ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

Theories are foundational for decision making. We point to a normative agenda that emphasizes the need for decision makers—including managers, firms, entrepreneurs, and startups—to develop their own theories. Our argument is that decision makers should be like scientists and use the scientific method—theories, causal reasoning, and experimentation—to problem solve and generate new data and value. In this paper and special issue introduction, we discuss the foundations of the theory-based view (TBV), particularly as it relates to forward-looking reasoning and decision making under uncertainty. Rather than handing prescriptive theories to others, the goal of the TBV is to provide the scaffolding for economic actors themselves to develop their own, idiosyncratic theories. Theories are built on heterogeneous beliefs and causal reasoning that enable the generation of unique paths to value. We discuss the implications of this argument for key theories within strategy and economics, along with highlighting research opportunities at the nexus of the TBV and topics such as learning, entrepreneurship, finance, ownership and leadership. We also introduce the special issue papers and discuss their contributions to the TBV. Funding: We appreciate ION Management Science Laboratory at Bocconi for funding the special issue conference and related activities. A. Gambardella also acknowledges support from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 Research and Innovation Programme [Grant 101021061].
Theory-Based Decisions: Foundations and Introduction
Teppo Felin,
a,b,
* Alfonso Gambardella,
c
Todd Zenger
d
a
Department of Strategy and Entrepreneurship, Huntsman School of Business, Utah State University, Logan, Utah 84322;
b
Department of
Strategy, Innovation and Management, Saïd Business School, University of Oxford, Oxford OX1 1HP, United Kingdom;
c
Department of
Management and Technology & ION Management Science Laboratory, SDA Bocconi, Bocconi University, 20136 Milan, Italy;
d
Department of
Entrepreneurship and Strategy & ION Management Science Laboratory, David Eccles School of Business, University of Utah, Salt Lake City,
Utah 84122
*Corresponding author
Contact: teppo.felin@usu.edu, https://orcid.org/0000-0003-2044-0145 (TF); alfonso.gambardella@unibocconi.it,
https://orcid.org/0000-0002-8714-5813 (AG); todd.zenger@utah.edu, https://orcid.org/0000-0002-9830-4066 (TZ)
https://doi.org/10.1287/stsc.2024.intro.v9.n4
Copyright: © 2024 INFORMS
Abstract. Theories are foundational for decision making. We point to a normative agenda that
emphasizes the need for decision makers—including managers, firms, entrepreneurs, and
startups—to develop their own theories. Our argument is that decision makers should be like
scientists and use the scientific method—theories, causal reasoning, and experimentation—to
problem solve and generate new data and value. In this paper and special issue introduction,
we discuss the foundations of the theory-based view (TBV), particularly as it relates to forward-
looking reasoning and decision making under uncertainty. Rather than handing prescriptive
theories to others, the goal of the TBV is to provide the scaffolding for economic actors them-
selves to develop their own, idiosyncratic theories. Theories are built on heterogeneous beliefs
and causal reasoning that enable the generation of unique paths to value. We discuss the impli-
cations of this argument for key theories within strategy and economics, along with highlight-
ing research opportunities at the nexus of the TBV and topics such as learning,
entrepreneurship, finance, ownership and leadership. We also introduce the special issue
papers and discuss their contributions to the TBV.
Funding: We appreciate ION Management Science Laboratory at Bocconi for funding the special issue
conference and related activities. A. Gambardella also acknowledges support from the European
Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 Research and Innovation Pro-
gramme [Grant 101021061].
Keywords:theory-based view decision making strategy entrepreneurship causal reasoning theories governance
Introduction
The theory-based view (TBV) begins with the premise
that unique beliefs and theories guide economic actors.
To develop and test their beliefs and theories, economic
actors—entrepreneurs, managers, innovators, startups,
and firms—should act like scientists (Felin and Zenger
2009, 2017; Camuffo et al. 2020). The TBV provides nor-
mative guidance about how to utilize the scientific
method, specifically emphasizing the roles of causal
reasoning, problem framing and solving, and experi-
mentation in the generation of economic value. Theories
are practical instruments that enable economic actors to
craft unique causal paths for value creation. Instead of
the traditional academic approach of prescribing deci-
sions, strategies, or universal theories to managers or
entrepreneurs, the TBV provides economic actors with
the scaffolding—tools and processes—they need to
develop their own theory of value, which then guides
their unique actions and decisions.
In this introduction to the Strategy Science special
issue, we first offer an overview of the TBV. We specifi-
cally discuss the unique and differentiating attributes of
the TBV, focusing on cognition, causal reasoning and its
normative focus on actor-specific theories. Thereafter, we
highlight the implications of the TBV for key theories
within the field of strategy (like the resource-based view
and positioning school) and also discuss opportunities for
future research in domains such as learning, entrepreneur-
ship, finance, and governance and ownership. We then
introduce the special issue papers and point to the respec-
tive contributions that these papers make to the TBV.
TBV: An Overview
Theorizing is traditionally thought of as a cognitive
activity performed by scientists. But the TBV builds on
the idea that all human cognition—whether it involves
scientists, infants, entrepreneurs or executives—involves
theorizing and experimentation (Gopnik et al. 1999, Felin
and Zenger 2009).
1
The TBV sees theorizing as central for any decision
maker. Perhaps the most ambitious claim of the TBV is
that everything within the domain of economic decision
making is theory driven. Theories shape what economic
actors perceive and see, what they search for, how or
297
STRATEGY SCIENCE
Vol. 9, No. 4, December 2024, pp. 297–310
ISSN 2333-2050 (print), ISSN 2333-2077 (online) https://pubsonline.informs.org/journal/stsc
Downloaded from informs.org by [144.39.162.95] on 13 December 2024, at 09:54 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
whether they learn, what experiments they engage in,
and how they govern. Theories shape the engagement
of actors with the world, whether the theory is implicit
or explicit, shallow or profound, based on tight or weak
logic. Theories can of course be tested and experimen-
ted on to assess whether they are plausible. But the TBV
seeks to make theories and the theorizing of economic
actors more explicit, rational and productive, enabling
decision makers to compose better theories that are
more unique and pragmatically useful in guiding deci-
sion making.
A central premise of the TBV is that economic actors—
much like scientists—can be taught to be more effective
in composing theories and utilizing the scientific method
(Felin et al. 2024). Although humans have a natural
capacity for theorizing, this ability can be enhanced and
emphasized. Thus, the agenda of the TBV is normative.
Accordingly, theory-based treatments and interventions
can be compared with other treatments, and their effi-
cacy tested in terms of the decisions and outcomes they
yield. Existing empirical work—largely with random-
ized controlled trials (RCTs)—provides strong support
for the theory-based approach (Camuffo et al. 2020),
including a number of large-scale replications (Agarwal
et al. 2023, Camuffo et al. 2024b, Coali et al. 2024, Novelli
and Spina 2024).
Given the importance of theories in guiding strategic
decision making, we turn now to an overview of the
TBV. We emphasize the unique aspects of theory-based
reasoning, and where appropriate draw links to related
areas and perspectives.
Cognition: From Information Processing to Belief
Heterogeneity
In terms of cognition, the TBV emphasizes heteroge-
neous beliefs—a sharp departure from traditional mod-
els of cognition in economics and strategy. Existing
models are grounded in information processing and
bounded rationality (Simon 1956, Kahneman 2003).
They emphasize human cognition as constrained by
computational limits. The central emphasis is on
how the mind’s capacity to process information is
finite, leading to biases and bounded decision making.
Bounded rationality has been a central pillar for large
swaths of the judgment and decision-making literature
across economics and management (for a review, see
Chater et al. (2018)). The core concern in this literature is
on how decision makers rationally handle information
asymmetries and mitigate cognitive biases by proces-
sing more information, thereby becoming more rational
within their local environments (Arrow 1986). The
emphasis is on the quantity of information and the abil-
ity of economic actors to appropriately process it.
This work assumes that differences in economic per-
formance arise from the ability to overcome cognitive
constraints and biases through enhanced information
processing. This literature is also intimately tied to artifi-
cial intelligence (AI) (Simon 1990), with cognition viewed
as an exercise in increasing the amount and accuracy of in-
formation considered before decision making.
In contrast, the TBV shifts the focus from information
processing to the generative aspects of cognition, espe-
cially in situations where decisions are not simply about
the accurate processing of given information or data.
Rather than emphasize the cognitive limits of human
information processing, the TBV highlights the capacity
of economic actors to generate novel beliefs. Belief het-
erogeneity and belief asymmetry, essentially, provide
the raw material for new choice options. Although
belief asymmetries—where beliefs might be contrary to
existing data and evidence—are traditionally seen as
biases (Benabou and Tirole 2016, Pinker 2021), in the
TBV they are a central starting point for the generation
of value. That is, contrarian beliefs enable economic
actors to see value that others may not be able to see.
The TBV does not question that humans have cogni-
tive and computational limits when it comes to decision
making, but the perspective’s focus is elsewhere.
The focus of the TBV is the human capacity to
endogenouslygenerate information, knowledge and
options that previously were not salient or obvious to
others. Here the idea of heterogeneous beliefs is funda-
mental. Asymmetric or (in some form) contrarian
beliefs are the cognitive raw material of theories and
novel, economically useful knowledge. From the per-
spective of the TBV, the very notion of informationis
a black box that demands further specification. What
becomes uniquely salient as relevant information is
driven by the ex ante beliefs of economic actors. That is,
beliefs condition the salience and value of information.
To illustrate this view of cognition, consider how it
reshapes the notion of searchin economics and strat-
egy. Traditional models conceptualize search as initiated
by a process of representing an environment, either par-
tially or exhaustively (Simon 1955, Kauffman 1993,
Gavetti and Levinthal 2000). In these models, search is
largely about processing information to evaluate a prede-
fined array of options, with scholars often urging a shift
from local searchto more expansive global search
where untapped possibilities may be found. The focus is
further on the efficiency of information gathering, as
firms differ in how quickly and effectively they process
data about potential resources (Makadok and Barney
2001; also see Lippman and Rumelt (2003)). Also, search
is about refining the ability to capture and represent the
environment accurately, assessing the value of resources
based on the information at hand.
In contrast, the TBV shifts the focus away from search
as information processing or representation of an environ-
ment. Instead, the TBV emphasizes the endogenous crea-
tion of salience for specific things in the environment,
including latent sources of value. The emphasis is on how
Felin, Gambardella, and Zenger: Theory-Based Decisions
298 Strategy Science, 2024, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 297–310, © 2024 INFORMS
Downloaded from informs.org by [144.39.162.95] on 13 December 2024, at 09:54 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
actors generate the awareness for things to search for, which
are not obvious to others (Felin and Koenderink 2022).
