ArticlePDF Available

Abstract and Figures

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Content may be subject to copyright.
ENERGY SUPPLY, PUBLIC DEBT, AND ECONOMIC GROWTH
Author(s): Mohamed Awada, Moustapha Badran, Imtynan Khalifeh and Jules Sadefo
Kamdem
Source:
The Journal of Energy and Development
, Autumn 2022 and Spring 2023, Vol. 48,
No. 1/2 (Autumn 2022 and Spring 2023), pp. 233-258
Published by: International Research Center for Energy and Economic Development (ICEED)
Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/10.2307/27284861
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
International Research Center for Energy and Economic Development (ICEED)
is collaborating with
JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
The Journal of Energy and Development
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
ENERGY SUPPLY, PUBLIC DEBT, AND ECONOMIC
GROWTH: CAUSALITY ANALYSIS FOR A PANEL
OF OECD EUROPEAN COUNTRIES
Mohamed Awada, Moustapha Badran, Imtynan Khalifeh, AND
Jules Sadefo Kamdem*
Introduction
Economists have focused on the importance of growth as it is considered a core
government objective and driver of living standards. Economic growth is
*Mohamed Awada earned his Doctorate in Economic Sciences from the University of Montpellier.
In his thesis, he examined the interrelationships between energy supply, public debt, and economic
growth as applied to a group of OECD European countries. His research interests include
macroeconomics, nance, and energy economics with a focus on European countries. His teaching
expertise covers several subjects including corporate nance, nancial analysis, statistics,
microeconomics, macroeconomics, and nancial mathematics.
Moustapha Badran earned his Doctorate in Economic Sciences from the University of Montpellier.
The authors strong command and knowledge of the main nancial and economic theoretical
frameworks have led to his earning multiple scholarships and awards. His research interests include
corporate nance, nancial crises, and capital structure. He currently is at the University of Montpellier
as a temporary Teaching and Research Associate. His teaching expertise covers theoretical
econometrics, time series econometrics, macroeconomics, and microeconomics.
Imtynan Khalifeh is a Ph.D. candidate in Economics Sciences at the University of Montpellier,
specializing in Finance. She holds dual Masters degrees in Banking and Financial Economics from the
Lebanese University and Banking and Finance from Limoges, establishing her strong academic
background. The authors research centers around the impact of Basel III regulations on European
banks, showcasing her expertise in nance, banking, economics, and econometrics. Additionally, she
actively contributes to academia as a Lecturer of Statistics for Business at Montpellier Business School,
imparting her knowledge and fostering analytical skills among her students.
Jules Sadefo Kamdem is currently a Full Professor of Economics & Finance at the University
of Montpellier (UM). He previously was a Professor at the University de Guyane and Lecturer at UM.
(continued)
The Journal of Energy and Development, Vol. 48, Nos. 1-2
Copyright #2023 by the International Research Center for Energy and Economic Development
(ICEED). All rights reserved.
233
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
strongly linked to production, energy, debt, the natural environment, and human
health. Therefore, countries must be aware of the essential role of economic growth
and its impact on economic development and global sustainability. The challenge
is how best to integrate these ideas into mainstream policies and consider how they
can be effectively implemented to support sustainability goals, which in our
research focus is within the context of Europe.
Today, the COVID-19 crisis and the Russian-Ukrainian conict highlight the
importance of energy supply as an eco-political factor due to its role as a catalyst
for economic development and its implications on the worldwide economy via
public debt levels and ination rates. The relationship between energy and eco-
nomic development has captured the attention of both researchers and academia
because of its crucial policy ramications during the past decade. There have been
several studies undertaken to determine the causal linkages between energy and
economic growth applying various methods such as time-series analysis and panel
approaches especially after the seminal work of J. Kraft and A. Kraft in 1978,
which is considered as the starting point in this eld. Energy plays a critical role in
an economy both on the demand and supply sides. On the demand side, energy is
one of the commodities that a consumer chooses to purchase to maximize his or
her utility. On the supply side, energy is an important input to production, capital,
human labor, and materials. In addition, energy supply is considered a vital factor
for the economic and social development of countries, where the countries that
produce the energy have a high probability of increasing both their economic
growth and living standards. Limiting energy supply can lead to negative effects
on a nations development and its economic growth.
1
An energy shortage and inad-
equate energy supply are essential factors that can adversely impact energy secu-
rity, economic and social welfare, and increase the costs of production and
transportation. The other topic that has been vigorously discussed in the literature
is the relationship between public debt expansion and economic growth, which has
grabbed the attention of many analysts during recent years stimulated by the sharp
increase in public debt after the 2008 nancial crisis, especially in the Euro area.
Indeed, in response to the nancial crisis, governments employed scal policies to
raise aggregate demand. The consensus among economists is that increases in pub-
lic debt in the short run, due to scal policies, will result in a boost to economic
growth. However, there are dissenting views about the long-term impact, some
After earning his Ph.D. in Mathematical Finance and the qualication to be MCF in Applied
Mathematics, he obtained a HDR in Economics and the qualications to be Professor in Economics
and Management. He has published numerous economics, nance, and mathematics articles in
journals such as Insurance: Mathematics and Economics,Environmental Modeling and Assessment,
JORS,IJTAF,Economic Modeling,Journal of Multivariate Analysis,Quantitative Economics,ROIW,
Annals of Finance,CSDA,New Mathematics and Natural Computation,Annals of Operations
Research,andJQE, among others.
234 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
economists suggest that there is a negative relationship between public debt and
economic growth, while others deny the relationship between these variables in the
long term.
The explanation of economic growtheither by debt or by energyappears to
be more complex than an intuitive interpretation of policy makers. Debt is a
double-edged sword. On the one hand, it promotes consumption and accelerates
capital accumulation, thus contributing to economic growth. On the other hand, by
increasing debt servicing costs, it exposes countries to nancial risks. A strong
expansion of the debt can be associated with a signicant economic contraction
that can last for years.
2
Whatever the economic situation (expansion or recession),
we have noted that for some European OECD countries, the pace of growth is not
the same as for others due to their high indebtedness ratios and lack of energy
resources,
3
where the pace of GDP growth is affected by energy supply for some
countries or by their debt policies for others. Given the nancial and economic
downturn, the group of European OECD members, especially the ones with weak
economiesthe so-called GIIPS countries (Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and
Spain)represent a valuable case for testing the dynamics and relationships of per-
sistently high levels of public decits and external imbalances. It is, therefore,
important to understand the link not only between debt and economic growth but
also between energy and economic growth to derive useful policy indications,
which are necessary to understand whether a reduction in debt or an increase in
energy supply is sufcient to resolve the imbalances.
4
Therefore, the added value
of our study lies in taking into account the energy supply for a better three-
dimensional explanation between energy, debt, and economic growth, on the one
hand, and by splitting the OECD European countries into two sub-samples, GIIPS
and Non-GIIPS counties, on the other hand. It would be appropriate to highlight
our variables of interest, which are energy supply, public debt, and economic
growth, and will be addressed further in the subsequent parts of our article.
First of all, priority must be given to an efcient and sustainable energy supply.
