mins.
Optimisation concluded.
Posterior marginal likelihood: -932.553
Hyperparameters: lambda = 0.27747
|=============================| 100%
Finished MCMC after 8.93 mins.
Source: Author’s calculation based on WDI (2024) and SWIID (Solt, 2020) data.
The BVA function returns a BVAR class object that generates outputs, such as hyperparameters,
VCOV matrix, and VAR coefficients. The BVAR object also contained marginal likelihood
values, prior settings, initial hyperparameter values, and established values from the original call
to the BVAR function. This object is hierarchically handled and automatically established. For the
model with the sign restriction, the author follows the identification via sign restrictions. BVAR
uses various schemes, such as sign restrictions, to facilitate the interpretation of impulse response
functions. These schemes are flexible and user-friendly, relying on forming expectations about
response directions following specific shocks (Rubio-Ramirez et al. 2010). Economic theory is
used to set up sign identification of shocks in BVAR, which can be accessed directly or through
the ellipsis argument of irf(). To toggle identification, the author creates a matrix SR with sign
restrictions, setting all elements SRij equal to 1 (-1) if the contemporaneous response of variable i
to a shock from variable j is expected to increase (decrease). Setting elements equal to 0 imposes
zero restrictions, while setting elements to NA allows no restrictions, requiring unique
identification of shocks (Kilian and Lütkepohl 2017). After running the bv-irf() function, the
author prints and chooses the sign restrictions, while irf() calculates IRF using ellipsis arguments.
IRFs are calculated using suitable shocks, following algorithms by Rubio-Ramirez et al. (2010) or
Arias et al. (2018) if zero restrictions are imposed. Table 1A in the appendix shows how the
variables were restricted for the second model, where the impulse responses are reported in Figure
4.
4.3.1. The result of the convergence of Markov chain Monte Carlo in a BVAR model
This section provides an overview and convergence of the model stimation MCMC algorithm,
which is important for stability.
Table 3. Summary of the BVAR model
Bayesian VAR With no sign restrictions
Bayesian VAR With sign restrictions
Bayesian VAR consisting of 29 observations, 13
variables and 2 lags.
Time spent calculating: 10.85 mins
Hyperparameters: lambda
Hyperparameter values after optimisation: 0.43265
Iterations (burnt / thinning): 1500000 (500000 / 1)
Accepted draws (rate): 36322 (0.363)
Bayesian VAR consisting of 29 observations, 12
variables and 2 lags.
Time spent calculating: 8.93 mins
Hyperparameters: lambda
Hyperparameter values after optimisation: 0.27747
Iterations (burnt / thinning): 1500000 (500000 / 1)
Accepted draws (rate): 36913 (0.369)
Source: Author’s calculation based on WDI (2024) and SWIID (Solt, 2020) data.
Table 3 provides a summary of the BVAR models with and without sign restrictions. Arguments
_ and _ provide a concise alternate method for acquiring autoregressive
coefficients.
Figure 2. Trace and density plots of all hierarchically treated hyperparameters and the ml.
Source: Author’s calculation based on WDI (2024) and SWIID (Solt, 2020) data.
The researcher used a reasoned approach to select a visualization technique, as shown in Figure 2,
which displays the density6, trace7, and hierarchical hyperparameter treatments. The analysis
indicates convergence in the critical hyperparameters within the estimated BVAR model, and the
MCMC chain effectively explores the posterior distribution without identifying outliers.
4.3.2. Impulse responses of the Bayesian VAR With no sign restrictions
This study aims to understand how income inequality responds to the fiscal theory of income
distribution and both regressive and aggressive taxes and government expenditure in the South
African economy from 1979- 2022. This is motivated by the fact that the government adopted a
taxation system to achieve two goals: (1) to reduce income inequality by taxing more on those
earning more, and (2) providing a means of revenue collection to fund government expenditures.
The impulse response functions (IRFs) generated from the BVAR using hierarchical selection are
depicted in Figure 3, where the coefficients for the dynamic impact of tg, ge, ts, tx, itx, tvp, em,
gd, inf, gf, and cc on income inequality have been given a tighter hierarchical prior distribution,
with shaded regions representing the 16% and 84% credible sets, respectively. Figure 3a shows
the results of the fiscal theory of income distribution and the impact of government expenditures
6 This Figure presents graphical representations of the density, trace, and hierarchical treatment of hyperparameters. The scrutiny of these density
and trace plots serves as an indicator of the convergence achieved in the critical hyperparameters within the estimated BVAR model.
7 The trace plot, on the other hand, is a time series plot that displays the values of the hyperparameters as the MCMC chain progresses. It allows us
to monitor how the chain traverses the parameter space.
on income inequality. This study adopted variables such as total government expenditure (%
GDP), government education expenditure (Malla and Pathranarakul, 2022), and government
health expenditure (gh) to capture the fiscal theory of income distribution (Zungu, 2024). The
results for both progressive taxes (itx) and regressive taxes (ts) are also included in Figure 3b.
Figure 3a. Generated impulse responses of the income inequality redistributional fiscal policy
from the Bayesian VAR..
Source: Author’s calculation based on WDI (2024) and SWIID (Solt, 2020) data.