Rather than exhaustively scan the environment for pre-
existing resources, the TBV argues that value itself is gen-
erated through heterogeneous, often contrarian beliefs
and theories that make certain resources or opportunities
salient to some but not others. The environment—or stra-
tegic choices or resources—does not objectively present
itself for evaluation; instead, what is salient in the environ-
ment is shaped and constructed by the heterogeneous
beliefs and theories of the economic actor. Rather than
emphasize bounded rationality, the TBV emphasizes
generative rationality.Search, in this sense, is not about
accurately representing or mirroring what is already there,
but about creating salience for something previously
unnoticed or undervalued. This endogenous view of
search, rooted in belief heterogeneity, reflects the TBV’s
focus on the generative capacity of cognition, where actors
create rather than discover value (Felin et al. 2023) through
the pragmatic deployment of the scientific method (Zell-
weger and Zenger 2023).
This generative feature of cognition is achieved as actors
not only think with data and experience (i.e., process infor-
mation) to predict a future state, but think past it to imag-
ine the future, and then causally reason how this future
state might logically be attained (Felin and Holweg 2024).
Admittedly, envisioning the future through causal logic,
rather than predicting it from past data or information
may be an infrequent activity. More frequently, firms may
simply update goals and set new benchmarks as linear
extensions to existing metrics. But solely updating bench-
marks is an admission to being inside an already existing
performance frontier. The TBV advocates a different path
of imaging a world that does not exist, composing a logical
path to creating it, built with assumptions, subproblems,
and premises, and then gathering data to test the validity
of that causal logic.
Given the TBV’s cognitive emphasis on belief
heterogeneity—rather than mere information processing—
there are useful connections between the TBV and Bayes-
ian reasoning (Zellweger and Zenger 2023, Agrawal et al.
2024, Camuffo et al. 2024a). At the heart of Bayesian
approaches is the idea that decision making under uncer-
tainty can be structured by subjective probabilities, with
priors representing the beliefs that decision makers
hold before encountering new evidence (Savage 1972).
These subjective priors align with the TBV’s emphasis on
the importance of heterogeneous beliefs, perhaps offer-
ing a way to formally model how theories and divergent
perspectives shape cognition and decision making. In
both approaches, an actors’ beliefs—rather than an
exhaustive processing of information—drive decisions,
highlighting how beliefs are updated as individuals
respond to new information or evidence.
Although Bayesianism provides a possible way to
formalize belief heterogeneity in the context of the TBV,
there are active conversations about how well it opera-
tionalizes this idea and whether modifications are
needed (Ehrig and Schmidt 2022, Camuffo et al. 2024a,
Ehrig et al. 2024). A concern is that standard Bayesian
models understate the generative aspects of belief for-
mation emphasized in the TBV, particularly in situa-
tions of deep uncertainty where relevant data are scarce
or nonexistent. Furthermore, the process by which the
relevant evidence is identified, generated and incorpo-
rated into belief revision is not explicitly discussed
within the Bayesian framework. The intuitive, broad
logic is that a signal consistent with a belief or focal
event (a goodsignal) updates positively the expected
probability of the event, whereas an inconsistent signal
(badsignal) updates it negatively. But Bayesian logic
is more restrictive because Bayes’ law has explicit rules
about the posterior distributions of a Bayesian prior
distribution. Bayesian posterior distributions, which
update an initial prior distribution, are simplified when
we use a conjugate prior—a prior distribution that
matches the form of the posterior distribution produced
by Bayes’ law, combining the probability distributions of
the signal and the event. What this means in practice is
that there are substantial updates and learning that extend
beyond formal Bayesianism (in highly uncertain or com-
plex environments). De facto, this amounts to saying that
not all positive or negative updates of a good or bad signal
are consistent with Bayes’ law, and we can update consis-
tently with the broad logic above even if the update does
not follow Bayes’ law. More importantly, Bayes’ law can-
not deal with unknown events, and thus demands non-
Bayesian logic to be incorporated.
Nevertheless, the TBV’s emphasis on forward-looking
beliefs certainly has some parallels with Bayesianism
and offers a plausible mechanism for formally modeling
aspects of this process, perhaps in amended form
(Ehrig and Foss 2022, Zellweger and Zenger 2022b).
In both frameworks, the diversity and heterogeneity
of forward-looking beliefs are fundamental starting
points for generating value in uncertain environments.
But a central emphasis from the perspective of the TBV
is placed on the causal reasoning and experimentation
that enables the generation of new evidence (Felin and
Holweg 2024).
From Data-Driven Decision Making to Forward-
Looking Causal Reasoning
Existing theories of decision making place a significant
emphasis on rationality, specifically defined as deci-
sions driven by existing data and evidence (for a review,
see Pinker (2021)). Thus, economists emphasize how
decision makers are frequently inattentiveto the right
data or to sample sizes (Gabaix 2019) or how they
engage in biases in probabilistic reasoning (Benjamin
2019). Behavioral biases and flaws in judgment and
information processing are said to pervade human
Felin, Gambardella, and Zenger: Theory-Based Decisions
Strategy Science, 2024, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 297–310, © 2024 INFORMS 299
Downloaded from informs.org by [144.39.162.95] on 13 December 2024, at 09:54 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
cognition (Thaler 2016, Chater 2018, Kahneman et al. 2021).
For example, Benabou and Tirole (2016, pp. 142–148) dis-
cuss how humans engage in information avoidance
and are resistant to many forms of evidence.
Of course, when the right data are available, eco-
nomic actors should rationally update their beliefs. But
as suggested by our discussion above, the TBV is more
interested in decision making where data or evidence is
not yet available, or where existing evidence is con-
tested. The TBV is focused on asymmetric beliefs and
their role in triggering what might be called forward-
looking causal reasoning. From the perspective of the
TBV, when data and evidence for a belief or some hypo-
thetical future state are absent (or contested), economic
actors can engage in actions that generate the requisite
new data. In the TBV economic actors intervene in
their surroundings to generate new knowledge and evi-
dence, rather than passively reador scan their envir-
onments. Causal reasoning enables them to delineate a
path—a set of actions, steps or experiments—that help
them create the conditions for the realization of beliefs
that previously appeared unwarranted and lacking in
evidence.
The focus on causal reasoning in the TBV builds on and
extends Pearl’s existing work on causal inference (Pearl
and MacKenzie 2018; also see Heckman and Pinto (2024)),
particularly the emphasis on counterfactual reasoning and
interventions that go beyond merely analyzing existing
data. These causal models allow decision makers to under-
stand the relationship between variables by imagining
hypothetical interventions and observing their potential
effects. However, Pearl’s work largely emphasizes causal
reasoning on the part of scientists and researchers—using
data to understand past events. To illustrate, Pearl’s most
frequent example is about determining whether smoking
causes cancer, which highlights how causal reasoning can
be applied retrospectively to analyze data. TBV builds on
and extends this framework to forward-looking decision
making and causal reasoning by all decision makers, not
just scientists or researchers. Emphasis is placed on
forward-looking decision making by asking what should
be done—how might we intervene—to achieve desired
future outcomes. The TBV is not only concerned with
understanding what has already happened but also in
determining what could or needs to happen for a particu-
lar belief or outcome to be realized. In this forward-looking
approach, the emphasis shifts to exploring what interven-
tions, experiments, or conditions are necessary and suffi-
cient to bring about some presently implausible sounding
future state.
To offer an example of how the TBV’s emphasis on
causal reasoning provides a unique lens on central ques-
tions in strategy, consider its implications for re-
combinationas an explanation for technological novelty
and value creation (Schumpeter 1934, Weitzman 1998,
Fleming and Sorenson 2004, Bresnahan 2012, Koppl et al.
2023). The central premise of recombination is that new
technologies and innovations arise from novel combina-
tions of existing components. Although this idea has been
widely accepted, much of the literature lacks an explana-
tion for how or why specific combinations are selected
from an almost indefinite set of possibilities. If countless
recombinations are possible—and searching through
them is costly—then what drives economic actors to
choose and pursue particular combinations over others?
The TBV offers a cognitive mechanism that explains
how certain components and combinations become
salient in the minds of economic actors. At the core of
this process is the identification and formulation of a
problem, which directs actors’ attention to specific com-
ponents that are relevant for solving it. Rather than
searching through random combinations, economic
actors are far more focused. They use problem solving
and causal reasoning to identify which elements might
be pragmatically useful with the selected problem. If
existing solutions or components cannot be identified,
decision makers may also create or modify components
to develop solutions. Through active theorizing, actors
recognize underappreciated possibilities, leverage their
asymmetric beliefs to envision how interventions—
such as recombining or altering existing technologies—
could generate value. In this way, the TBV not only
explains how certain combinations come into focus but
also how individual components, even those requiring
modification, become salient as part of a broader pro-
cess of problem solving and value creation.
Consider the distinction between data-driven decision
making and theory-guided causal reasoning in a context
like mergers and acquisitions. Data-driven strategists
might examine performance correlations with existing
events or cases and from these make a conjecture about
the attractiveness of acquisition targets. Firms might
assess whether to embark on an acquisition by looking at
the performance of cases that are as similar as possible to
theirs. Or an opportunity for a merger might be analyzed
on the basis of various financial metrics. Variables like
experience—the number of times an activity has been
performed—traditionally also play an important role in
varied types of corporate transactions. But from the nor-
mative perspective of the TBV, any corporate action
should be guided by a theory and associated causal rea-
soning. Theory-less decisions lead to needlessly costly
mistakes and generic strategies, while theory-guided
causal reasoning enables economic actors to identify and
build unique, firm-specific sources of value.
Our point is not that some firms only observe correla-
tions and make predictions, whereas others theorize
and test. Most likely, firms will vary in the emphasis
they give to each and may even match their use to the
problems and opportunities they face. But our more
general point is that the more firms engage in theory
development and causal reasoning, the more likely they
Felin, Gambardella, and Zenger: Theory-Based Decisions
300 Strategy Science, 2024, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 297–310, © 2024 INFORMS
Downloaded from informs.org by [144.39.162.95] on 13 December 2024, at 09:54 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
will be innovative, push the frontier, and enjoy competi-
tive advantages. The extent to which firms engage more
with one or the other then depends on their attitudes
toward risk and uncertainty, their time horizons, their
ability to theorize, and their awareness of the benefits
and consequences of these processes for different cir-
cumstances. As noted, the aim of the TBV is to be nor-
mative, providing guidance as to how to deploy a
scientific, theory-guided approach to decision making.