Sustainability is no longer limited to the preservation of the environment. Accord-
ing to the OECD, primary energy supply is dened as energy production plus
energy imports, minus energy exports, minus international bunkers, then plus or
minus stock changes. The International Energy Agency (IEA) energy balance
methodology is based on the caloric content of the energy commodities and a
common unit of account: tone of oil equivalent (toe). Toe is dened as 107 kilocal-
ories (41.868 gigajoules). This quantity of energy is, within a few percent, equal to
the net heat content of one tone of crude oil. The difference between the netand
the grosscaloric value for each fuel is the latent heat of vaporization of the
water produced during the combustion of the fuel. For coal and oil, the net caloric
value is about 5% less than the gross, but for most forms of natural and manufac-
tured gas the difference is 9% to 10%, while for electricity the concept of caloric
has no meaning. The IEA calculates balances using the physical energy content
235ENERGY SUPPLY, PUBLIC DEBT, & ECONOMIC GROWTH
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
method to nd the primary energy equivalent. This indicator is measured in million
tons of oil equivalent (toe) and toe per $1.000 USD. Secondly, public debt refers
to the total nancial commitments made in the form of loans by the State, public
authorities, and the organizations that depend directly on them. It is constantly
changing as a function of the rate of repayment of loans by the State and public
administrations and the new loans they take out to nance their decits, which
occur when expenditures, made possible by borrowing, exceed revenues, leading
to an increase in the debt. Finally, a countrys growth is measured by the increase
in its gross domestic product (GDP) over a given period: month, quarter, half-year,
or year. It is calculated in constant euros,i.e., excluding price increases. It is
manifested by a signicant and lasting increase in the supply of goods and services.
This positive uctuation is evaluated by the annual variation of the GDP indicator,
evaluated in constant currency to take into account ination. This is an indispens-
able, but not always sufcient, proxy for development. Therefore, gaining a greater
understanding of the interactions between these variables is immensely useful for
policy formulation.
This paper proceeds as follows. The next section reviews the literature to estab-
lish the existing knowledge of the relationships between energy, debt, and eco-
nomic growth. The methodology section includes details of the model and
hypotheses, then the results are analyzed and discussed. Finally, future research
directions are suggested.
Brief Literature Review
Energy Economic Growth: In considering the relationship between energy
consumption and economic growth, two opposing views have emerged. One view
is that energy consumption limits growth. It also is argued that the potential impact
of energy consumption on growth varies with the structure of the economy and the
economic growth cycle of the country. Through the development of the economy,
its production structure should move toward services, which are not energy-
intensive activities, as argued by a group of authors such as E. Denison, B. Cheng,
J. Asafu-Adjaye, and R. Solow.
5
The other view implies that energy can be the
source and driver of economic growth. The increase of energy consumption is one
of the effects of economic growth. Moreover, energy is a key source of economic
growth because it multiplies consumption and production activities that involve
energy as a basic production factor.
6
From a physical perspective, energy con-
sumption drives economic productivity and industrial growth and is essential to the
development of any modern economy.
7
Broadly speaking, the connections between energy and growth, developed by
C. Jumbe, A. Shiu and P.-L. Lam, G. Altinay and K. Erdal, S.-T. Chen et al., P.
Mozumder and A. Marathe, J. Squalli, N. Apergis and J. E. Payne, and I. Ozturk
236 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
and A. Acaravci, have been grouped into four categories, each of which has impor-
tant implications for energy policy:
8
(i) The growth hypothesis asserts that there is a unidirectional relationship
between energy consumption and economic growth. It argues that energy
consumption plays a dominant role in economic growth both as a direct
factor in the production process and indirectly as a complement to labor
and capital. Energy is considered here as a complementary factor of
production to the usual factors such as capital and labor. Under these con-
ditions, the implementation of energy policy inuences the level of produc-
tion, according to E. Yu and J.-Y. Choi, S. Tsani, A. Belke et al., and
M. Destek.
9
(ii) The conservation hypothesis suggests that growth generates an increase in
energy consumption. This assumes that a restrictive energy policy can be
implemented in an economy without negative effects on growth. If there is
a unidirectional Granger causality from growth to energy consumption,
this hypothesis is conrmed. Indeed, S. Paul and R. Bhattacharya, A.
Hatemi et al., and T. Gelo assert that energy conservation policies can be
implemented with little or no negative effects on economic growth.
10
(iii) The neutrality hypothesis implies that there is no causal relationship
between energy consumption and economic growth. These two variables
are not correlated. In other words, any increase or decrease in energy con-
sumption does not affect economic growth. This means that neither an
energy-saving policy nor an energy-intensive policy inuences the level of
wealth creation in an economy, as explained by T. Jobert and F. Karanl.
11
(iv) The feedback hypothesis states that there is a two-way causality between
energy consumption and economic growth. This means that energy and
economic policies will be implemented jointly. In this case, the energy
consumption policy should be developed to avoid a negative impact of
energy consumption on economic growth (studies applied to one or groups
of countries: Greece, G7, OECD countries), according to G. Hondroyian-
nis, C.-C. Lee et al., M. Mutascu, and J. Dos et al.
12
Thus, empirical studies related to the above-mentioned hypotheses show a uni-
directional causality that exists from total energy consumption to economic growth
(applied to a group of African countries) concluded by A. Akinlo and S. Solarin.
13
A unidirectional causality in the other direction was concluded by J. Kraft and A.
Kraft
14
applied to the United States for a period from 1947 to 1974 and by R.
Abaidoo
15
using quarterly data over 39 years. The study by M. Behname found a
bidirectional relationship between the two variables.
16
No relationship between
energy and growth was concluded by T. Carminel, explaining that the decoupling
between energy and growth is limited by concerns about the supply of raw materi-
als.
17
As an example, energy-related technologies needed to extract certain
237ENERGY SUPPLY, PUBLIC DEBT, & ECONOMIC GROWTH
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
materials are subject to geopolitical constraints. The raw material supply problem,
in turn, limits the deployment of the equipment needed to improve energy inten-
sity. U. Erol and E. Yu researched a group of countries to nd the causal link
between energy consumption and GDP using the Granger and Sims causality
tests.
18
They concluded that there was one-way causality between energy con-
sumption and GDP for West Germany, two-way causality in Italy, and a lack of
causality between the two variables for France, the United Kingdom, and Canada.
A. Masih and R. Masih applied their work to six Asian countries (India, Indonesia,
Malaysia, Pakistan, the Philippines, and Singapore) using Johansens methodology,
vector error-correction model, and variance decomposition.
19
The discrepancies in
the results are summarized as cointegration between energy consumption and GDP
in India, Indonesia, and Pakistan, and non-cointegration between the two variables
in Malaysia, Singapore, Pakistan, and the Philippines; energy consumption causing
GDP (more energy consumption, more growth) in India; GDP causing energy con-
sumption in Indonesia; and two-way causality in Pakistan. J. Chontanawat et al.
assessed the relationship between the two variables on a panel of over 100 coun-
tries, including 30 OECD and 78 non-OECD countries, to detect the relationship
between energy and growth.
20
Their ndings reveal that energy consumption
drives GDP (more energy consumption, more growth) in 21 OECD countries. For
non-OECD countries, this relationship is found in 36 of the 78 countries or 46%.
In summary, a more common causality between energy consumption and GDP is
noted for advanced OECD countries. From this point of view, a measure focused
on limiting energy consumption would have a greater negative impact on GDP in
OECD countries than in non-OECD countries.