As expected, the results in Figure 3a depict that government expenditure appears to be more
instrumental in reducing income inequality, when both Total government expenditure (tg) and
Government expenditure on health (gh) are used a fiscal policy instance8, following a one percent
standard deviation shock to total government expenditure (tg) and attaining a maximum impact of
0.12 seven years after the shock to tg, which then converges immediately, reversing to the steady
state region and dying after 11 years. While for government expenditure on health (gh), it reaches
a maximum impact of 0.03 in 4 years and dying after 10 years. The findings are empirical and
credible with the current literature on the impact of fiscal policy on income inequality, such as
those of Moene and Wallerstein (2003), Samanta and Cerf (2009), Aye and Odhiambo
8 Note that a separate model was estimated to see if there were any differences from the results when both tg and gh
were estimated separately. However, the results were not different from the one reported.
(2022), Abramovsky and Selwaness (2023), Gunasinghe et al. (2020), Smith (2024), and Kebalo
and Zouri (2024).
Figure 3b shows the impact of fiscal policy shocks, captured by regressive and progressive
taxes on income inequality. A positive response is observed after a one percent standard deviation
shock on ts and itx, reaching a maximum impact of 0.02% after three years, which then converges
immediately; however, this does not reach the steady-state region. For itx, it reaches a maximum
impact of 0.10 after 5 years, converges to the steady state, and dies after 12 years. These results
contradict the government's definition of taxation as a revenue-generation tool. The findings of
this study are supported by existing literature on fiscal policy and income inequality, including
studies by Sameti and Rafie (2010), Cevik and Correa-Caro (2015), Balseven and Tugcu (2017),
Demirgil (2018), and William and Taskin (2020) for Iran, China, and Turkey.
Figure 3b. Generated impulse responses of income on taxation variables from the Bayesian
VAR.
Source: Author’s calculation based on WDI (2024) and SWIID (Solt, 2020) data.
This study used time-varying CAPB for government expenditure (tvp) to assess fiscal
sustainability and budget constraints over time, evaluating their impact on income inequality and
total government revenue evolution. The results showed that tvp has a gradually declining impact
on income inequality in both models, reaching a minimum level in five years and -0.02 in two
years, then converges and dies after 12 years and 3 years, respectively, with an asymmetric and
persistent impact, especially in Model 3b.
This study investigates the impact of fiscal policy shocks on income inequality by
controlling for real balance (em) in the model. em, representing the real value of money or financial
assets held by households and firms, plays a pivotal role in the transmission of fiscal policy shocks
to income inequality. The results show that income inequality responds positively to a one percent
standard deviation shock on em, reaching a maximum impact of 0.07 over eight years in model
2a. In Model 2b, the effect occurs four years after the shock on em. The effect declined gradually
and became statistically insignificant after 12 years. The empirical findings in this context support
those of Majumdar and Partridge (2009). In both models, income inequality declines following a
one percent standard deviation shock on GDP per capita (gd), reaching a maximum impact of -
0.09, eight years after the shock on gd. The study also controls for inflation, showing that income
inequality responds positively to a one percent standard deviation shock on inflation (inf) shock,
reaching a maximum of 0.04 eight years after the shock in model 3a. This supports the findings
reported by Ndou (2024) for South Africa and Glawe and Wagner (2024) in a panel of 101
countries.
Lastly, the examination of government effectiveness and corruption control and how it
triggers the current subject matter was undertaken, and the results are reported in Models 2a and
2b. It was found that inequality in low earnings initially improves after a one percent standard
deviation shock, reaching a maximum level of 0.03 after seven years for gf and six years for cc.
The impact converged immediately, reverted to the steady-state region, and died after 12 years.
This result supports the findings of Gupta et al. (1998) pertaining to the impact of corruption and
income inequality.
4.3.3. Impulse responses of the Bayesian VAR with sign restrictions for only fiscal policy
variables
In Figure 3c, the author included sign restrictions in the model for all fiscal policy variables,
considering the definition and fiscal theory of income distribution (FTID) and GDP per capita
given its definition. The negative sign restriction on GDP per capita when modeling fiscal policy
impacts on income inequality serves to highlight how reduced economic output from fiscal
contraction may exacerbate inequality, particularly among lower-income groups. All these
variables were restrained to have a negative shock to income inequality, and the main interest was
to determine how income inequality responds to a simultaneous shock on the fiscal policy variable
given its full definition and considering the level of the country's economy. Table 1A in the
appendix shows how the variables were restricted for this model. The transmission mechanism
using the sign restriction identification method involves imposing constraints on the expected
direction of responses from fiscal variables to shocks, such as government spending or taxation.
This method allows for the identification of how fiscal policy affects income inequality by
observing the signs of the dynamic responses of income distribution and macroeconomic variables.
For example, a positive government spending shock could be expected to reduce inequality, while
a tax cut for the wealthy might increase it. The sign restrictions help isolate causal relationships
and improve the accuracy of the model’s predictions.
Figure 3c. Generated impulse responses of income on taxation variables from the Bayesian
VAR.
Source: Author’s calculation based on WDI (2024) and SWIID (Solt, 2020) data.
What is observed is that the results are not different from what has been reported in Figures 3a and
c. This further suggests that fiscal policy through government expenditure reduces income
inequality in South Africa; however, fiscal policy through taxation instruments failed to achieve
its definition, as it exacerbated income inequality for low-income earners. Fiscal policy
transmission can fail when tax cuts or increases disproportionately benefit higher-income earners,
leaving lower-income groups without relief. This widens the income gap, as the wealthy have more
capacity to save or invest, while lower-income earners experience little improvement in disposable
income. As a result, instead of stimulating broad-based demand, the policy exacerbates income
inequality. In such cases, fiscal policy fails to achieve its goal of equitable economic growth and
poverty reduction.