What Is Strategy? One-Size-Fits-All vs. Idiosyn-
cratic Theories and Decisions
A central premise of the TBV is that there is no one-size-
fits-all theory, tool, or set of practices for creating
economic value. Theories should be unique and idio-
syncratic, built from forward-looking causal logic to
enable the realization of future states. This need for
economic actors to develop their own unique theories
has interesting implications for the theories we as
academics produce. Theories of decision making and
strategy tend to—explicitly or implicitly—suggest one-
size-fits-all normative prescriptions. For example, the
resource-based view says that firms should look
insideto find valuable resources, as buying resources
is not plausible due to the efficiency of factor markets
(Barney 1986, 1995; Denrell et al. 2003; Maritan and
Peteraf 2011). The vast literature on open innovation
argues that openness is the key to value creation and
innovation (Chesbrough 2003, Laursen and Salter 2006).
In entrepreneurship, a tool like lean startup’s minimum
viable product is said to be critically important (Blank
and Eckhardt 2024).
The problem is that most academic theories in strat-
egy and entrepreneurship draw conclusions from retro-
spective data, estimated from a common model, to
empirically report average effects, essentially highlight-
ing strategies that worked in the past—on average (Lei-
blein et al. 2018). But strategy is a forward-looking
exercise that demands economic actors build their own
unique models about what might drive performance.
The problem is that estimates from one-size-fits-all the-
ories simply provide a mirror on the past that necessar-
ily delimits the range of plausible approaches for
creating value. They leave little room for contrarian
approaches that go against existing theories and frame-
works. To illustrate, while openness was being lauded
as a universal strategy for creating value, Apple
maintained a closed ecosystem and achieved unprece-
dented success by focusing on integrated hardware and
software. Similarly, at a time when Porter’s Five Forces
identified industries like retail or airlines as wildly unat-
tractive (due to low profitability and intense competi-
tion), companies like WalMart and Southwest Airlines
defied these predictions. Tesla, in an era dominated by
outsourcing, pursues vertical integration, keeping pro-
duction and innovation in-house to maintain control
over its supply chain and accelerate breakthroughs in
electric vehicles. Contrarian strategies that run counter
to existing theories and instead rely on firms’ own idio-
syncratic theories and causal paths can lead to signifi-
cant value creation.
The TBV is a one-size-fits-all theory only in the meta-
theoretical sense that every firm needs to have their
own theory. But what that theory is—what it implies for
resources, positioning, the actions that need to be taken,
or the extent to which the firm should be open or closed,
or how it should govern itself—is highly idiosyncratic.
A firm’s theory offers unique guidance for downstream
decision making related to these issues, as well as a
wealth of other practical matters such as what assets to
secure or combine, what type(s) of experiments to run,
how to think about human capital, and the right forms
of organizational governance (Wuebker et al. 2023).
Overall, a firm’s strategic theory is essentially an experi-
ment in value creation.
Applying the TBV and Future Agenda
As a normative cognition- and action-oriented approach
to exploring any uncertain future, the TBV’s aspirational
reach and ambition is substantial. We highlight here a
range of topics core to the strategy and entrepreneurship
literature around that we believe the TBV has much to
contribute. For each core theory or topic, we highlight
valuable insights or alternative framings that the TBV
provides, and discuss important, unanswered questions.
This also represents an implicit future agenda, as signifi-
cant work in each of these domains remains to be done.
We begin with a discussion of the TBV’s connection to
strategy’s two most predominant theories, before turn-
ing to the topics of learning, valuation, entrepreneurship,
and leadership.
Theories as the Origin of Resources
The underlying logic of the resource-based view rests on
the assumption that competitive advantage either stems
from (a) superior information about resource value that
allows resource procurement at a discount (Barney 1986)
or from (b) the unique possession of valuable resources
that are difficult to imitate (Barney 1991). However,
because the field has generally assumed that factor mar-
kets for resources are informationally efficient—that is,
prices reflect all available information—securing dis-
counted resources has been seen as unlikely (Denrell et al.
2003). Therefore, the field’s focus has largely been on
looking inside(Barney 1995) for unique resources that
are already possessed by an organization.
The TBV begins from an alternative premise, namely,
that resources are an epiphenomenon of the theories
that animate them(2017, p. 259). In this way, the TBV
solves a central puzzle related to resource-based argu-
ments in strategy. Namely, idiosyncratic theories offer a
Felin, Gambardella, and Zenger: Theory-Based Decisions
Strategy Science, 2024, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 297–310, © 2024 INFORMS 301
Downloaded from informs.org by [144.39.162.95] on 13 December 2024, at 09:54 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
key mechanism for seeing value amongst the a vast
reservoir of unpriced resources and resource
combinations (Lippman and Rumelt 2003, p. 1085;
Felin et al. 2023). Resource-based arguments emphasize
search (which can be costly), whereas the emphasis in
the TBV is placed on generating awareness of unseen
states and potential problem solutions through theories
(Felin and Zenger 2017, Ehrig and Zenger 2024). Fur-
thermore, although the superior expectations that
enable discovering resources in factor markets may
reflect information differences (Makadok and Barney
2001), the TBV recognizes that actors with equivalent
information, but different theories can routinely identify
and fabricate valuable resources (Felin and Zenger
2017, Ehrig and Zenger 2024). The rational expectations
assumption that undergirds the RBV assumes that mar-
kets are efficient, there are no $500 bills on the sidewalk.
Essentially, all actors use the same model to interpret
information; or as put by Thomas Sargent, there is a
communism of models(Evans and Honkapohja 2005,
p. 566). The TBV recognizes that divergent actors com-
pose divergent models through which they perceive,
process information, reason causally and evaluate
resources. These actor-specific models animate other-
wise inert resources and reveal previously unseen paths
to value creation and rents.
Notably, with the TBV, the unit of analysis shifts from
resources to a firm-specific theory and the problem it
seeks to solve. This focus elevates the importance of
classifying theories, as differences in theories can then
be linked to differences in sources of rents. Thus, Rin-
dova and Martins (2024) classify theories as analytic,
reconfigurative, and projective, whereas Wuebker et al.
(2023) classify theories based on the types of rents they
seek: arbitrage rents, recombinative or Schumpeterian
rents, and cospecialization or Williamsonian rents.
There remains valuable theoretical work to be done in
mapping theories to the formation or acquisition of
resources and rents. We see considerable opportunity
for further formal work linking concepts from the TBV
to the value-added literature stream (Brandenburger
and Stuart 1996, MacDonald and Ryall 2004, Bryan et al.
2022), such as the paper by Ehrig and Zenger (2024).
Theories expand the state spaces visible to managers
and entrepreneurs (Camuffo et al. 2024a) and funda-
mentally alter both the paths available for learning and
bargaining leverage that actors possess. We also see
additional opportunities to further classify theory types
or forms of cognition and map these to rents and
resources. An empirical agenda of equal importance
might directly explore the origins of resources—
whether they reflect serendipitous endowments or cog-
nitive creations.
Research might also apply the TBV to work on
resource fungibility and redeployment (Helfat and
Eisenhardt 2004, Sakhartov and Folta 2015, Levinthal
and Wu 2024). Although this research ties resource rede-
ployment to certain intrinsic resource characteristics
(Anand et al. 2016), the specific mechanisms behind how a
new use for a resource—or novel resource combination—
is made salient has not been studied. Theory-based cogni-
tion and reasoning provides a plausible mechanism for
explaining why and how some actors are able to see
novel uses for resources (even if these resources are
owned by others).
Theories as Causal Paths to Positions
The TBV also carries important implications for strat-
egy’s positioning perspective, as initially advanced by
Michael Porter (1985, 1991). In contrast to the RBV’s
common focus on internal resources, in this perspective
firms achieve competitive advantage through strategic
positioning, selecting positions based on an analysis of
industry factors that shape profitability. From a norma-
tive perspective, the task is to select from among rather
generic strategy types that vary in focus from broad to
narrow and in their emphasis either from cost or differ-
entiation. The perspective also highlights the concept of
fit among the choices and activities that support these
positions (Ghemawat and Levinthal 2008, Porter and
Siggelkow 2008).
Although critiques of this perspective focus on its
static nature and neglect of internal resources, the
theory-based critique is that it fails to articulate the
causal path to generating these positions or activity sys-
tems that yield competitive advantages. The focus of
existing work is on simply describing positions and the
sets of choices, activities, and assets that support
them. This approach effectively highlights what grants
Southwest or Walmart its advantage, perhaps noting
Southwest’s remarkable fit among activity choices or
Walmart’s scale. And it provides a set of tools that help
describe these valuable states (or positions) already
achieved in an industry or illuminate those still avail-
able. But importantly, neither firm started from these
positions. What the emphasis on positions or activities
fails to provide is a mechanism or tool to guide the pro-
cess of achieving these positions.
Unique activities and strategic positions are an out-
come for the TBV. The TBV asks economic actors to
identify contrarian or asymmetric beliefs about the
future and to formulate the problems that stand in the
way of realizing these future states. It is the process of
reasoning and problem solving that enables economic
actors to delineate their unique causal path to valuable
positions and the relevant activities. But much work
remains to be done here to build the normative tools
that will help managers select targeted future states (as
distinct problems to solve), build the causal logic to
achieve them, and then test and update these theories,
ideally building sufficient confidence in their usefulness
to warrant their pursuit and funding. This suggests a
Felin, Gambardella, and Zenger: Theory-Based Decisions
302 Strategy Science, 2024, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 297–310, © 2024 INFORMS
Downloaded from informs.org by [144.39.162.95] on 13 December 2024, at 09:54 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
robust research agenda linking the positioning school
and competitive strategy more broadly.
Learning with Theories
Learning is a central path to value creation for both
entrepreneurs and strategists, with simple experience,
repeated practice, failure, and various forms of experi-
mentation seen as the central mechanisms of learning
(Leatherbee and Katila 2020, Pillai et al. 2020). These
processes lead to accumulating knowledge, often
empirically captured as learning curves, where experi-
ence in a task reduces cost or improves productivity
across time. These well-known learning mechanisms
are also the central foundation of the literature on
dynamic capabilities (Eisenhardt and Martin 2000, p.
1105).
But learning is not so straightforward (Levinthal
and March 1993), as the plausible sources from which
one might learn are highly varied and extremely hetero-
geneous. This is particularly evident in entrepreneur-
ship. From whom or what should an entrepreneur or
startup learn from: other entrepreneurs, customers,
experts, experience, or the environment? For exam-
ple, lean startup argues the answer is customers and
therefore advises deploying minimum viable products
(MVPs), which enable validatedlearning (Shepherd
and Gruber 2021, Blank and Eckhardt 2024). Others
emphasize learning from the advice from peers or
learning from mentors(Chatterji et al. 2019, Cohen
et al. 2019a, b). But peers, mentors, other founders, and
investors all come with different advice. How should a
startup decide which advice is correct, which to ignore,
and which to learn from? For those deploying lean
startup, which customers should be listened to? The
problem is that using lean startup might lead decision
makers to learn trivial things—reaching conclusions
that are seemingly validatedby customers but lead-
ing to incremental learning (Felin et al. 2024). In all,
among the cacophony of heterogeneous advice and
plausible sources of learning, economic actors need to
avoid learning the wrong things.