I. Ozturk and A. Acaravci sought to test the relationship between energy and
growth in four Eastern European countries (Albania, Bulgaria, Hungary, and
Romania) over the period 1980-2006 using the Engle and Granger model.
21
They
found a lack of causality for Albania, Bulgaria, and Romania; however, a presence
of bidirectional causality was observed in Hungary.
Public Debt Economic Growth: The second strand of literature is related to
the relationship between public debt and economic growth. The empirical literature
on this topic not only presents ambiguous results but focuses mainly on the possi-
ble impact of high debt levels on economic growth, ignoring the possibility of
reverse causality from growth to debt, with rare exceptions such as the works of
M. Ferreira and M. Puente.
22
However, A. Bell et al. nd that there is some theo-
retical evidence that public debt is likely to accumulate when growth is low.
23
In
this regard, since low growth means more limited government revenues, govern-
ments may be forced to increase their debt levels to maintain the welfare state,
stimulate demand in the short run, and increase growth in the long run, according
to M. Feldstein.
24
Theoretically, neoclassical and endogenous growth models, such
as those of F. Modigliani, P. Diamond, G. Saint-Paul, and J. Aizenman et al., sug-
gest that high levels of public debt would undeniably reduce the rate of economic
238 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
growth.
25
Other channels to support the negative effect of public debt on long-run
growth include the debt overhang hypothesis (P. Krugman and N. Roubini et al.),
26
the liquidity constraint hypothesis (T. Moss and H. Chiang),
27
the crowding-out
hypothesis (H. Hansen),
28
and the uncertainty hypothesis (L. Codogno et al. and J.
Cochrane).
29
Another channel through which high debt can negatively impact
growth is through long-term interest rates (D. Elmendorf and G. Mankiw, V. Tanzi
and N. Chalk).
30
Finally, some of the effects associated with nancial liberaliza-
tion, ranging from increased risk-taking by banks to the accumulation of large
external debt, can make a country vulnerable to economic shocks that often can
have severe recessionary consequences (B. Eichengreen and D. Leblang, U. Nyam-
buu and L. Bernard).
31
Given the theoretical predictions highlighted above, it is
somewhat surprising that C. Reinhart and K. Rogoff concluded that a countrys
debt must reach a threshold of 90% of GDP, beyond which the rate of GDP growth
declines signicantly, has generated such controversy.
32
Other researchers have
strongly criticized this by noting that over the period 1946-2009, countries with
a debt-to-GDP ratio above 90% had an average annual real GDP growth of 2.2%
not -0.1%.
Additional empirical studies have shown the relationship between debt and
growth. C. Checherita-Westphal and P. Rother analyzed the average impact of pub-
lic debt on GDP per capita growth in 12 euro area countries over about 40 years,
starting in 1970.
33
They conclude that there is a non-linear effect of debt on growth
with a turning point beyond which the ratio of public debt to GDP harms growth
in the long run at around 90/100% of GDP. U. Panizza and A. Presbitero studied
the causal effect of government debt on economic growth in a sample of OECD
countries.
34
Their results are consistent with the existing literature, showing a nega-
tive correlation between the two variables. J. Mencinger et al. empirically analyzed
the relationship between the ratio of government debt to GDP and GDP growth on
a panel dataset of 25 European Union (EU) countries.
35
To take into account the
impact of the level of the debt-to-GDP ratio on the real GDP growth rate, they
used panel estimation on a generalized economic growth model augmented with a
debt variable, while also considering some methodological issues such as heteroge-
neity and endogeneity problems. The results of all models indicate a statistically
signicant non-linear impact of government debt ratios on annual growth rates of
GDP per capita. Their research has contributed to a better understanding of the
problem of high public debt and its effect on economic activity in the EU.
The debt-growth and energy-growth relationships have been discussed in the lit-
erature, which leads us to look at the decoupling of growth and energy, on the one
hand, and the problem of public debt in OECD European countries, on the other.
These two facts raise a fundamental question: What can be said about the links
between energy, debt, and GDP? The question is crucial today because we are
exposed to many challenges. The current fall in the global growth rate and its con-
sequences are the subjects of much debate. Is it due to pressure on energy
239ENERGY SUPPLY, PUBLIC DEBT, & ECONOMIC GROWTH
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
resources? Is the high level of public debt related to the link between energy and
economic growth? All of these issues spur greater interest in determining the
potential econometric short- and long-term relationships between energy, debt, and
growth.
Model and Methodology
Model: Based on our brief literature review, and to achieve the studysobjec-
tive, we form a long-run relationship between economic growth, energy supply,
and public debt in a linear logarithmic form as follows in equation (1):
EGRit 5
a
01
b
1ESUit 1
b
2PDEit 1uit (1)
Where i51, , N (number of the chosen countries) denotes the country; t5
1, ,T denotes the time period from 1970 to 2021; u
it
is assumed to be a serially
uncorrelated error term;
a
0
represents the constant in our model; EGR represents
the economic growth, which is our dependent variable; and ESU and PDE repre-
sent the energy supply and the public debt, respectively, which are our independent
variables. The expected signs of energy supply and public debt are positive and
negative, respectively, meaning that energy supply and public debt have, respec-
tively, a positive and negative impact on economic growth in the long term.
Cointegration Methodology: To test the existence of a long-run relationship
among the variables and to capture the short-run dynamics of the variables using
the vector error-correction model (VECM), our methodological strategy is com-
posed of two essential steps.
The rst step is to verify the order of integration for all variables because the
several cointegration tests are valid only if all the studys variables are integrated
in the same order, meaning that they have the same order of integration. We test
the stationarity using four different types of unit root tests divided into common
and individual unit root: Levin, Lin, and Chu (LLC); Im, Pesaran, and Shin (IPS);
a Fisher-type test using Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF); and Phillips-Perron
(PP). In 1997, H. Zapata and A. Rambaldi
36
reported that if the variables are not
integrated in the same order (meaning that some variables are I(0) and the others
are integrated of order one I(1)), the application of Toda and Yamamoto (TY) is
required to be on the safe side and to overcome this problem, whereas the TY pro-
cedure does not impose any prerequisites and knowledge on cointegration.
The second step requires testing the panel cointegration relationship. When all
series and variables are integrated into the same, we can move on to test the panel
cointegration between the variables based on the three fundamental tests: Pedroni;
Kao; and Johansen Fisher. The Pedroni and Kao tests are based on the Engle-
Granger two-step (residual-based) cointegration test. Overall, Pedroni provides
240 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
seven statistics to test the null hypothesis of no cointegration in the heterogeneous
panels. These seven tests can be categorized as either within-dimension (panel tests)
or between-dimension (group tests). These tests are all based on the residuals from
equation (1) and are variants of the ADF and PP tests. The within-dimension tests
pool the autoregressive coefcients across different members of the panel. On the
other hand, the between-dimension tests are less restrictive than the within-dimension
tests in the sense that they allow for the heterogeneity of the parameters across coun-
tries. Kaos test follows the same basic approach as Pedronis tests but species
cross-section-specic intercepts and homogeneous coefcients in the rst step. In
addition, the Fisher test is a combined Johansen and Juselius test. If cointegration
exists between the variables, the ordinary least squares (OLS) method is applied to
ensure that the estimation of equation (1) does not lead to a spurious regression result.