4.3.4. Impulse responses of the Bayesian VAR for the high income eaners
Fiscal policy significantly impacts high earners' through taxation, government spending, and
regulatory policies, making them sensitive to changes due to their reliance on investments and
business profits.This section of the paper investigates the influence of fiscal policy on high-income
earners, examining how changes in tax rates and government spending affect their economic status
and overall well-being9. Therefore, the researcher utilized the top 10% of the World Inequality
Database to measure income inequality among high-earners. The idea behind the results generated
in Figure 4 was based on the assumption that both high-income and low-income earners receive
benefits from the government.The results drawn from this section are interesting and make
significant contributions to both the empirical literature and useful policy conclusions . Figures 4a
to b show the generated impulse responses of income inequality of the high earner to policy change
from the Bayesian VAR, similar to the variable definition adopted in the first model in Figures 3a
to b. However, for this model sensitivity, an additional variable, time-varying CAPB for
government expenditure (tv), was included as a control variable in the model..
Figure 4a shows that government expenditure (gh) is more effective in accelerating income
levels for high-income households, with a maximum impact of 0.14 five years after a one percent
standard deviation shock, then converges, reverts to the steady state, and dies after 10 years.
The study found that a one percent standard deviation shock to total government
expenditure (tg) had a positive response to income inequality, reaching a maximum impact of
0.005 in four years. This impact increased to 0.18 in a year, then converged, reverted to a steady
state, and died after 12 years. This asymmetric and persistent impact contradicts the fiscal theory
9 High-income earners often benefit from tax breaks, deductions, and subsidies that favor wealth accumulation, such
as capital gains tax rates or tax-exempt investment vehicles, and government policies that enhance access to public
services like education and healthcare through their ability to afford private alternatives.
of income distribution, which suggests fiscal policy as the main means to reduce income
inequality. However, these results are not surprising, as in this section, the focus was on high-
income earners. Government expenditure can accelerate income levels for high-income
households through targeted investments in infrastructure, technology, and financial markets that
primarily benefit high-net-worth individuals and industries. Additionally, subsidies or tax
incentives for businesses owned by wealthier individuals can lead to increased profits and higher
incomes for them.
Figure 4a. Generated impulse responses of the income inequality redistributional fiscal policy
from the Bayesian VAR..
Source: Author’s calculation based on WDI (2024) and SWIID (Solt, 2020) data.
Figure 4b illustrates the impulse responses of income inequality to fiscal policy shocks through
regressive tax (taxes on goods and services) and progressive tax (income tax) using the Bayesian
VAR for goods and services. Interestingly, the study reveals that income inequality decreases after
a one percent standard deviation shock on goods and services taxes (ts), reaching a maximum
impact of 0.08% after 4 years. This converges immediately, reverts to the steady-state region, and
dies after 8 years. The overall effect of ts on income inequality is asymmetric and persistent. The
results further report that income inequality gradually declines after a one percent standard
deviation shock on income tax (itx), attaining a maximum impact of -0.24 four and becoming
statistically insignificant after 12 years.
Figure 4b. Generated impulse responses of the income inequality redistributional fiscal policy
from the Bayesian VAR.
Source: Author’s calculation based on WDI (2024) and SWIID (Solt, 2020) data.
The control variables yielded different results when the same model was used. The study reveals
that income inequality responds to investment in both Models 3a and 3b, as shown in Figures 3a
and 3b. However, income inequality responds oppositely to a shock in Models 2a and 3a, as shown
in Table A2. This is because of the different Gini coefficients used to capture high-income earners,
and the results are consistent across all variables. This exercise was dome for robustness check of
the main models.
For instance, starting with gd, which captures the level of economic development, this
study reveals that economic development, specifically gd, benefits high-income earners, leading
to increased inequality. This effect is accelerated by a one percent standard deviation shock to gd,
reaching a maximum impact of 0.004 within seven years. The impact then converged, reverted to
a steady state, and died after 12 years. The logic behind these results is that economic development
boosts productivity, creating job growth and higher wages for high-earning households10.
Investments in infrastructure and education attract skilled workers, drive innovation and increase
wealth and income. Interestingly, as expected in Model 2, when the study controls for government
effectiveness (gf) and corruption (cc), the study shows that income inequality gradually declines
following a one percent standard deviation shock on government effectiveness and corruption,
reaching a maximum impact of -0.005 four years and -0.005 five years after the shock. The effect
declined gradually and became statistically insignificant after 12 years.
4.3.3 Discussion of the Bayesian VAR results.
Income inequality in South Africa has persisted even during and post apartheid eara, a result of
historical injustices and systemic issues that perpetuate wealth and opportunity disparities.
Therefore, the democratic government has adopted various policy measures to create a more
equitable society, including government expenditure (Zungu, 2024).. This study aims to illustrate
how low-income and high-income earners respond to fiscal policy shocks in South Africa. This is
to determine who benefits the most from fiscal policy, assuming that both high- and low-income
earners benefit from the government.The findings show that government expenditure on health
and social welfare programs in South Africa is beneficial in reducing income inequality. Access
to quality health care is essential for all citizens to lead healthy and productive lives. Addressing
health disparities can improve overall health outcomes, reduce health care costs, and prevent
poverty. This study adopted variables such as total government expenditure (% GDP), government
education expenditure (Malla and Pathranarakul, 2022), and government health expenditure (gh)
to capture the fiscal theory of income distribution (Zungu, 2024).