The TBV advocates a completely different approach
to learning. Learning is theory dependent. Theory-
driven learning is more about validating the underlying
causal path to value rather than gaining social validation
or learning from others’ advice. Social validation and
advice can of course be vitally important, though it
plays a different role within the TBV. But given that
future states are inherently difficult to validate in the
first place, the emphasis is on the causal reasoning itself.
Perhaps a counterintuitive and provocative claim of the
TBV is that while focal economic actors—like startups
and firms—can certainly learn from others, it might be
that others should just as readily learn from these eco-
nomic actors. The learning literature has been overly
focused on exogenous sources of learning (including
peers, others, experts, and the environment), whereas
learning might also be endogenous to the theories of
economic actors. If this is the case, then a central issue is
the ability of economic actors to persuade others
about the plausibility of their theory and causal path
(Ehrig and Schmidt 2022, Adner and Levinthal 2024).
Of course, the method the TBV advocates for eco-
nomic actors is simply the scientific method that we
advocate for and use ourselves. Theories guide the
experiments and evidence gathering that we take up
for validation. Rather than relying on simple trial and
error, theories define hypotheses and premises to test.
Through the scientific method, organizations test
hypotheses in practice and gather data and feedback
to refine their understanding of what pragmatically
works. From this perspective, learning is an ongoing,
iterative process of developing and testing theories to
continuously improve decision making and organiza-
tional performance.
Many of the papers in the special issue directly con-
nect to learning, highlighting ways in which a theory-
based, scientific approach shapes and often accelerates
the process of learning (Adner and Levinthal 2024,
Camuffo et al. 2024a, Chavda et al. 2024, Ehrig and
Zenger 2024, Hannah and Ott 2024, Sorenson 2024, Val-
entine et al. 2024). We see vast opportunities for contin-
ued theoretical and empirical progress, as future work
either integrates theory-based learning with traditional
approaches to learning or provides important contrasts.
In addition, there is important work to do within the
TBV to better integrate Bayesian learning and experi-
mentation with concepts of belief revision (Ehrig and
Schmidt 2022). The RCT work that has already emerged
under the theory-based umbrella tests the comparative
usefulness of two approaches to learning in an entrepre-
neurial setting. But the implications for learning extend
far beyond entrepreneurship. Learning is central to per-
formance in innovation, in organizational design, in
strategy, and at all levels of an organization, and explor-
ing the nature and usefulness of theory-based learning
in these contexts remains a significant opportunity.
Financing and Evaluating Theories
The process of valuing companies, especially early stage
ventures, remains a particularly challenging task.
Venture capitalists and private equity of course exist for
precisely this reason—they are in the business of evalu-
ating, valuing and investing in companies which
otherwise have difficulty attracting financing(Gom-
pers and Lerner 2001, p. 145; Lerner and Leamon 2023).
Much of this literature remains relatively descriptive,
focusing on financing aspects such as how venture capi-
talists structure contracts to manage uncertainty (Ewens
et al. 2022), cycles in venture capital investment (Jane-
way et al. 2021), and the critical role venture capital
plays in fostering innovation (Lerner and Nanda 2020).
Felin, Gambardella, and Zenger: Theory-Based Decisions
Strategy Science, 2024, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 297–310, © 2024 INFORMS 303
Downloaded from informs.org by [144.39.162.95] on 13 December 2024, at 09:54 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Other work has asked the important question of
whether valuations should prioritize the management
team (the jockey) or the business idea and execution
(the horse) in their decision making (Kaplan et al.
2009), generally concluding with an answer of both
(Gompers et al. 2020).
But, of course, evaluating the team is much easier
than evaluating the business idea itself. There is enor-
mous uncertainty involved in building a valuation
model that captures the potential prospects for and
payoffs of a new venture. Much of the uncertainty
surrounds the theory that undergirds the venture,
including the validity of its assumptions and the sound-
ness of the logic that connects them. Inherent to the val-
uation task is an information asymmetry problem
(Akerlof 1970). Founders seek to persuade investors of
the soundness of their theory, whereas investors seek to
evaluate it. Of course, as with any information asymme-
try problem, there is the potential for an unfavorable
market for lemonsoutcome to result. In this case, the
quality of a venture’s theory may be difficult to commu-
nicate, particularly because high quality theories are
also unique and contrarian. Therefore, to elevate valua-
tion, founders may choose to diminish the uniqueness
of their theories, thereby lowering uncertainty and
enabling easier evaluation of their ventures (Litov et al.
2012, Benner and Zenger 2016). This bias toward easy
evaluation leads to more incremental value creation.
Thus, this information asymmetry not only affects
the flow of capital but also influences the very strate-
gies firms are willing to pursue, potentially leading to
suboptimal outcomes for both the entrepreneur and
the VC.
In the TBV this asymmetry runs beyond pure infor-
mation. It is not merely that the founder and financier
possess different information, but rather that they pos-
sess different beliefs (Felin et al. 2024). In the TBV, the
asymmetry arises not merely from differences in avail-
able data, but from fundamental differences in how
investors and entrepreneurs understand the venture’s
theory of value. For example, entrepreneurs may have
a contrarian belief about a causal path to some future
state and they seek funding to pursue relevant experi-
ments that test this causal path. The central valuation
challenge is not really about information asymmetry
or even whether these experiments will overcome it,
but rather awareness asymmetry regarding the under-
lying causal logic and strategic narrative. This places a
premium on the ability of entrepreneurs to persuade
funders that their causal path is plausible—a task that
becomes more challenging the more novel and com-
plex the underlying theory. We see enormous opportu-
nity to draw on the emerging TBV to build and
empirically test normative solutions to evaluating and
valuing theories in contexts such as entrepreneurship
and finance.
Entrepreneurs as Theorists
The TBV has made its deepest inroads into entrepre-
neurship (Felin and Zenger 2009, Camuffo et al. 2024b,
Coali et al. 2024). Early-stage entrepreneurs are a natu-
ral context for studying, analyzing and empirically test-
ing the TBV (Camuffo et al. 2020). Entrepreneurs, at
early stages, face rampant uncertainty. And the TBV is a
normative approach that asks entrepreneurs and start-
ups to utilize the scientific method to develop their own
theory and path to value creation (Felin et al. 2024).
Some critiques of the TBV argue its link to the scien-
tific method makes it poorly suited for understanding
the uncertain process of entrepreneurship. As the argu-
ment goes, entrepreneurs aim to create uncertain
futures, whereas scientists seek to explain the present or
uncover truths (Sergeeva et al. 2022). Similar logic is
often used to place the TBV and its application of the sci-
entific method (Zellweger and Zenger 2023) within the
discovery side of the creation versus discovery debate
(Alvarez et al. 2024). Although the creation-discovery
distinction is valuable, the pragmatist orientation of the
TBV and the scientific method finds it less central to its
agenda (see Zellweger and Zenger (2022a) for a more
complete discussion). As the pragmatist philosopher
Richard Rorty argues, scientists themselves are better
thought of as solving puzzles than as gradually disclos-
ing the true nature of things (2007, p. 77). The TBV
simply sees entrepreneurs, like scientists, as problem
finders and solvers (Nickerson and Zenger 2004, Felin
et al. 2021), who pragmatically fixbeliefs, which if
they work out well count as discoveries(Williams
2009, p. xxviii). Economic actors acting as pragmatist
scientists simply have less need for this the made-
versus-found distinction (Zellweger and Zenger 2022a;
see also Dewey (1916)).
The TBV is most interested in the practical agenda of
enabling startups and economic actors to create value
through the development of unique theories and causal
paths. Randomized control trials—thus far, largely with
entrepreneurs and small firms—have offered unique
insights into this process. For instance, research shows
that entrepreneurs who adopt a theory-based, scientific
approach terminate underperforming ventures earlier,
thereby avoiding the unnecessary waste of resources.
They also perform better conditional on their survival
(Camuffo et al. 2020, 2024b). These firms are also more
likely to avoid false positives—bad ventures or
ideas—because the approach fosters skepticism and
doubt, leading economic actors to more carefully assess
their decisions and steer clear of poorly performing pro-
jects while still allowing them to exploit potentially
valuable new ideas (avoid false negatives). A recent
study by Coali et al. (2024) demonstrates that adopting
a scientific approach to decision making leads to stricter
project selection, with entrepreneurs terminating low-
potential projects earlier. Although this might suggest
Felin, Gambardella, and Zenger: Theory-Based Decisions
304 Strategy Science, 2024, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 297–310, © 2024 INFORMS
Downloaded from informs.org by [144.39.162.95] on 13 December 2024, at 09:54 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
an increased likelihood of false negatives (discarding
potentially viable projects), the evidence shows that
these entrepreneurs are more accurate in identifying
which projects to terminate. Over the long term, the sci-
entific approach results in better economic outcomes, as
resources are reallocated to more promising ventures
that receive more external funding and survive longer.
A significant research opportunity lies in comparing
how various treatments and interventions derived from
alternate entrepreneurship theories fare and compete
against each other (Felin et al. 2024). That is, we should
allow varied entrepreneurial approaches to put forward
their normative implications and treatments and then
compare their efficacy. Some recent empirical work
within the TBV has started this process. For example,
Gambardella and Messinese (2024) study 308 early
stage entrepreneurs in Italy and show that theory-
driven entrepreneurs perform better on average than
entrepreneurs who follow a design-based approach
that puts actions before theories, although for more
innovative projects the ideal approach is a combination
of the two. Agarwal et al. (2023) run an RCT with Tanza-
nian entrepreneurs that compares a theory- and
evidence-based approach with an approach that focuses
only on the collection of evidence and find that the com-
bination of theory- and evidence-based generates
higher performance. In all, we see a need to better under-
stand how and why theory-based approaches elevate
performance, as well as further theoretical and empirical
work comparing varied treatments and approaches. This
might include horse racesbetween various treatments
as well as studies of their interrelation.
Ownership and Strategic Leadership
The TBV offers a unique perspective on ownership.