In addition, the parameters estimated by the OLS method are super consistent.
Granger Causality: Then, we look forward to examining the existence and the
direction of the causality between the variables in a panel context. The existence of
cointegration implies that there are long-run equilibrium relationships between the
variables and, thus, Granger causality between them in at least one direction. The
vector error-correction model (VECM) is used to correct the disequilibrium in the
cointegrating relationship, captured by ECT,as well as to test for long- and
short-run causality between the cointegrated variables. The VEC model by deni-
tion is a restricted VAR that has cointegration restrictions built into the specica-
tion so it is designed for use with nonstationary series that are known to be
cointegrated. The VEC specication restricts the long-run behavior of the endoge-
nous variables to converge to their cointegrating relationships while allowing a
wide range of short-run dynamics. The cointegration term is known as the error-
correction term since the deviation from long-run equilibrium is corrected gradu-
ally through a series of partial short-run adjustments. The panel-based VECM is
dened as follows in equation (2):
DEGRit
DESUit
DPDEit
2
6
43
7
51
a
1
a
2
a
3
2
6
43
7
51Pr
p51
b
11p
b
21p
b
31p
b
12p
b
22p
b
32p
b
13p
b
23p
b
33p
2
6
6
43
7
7
5
DEGRit2p
DESUit2p
DPDEit2p
2
6
43
7
5
1
u
1
u
2
u
3
2
6
43
7
5ECTit211
«
1it
«
2it
«
3it
2
6
43
7
5
(2)
Where i51, , N (number of the chosen countries) denotes the country; t5
1, ,T denotes the time period from 1970 to 2021;
«
it
is assumed to be a serially
uncorrelated error term; and ECT is the lagged error-correction term derived from
the long-run cointegration relationship. We follow Abdalla and Murindes process
241ENERGY SUPPLY, PUBLIC DEBT, & ECONOMIC GROWTH
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
to determine the optimal lag length in each equation for a linear system which is
selected by maximizing the value of the R-squared (R
2
) and minimizing the AIC
criteria. In terms of causality, we test four main hypotheses that sum up all the
cases between the three chosen variables as follows:
H
1
: Unidirectional causality relation from variable 1 to variable 2 (Meaning
that the rst variable does Granger causes the second one).
H
2
: Unidirectional causality relation from variable 2 to variable 1 (Meaning
that the second variable does Granger causes the rst one).
H
3
: Bidirectional causality relation between variable 1 and variable 2 (Mean-
ing that both variables do Granger cause each other).
H
4
: No causality relation between both variable 1 and variable 2 (Meaning
that the rst variable does not Granger causes the second variable).
Empirical Results
Data Analysis: In this paper, we have conducted a statistical and econometrical
analysis of 21 OECD European countries for which the most energy-related and
macroeconomic annual data are available from 1970 to 2021. The 21 countries
include the 5 GIIPS (Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, Spain) and the 16 Non-GIIPS
(Germany, Belgium, Finland, France, Netherlands, Luxembourg, Austria,
Denmark, Poland, Hungary, Sweden, Switzerland, Norway, England, Iceland, and
Turkey). The objective was to select the largest and the longest balanced panel.
The full sample is divided into two sub- samples: GIIPS and the Non-GIIPS. Thus,
we construct three different models (balance panel) for the analysis. The data
come from OECDsEconomic Outlook No 110-December 2021 (primary energy
supply, general government gross nancial liabilities, and gross domestic product
volume market prices). To complete the series, we have also used the OECDs
Economic Outlook No 73-June 2003 for all the countries selected to have the
largest observations possible (data calibration between two data sources).
Figures 1-3 show the changing trends for each series of the OECD European
countries (Full sample, GIIPS, and Non-GIIPS countries). Figure 1 shows that the
full sample and Non-GIIPS countries have shown the same signicant increase in
economic growth all over the period (1970-2021). Whereas the series for the other
sample (GIIPS countries) show an almost monotonic increase over the entire time
span. In term of economic growth, we can notice that the full sample is well pre-
sented by the Non-GIIPS countries.
Figure 2 represents the evolution of energy supply from 1970 to 2021 for the
three samples. Overall, we observe that the series have almost the same trend;
however, there were two impactful events. The rst was marked by the response of
energy supply following the nancial crisis of 2008, where we nd the effect to be
242 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
more pronounced for the GIIPS (countries with low growth and high debt as already
discussed in the literature). The second event was in regard to the COVID-19 crisis,
which favored the GIIPS countries as their energy supply was improved in compari-
son to the other two samples (full sample and non-GIIPS countries).
Figure 1
ECONOMIC GROWTH: AVERAGE FOR GDP PER YEAR, 19702021
4,5E+12
4E+12
3,5E+12
3E+12
2,5E+12
2E+12
1,5E+12
1E+12
5E+11
0
Full sample GIIPS countries Non-GIIPS countries
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
2020
Source: Authors.
Figure 2
ENERGY SUPPLY: AVERAGE PER YEAR, 19702021
100000000
90000000
80000000
70000000
60000000
50000000
40000000
30000000
20000000
10000000
Full sample GIIPS Non-GIIPS
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
2020
Source: Authors.
243ENERGY SUPPLY, PUBLIC DEBT, & ECONOMIC GROWTH
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The trend for public debt is presented in Figure 3. The graph shows that all
three series have the same upward trend reected in an excessive increase in debt
levels, mainly in response to three important events: the 2008 nancial crisis; the
sovereign debt crisis (2011); and the COVID-19 crisis (2019).
Descriptive Statistics and Correlation Matrix: We present the summary of
descriptive statistics of the studys variables as shown in table 1. The mean of eco-
nomic growth in the full sample is equal to 27.16 and ranges from 23.10 to 31.36,
which are the same minimum and maximum values for the Non-GIIPS countries.
We have recognized that the energy supply and public debt have a difference in
the mean between the GIIPS countries and the Non-GIIPS countries. The results
ensure the energy supply and public debt vary between the GIIPS countries and
the Non-GIIPS countries, indicating the need to split the full sample into two sub-
samples to capture the difference.
We present the Pearson correlation coefcients among the studys variables in
Table 2. The correlation between economic growth and energy supply is negative
and signicant at 1% while there is a positive and signicant correlation between
economic growth and public debt. The result supports the hypothesis according to
which there is a positive relationship between economic growth and public debt
and a negative relationship between economic growth and energy supply. Regard-
ing the correlation between the energy supply and public debt, the results indicate
a strong positive relationship between these two variables.
Figure 3
ENERGY SUPPLY: AVERAGE PER YEAR, 19702021
1,6E+12
1,4E+12
1,2E+12
1E+12
8E+11
6E+11
4E+11
2E+11
0
Full GIIPS Non-GIIPS countries
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
2020
Source: Authors.
244 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Panel Unit Root and Panel Cointegration Tests: The time-series properties
of the variables in Eq. (1) are checked through four types of panel unit root tests:
LLC, IPS, ADF, and PP tests. The panel unit root test is based on the null hypothe-
sis to prove the existence of the unit root, while the alternative hypothesis indicates
the absence of the unit root. (H
0
: Data are not stationary (Unit root exists) and H
1
:
Data are stationary (Unit root does not exist)). We apply the common unit root test
by using the LLC and the individual unit root by applying IPS, ADF, and PP. The
results as shown in table 3 indicate that all the series in Eq (1) appear to contain a
panel unit root in their level while stationary in their rst difference, showing that
they are integrated at order one I (1).