Allocating resources for health and social welfare programs is a privilege for citizens,
especially in developing countries. Government expenditures on health can indirectly affect
income inequality by addressing the social determinants of health that contribute to disparities in
health outcomes. Investments in education, literacy programs, clean water sanitation, housing, and
employment issues can positively impact overall health and well-being, ultimately helping reduce
income inequality. Social welfare programs, such as social grants, unemployment benefits,
10 Government investments in high-skill industries, innovation, and education boost demand for specialized labour,
creating a competitive labour market and higher wages for skilled professionals and executives
housing subsidies, and food assistance, provide a safety net for individuals and families struggling
to meet ends. These programmes can also help reduce the intergenerational transmission of poverty
by providing opportunities for children and families to access education, healthcare, and other
essential services. The findings are empirical and credible with the current literature on the impact
of fiscal policy on income inequality, such as those of Moene and Wallerstein (2003), Samanta
and Cerf (2009), Aye and Odhiambo (2022), Abramovsky and Selwaness (2023), Gunasinghe et
al. (2020), Smith (2024), and Kebalo and Zouri (2024).
With regard to both forms of taxation,the study reveals that low-income households in
South Africa are most affected by both income tax and goods and services tax. These taxes are
crucial for governments to generate revenue and redistribute wealth; however, their regressive
nature has led to an increase in income inequality. VAT, a consumption tax, is imposed on goods
and services at each production stage, based on an individual’s ability to pay. However, it has a
greater impact on lower-income households, as they tend to spend more on basic necessities, which
are subject to VAT at a standard rate of 15%. The VAT system in South Africa also includes
exemptions and zero-rated items that primarily benefit higher-income households, such as basic
food items, such as fruits and vegetables. An income tax is a progressive tax aimed at ensuring
that higher-income earners contribute more to government revenue for social services and support.
In South Africa, the income tax system is relatively flat, with a top marginal tax rate of 45% applied
to individuals earning over R1.5 million per year. This places the burden of income tax on middle-
income earners, while high-income earners can use tax loopholes and deductions to reduce their
taxable income. However, the Gini coefficient of high-income earners suggests that higher-income
households benefiting from the government increase income inequality. The transmission
mechanism is that government policies benefiting higher-income households disproportionately
increase their wealth and income, thereby increasing the income gap between high-income and
low-income earners, as the benefits are not equally distributed. Consequently, government
interventions that favor wealthier households can exacerbate income inequality, reflected in a
rising Gini coefficient.
Taxation is a key tool in fiscal policy, but it can negatively affect high-income household
income. This is because the progressive nature of the tax system results in higher tax rates, reducing
the overall income of high earners. Additionally, additional taxes, such as the Alternative
Minimum Tax or net investment income tax, can further affect their earnings. This results in less
disposable income for savings, investments, or spending, which can hinder economic growth and
wealth accumulation. The findings of this study are supported by existing literature on fiscal policy
and income inequality, including studies by Sameti and Rafie (2010), Cevik and Correa-Caro
(2015), Balseven and Tugcu (2017), Demirgil (2018), and William and Taskin (2020) for Iran,
China, and Turkey.
5. Conclusion
This study uses Bayesian Vector autoregression to analyze the South African income inequality
response to fiscal policy shocks from 1979 to 2022, providing valuable insights for policymakers
and researchers and offering new insights into the dynamics of the South African economy. First,
the study analyzes the impact of fiscal policy on the income distribution of low- and high-income
earners, examining how changes in tax rates and government spending can impact their economic
status and overall well-being. Contrary to the predictions of the fiscal theory of income
distribution, an unexpected 1% increase in government expenditure results in a decrease in income
inequality, while all forms of taxation positively contribute to income inequality among low-
income earners. Interestingly, with regard to high-income earners, the findings show that income
inequality responds positively following an unexpected 1% increase in government expenditure,
while taxation was found to play a significant role in reducing income inequality as the response
was found to be negative. Second, this study explores how income inequality responds to shifts in
government expenditure. The lagged response of income inequality to unexpected shifts in these
two variables suggests that expectations and market dynamics play a pivotal role in reducing
income inequality, whether it is high or low. These findings underscore the need for coordinated
policymaking.
To address income inequality in South Africa, a balanced tax policy that combines
regressive and progressive measures is recommended, as this could aim to stimulate economic
growth while addressing income inequality. Regressive taxes, such as VAT, disproportionately
affect lower-income individuals, while aggressive taxes, such as higher-income tax rates for the
wealthy, target higher-income individuals. Balancing these taxes ensures an equitable distribution
of the burden across income levels. Revenue from progressive taxes can be used to fund social
welfare programs such as education, healthcare, and affordable housing, thereby reducing the
wealth gap, promoting social mobility, and creating a more just society. This comprehensive,
balanced tax policy could be an effective solution to income inequality in South Africa. The key
difference from existing policies would be ensuring that regressive taxes do not disproportionately
burden the poor while ensuring that progressive taxes are robust enough to fund critical social
welfare programs. This balance could promote both social equity and economic development, a
shift from current policies that often lean too heavily on regressive taxes that exacerbate inequality.