Ownership is not merely a governance solution, but
something that privileges one economic actor’s theory
over another. Consequently, setting aside the substan-
tial issues of effective persuasion and related politics,
competition for ownership is fundamentally a competi-
tion over theories. In this regard, the TBV relates to the
recent literature on ownership competence. Decisions
by the owner-leader are driven by a firm’s unique the-
ory about how to create value, with a firm-specific the-
ory providing overarching guidance about what to own
(matching competence), how to own (governance com-
petence), and when to own (timing competence) (Foss
et al. 2021). As this literature describes, ownership is not
just about aligning incentives, as traditional agency the-
ory suggests, but about exercising judgment and apply-
ing a theory of value creation to make decisions about
assets and their use, combination and modification.
Of course, owner-leaders also compete based on their
capacity to learn through a scientific, theory-based
approach to decision making (Camuffo et al. 2023).
Concentrated ownership that enables the pursuit of
rather contrarian theories may be of particular impor-
tance in uncertain environments where opinions about
how to proceed are most varied. This dynamic may
explain why concentrated ownership often outper-
forms more dispersed ownership models, particularly
in environments where innovation and strategic flexi-
bility are critical.
We see greater need for work that explores the
linkages between ownership, leadership and types of
theories. As noted, some theories demand tacit under-
standing and expertise that are particularly difficult
to share without costly investments to persuade and
build understanding (both cognitive and in terms of
resources). These unique theories make decision dele-
gation particularly difficult and elevate the need for
owners to also be strategists (Camuffo et al. 2023). These
owners may then recruit teams which share similar
values and understanding of the underlying theory—
an additional topic worth empirical inquiry.
Finally, there are interesting unexplored questions
around how to motivate and incentivize the exploration
of a theory. Incentives are effective when contracts are
anchored to easily observed inputs or outputs. But in
the case of exploring theories, correct inputs or outputs
may be difficult to specify, in part because learning
that a theory does not work may be as valuable as learn-
ing that one does. Another testable hypothesis is that
recruiting teams that believe the owner’s theory may be
more important to performance than crafting the correct
incentives.
Special Issue Papers
The papers in this special issue highlight both the
expansiveness and the foundational nature of the TBV
as a general perspective on value creation. In briefly
summarizing the papers, we divide them into two cate-
gories: (a) papers focused on the theory formation pro-
cesses and (b) papers focused on learning, competing,
and persuading with theories.
Theory Formation Processes
One stream of papers tackles the important question of
where theories come from and how they are developed.
These papers highlight the role of cognition, imagina-
tion and analogy, and introduce various theory devel-
opment practices. Two of these papers also frame a
timely, yet foundational debate about the role that AI
versus human cognition may play in generating theo-
ries that underlie valuable strategies.
Rindova and Martins (2024) argue that the process of
developing a theory starts with a problem and its repre-
sentation (Nickerson and Zenger 2004, Felin and Zenger
2017). They propose that the nature of the problem
determines the type of theory required. For instance,
Felin, Gambardella, and Zenger: Theory-Based Decisions
Strategy Science, 2024, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 297–310, © 2024 INFORMS 305
Downloaded from informs.org by [144.39.162.95] on 13 December 2024, at 09:54 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
problems where current knowledge appears sufficient
for a solution call for analytic theories based on deduc-
tive reasoning and hypothesis testing. By contrast, pro-
blems where current knowledge is deemed insufficient
or inadequate demand constructive theories that define
steps or movements of transformation(Shackle 1972,
p. 51, as quoted by Rindova and Martins (2024)). Within
this constructive category, they further distinguish
between reconfiguration theories—theories that seek
to reorganize or recombine existing knowledge—and
projective theories that propose entirely novel new
states of the world. The paper thus highlights three dis-
tinct paths to theory formation, each linked to specific
problem types.
Carroll and Sorensen (2024) begin with the simple
observation that while causal logic, as advocated by the
TBV, is the optimal method for composing theories of
value, developing causal logic is a difficult and foreign
way to thinkand is not the way most people naturally
discuss strategy(page xxx). Although the TBV is nor-
mative, admittedly what it asks of managers, execu-
tives, and entrepreneurs is difficult. Using different
forms of logic requires disciplined systematic thinking
with detailed attention to unstated assumptions, logical
fallacies, and the like(page xxx). They argue that such
an effort may stymie rather than stimulate efforts to
discuss and debate strategy. Carroll and Sorensen
highlight analogy as a tool that can ease theory develop-
ment and elevates its persuasive capacity. The paper
proposes methods to strengthen analogical reasoning in
strategy, including decomposing analogies into features
or premises, considering both positive and negative
analogies, evaluating both horizontal and vertical rela-
tionships in analogies, and assessing implicit back-
ground knowledge implicit in analogies.
Hannah and Ott (2024) begin with TBV’s fundamen-
tal premise that valuable theories are novel and contrar-
ian and formed from mere fragments of experience and
observation that are then paired with imaginative leaps
to form novel, cohesive, causal understandings of the
world (page xxx). But, as they note, prior empirical
work in the TBV has not focused on the practices associ-
ated with theory development and the formation of
strategy. Through extensive interviews and archival
data analysis, these authors provide a deep empirical
examination of nine new ventures engaged in practices
and unique processes of theory formation. They find
that firms move from a spark of a new idea to a well-
developed actionable theory,by deploying a distinct
set of theorizing practices, and by generating data to
refine their theories.
Csaszar et al. (2024) explore how AI—particularly large
language models—can impact the strategic decision-
making process within firms. The authors examine
whether AI could assist or even substitute human deci-
sion makers in generating and evaluating strategies,
presenting empirical evidence from two studies: one with
a leading accelerator program and another from a startup
competition. The results show that AI-generated business
plans and evaluations are comparable to those created by
human entrepreneurs and investors. Importantly, the
authors link their work to the TBV of strategy, considering
how AI might support or challenge core TBV principles,
which emphasize the role of unique, idiosyncratic theo-
ries in guiding strategic decisions. The paper suggests
that while AI could streamline strategy formation, there is
a risk that it might reinforce conventional approaches at
the expense of novelty. Overall, the authors propose a
framework connecting AI use in strategic decision mak-
ing to firm outcomes and explore how AI might reshape
traditional sources of competitive advantage in strategy,
potentially altering both the application and limits of the
TBV.
Felin and Holweg (2024) criticize the common analogy
between human cognition and computers, arguing that,
although AI relies on backward-looking, data-based
approaches that mirror past patterns, human cognition is
fundamentally different. Human cognition involves
theory-based causal reasoning that is forward-looking,
enabling humans to theorize and experiment in order to
generate new data and knowledge. The authors intro-
duce the idea of data-belief asymmetries,where beliefs
often outpace available data and evidence, motivating
individuals to engage in experimentation to create new
knowledge. AI—including related computational and
probabilistic models of cognition—lacks this ability. Felin
and Holweg link their work to the TBV, emphasizing that
in both strategy and cognition, theories guide individuals
and economic actors to intervene and experiment to enable
the generation of new data and novelty. Although AI
excels at prediction (defined as the minimization of sur-
prise based on past data), it cannot replicate the forward-
looking, experimental approach that is essential to human
reasoning and the creation of novelty. As a result, Felin
and Holweg argue that the potential of AI, as currently
instantiated, to replace human decision making in uncer-
tain environments is fundamentally limited.
Learning, Competing, and Persuading
with Theories
A second stream of papers takes up questions related
to how strategic actors learn, compete, and gather
resources when armed with theories. This stream
explicitly links the consequences for action from posses-
sing a theory, as well as the consequences for theory
development from engaging in action. Several papers
explore the role that theories play in learning. The TBV
argues that the possession of a theory should accelerate
learning. Rather than restrict learning to learning by
doing, theories provide a structured and causal path to
learning—revealing assumptions to test (and poten-
tially revise), subproblems to solve, and necessary
Felin, Gambardella, and Zenger: Theory-Based Decisions
306 Strategy Science, 2024, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 297–310, © 2024 INFORMS
Downloaded from informs.org by [144.39.162.95] on 13 December 2024, at 09:54 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
conditions to make true. More broadly, this stream also
tackles questions related to experimentation, data gath-
ering, persuasion, and resource access.
Sorenson (2024) explores how the internal structure
of theories—such as their size, complexity, and the con-
fidence actors place in their assumptions—affects the
way individuals and organizations search for solutions
to problems. Rather than relying on random or trial-
and-error methods, the paper highlights how having a
theory can guide exploration and experimentation.
Importantly, the paper highlights that simpler, less con-
fident theories can lead to more flexible and rapid learn-
ing, while more elaborate theories may restrict the
range of potential solutions but improve efficiency and
persistence in complex problem solving. These argu-
ments contribute to the TBV by deepening the under-
standing of how theories, beyond just their predictive
accuracy, shape decision making and strategic search,
aligning with TBV’s emphasis on actors developing
their own theories to guide value creation.
Chavda et al. (2024) explicitly compare how learning
processes differ for entrepreneurs who possess theories
from those who lack theories. They distinguish between
theory-based entrepreneurs or entrepreneurs who
hold abstract understandings of their ideas, and what
they term practice-based entrepreneurs—entrepreneurs
who experiment on particular strategies rather than on
underlying logic or ideas. They develop a formal model
that suggests that theory-based entrepreneurs update
their beliefs about the distribution of strategy outcomes
as they search, while practice-based entrepreneurs main-
tain fixed beliefs about these distributions throughout
the search process. They find that theory-based entrepre-
neurs, unlike practice-based entrepreneurs, may con-
tinue searching after finding a high-value strategy.
Further, theory-based entrepreneurs may revert to a pre-
viously discovered strategy, whereas practice-based
entrepreneurs always execute the last strategy found.
Overall, their model shows theory- and practice-based
entrepreneurs use different search behaviors that lead to
different subjective valuations of entrepreneurial ideas.
Their work bridges prior work on entrepreneurial search
theory and the TBV of strategy and contributes to under-
standing how entrepreneurial mindsets shape opportu-
nity discovery and exploitation.
Adner and Levinthal (2024) highlight two factors that
make the process of scientific learning with theories par-
ticularly complex. First, many strategic experiments are
simply nonrepeatable. The very act of experimenting
alters the context in which the next experiment will be
performed (Shelef et al. 2024). Second, many experi-
ments must be jointly taken up by multiple actors, who
must all be collectively persuaded that doing so is use-
ful. These two properties pose challenges for learning
and inference. Nonrepeatability of strategic actions
hampers generalizations and learning across contexts,
conditions, and different types of experience. Joint
experiments imply joint actions that require persuasion
and alignment of multiple stakeholders. Their paper
presents a simple two-by-two matrix of strategy con-
texts based on these dimensions and argues that as
firms grow, they tend to shift toward nonrepeatable
joint action contexts. Theories become more crucial for
prediction and persuasion in complex strategic con-
texts, but the endogenous nature of strategic actions
complicates learning and generalization, and theorizing
in strategy differs from scientific experimentation due
to these unique challenges.