Table 2
CORRELATION MATRIX
a
Economic Growth Energy Supply Public Debt
EGR 1.0000
ESU 20.0564* 1.0000
(0.0626)
PDE 0.5888*** 0.2355*** 1.0000
(0.0000) (0.0000) 1.0000
a
Numbers in parentheses 5p-values; * indicates signicance at 10%; ** indicates signicance at
5%; and *** indicates signicance at 1%.
Table 1
DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS
a
Variables Mean Median Min Max Std. Dev. No. of Obs.
Full Sample
EGR 27.16812 27.24722 23.10801 31.36414 1.491998 1,092
ESU 16.9409 17.30243 10.83985 19.71831 2.138101 1,092
PDE 25.91719 26.1166 19.08927 28.91897 1.647482 1,092
GIIPS Countries
EGR 26.40955 26.0062 24.1153 28.21585 1.114771 260
ESU 17.3481 17.01438 15.56645 19.08631 1.090601 260
PDE 25.44128 25.53252 19.08927 28.81175 1.938355 260
Non-GIIPS Countries
EGR 27.40517 27.52745 23.10801 31.36414 1.516219 832
ESU 16.81364 17.34393 10.83958 19.71831 2.358597 832
PDE 26.06592 26.24476 10.85372 28.91897 1.516368 832
a
Min5minimum; Max 5maximum; Std. Dev. 5standard deviation; No. of Obs. 5number of
observations.
245ENERGY SUPPLY, PUBLIC DEBT, & ECONOMIC GROWTH
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
According to the ndings from the panel unit root test, the cointegration
between economic growth, energy supply, and public debt can be investigated. For
that, we apply the panel cointegration test between economic growth and its deter-
minants by using the Pedroni test, Kao test, and Fisher test. (H
0
: there is no cointe-
gration and H
1
: there is cointegration). The results are provided in table 4.
Based on the Pedroni test results, we nd that 9 out of 11 of the results are sig-
nicant at 1%, and this is an indicator of panel cointegration. After applying the
Kao test, the results indicate the existence of panel cointegration where it is signi-
cant at 1%. Additionally, the Johansen Fisher test reveals the existence of two
cointegration vectors at 1%. We can summarize that there is strong statistical evi-
dence of panel cointegration among our variables: economic growth (EGR), energy
supply (ESU), and public debt (PDE). The existence of cointegration among the
variables attempts to exclude the possibility of having a bias in the equation.
VEC-Model and Panel Causality Tests: The time series of our model must be
stationary in a long-run analysis to avoid dummy results. For that, before examin-
ing the panel cointegration, all variables (economic growth, energy supply, and
Table 3
PANEL UNIT ROOT TESTS
a
Common Unit Root
LLC IPS
Variable Level 1
st
Diff. Level 1
st
Diff.
EGR 23.223 212.760*** 1.064 222.459***
(1.0000) (0.0000) (0.8564) (0.0000)
ESU 6.043 226.521*** 22.856*** 226.108***
(1.0000) (0.0000) (0.0021) (0.0000)
PDE 15.046 211.476*** 0.326 219.636***
(1.0000) (0.0000) (0.6278) (0.0000)
Individual Unit Root
ADF PP
Level 1
st
Diff. Level 1
st
Diff.
EGR 0.4149 212.449*** 0.0641 214.413***
(1.0000) (0.0000) (1.0000) (0.0000)
ESU 7.931 226.474*** 8.943 227.510***
(1.0000) (0.0000) (1.0000) (0.0000)
PDE 1.927 213.188*** 1.238 216.007***
(1.0000) (0.0000) (1.0000) (0.0000)
a
Numbers in parentheses 5p-values; * indicates signicance at 10%; ** indicates signicance at
5%; and *** indicates signicance at 1%.
246 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
public debt) must be integrated into order one. Table 5 provides the short- and
long-run equilibrium results for the full sample.
The VEC model for the dependent variable EGR is as follows:
D EGR
ðÞ
520:53208 20:13937EGR 21
ðÞ
20:00000283ESU 21
ðÞ
20:0000184ESU 22
ðÞ
20:00000591PDE 21
ðÞ
20:00000334PDEð22Þ
EGRð21Þ50:00000677ESU ð21Þ20:00000688PDEð21Þ
The result in the equation shows in the short run there is no impact of energy
supply and public debt on economic growth in the rst equation. However, in the
third model where the public debt is the dependent variable, the coefcient of
adjustment is negative and signicant at 1%. Contrarily, in the long run, both
energy supply and public debt are signicant at 1%. The impact of energy
supply is positive and signicant by 0.00000677 on economic growth while there
is a negative and signicant impact of public debt on economic growth by
0.00000688.
Table 4
PANEL COINTEGRATION TESTS
a
Pedroni Test
Test statistics Statistics (p-value) Weighted statistic (p-value)
Alternative hypothesis: Common AR coefs. (within-dimension)
Panel v-stat 0.224690 (0.4111) 20.773904 (0.7805)
Panel rho-stat 26.756258*** (0.0000) 26.738820*** (0.0000)
Panel PP-stat 28.899870*** (0.0000) 29.365574*** (0.0000)
Panel ADF-stat 28.517234*** (0.0000) 29.151758*** (0.0000)
Alternative hypothesis: Individual AR coefs. (between dimension)
Group rho-stat 26.120249*** (0.0000)
Group PP-stat 212.62997*** (0.0000)
Group ADF-stat 211.65244*** (0.0000)
Kao Test t-Statistic
ADF 28.623625*** (0.0000)
Fisher Test Trace test Maximum Eigen Value
Null hypothesis
r50 301.8*** (0.0000) 215.8*** (0.0000)
r#1 161.0*** (0.0000) 138.0*** (0.0000)
r#2 77.83*** (0.0006) 77.83*** (0.0000)
a
*, **, and *** indicate the rejection of the null hypothesis at 10%, 5%, and 1% level of
signicance, respectively. r denotes the number of cointegration equations.
247ENERGY SUPPLY, PUBLIC DEBT, & ECONOMIC GROWTH
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table 5
VEC MODEL: SHORT- AND LONG-RUN EQUILIBRIUM FOR THE FULL SAMPLE
a
Dep. Var. Source of causation (independent variables)
Short-run equation R
2
F-statistics
ECT DEGR
(21)
DEGR
(22)
DESU
(21)
DESU
(22)
DPDE
(21)
DPDE
(22)
DEGR 20.53208*** 20.13937*** 20.13352*** 22.83E-06 21.84E-05 25.91E-06 23.34E-06 0.3522
DESU 129.9695 29.9088 210.8347 20.3188*** 20.0117 0.0572** 20.0015 0.1048
DPDE 2288.7375*** 129.1592 168.0498 20.0280 20.0230 20.1463*** 20.1714*** 0.0471
Long-run equation
t-statistics
DEGR
(21)
DESU
(21)
DPDE
(21)
ECT 1.0000 6.77E-06*** 26.88E-06***
a
Dep. Var. 5dependent variable; *, ** and *** indicate the level of signicance at 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.