Author Contributions: Conceptualization, LTZ; Methodology, LTZ; Software, , LTZ;
Validation,LTZ; Formal analysis, LTZ; Investigation, LTZ; Data curation, , LTZ; Writing
original draft, LTZ; Writing – review & editing, LTZ; Visualization, LTZ.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Data Availability Statement: Publicly available datasets were analysed in this study. These data
can be found here: [United Nations Office on Drugs Crime UNODC. 2019. Global Study on
Homicide. Vienna. Available online: https://www.unodc.org/gsh/ (accessed on 10 February 2023)
and World Development Indicators WDI. 2023. World Bank. Washington, DC. Available online:
http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators (accessed on 20 February
2023). Further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.
Acknowledgements: We are thankful for the comments we received from the 2023 Imbali
International Conference Department hosted by the University of Zululand (South Africa), as their
comments and criticism were invaluable in improving this paper. We would like to express my
gratitude to my language editor, Mrs H. Henneke, hennekeh@wcsisp.co.za or
herminehenneke@gmail.com, for her valuable and consistent input. Thank you so much.
Conflicts of Interest: The author declares no conflict of interest. Additionally, the funders had no
role in the design of the study; in the collection, analyses, or interpretation of data; in the writing
of the manuscript, or in the decision to publish the results.
References
Abramovsky, L. & Selwaness, I. 2023. ‘Fiscal policy and gender income inequality:the role of
taxes and spending. ODI Working Paper. London: ODI (www.odi.org/en/publications/
Artige, L & Laurent, C. 2023. ‘Public education expenditures, growth and income inequality.’
Journal of Economic Theory 209. DOI: 10.1016/j.jet.2023.105622
Aye,GC & Odhiambo, NM. 2022. ‘Dynamic effect of fiscal policy on wealth inequality: Evidence
from middle-income countries.’ Cogent Economics & Finance 10:2119705-211
Balseven, H. & Tugcu, C. T. 2017. ‘Analyzing the effects of fiscal policy on income distribution:
A comparison between developed and developing countries.’ International Journal of
Economics and Financial Issues 7: 377-383.
Bańbura, M., Giannone, D. & Reichlin, L. 2010. ‘Large Bayesian vector auto regressions.’ Journal
of applied Econometrics 25:71-92.
Bhatti, A.A., Batool, Z, Naqvi, H. 2015. ‘Fiscal Policy and Its Role in Reducing Income
Inequality: A CGE Analysis for Pakistan.’ The Pakistan Development Review 54:843-862.
Breiman, L. 2001. ‘Random forests.’ Machine Learning 45:5-32.
Brown, M.L., Becker, J.M, Carbone, J, Goforth, T, Mcfarland, J, Nock, D, Pitman, K, & Steinberg,
D.L. 2023. ‘Tax Credits for Clean Electricity: The Distributional Impacts of Supply-Push
Policies in the Power Sector.’ National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
Series No. 31621. DO - 10.3386/w3162
Buthelezi, E.M & Nyatanga ,P. 2023. ‘Impact of fiscal consolidation in different states of domestic
government debt in South Africa 1979 to 2022.’ Cogent Economics & Finance 11:
2280326
Carneiro, F.M., Turnovsky, S.J, & Toutinho, O.A.F. 2022. ‘Economic growth and inequality
tradeoffs under progressive taxation.’ Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control
143:104513
Celikay, F & Gumus, E. 2017. ‘The effect of social spending on reducing poverty.’ International
Journal of Social Economics 44:620-632.
Cevik, S & Correa-Caro, C. 2015. ‘Growing (Un)equal: Fiscal Policy and Income Inequality in
China and BRIC+.’ International Monetary Fund, WP/15/68.
https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2016/12/31/Growing-Un-equal-Fiscal-
Policy-and-Income-Inequality-in-China-and-BRIC-42806
Cevik, S &Correa-Caro,C. 2020. ‘Growing (un)equal: fiscal policy and income inequality in China
and BRIC+, Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy, Taylor & Francis Journals 25:634-653
Chancel L., Piketty, T, Saez, E, & Zucman, G. 2022. ‘The report also draws on the extensive work
of researchers associated to the World Inequality Database available at
www.wid.world/team
Cimoli, M., Garriel, P. Antontio, M.N, & Fernando, S. 2017. ‘Productivity, social expenditure and
income distribution in Latin America.’ Brazilian Journal of Political Economy 37:660-679
Coady, D &Dizioli, A. 2018. ‘Income inequality and education revisited: persistence, endogeneity
and heterogeneity.’ Applied Economics 50:2747-2761
Del-Negro, M & Schorfheide,F. 2004. ‘Priors from General Equilibrium Models for VARS.’
International Economic Review 45:643-673
Demirgil, B. 2018. ‘Vergilerin gelir dagilimi uzerindeki etkisi: Ampirik bir calisma.’ Cumhuriyet
Universitesi Iktisadi ve Idari Bilimler Dergisi, 19:118-131.
Diamond, P. A. 1971. ‘A Search for Common Ground in Tax Policy’. The Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 5(3), 45-57.
Dix-Carneiro,R., João, PP, Ricardo, R, & Sharon T. (2023). ‘Globalization, Trade Imbalances, and
Labor Market Adjustment.’ The Quarterly Journal of Economics 138:1109–1171
Doan, T., Litterman, R. & Sims, C. 1984. ‘Forecasting and conditional projection using realistic
prior distributions.’ Econometric reviews 3:1-100.
Dotti, V, 2020. ‘Income inequality, size of government, and tax progressivity: A positive theory.’