Valentine et al. (2024) explore how adopting a more
formalized approach to theory formation and experi-
mentation shapes the type and nature of pivots that
occur in the process of entrepreneurial learning. The
study examines how formalization in cognitive pro-
cesses (theorization) and evidence evaluation (experi-
mentation) combine to shape entrepreneurial pivots.
Their paper uses both quantitative analysis of human-
coded and machine-learning coded measures, and qual-
itative case studies from a randomized control trial. A
theory-based treatment increased formalization in both
theorization and experimentation. Valentine et al. find
that theorization and experimentation are strongly
complementary in generating focused, radical pivots.
The study contributes to research on theory-driven stra-
tegic decisions and provides practical implications for
entrepreneurs and policymakers. It also demonstrates
the use of AI-generated measures to complement
human coding in strategy research.
Camuffo et al (2024a) develop a framework for
theory-based strategic decision making under uncer-
tainty. The paper represents causal links among the
elements (attributes) of a problem as directed a-cyclical
graphs (DAG, or Bayesian networks). They show
that decision makers should experiment with more
surprising theories, as these experiments produce
greater learning. The framework also distinguishes
between experiments to test theories within a given
problem and experiments that test whether decision
makers have chosen the right problem. In so doing, the
paper tackles the type III error problem (model misspe-
cification) and takes into account the non-Bayesian
aspect of updating with unknown state spaces. This is
equivalent to the call for starting the strategy formation
process by first formulating problems rather than focus-
ing on solutions for given problems (Nickerson and
Zenger 2004, Rumelt 2012). The paper illustrates the
framework using examples from Luxottica and PayPal.
It contributes to the TBV by microfounding the concept
of theory and providing a normative protocol for theory
construction and selection.
Ehrig and Zenger (2024) explore how resource-poor
entrants can secure resources and rents from incum-
bents by competing with their theories and awareness.
Felin, Gambardella, and Zenger: Theory-Based Decisions
Strategy Science, 2024, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 297–310, © 2024 INFORMS 307
Downloaded from informs.org by [144.39.162.95] on 13 December 2024, at 09:54 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
They develop a model that combines the TBV with
value capture theory, particularly as extended by Bryan
et al. (2022). Their model distinguishes between three
types of rents that economic actors can generate: aware-
ness rents, confidence rents, and resource rents. Aware-
ness rents arise when entrants have superior awareness
of future states due to novel theories; confidence rents
can occur when actors share awareness but differ in con-
fidence about theories’ probabilities; and resource rents
reflect traditional value added from unique and valu-
able resources. The paper employs the Tesla-Daimler
partnership as an extended example to illustrate these
concepts and shows how partial theory revelation can
allow entrants to secure resources while maintaining an
advantage. Overall, the paper challenges assumptions
of factor market efficiency in the strategy literature and
calls for rethinking rationality and disclosure in strate-
gic factor markets given competing theories and levels
of awareness.
Conclusion
The TBV offers a framework for understanding how eco-
nomic actors can navigate decision making under uncer-
tainty by developing their own unique and idiosyncratic
theories. By embracing forward-looking causal reason-
ing, experimentation, and problem solving, economic
actors are encouraged to craft causal paths to value
creation. This approach challenges traditional models
and theories—which often are prescribed to decision
makers—by emphasizing the cognitive role of economic
actors themselves in building their own theories. The
papers in this special issue further enrich our under-
standing of the TBV, offering new insights and research
opportunities across key domains like strategy, entrepre-
neurship, and governance.
Endnote
1
This logic is also captured by John Dewey who saw science as a
practical artand further argued that the entities of science are not
only from the scientist and that individuals in every branch of
human endeavor should be experimentalists (Dewey 1916, pp.
413, 438–442). For the evolutionary roots of human theorizing and
proto-scientific reasoning, see Felin and Kauffman (2023, pp.
1382–1387).
References
Adner R, Levinthal D (2024) Strategic experiments in non-
experimental settings: Challenges of theory, inference, and per-
suasion in business strategy. Strategy Sci. 9(4):311–321.
Agrawal A, Camuffo A, Gambardella A, Scott E, Stern S, eds. (2024)
Bayesian Entrepreneurship (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA).
Agarwal R, Bacco F, Camuffo A, Coali A, Gambardella A, Msangi
H, Sonka ST, Temu A, Waized B, Wormald A (2023) Does a
theory-of-value add value? Evidence from a randomized con-
trol trial with Tanzanian entrepreneurs. Preprint, submitted
April 20, http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.4412041.
Akerlof GA (1970) The market for lemons: Quality uncertainty and
the market mechanism. Quart. J. Econom. 84(3):488–500.
Alvarez SA, Barney JB, Arikan AM, Arikan I (2024) The creation
theory of entrepreneurship and lean startup frameworks: Com-
plementary or contradictory? J. Management 50(8):3064–3079.
Anand J, Kim H, Lu S (2016) Resource characteristics and redeploy-
ment strategies: Toward a theoretical synthesis. Resource Rede-
ployment and Corporate Strategy (Emerald Group Publishing
Limited, Bingley, UK), 155–184.
Arrow KJ (1986) Rationality of self and others in an economic sys-
tem. J. Bus. 59(4):S385–S399.
Barney JB (1986) Strategic factor markets: Expectations, luck, and
business strategy. Management Sci. 32(10):1231–1241.
Barney J (1991) Firm resources and sustained competitive advan-
tage. J. Management 17(1):99–120.
Barney JB (1995) Looking inside for competitive advantage. Acad.
Management Perspective 9(4):49–61.
Benabou R, Tirole J (2016) Mindful economics: The production, con-
sumption, and value of beliefs. J. Econom. Perspective 30(3):141–164.
Benjamin DJ (2019) Errors in probabilistic reasoning and judgment
biases. Douglas Bernheim B, DellaVigna S, Laibson D, eds.
Handbook of Behavioral Economics: Applications and Foundations
(Elsevier, Amsterdam), 69–186.
Benner MJ, Zenger T (2016) The lemons problem in markets for
strategy. Strategy Sci. 1(2):71–89.
Blank S, Eckhardt JT (2024) The lean startup as an actionable theory
of entrepreneurship. J. Management 50(8):3012–3034.
Brandenburger AM, Stuart Jr HW (1996) Value-based business strat-
egy. J. Econom. Management Strategy 5(1):5–24.
Bresnahan TF (2012) Generality, recombination, and reuse. The Rate
and Direction of Inventive Activity Revisited (University of Chi-
cago Press, Chicago), 611–656.
Bryan KA, Ryall MD, Schipper BC (2022) Value capture in the face
of known and unknown unknowns. Strategy Sci. 7(3):157–189.
Camuffo A, Gambardella A, Pignataro A (2023) Framing strategic
decisions in the digital world. Strategic Management Rev. 4(2):
127–160.
Camuffo A, Gambardella A, Pignataro A (2024a) Theory-driven
strategic management decisions. Strategy Sci. 9(4):382–396.
Camuffo A, Cordova A, Gambardella A, Spina C (2020) A scientific
approach to entrepreneurial decision making: Evidence from a
randomized control trial. Management Sci. 66(2):564–586.
Camuffo A, Gambardella A, Messinese D, Novelli E, Paolucci E,
Spina C (2024b) A scientific approach to entrepreneurial deci-
sion-making: Large-scale replication and extension. Strategic
Management J. 45(6):1209–1237.
Carroll G, Sørensen JB (2024) Strategy theory using analogy: Ratio-
nale, tools, and examples. Strategy Sci. 9(4):483–498.
Chater N (2018) Mind Is Flat: The Remarkable Shallowness of the Impro-
vising Brain (Yale University Press, New Haven, CT).
Chater N, Felin T, Funder DC, Gigerenzer G, Koenderink JJ, Krue-
ger JI, Noble D, et al. (2018) Mind, rationality, and cognition:
An interdisciplinary debate. Psychonomics Bull. Rev. 25:793–826.
Chatterji A, Delecourt S, Hasan S, Koning R (2019) When does
advice impact startup performance? Strategic Management J.
40(3):331–356.
Chavda A, Gans JS, Stern S (2024) Theory-based entrepreneurial
search. Strategy Sci. 9(4):397–415.
Chesbrough HW (2003) Open Innovation: The New Imperative for Cre-
ating and Profiting from Technology (Harvard Business School
Publishing Company, Cambridge, MA).
Coali A, Gambardella A, Novelli E (2024) Scientific decision-
making, project selection and longer-term outcomes. Res. Policy
53(6):105022.
Cohen SL, Bingham CB, Hallen BL (2019a) The role of accelerator
designs in mitigating bounded rationality in new ventures.
Admin. Sci. Quart. 64(4):810–854.
Cohen S, Fehder DC, Hochberg YV, Murray F (2019b) The design of
startup accelerators. Res. Policy 48(7):1781–1797.
Felin, Gambardella, and Zenger: Theory-Based Decisions
308 Strategy Science, 2024, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 297–310, © 2024 INFORMS
Downloaded from informs.org by [144.39.162.95] on 13 December 2024, at 09:54 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Csaszar FA, Ketkar H, Kim H (2024) Artificial intelligence and stra-
tegic decision-making: Evidence from entrepreneurs and inves-
tors. Strategy Sci. 9(4):322–345.
Denrell J, Fang C, Winter SG (2003) The economics of strategic
opportunity. Strategic Management J. 24(10):977–990.
Dewey J (1916) Essays in Experimental Logic (University of Chicago
Press, Chicago).
Ehrig T, Foss N (2022) Why we need normative theories of entrepre-
neurial learning that go beyond Bayesianism. J. Bus. Venturing
Insights 18:e00335.
Ehrig T, Schmidt J (2022) Theory-based learning and experimenta-
tion: How strategists can systematically generate knowledge at
the edge between the known and the unknown. Strategic Man-
agement J. 43(7):1287–1318.
Ehrig T, Zenger T (2024) Competing with theories: Using awareness
and confidence to secure resources and rents. Strategy Sci.
9(4):416–432.
Ehrig T, Felin T, Zenger T (2024) Causal reasoning and the scientific
entrepreneur: Beyond Bayes. Agrawal A, Camuffo A, Gambar-
della A, Scott E, Stern S, eds. Bayesian Entrepreneurship (MIT
Press, Cambridge, MA).
Eisenhardt KM, Martin JA (2000) Dynamic capabilities: What are
they? Strategic Management J. 21(10-11):1105–1121.