248 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
In the long run, the results indicate for every 1% increase in the energy supply,
there will be an increase in the economic growth by 0.000677%. The results also
indicate that for every 1% increase in the public debt there will be a decrease in
the economic growth by 0.000688%.
The existence of a panel long-run cointegration relationship among economic
growth, energy supply, and public debt suggests that there is Granger causality in
at least one direction. The balanced panel Granger causality results are presented
in table 6. We have divided our work into three samples to provide a more
in-depth analysis between the GIIPS and Non-GIIPS countries. After applying the
panel Granger causality test for the full sample, the results show unidirectional cau-
sality from public debt to economic growth, while there is bidirectional causality
from energy supply to economic growth, economic growth to energy supply, eco-
nomic growth to public debt, public debt to energy supply, and energy supply to
public debt.
To permit the use of the Granger causality test for the GIIPS countries, we have
applied the VEC model. The results, shown in table 7, indicate there is a negative
and signicant impact of 1% of energy supply on economic growth, where every
1% increase in energy supply will decrease the economic growth in the long
run by 38.63%. For the public debt, the results demonstrate there is a negative
and signicant impact of 1% of public debt on economic growth in the long run,
where every 1% increase in public debt will decrease the economic growth
by 70.70%.
As can be seen in table 8, the panel Granger causality test for the GIIPS coun-
tries demonstrates there is unidirectional causality from energy supply to economic
growth, from economic growth to energy supply, from public debt to economic
growth, and from public debt to energy supply, while there is bidirectional causal-
ity from economic growth to public debt, and energy supply to public debt.
Table 6
PANEL GRANGER CAUSALITY TEST FOR THE FULL SAMPLE
a
Null hypothesis No. of Obs. F-Statistic P-value
ESU does not Granger cause EGR 1050 9.99874*** 5.E-05
EGR does not Granger cause ESU 11.4395*** 1.E-05
PDE does not Granger cause EGR 1050 1.79728 0.1663
EGR does not Granger cause PDE 13.9026*** 1.E-06
PDE does not Granger cause ESU 1050 10.1356*** 4.E-05
ESU does not Granger cause PDE 5.68112*** 0.0035
a
No. of Obs. 5number of observations; *, ** and *** indicate the level of signicance at 10%, 5%
and 1%, respectively.
249ENERGY SUPPLY, PUBLIC DEBT, & ECONOMIC GROWTH
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table 7
VEC MODEL: SHORT- AND LONG-RUN EQUILIBRIUM FOR THE GIIPS COUNTRIES
a
Dep. Var. Source of causation (independent variables)
Short-run equation R
2
F-statistics
ECT DEGR
(21)
DEGR
(22)
DESU
(21)
DESU
(22)
DPDE
(21)
DPDE
(22)
DEGR 0.005409*** 0.365950*** 0.156006* 20.066823 0.003312 20.007864 0.020506 0.1614
DESU 0.012910** 20.358241** 0.610836*** 20.394976* 20.026784 20.007611 0.009621 0.0816
DPDE 0.053573*** 20.333889 20.186522 20.105665 20.186808 0.139021** 0.081984 0.0819
Long-run equation
t-statistics
DEGR
(21)
DESU
(21)
DPDE
(21)
ECT 1.0000 20.386387*** 20.707003***
a
Dep. Var. 5dependent variable; *, ** and *** indicate the level of signicance at 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.
250 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The same procedure follows to test the Granger causality test for the Non-
GIIPS countries. Table 9 provides the VEC model short- and long-run equations
for the Non-GIIPS, and the results indicate a long-run relationship. The impact of
energy supply has a positive and signicant impact of 1% on the economic growth,
where the increase of 1% of energy supply will increase the economic growth by
64.04%; while the impact of public debt on economic growth is negative and sig-
nicant at 1%, where any increase of 1% of public debt will decrease the economic
growth by 11.005%.
The panel Granger causality test for Non-GIIPS countries, as can be seen in
table 10, demonstrates there is just unidirectional causality from public debt to eco-
nomic growth, while there is bidirectional causality from energy supply to eco-
nomic growth, from economic growth to energy supply, from economic growth to
public debt, from public debt to energy supply, and energy supply to public debt.
We recognize that the panel causality relations for the Non-GIIPS countries fol-
low the same path as the full sample, caused by the fact that the Non-GIIPS coun-
tries represent three-quarters of the full sample. Based on the strong causality
results, evidence shows that economic growth does Granger cause public debt,
while public debt does not Granger cause economic growth. We can conclude that
economic growth can attract the public debt in the full sample, GIIPS, and Non-
GIIPS countries. Moreover, the causality runs from energy supply to public debt
and public debt to energy supply in the full sample and the Non-GIIPS countries.
In the GIIPS countries, the direction is not reversed, where the causality is unidi-
rectional. Nevertheless, the results indicate that the development of energy is a key
factor for domestic economic growth, which is an essential factor for the energy
supply. Both economic growth and energy supply depend on each other due to a
bidirectional causality relationship. Figure 4 provides a visual overview of the
panel causality relationships in our study. Our results are in line with the ndings
of C. Checherita-Westphal and P. Rother.
37
They nd that public debt has a
Table 8
PANEL GRANGER CAUSALITY TEST FOR THE GIIPS COUNTRIES
a
Null hypothesis No. of Obs. F-Statistic P-value
ESU does not Granger cause EGR 250 2.23562 0.1091
EGR does not Granger cause ESU 1.30216 0.2738
PDE does not Granger cause EGR 250 0.23344 0.7920
EGR does not Granger cause PDE 12.5350*** 7.E-0.6
PDE does not Granger cause ESU 250 1.04650 0.3527
ESU does not Granger cause PDE 11.2017*** 2.E-05
a
No. of Obs. 5number of observations; *, ** and *** indicate the level of signicance at 10%, 5%
and 1%, respectively.
251ENERGY SUPPLY, PUBLIC DEBT, & ECONOMIC GROWTH
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table 9
VEC MODEL: SHORT- AND LONG-RUN EQUILIBRIUM FOR THE NON-GIIPS COUNTRIES
a
Dep. Var. Source of causation (independent variables)
Short-run equation R
2
F-statistics
ECT DEGR
(21)
DEGR
(22)
DESU
(21)
DESU
(22)
DPDE
(21)
DPDE
(22)
DEGR 20.001581*** 0.257541 0.144308 0.033658 20.064739** 20.005236 0.005667 0.1425
DESU 0.002676*** 20.316063** 0.251094*** 0.019722** 0.039701 0.003066 0.015695 0.0433
DPDE 0.017706 20.247384*** 0.159324*** 20.086160 0.059519 0.104183 0.031107 0.0565
Long-run equation
t-statistics
DEGR
(21)
DESU
(21)
DPDE
(21)
ECT 1.0000 0.640416*** 21.100575***
a
Dep. Var. 5dependent variable; *, ** and *** indicate the level of signicance at 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.
252 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
negative effect on economic growth in the long term. The ndings are also some-
what consistent with those of U. Panizza and A. Presbitero, who reported evidence
of a negative correlation between government debt and economic growth.
38
In con-
trast, in 2009, M. Ferreira, using OECD annual data for 20 countries from 1988 to
2001, nds evidence of a clear bidirectional Granger causality relationship between
economic growth and public debt.