European Economic Review 121.
Giannone, D., Lenza, M. & Primiceri, G.E. 2015. ‘Prior selection for vector autoregressions.
Review of Economics and Statistics 97:436-451.
Glawe, L & Wagner, H. 2024. ‘Inflation and inequality: new evidence from a dynamic panel
threshold analysis.’ International Economics and Economics Policy.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-023-00580-x
Gründler, K & Scheuermeyer, P. 2018. ‘Growth effects of inequality and redistribution: What are
the transmission channels?.’ Journal of Macroeconomics 55:293-313
Gu, Y & Wang, Z. 2022. ‘Income Inequality and Global Political Polarization: The Economic
Origin of Political Polarization in the World.’ Journal of Chinese Political Science 27:375–
398.
Gunasinghe, C., Selvanathan, EA., Naranpanawa, A & Forster, J. 2020. The impact of fiscal
shocks on real GDP and income inequality: What do Australian data say?. Journal of Policy
Modeling 42:250-270.
Gupta, S & Jalles, J.T. 2022). ‘Do tax reforms affect income distribution? Evidence from
developing countries.’ Economic Modelling 110. DOI: 10.1016/j.econmod.2022.105804
Gupta, S., Davoodi, H & Alonso-Terme, R. 1998. ‘Does corruption affect income inequality and
poverty.’ IMF working paper WP/98/76.
https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/wp9876.pdf
Heshmati, A & Kim, J. 2014. ‘A Survey of the Role of Fiscal Policy in Addressing Income
Inequality.’ Poverty Reduction and Inclusive Growth, No 8119, IZA Discussion Papers,
Institute of Labor Economics (IZA)
IMF report (2020) Six Charts Explain South Africa's Inequality, Available online:
https://www.imf.org/en/News/Articles/2020/01/29/na012820six-charts-on-south-africas-
persistent-and-multi-faceted-inequality (accessed on 2 February 2024).
Kebalo,L & Zouri, S. 2024. ‘Income inequality in developing countries: fiscal policy’s role amid
uncertainty.’ Journal of Applied Economics 27.
https://doi.org/10.1080/15140326.2024.2316969.
Keynes, J. M. (1936). ‘The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money.’ Harcourt Brace.
Kilian, L. & Lütkepohl, H. 2017. ‘Structural vector autoregressive analysis. Cambridge University
Press.
Kilinc, Savrul B. & Taskin, A. 2020. ‘Dolayli ve dolaysiz vergilerin Turkiye’deki gelir dagilimi
uzerine etkileri.’ Eurasian Academy of Sciences Social Sciences Journal 29:1-19.
Koop, G.M. 2013. ‘Forecasting with medium and large Bayesian VARs.’ Journal of Applied
Econometrics 28:177-203.
Kouadio, H.K & Gakpa, L. 2022. ‘Do economic growth and institutional quality reduce poverty
and inequality in West Africa?.’ Journal of Policy Modeling 44:41-63
Kuschnig, N & Vashold, L. 2019. ‘BVAR: Bayesian Vector Autoregressions with Hierarchical
Prior Selection in R.’ Department of Economics Working Paper Series 296, WU Vienna
University of Economics and Business.
Lee, C & Wang, C. 2022. ‘Financial development, technological innovation and energy security:
Evidence from Chinese provincial experience.’ Energy Economics 112:106161
Lerner, A. P. 1943. ‘Functional Finance and the Federal Debt.’ The Social Science Journal, 1(1),
38-58.
Litterman, R.B.1980. ‘Bayesian procedure for forecasting with vector autoregressions.’
Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Lucas, R. E. 1988. ‘On the Mechanics of Economic Development.’ Journal of Monetary
Economics, 22(1), 3-42.
Majumdar, S & Partridge, M.D. 2009. ‘Impact of Economic Growth on Income Inequality: A
Regional Perspective.’ Conference Paper/ Presentation, AgEcon resrarch in Agriculture
and economics. Milwaukee, Wisconsin.10.22004/ag.econ.49270
Malla, M.H, & Pathranarakul, P. 2022. ‘Fiscal Policy and Income Inequality:The Critical Role of
Institutional Capacity.’ Economies 10: 115.
McCracken, M.W & Ng, S. 2016. FRED-MD: A Monthly Database for Macroeconomic
Research.’ Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 34: 574-589
Moene K.O, & Wallerstein, M. 2003. ‘Earnings Inequality and Welfare Spending: A
Disaggregated Analysis. World Politics.’ 55:485-516.
Moyo, C., Mishi, S, & Ncwadi, R. 2022. ‘Human capital development, poverty and income
inequality in the Eastern Cape province.’ Development Studies Research 9:36-47
Muinelo-Gallo, L & Roca-Sagalés, O. 2013. ‘Joint determinants of fiscal policy, income inequality
and economic growth.’ Economic Modelling 30:814-824.
Ndou, E. 2024. ‘Inflation-income inequality nexus in South Africa: the role of inflationary
environment.’ Journal of Applied Economics 27. doi: 10.1080/15140326.2024.2316968.
Nolan, B., Richiardi, MG & Valenzuela, L. 2019. ‘The drivers of income inequality in rich
countries.’ Journal of Economic Surveys 33; DOI: 10.1111/joes.12328
Piketty,T & Saez, M. 2003. ‘Income Inequality in the United States, 1913–1998.’ The Quarterly
Journal of Economics 118:1–41.