Evans GW, Honkapohja S (2005) An interview with Thomas. Macro-
econom. Dynamics 9(4):561–583.
Ewens M, Gorbenko A, Korteweg A (2022) Venture capital con-
tracts. J. Financial Econom. 143(1):131–158.
Felin T, Holweg M (2024) Theory is all you need: AI, human cogni-
tion, and causal reasoning. Strategy Sci. 9(4):346–371.
Felin T, Kauffman S (2023) Disruptive evolution: Harnessing func-
tional excess, experimentation, and science as tool. Industry Cor-
porate Change 32(6):1372–1392.
Felin T, Koenderink J (2022) A generative view of rationality and
growing awareness. Frontiers Psych. 13:80726.
Felin T, Zenger TR (2009) Entrepreneurs as theorists: On the origins
of collective beliefs and novel strategies. Strategic Entrepreneurial
J. 3(2):127–146.
Felin T, Zenger TR (2017) The theory-based view: Economic actors
as theorists. Strategy Sci. 2(4):258–271.
Felin T, Gambardella A, Zenger T (2021) Value laboratory: A tool
for entrepreneurial strategy. Management Bus. Rev. 1(2):68–76.
Felin T, Kauffman S, Zenger T (2023) Resource origins and search.
Strategic Management J. 44(6):1514–1533.
Felin T, Gambardella A, Novelli E, Zenger T (2024) A scientific
method for startups. J. Management 50(8):3080–3104.
Fleming L, Sorenson O (2004) Science as a map in technological
search. Strategic Management J. 25(8-9):909–928.
Foss NJ, Klein PG, Lien LB, Zellweger T, Zenger T (2021) Owner-
ship competence. Strategic Management J. 42(2):302–328.
Gabaix X (2019) Behavioral inattention. Handbook of Behavioral Eco-
nomics: Applications and Foundations 1, vol. 2 (North-Holland,
Amsterdam), 261–343.
Gambardella A, Messinese D (2024) Design-based and theory-based
approaches to strategic decisions. Organ. Sci., ePub ahead of
print October 17, https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.2023.18245.
Gavetti G, Levinthal D (2000) Looking forward and looking back-
ward: Cognitive and experiential search. Admin. Sci. Quart.
45(1):113–137.
Ghemawat P, Levinthal D (2008) Choice interactions and business
strategy. Management Sci. 54(9):1638–1651.
Gompers P, Lerner J (2001) The venture capital revolution. J.
Econom. Perspect. 15(2):145–168.
Gompers PA, Gornall W, Kaplan SN, Strebulaev IA (2020) How do ven-
ture capitalists make decisions? J. Financial Econom. 135(1):169–190.
Gopnik A, Meltzoff AN, Kuhl PK (1999) The Scientist in the Crib:
Minds, Brains, and How Children Learn (William Morrow & Co.,
Farfield, NJ).
Hannah D, Ott T (2024) On the origin of entrepreneurial theories:
How entrepreneurs craft complex causal models with theoriz-
ing and data. Strategy Sci. 9(4):461–482.
Heckman J, Pinto R (2024) Econometric causality: The central role of
thought experiments. J. Econometrics 243(1–2):105719.
Helfat CE, Eisenhardt KM (2004) Inter-temporal economies of scope,
organizational modularity, and the dynamics of diversification.
Strategic Management J. 25(13):1217–1232.
Janeway WH, Nanda R, Rhodes-Kropf M (2021) Venture capital
booms and start-up financing. Annu. Rev. Financial Econom.
13(1):111–127.
Kahneman D (2003) Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for
behavioral economics. Amer. Econom. Rev. 93(5):1449–1475.
Kahneman D, Sibony O, Sunstein CR (2021) Noise: A Flaw in Human
Judgment (Hachette, New York).
Kaplan SN, Sensoy BA, Str ¨
omberg P (2009) Should investors bet on
the jockey or the horse? Evidence from the evolution of firms
from early business plans to public companies. J. Finance
64(1):75–115.
Kauffman SA (1993) The Origins of Order: Self-Organization and Selec-
tion in Evolution (Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK).
Koppl R, Gatti RC, Devereaux A, Fath BD, Herriot J, Hordijk W,
Kauffman S, et al. (2023) Explaining Technology (Cambridge Uni-
versity Press, Cambridge, UK).
Laursen K, Salter A (2006) Open for innovation: The role of openness
in explaining innovation performance among UK manufacturing
firms. Strategic Management J. 27(2):131–150.
Leatherbee M, Katila R (2020) The lean startup method: Early-stage
teams and hypothesis-based probing of business ideas. Strategic
Entrepreneurial J. 14(4):570–593.
Leiblein MJ, Reuer JJ, Zenger T (2018) What makes a decision strate-
gic? Strategy Sci. 3(4):558–573.
Lerner J, Leamon A (2023) Venture Capital, Private Equity, and the Financ-
ing of Entrepreneurship (John Wiley & Sons, Hoboken, NJ).
Lerner J, Nanda R (2020) Venture capital’s role in financing innova-
tion: What we know and how much we still need to learn. J.
Econom. Perspective 34(3):237–261.
Levinthal DA, March JG (1993) The myopia of learning. Strategic
Management J. 14(S2):95–112.
Levinthal DA, Wu B (2024) Resource redeployment and the pursuit
of the new best use: Economic logic and organizational chal-
lenges. Strategy Sci., ePub ahead of print June 21, https://doi.
org/10.1287/stsc.2022.0105.
Lippman SA, Rumelt RP (2003) A bargaining perspective on
resource advantage. Strategic Management J. 24(11):1069–1086.
Litov LP, Moreton P, Zenger TR (2012) Corporate strategy, analyst
coverage, and the uniqueness paradox. Management Sci. 58(10):
1797–1815.
MacDonald G, Ryall MD (2004) How do value creation and compe-
tition determine whether a firm appropriates value? Manage-
ment Sci. 50(10):1319–1333.
Makadok R, Barney JB (2001) Strategic factor market intelligence: An
application of information economics to strategy formulation
and competitor intelligence. Management Sci. 47(12):1621–1638.
Maritan CA, Peteraf MA (2011) Invited editorial: Building a bridge
between resource acquisition and resource accumulation. J.
Management 37(5):1374–1389.
Nickerson JA, Zenger TR (2004) A knowledge-based theory of the
firm—The problem-solving perspective. Organ. Sci. 15(6):617–632.
Novelli E, Spina C (2024) Making business model decisions like
scientists: Strategic commitment, uncertainty, and economic
performance. Strategic Management J., ePub ahead of print July
9, https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3636.
Pearl J, Mackenzie D (2018) The Book of Why: The New Science of
Cause and Effect (Basic Books, New York).
Pillai SD, Goldfarb B, Kirsch DA (2020) The origins of firm strategy:
Learning by economic experimentation and strategic pivots
Felin, Gambardella, and Zenger: Theory-Based Decisions
Strategy Science, 2024, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 297–310, © 2024 INFORMS 309
Downloaded from informs.org by [144.39.162.95] on 13 December 2024, at 09:54 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
in the early automobile industry. Strategic Management J. 41(3):
369–399.
Pinker S (2021) Rationality: What It Is, Why It Seems Scarce, Why It
Matters (Penguin, New York).
Porter ME (1985) Competitive Advantage (Free Press, New York).
Porter ME (1991) Toward a dynamic theory of strategy. Strategic
Management J. 12(S2):95–117.
Porter M, Siggelkow N (2008) Contextuality within activity systems
and sustainability of competitive advantage. Acad. Management
Perspect. 22(2):34–56.
Rindova V, Martins L (2024) The imagination advantage: Why and
how strategists combine knowledge and imagination in devel-
oping theories. Strategy Sci. 9(4):499–514.
Rorty R (2007) Philosophy as Cultural Politics: Volume 4: Philosophical
Papers (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK).
Rumelt RP (2012) Good Strategy/Bad Strategy: The Difference and Why
It Matters (Crown Currency, New York).
Sakhartov AV, Folta TB (2015) Getting beyond relatedness as a driver
of corporate value. Strategic Management J. 36(13):1939–1959.
Savage LJ (1972) The Foundations of Statistics (Courier Corporation,
Chelmsford, MA).
Schumpeter JA (1934) The Theory of Economic Development (Harvard
University Press, Cambridge, UK).
Sergeeva A, Bhardwaj A, Dimov D (2022) Mutable reality and
unknowable future: Revealing the broader potential of pragma-
tism. Acad. Management Rev. 47(4):692–696.
Shackle GLS (1972) Epistemics and Economics: A Critique of Economic
Doctrines (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK).
Shelef O, Wuebker R, Barney JB (2024) Heisenberg effects
in experiments on business ideas. Acad. Management Rev.
Forthcoming.
Shepherd DA, Gruber M (2021) The lean startup framework: Clos-
ing the academic–practitioner divide. Entrepreneurial Theory
Practice 45(5):967–998.
Simon HA (1955) A behavioral model of rational choice. Quart. J.
Econom. 69(1):99–118.
Simon HA (1956) Rational choice and the structure of the environ-
ment. Psych. Rev. 63(2):129.
Simon HA (1990) Invariants of human behavior. Annu. Rev. Psych.
41(1):1–20.
Sorenson O (2024) Theory, search, and learning. Strategy Sci.
9(4):372–381.
Thaler RH (2016) Behavioral economics: Past, present, and future.
Amer. Econom. Rev. 106(7):1577–1600.
Valentine J, Novelli E, Agarwal R (2024) The theory-based view and
strategic pivots. Strategy Sci. 9(4):433–460.
Weitzman ML (1998) Recombinant growth. Quart. J. Econom.
113(2):331–360.
Williams M (2009) Introduction to the thirtieth-anniversary edition.
Philosophy and the Mirror of Nature (Princeton University Press,
Princeton, NJ), xiii–xxx.
Wuebker R, Zenger T, Felin T (2023) The theory-based view: Entre-
preneurial microfoundations, resources, and choices. Strategic
Management J. 44(12):2922–2949.
Zellweger T, Zenger T (2022a) Entrepreneurs as scientists: A prag-
matist alternative to the creation discovery debate. Acad. Man-
agement Rev. 47(4):696–699.
Zellweger T, Zenger T (2022b) Entrepreneurs as scientist, Bayesian infer-
ence, and belief revision. J. Bus. Venturing Insights. Forthcoming.
Zellweger T, Zenger T (2023) Entrepreneurs as scientists: A pragma-
tist approach to producing value out of uncertainty. Acad. Man-
agement Rev. 48(3):379–408.