39
Figure 4
PANEL CAUSALITY RELATIONS
EGR
ESU PDE
Full
Sample
GIIPS
countries
Non-GIIPS
countries
Table 10
PANEL GRANGER CAUSALITY TEST FOR THE NON-GIIPS COUNTRIES
a
Null hypothesis No. of Obs. F-Statistic P-value
ESU does not Granger cause EGR 800 9.09218*** 0.0001
EGR does not Granger cause ESU 5.91700*** 0.0028
PDE does not Granger cause EGR 800 0.81032 0.4451
EGR does not Granger cause PDE 8.48876*** 0.0002
PDE does not Granger cause ESU 800 5.45424*** 0.0044
ESU does not Granger cause PDE 2.96195* 0.0523
a
No. of Obs. 5number of observations; *, ** and *** indicate the level of signicance at 10%, 5%
and 1%, respectively.
253ENERGY SUPPLY, PUBLIC DEBT, & ECONOMIC GROWTH
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Conclusions
In this article, we analyze the impact of energy supply and public debt on eco-
nomic growth taking the European countries as a case study during 1970-2021 by
applying a panel approach. To achieve added value in our research, we divided our
sample into GIIPS countries (which are the weaker economies of Greece, Ireland,
Italy, Portugal, and Spain) and Non-GIIPS countries. In addition, previous articles
focused on energy consumption and its impact on economic growth; however,
these researchers did not pay attention to energy supply, which elevates the value
of our study. The main ndings for the GIIPS countries are the non-evidence of a
causal relationship between energy supply and economic growth. These two vari-
ables are not correlated. In other words, any increase or decrease in energy supply
does not affect economic growth. This means that neither an energy-savings policy
nor an energy-intensive policy inuences the level of wealth creation in the econ-
omy. Regarding the two other samples (full and Non-GIIPS), we found a two-way
causality between energy supply and economic growth. This means that energy
and economic policies will be implemented jointly. In this case, the energy supply
policy should be developed as an essential factor to attain higher levels of eco-
nomic growth in the long term while avoiding its negative impact in the short
term. In addition, there is a negative relationship between public debt and eco-
nomic growth in full, GIIPS, and Non-GIIPS countries. In regard to causality, there
is unidirectional causality from economic growth to public debt. Thus, the Euro-
pean countries should consider the accumulation of government liabilities as a
main issue due to the fact that public debt, in the long term, will deactivate the
wheels of the economy and disrupt economic growth. Governments in European
countries have to perceive the importance of public debt and energy supply as part
of their public policy and they should be aware that the public debt is a double-
edged sword. The governmentsstrategic priorities should focus more on energy
supply, especially renewable energy sources, and other economic factors that can
stimulate economic growth as a way of combatting public debt in the long run.
Moreover, in terms of energy, it would be useful for future research papers to
include in their modeling the primary energy consumption that represents the
demand to know its effect on the causal relationships between the variables.
Acknowledgments
The authors would like to thank anonymous reviewers for their valuable sug-
gestions and helpful comments, which have greatly enhanced the quality of this
paper.
254 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
NOTES
1
A. Halldorsson and M. Svanberg, Energy Resources: Trajectories for Supply Chain Manage-
ment,Supply Chain Management: An International Journal, vol. 18, no. 1 (2013).
2
C. Beetz Fenske, Y. J. Kim, and J. Zhang, The Dynamic Relationship Between Global Debt
and Output,Chicago Fed Letter, no. 457 (2021), pp. 15.
3
M. G
omez-Puig and S. Sosvilla-Rivero, The Causal Relationship Between Debt and Growth
in EMU Countries,Journal of Policy Modeling, vol. 37, no. 6 (2015), pp. 97489.
4
B. Algieri, Drivers of Export Demand: A Focus on the GIIPS Countries,The World Econ-
omy, vol. 37, no. 10 (2014), pp. 1454482.
5
E. Denison, Trends in American Economic Growth (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution,
1985); B. S. Cheng, An Investigation of Cointegration and Causality between Energy Consump-
tion and Economic Growth,The Journal of Energy and Development, vol. 21, no. 1 (1995),
pp. 7384; J. Asafu-Adjaye, The Relationship between Energy Consumption, Energy Prices and
Economic Growth: Time Series Evidence from Asian Developing Countries,Energy Economics,
vol. 22, no. 6 (2000), pp. 61525; and R. M. Solow, Resources and Economic Growth,The
American Economist, vol. 61, no. 1 (2016), pp. 5260.
6
M. J. Mouhtadi and J. S. Kamdem, Economic Growth, Energy Consumption, and Transition
in Morocco,The Journal of Energy and Development, vol. 44, nos. 12 (2018), pp. 28398.
7
I. Sacko, Analyse des liens entre croissance
economique et consommation d
energie au
Mali,CERFOD-FSJE, Universit
e du Mali (2004).
8
C. B. L. Jumbe, Cointegration and Causality Between Electricity Consumption and GDP:
Empirical Evidence from Malawi,Energy Economics, vol. 26, no. 1 (2004), pp. 618; A. Shiu
and P.-L. Lam, Electricity Consumption and Economic Growth in China,Energy Policy,
vol. 32, no. 1 (2004), pp. 4754; G. Altinay and K. Erdal, Electricity Consumption and Economic
Growth: Evidence from Turkey,Energy Economics, vol. 27, no. 6 (2005), pp. 84956; S.-T.
Chen, H.-I. Kuo, and C.-C. Chen, The Relationship between GDP and Electricity Consumption
in 10 Asian Countries,Energy Policy, vol. 35, no. 4 (2007), pp. 2611621; P. Mozumder and A.
Marathe, Causality Relationship Between Electricity Consumption and GDP in Bangladesh,
Energy Policy, vol. 35, no. 1 (2007), pp. 395402; J. Squalli, Electricity Consumption and Eco-
nomic Growth: Bounds and Causality Analyses of OPEC Members,Energy Economics, vol. 29,
no. 6 (2007), pp. 1192205; N. Apergis and J. E. Payne, Renewable Energy Consumption and
Economic Growth: Evidence from a Panel of OECD Countries,Energy Policy, vol. 38, no. 1
(2010), pp. 65660; and I. Ozturk and A. Acaravci, The Causal Relationship Between Energy
Consumption and GDP in Albania, Bulgaria, Hungary and Romania: Evidence from ARDL Bound
Testing Approach,Applied Energy, vol. 87, no. 6 (2010), pp. 1938943.
9
E. S. H. Yu and J.-Y. Choi, The Causal Relationship Between Energy and GNP: An Interna-
tional Comparison,The Journal of Energy Finance and Development, vol. 10 (1985),
pp. 24972; S. Tsani, Energy Consumption and Economic Growth: A Causality Analysis
for Greece,Energy Economics, vol. 32, no. 3 (2010), pp. 58290; A. Belke, D. Frauke, and
C. Dreger, Energy Consumption and Economic Growth: New Insights into the Cointegration
Relationship,Energy Economics, vol. 33, no. 5 (2011), pp. 78289; and M. A. Destek,
Renewable Energy Consumption and Economic Growth in Newly Industrialized Countries:
Evidence from Asymmetric Causality Test,Renewable Energy, vol. 95 (2016), pp. 47884.