Rezk, H., Goma, A Nahla F, & Sun, S. 2022.’The impact of FDI on income inequality in Egypt.’
Econ Chang Restruct 55:2011–2030
Rubio-Ramirez JF, Waggoner DF, Zha T (2010). ‘Structural Vector Autoregressions: Theory of
Identification and Algorithms for Inference.’ Review of Economic Studies, 77(2), 665
696. doi:10.1111/j.1467-937x.2009.00578.x.Arias JE, Rubio-Ramírez JF, Waggoner DF
.2018. ‘Inference Based on Structural Vector Autoregressions Identified with Sign and
Zero Restrictions: Theory and Applications.’ Econometrica, 86(2), 685–720.
doi:10.3982/ecta14468.)
Samanta, S.K & Cerf, G. 2009. ‘Income Distribution and the Effectiveness of Fiscal Policy:
Evidence from some Transitional Economies.' Journal of Economics and Business XII.
Sameti, M. & Rafie, L. 2010. ‘Interaction of income distribution, taxes and economic growth (The
case of Iran and some selected East Asian countries).’ Iranian Economic Review 14:67-81.
Sims, C. A, & Zha, T. 1998. ‘Bayesian Methods for Dynamic Multivariate Models.’ International
Economic Review 39:949–968.
Smith, B. 2024. ‘Fiscal Policy Effects on Income Inequality in the United States.’ American
Journal of Economics 8:1- 12.
Solt, F. 2020. ‘The standardized world Income-inequality database.’ Social Science Quarterly
90:231-242.
Tobin, J. 1965. ‘The Theory of Liquidity Preference’. The Review of Economics and Statistics,
47(3), 295-319.
United Nations .2020. ‘Inequality Bridging the Divide. Report.’ Available online:
https://www.un.org/en/un75/inequality-bridging-divide (accessed on 2 February 2024).
Villani, M. 2009. ‘Steady-state priors for vector autoregressions.’ Journal of Applied Econometrics
24: 630-650.
Wienk, MNA., Buttrick, NR & Oishi, S.2022. ‘The social psychology of economic inequality,
redistribution, and subjective well-being.’ European Review of Social Psychology 33:45-
80
William, M, & Taskin, T. 2020. ‘Determinants of Social Distancing and Economic Activity during
COVID-19.’ The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 9242
World Development Indicators. 2024. ‘World Bank, Washington, D.C.’ Available online:
http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators (accessed on 2
February 2024).
Zuazu, I. 2022. ‘Electoral systems and income inequality: a tale of political equality.’ Empirical
Economics :793-819
Zungu, L.T. 2024. ‘The nonlinear dynamic effect of government expenditure on income
inequality: The case of macroprudential policy switching.’ Journal of Infrastructure,
Policy and Development 8. doi: 10.24294/jipd.v8i4.2515.
Appendix
Table A1. Sign restriction for the ristrited model
Variables
Sign restriction
Government expenditure on health
Negative
Total government expenditure
Negative
Income tax
Negative
Taxes on goods and services
Negative
National government revenue as % of GDP
None
Time-varying CAPB for government expenditure
Negative
Time-varying CAPB for total government revenue
Negative
Real balance
Negative
GDP per capita
None
Inflation
None
Government effectiveness
None
Corruption control
None
Table A2. Summary of the shocks of BVAR for both model 2 and 3
Source: Author’s calculation based on WDI (2024) and SWIID (Solt, 2020) data.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
A panel data analysis of nonlinear government expenditure and income inequality dynamics in a macroprudential policy regime was conducted on a panel of 15 emerging countries from 1985-2019, where there had been a non-prudential regime from 1985-1999 and a prudential regime from 2000-2019. The paper explored the validity of the nonlinearity between government expenditure and income inequality in the macroprudential policy regime as well as the threshold level at which excessive spending reduces income inequality using the Bayesian spatial lag panel smooth transition regression (BSPSTR) and fix effect models. The BSPSTR model was adopted due to its ability to address the problems of heterogeneity, endogeneity, and cross-section correlation in a nonlinear framework. Moreover, as the transition variable often varies across time and space, the effect of the independent variables can also be time-and space-varying. The results reveal evidence of a nonlinear effect between government spending and income inequality, where the minimum level of government spending is found to be 29.89 percent of GDP, above which expenditure reduces inequality in emerging countries. The findings confirmed an inverted U-shaped relationship. The focal policy recommendation is that fiscal policy decisions that will reinforce the need for more emphasis on education and public expenditure on education and health, as important tools for improving income inequality, are crucial for these economies. Caution is needed when introducing macroprudential policies, especially at a low level of government expenditure.
Article
Full-text available
We estimate vector autoregressive models to examine the effect of the 3 to 6 per cent inflation target band in the inflation and income inequality nexus in South Africa. We use quarterly data spanning 1993Q1 to 2016Q3 to analyse how growth in income inequality responds to positive inflation shocks when inflation is within the 3 to 6 per cent target band versus when it exceeds 6 per cent. Evidence indicates that positive inflation shocks within the 3 to 6 per cent inflation target band lead to an insignificant decline in income inequality. However, greater income inequality results when inflation exceeds 6 per cent threshold. This suggests that the inflation-income inequality nexus in South Africa is nonlinear due to the 3 to 6 per cent inflation target range. Thus, inflation above 6 per cent is harmful as it increases income inequality. Policymakers should pursue policies that maintain the existing target band.