Felin, Gambardella, and Zenger: Theory-Based Decisions
310 Strategy Science, 2024, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 297–310, © 2024 INFORMS
Downloaded from informs.org by [144.39.162.95] on 13 December 2024, at 09:54 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
... This paper develops a formal model that explores how entrepreneurial teams develop, validate, and commit to a theory of value. We base our theorizing and subsequent modelbuilding on a particular strand of philosophy of science with connections to the theory-based view: pragmatism (Ehrig and Foss, 2022;Felin, Gambardella, and Zenger, 2024b;Sergeeva, Bhardwaj, and Dimov, 2022;Zenger, 2023, 2022). The model captures the decision-making process of a nascent entrepreneurial team at two distinct stages: (1) the construction of an initial theory and subsequent refinement and updating of the content of that theory and (2) the group decision to commit to act as a group to instantiate the theory as a new venture or abandon the process. ...
Article
Full-text available
Scholars argue that artificial intelligence (AI) can generate genuine novelty and new knowledge and, in turn, that AI and computational models of cognition will replace human decision making under uncertainty. We disagree. We argue that AI’s data-based prediction is different from human theory-based causal logic and reasoning. We highlight problems with the decades-old analogy between computers and minds as input–output devices, using large language models as an example. Human cognition is better conceptualized as a form of theory-based causal reasoning rather than AI’s emphasis on information processing and data-based prediction. AI uses a probability-based approach to knowledge and is largely backward looking and imitative, whereas human cognition is forward-looking and capable of generating genuine novelty. We introduce the idea of data–belief asymmetries to highlight the difference between AI and human cognition, using the example of heavier-than-air flight to illustrate our arguments. Theory-based causal reasoning provides a cognitive mechanism for humans to intervene in the world and to engage in directed experimentation to generate new data. Throughout the article, we discuss the implications of our argument for understanding the origins of novelty, new knowledge, and decision making under uncertainty.
Article
Full-text available
Research Summary This study abductively investigates how a firm's degree of business model development—the extent to which strategic choices are crystallized—moderates the impact of a scientific approach to decision‐making on performance. We present findings from a field experiment involving 261 entrepreneurs, where treated entrepreneurs learn to apply a scientific approach, while control counterparts receive comparable content without this approach. Results show that the effect of scientific decision making varies with business model development. Treated entrepreneurs with higher degrees of business model development elaborated their theories of value focusing on lower‐level choices, achieving superior economic performance compared to controls. Conversely, treated entrepreneurs with lower levels of business model development reevaluated fundamental aspects, resulting in increased epistemic uncertainty and less favorable short‐term economic outcomes compared to controls. Managerial Abstract Using a field experiment with 261 entrepreneurs, we explored how the degree of business strategy definition influences the benefits of adopting a scientific approach to decision‐making. In the experiment, half of the entrepreneurs were taught to use a scientific approach for making decisions (the treated group), while the others received similar training without the scientific approach (the control group). Results show that treated entrepreneurs with already defined strategies benefited more, experiencing improved performance even in the short term. Conversely, treated entrepreneurs with strategies still under definition experienced more uncertainty and lower short‐term economic performance, as the scientific approach prompted them to reassess and adjust their core strategic decisions.
Article
Full-text available
We theorize why and how strategists develop different types of theories when confronted with different types of problems by combining knowledge and imagination in different ways. We propose that strategists’ epistemic stances affect how they combine knowledge and imagination and whether they develop either analytic theories, or constructive theories of two types: reconfigurative and projective. We theorize how imagination complements knowledge in theory development to generate distinctive strategies and strategic advantages. We argue that analytic theories enable conjectural anticipation, which contributes to early timing of strategic actions; that reconfigurative theories posit novel value dimensions and enable industry shaping; and that projective theories articulate novel possibilities to shape desired and desirable futures. Our ideas advance research on how imagination is leveraged in theory development, future-oriented strategizing, and shaping strategies.
Article
Full-text available
We introduce two dimensions that help situate the approach to strategy as an exercise of theory building and experimentation. First, we consider whether a given experiment is repeatable or nonrepeatable: the extent to which the very undertaking of a given experiment will change how the world-consumers, competitors, ecosystem partners-will react to future experiments, even if identical to the original. Second, we consider whether a given experiment can be undertaken by a single actor or requires the joint effort and buy-in of other actors in the internal or external ecosystem of the firm, and, in turn, the extent to which persuasion becomes a critical role of theory. We show how these two properties-nonrepeatability and joint action-impact the nature of inference from strategic actions and the ability to benefit from learning. Further, these properties suggest a more deliberative calculus regarding the cost of experimentation and highlight the role of theory as a basis for both prediction and persuasion in the service of choosing how to initiate and learn from strategic acts in nonexperimental settings.
Article
The emerging theory-based view depicts entrepreneurs as sophisticated thinkers who form, update, and act on rich causal theories. In support of this view, recent empirical work has demonstrated both (a) the value of theories as well as (b) the importance of experimentation for testing and refining theories. Yet, the process by which entrepreneurs initially form these theories remains largely unobserved. To address this gap, we conduct a longitudinal study of nine consumer platform ventures over five years. Our primary contribution is to illuminate how entrepreneurs move from the spark of an initial idea to an actionable theory. This process begins with a thesis, which is an initial, poorly formed idea that guides subsequent learning and theorizing. To elaborate this thesis, entrepreneurs then knit together multiple distinct mental theorizing practices, as well as different approaches to generating new data. Extending prior work, we articulate the distinct roles these practices play in terms of adding novelty, identifying new subproblems, and explicating beliefs. We also add insight into the role of data generation in spurring further theorizing. Overall, we contribute empirical evidence and a rich processual understanding of how entrepreneurs articulate complex causal theories. Funding: We appreciate the generous support of the Strategy Research Foundation Dissertation Research Grant Program.
Article
An assumption of factor market efficiency is often used to grant primacy to firms’ existing unique and valuable resources as the source of economic rents. But this assumption is difficult to reconcile with observed market outcomes. For instance, five of the six companies with the highest global market capitalization in 2022 were upstarts in their industries with few resources at their origins. More surprising, three of these entrants were assisted by incumbents with vastly superior resources in assembling the resources they required. In this paper we explore how entrants compete with theories to secure resources from incumbents and capture rents. We introduce a modeling approach in which theories with causal logic generate awareness of valuable potential future states and shape the beliefs about payoffs and probabilities associated with these states. We combine work in the theory-based view and value capture theory to distinguish among three distinct sources of economic rents that are potentially available to entrants: awareness rents, confidence rents, and resource rents. We explore the circumstances under which these three types of rents are available. By exploring the role of theories and awareness in value creation and capture, our paper seeks to deepen our understanding of how entrants both attract resources and secure rents. Funding: T. Zenger was supported by the ION Management Science Lab, Utah.
Article
This paper explores how artificial intelligence (AI) may impact the strategic decision-making (SDM) process in firms. We illustrate how AI could augment existing SDM tools and provide empirical evidence from a leading accelerator program and a start-up competition that current large language models can generate and evaluate strategies at a level comparable to entrepreneurs and investors. We then examine implications for the key cognitive processes underlying SDM—search, representation, and aggregation. Our analysis suggests that AI has the potential to enhance the speed, quality, and scale of strategic analysis, while also enabling new approaches, like virtual strategy simulations. However, the ultimate impact on firm performance will depend on competitive dynamics as AI capabilities progress. We propose a framework connecting AI use in SDM to firm outcomes and discuss how AI may reshape sources of competitive advantage. We conclude by considering how AI could both support and challenge core tenets of the theory-based view of strategy. Overall, our work maps out an emerging research frontier at the intersection of AI and strategy. History: This paper has been accepted for the Strategy Science Special Issue on Theory-Based View. Funding: The authors are grateful to their collaborating organizations and to the University of Michigan, Bocconi University Junior Researchers’ Grant, and the INSEAD eLab Research Fund for financial support.
Article
We examine how formalization in cognitive processes (theorization) and evidence evaluation (experimentation) influence the type (frequency and radicalness) and nature (impetus, clarity, and coherence) of entrepreneurial pivots. We use a mixed-method research design to analyze rich data from over 1,600 interviews with 261 entrepreneurs within a randomized control trial in London. A quantitative analysis that complements human-coded and machine learning-coded measures reveals that conditional on pivoting, theorization and experimentation are complementary in their association with making single radical pivots. The extensive qualitative-case comparison further elucidates interactions between theorization and experimentation that generate differences in the nature of pivots that range from purposeful (clear and coherent rationale deriving from articulated theory and experimentation), postulatory (informed by articulated theory but not incorporating nuances or surprises generated from experimentation), and remedial (stemming from adjustments to preformed theories that drew on prior experiences) to reactive (driven by environmental stimuli absent a clear theory of value). These insights contribute to the theory-driven strategic decision-making literature and offer practical insights for entrepreneurs, incubators, and policymakers on the benefits of a scientific approach to entrepreneurship. History: This paper has been accepted for the Strategy Science Special Issue on Theory-Based View. Funding: The authors acknowledge financial support from the UK Government Department of Business Energy and Industrial Strategy—Innovate UK [Project 104754, “A Scientific Approach to SMEs Productivity”]. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/stsc.2024.0183 .
Article
This paper studies strategic decisions under uncertainty for which past data are not available. It provides microfoundations of the theory-based view of the firm by showing that the strategic problem starts with the selection of theories rather than choosing actions and that theories are selected through experiments. The value of experimenting with theories increases with the number of theories and with their uncertainty. Moreover, uncertainty makes theories superadditive—that is, experimenting with a more uncertain theory increases the benefits of experimenting with other more uncertain theories. The paper also shows that decision makers should experiment with more “surprising” theories because in this case experiments are more informative and enable more learning. A leading example helps to illustrate our concepts throughout the paper. Funding: A. Camuffo and A. Gambardella acknowledge support from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 Research and Innovation Programme [Grant 101021061].
Article
How should Theory-based entrepreneurs search for strategies to implement their ideas? The theory-based view of strategy posits that decision makers hold key conjectures about their path to success and use theory to understand and test beliefs underlying those conjectures. This causal framework also has implications for entrepreneurial search: the process by which entrepreneurs uncover strategies to implement their ideas. In this paper, we develop a Bayesian model where entrepreneurs update their beliefs as they conduct entrepreneurial search. We find several optimal behaviors for Theory-based entrepreneurs such as reverting to a previous strategy after finding a relatively poor strategy and continuing to search after finding a relatively good strategy, which are missing when entrepreneurs lack such a theory-based approach. As our theoretical predictions align with examples of successful entrepreneurs, our findings both provide a method to empirically identify Theory-based entrepreneurs and demonstrate the usefulness of applying the theory-based view to entrepreneurial behavior more generally.