Article
Full-text available
This study investigates the impact of uncertainty on income inequality in developing countries. Unlike prior studies, we analyse the role that the fiscal policy could play in the relationship. Using a sample of 66 developing countries over the period 2000–2020, we find at several levels of robustness that, uncertainty increases income inequality in developing countries, especially those with fiscal deficits and less fiscally disciplined. Additionally, we find that fiscal surpluses mitigate the negative effects of uncertainty on wealth distribution which in turn reduces income inequality. This result reveals the socio-economic stabilizing role that fiscal policy management could play during periods of uncertainty. Fiscal policy can maintain and enhance economic stability when countries face certain uncertainty.
Article
Full-text available
This paper investigates the impact of fiscal consolidation in different states on domestic government debt in South Africa. The government budget constraint theoretical framework and Markov-switching dynamic regression (MSDR) from 1979 to 2022. The contribution of this paper is to examine fiscal consolidation on domestic government debt in different states using measures of fiscal consolidation that account for time-varying elasticity in the cyclical adjusted primary balance (CAPB). The U-shape is found which indicates that fiscal consolidation is effective in reducing domestic government debt at a low level. However, as domestic government debt reaches a high-level fiscal consolidation becomes detrimental and further increase domestic government. Given the result, it recommended that South Africa use less fiscal consolidation in the effort to reduce domestic government debt. Fiscal authorities need to use government expenditure in the productive sector of the economy that will bring about an increase in revenue rather than an increase in the tax rate as advocated in the fiscal consolidation policy. Moreover, develop a tax system that generates optimal tax revenue with adjustment of the tax rates.
Technical Report
Full-text available
Fiscal policies may affect gender inequalities in income and opportunity. This report reviews the evidence on the impact of tax and spending policies on gender income gaps across countries, as well as on work incentives and labour market outcomes for women. The focus is on the role of tax (and social security contributions) and transfers in cash and some transfers in-kind (in the form of education and health services). Given their relevance for women’s outcomes after having children, we also survey the evidence on the impact of childcare subsidies (both demand and supply) and paid parental leave.
Article
Full-text available
The study examined the dynamic effect of fiscal policy on wealth inequality in middle-income countries using panel data from 2010 to 2018 and the system Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) method. Two measures of fiscal policy were considered, namely government expenses and taxes on income, profits and capital gains. GDP per capita and adult population were used as control variables. The findings of this study show that while taxes on income, profits and capital gains have a significant negative effect on wealth inequality, government expenses have no effect whatsoever on wealth inequality.
Article
Full-text available
Rising income inequality has become a defining global challenge that hinders the achievement of the United Nations Sustainable Development Goals. The paper investigates the effect of fiscal policy and institutional capacity on income inequality among developed and developing countries. Applying the system Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) to control potential endogeneity for countries from 2000 to 2019, the following results have been established. The dynamic effect captured by the first lag of inequality suggests that the widening income gap is persistent in both developed and developing countries. We also find evidence that income tax is more progressive and may abate income inequality in developing countries and not in developed countries. However, taxes on goods and services were found not to impact income equalization globally. Furthermore, the findings reveal that government size, education expenditure, and health expenditure are negatively associated with income inequality in developed countries only. Public debt was observed not to influence income distribution across the world. We observed that corruption and government effectiveness do not significantly impact income distribution in developed and developing countries for institutional capacity. However, in most cases, the coefficients of the interactions between fiscal policy and institutional capacity bear the expected signs, albeit insignificant. Some policy recommendations have been offered.
Chapter
Michael Wallerstein was a leader in developing a rigorous comparative political economy approach to understanding substantive issues of inequality, redistribution, and wage-determination. His early death from cancer left both a hole in the profession and a legacy that will surely provide the foundation for research on these topics. This volume collects his most important and influential contributions, organized by topic, with each topic preceded by an editorial introduction that provides overview and context.
Article
This paper examines the sensitivity of the growth-inequality tradeoff to the progressivity of the tax structure. Using an endogenous growth model calibrated to approximate the US tax structure, we simulate a 5% reduction in the economy-wide average tax rate attained by alternative combinations of a reduction in the base tax rate and an increase in progressivity. In all cases the dynamic responses across income classes are diverse. With fixed progressivity the tax benefits favor the poorer quintiles, but the richest quintile is the only group that increases its relative share of capital and income. The net long-run effect is a mild increase in the overall growth rate, accompanied by a substantial increase in inequality. Restructuring the tax cut by allowing a larger reduction in the base tax rate coupled with a large increase in progressivity, designed to maintain the tax burden on the richest quintile unchanged, the exact opposite responses emerge; growth and inequality both decline. By judicious choice of the crucial fiscal parameters, the tax cut can be structured so that the growth rate increases while inequality simultaneously declines. The required structural changes are small, highlighting the extreme sensitivity of the tradeoff to the degree of tax progressivity.
Article
We empirically assess the impact of tax reforms on income distribution in developing countries. We apply the local projection method to a new “narrative” database of tax reforms covering 45 emerging and low-income countries. Reforms of the personal income or strengthening of the revenue administration lower the disposable Gini and increase the bottom income share. This result does not hold for sub-Saharan Africa. To reduce inequality at a faster pace, it would be more effective to implement tax reforms when the economy is growing relatively slowly. Finally, the smaller the government spending envelope and the smaller the tax system, the larger the beneficial impact of tax reforms on inequality.