10
S. Paul and R. N. Bhattacharya, Causality Between Energy Consumption and Economic
Growth in India: A Note on Conflicting Results,Energy Economics, vol. 26, no. 6 (2004),
pp. 97783; A. Hatemi and M. Irandoust, Energy Consumption and Economic Growth in
Sweden: A Leveraged Bootstrap Approach (19652000),International Journal of Applied Econo-
metrics and Quantitative Studies, vol. 2, no. 4 (2005), pp. 8798; and T. Gelo, Causality Between
255ENERGY SUPPLY, PUBLIC DEBT, & ECONOMIC GROWTH
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Economic Growth and Energy Consumption in Croatia,Zbornik radova Ekonomskog fakulteta u
Rijeci:
casopis za ekonomsku teoriju i praksu, vol. 27, no. 2 (2009), pp. 32748.
11
T. Jobert and F. Karanfil, Sectoral Energy Consumption by Source and Economic Growth
in Turkey,Energy Policy, vol. 35, no. 11 (2007), pp. 5447456.
12
G. Hondroyiannis, Estimating Residential Demand for Electricity in Greece,Energy Eco-
nomics, vol. 26 (2004), pp. 31934; C.-C. Lee, C.-P. Chang, and P.-F. Chen, Energy-Income
Causality in OECD Countries Revisited: The Key Role of Capital Stock,Energy Economics, vol.
30, no. 5 (2008), pp. 2359373; M. Mutascu, A Bootstrap Panel Granger Causality Analysis of
Energy Consumption and Economic Growth in the G7 Countries,Renewable and Sustainable
Energy Reviews, vol. 63 (2016), pp. 16671; and J. Dos Santos Gaspar, C. Cardoso Marques, and
J. Alberto Fuinhas, The Traditional Energy-Growth Nexus: A Comparison Between Sustainable
Development and Economic Growth Approaches,Ecological Indicators, vol. 75 (2017),
pp. 28696.
13
A. E. Akinlo, Energy Consumption and Economic Growth: Evidence from 11 Sub-Sahara
African Countries,Energy Economics, vol. 30, no. 5 (2008), pp. 2391400, and S. A. Solarin,
Electricity Consumption and Economic Growth: Trivariate Investigation in Botswana with
Capital Formation,International Journal of Energy Economics and Policy, vol. 1, no. 2 (2011),
pp. 3246.
14
J. Kraft and A. Kraft, On the Relationship Between Energy and GNP,The Journal of
Energy and Development, vol. 3, no. 2 (1978), pp. 40103.
15
R. Abaidoo, Economic Growth and Energy Consumption in an Emerging Economy: Aug-
mented Granger Causality Approach,Research in Business and Economics Journal, vol. 4
(2011).
16
M. Behname, La consommation d'energie renouvelable et la croissance economique dans
l'europe de louest,Romanian Journal of Economics, vol. 2 (2012), pp. 16071.
17
T. Carminel, Limpossible d
ecouplage entre
energie et croissance,in
Economie de lapr
es
croissance. Politiques de lAnthropoc
ene II, ed. A. Sinaï (Paris: Presses de Sciences Po, 2015),
pp. 97115.
18
U. Erol and E. S. H. Yu, On the Causal Relationship Between Energy and Income for
Industrialized Countries,The Journal of Energy and Development, vol. 13, no. 1 (1987),
pp. 11322.
19
A. Masih and R. Masih, Energy Consumption, Real Income and Temporal Causality:
Results from a Multi-Country Study Based on Cointegration and Error-Correction Modelling
Techniques,Energy Economics, vol. 18, no. 3 (1996), pp. 16583.
20
J. Chontanawat, L. C. Hunt, and R. Pierse, Does Energy Consumption Cause Economic
Growth?: Evidence from a Systematic Study of over 100 Countries,Journal of Policy Modeling,
vol. 30, no. 2 (2008), pp. 20920.
21
I. Ozturk and A. Acaravci, op. cit.
22
M. C. Ferreira, Public Debt and Economic Growth: A Granger Causality Panel Data
Approach,Working Paper, 2009, and M. Puente-Ajov
ın and M. Sanso-Navarro, Granger
Causality Between Debt and Growth: Evidence from OECD Countries,International Review of
Economics & Finance, vol. 35 (2015), pp. 6677.
23
A. Bell, R. Johnston, and K. Jones, Stylised Fact or Situated Messiness? The Diverse
Effects of Increasing Debt on National Economic Growth,Journal of Economic Geography, vol.
15, no. 2 (2015), pp. 44972.
24
M. Feldstein, How to Achieve Stronger US Growth,Journal of Policy Modeling, vol. 36,
no. 4 (2014), pp. 64953.
25
F. Modigliani, Long-Run Implications of Alternative Fiscal Policies and the Burden of the
National Debt,The Economic Journal, vol. 71, no. 284 (1961), pp. 73055; P. A. Diamond,
256 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
National Debt in a Neoclassical Growth Model,The American Economic Review, vol. 55, no. 5
(1965), pp. 1126150; G. Saint-Paul, Fiscal Policy in an Endogenous Growth Model,The Quar-
terly Journal of Economics, vol. 107, no. 4 (1992), pp. 1243259; and J. Aizenman, K. Kletzer,
and B. Pinto, Economic Growth with Constraints on Tax Revenues and Public Debt: Implications
for Fiscal Policy and Cross-Country Differences,National Bureau of Economic Research
(NBER) Working Paper No. 12750, Cambridge, Massachusetts, NBER, 2007.
26
P. R. Krugman, Market-Based Debt-Reduction Schemes,National Bureau of Economic
Research (NBER) Working Paper No. 2597, Cambridge, Massachusetts, NBER, 1988, and N.
Roubini and J. D. Sachs, Political and Economic Determinants of Budget Deficits in the Indus-
trial Democracies,European Economic Review, vol. 33, no. 5 (1989), pp. 90333.
27
T. J. Moss and H. S. Chiang, The Other Costs of High Debt in Poor Countries: Growth,
Policy Dynamics, and Institutions,Issue Paper on Debt Sustainability, Washington, D.C., Center
for Global Development, 2003.
28
H. Hansen, The Impact of External Aid and External Debt on Growth and Investment,in
Debt Relief for Poor Countries, eds. T. Addison, H. Hansen, and F. Tarp (London: Palgrave
Macmillan, 2004), pp. 13457.
29
L. Codogno, C. Favero, and A. Missale, Yield Spreads on EMU Government Bonds,Eco-
nomic Policy, vol. 18 (2003), pp. 50332, and J. H. Cochrane, Understanding Policy in the Great
Recession: Some Unpleasant Fiscal Arithmetic,European Economic Review, vol. 55, no. 1
(2011), pp. 230.
30
D. W. Elmendorf and G. Mankiw, Government Debt,in Handbook of Macroeconomics,
Edition 1, eds. B. Taylor and M. Woodford (North Holland: Elsevier, 1999), pp. 1615669, and
V. Tanzi and N. Chalk, Impact of Large Public Debt on Growth in the EU: A Discussion of
Potential Channels,European Economy, vol. 2 (2000), pp. 2343.
31
B. Eichengreen and D. Leblang, Capital Account Liberalization and Growth: Was
Mr. Mahathir Right?International Journal of Finance & Economics, vol. 8, no. 3 (2003),
pp. 20524, and U. Nyambuu and L. Bernard, A Quantitative Approach to Assessing Sovereign
Default Risk in Resource-Rich Emerging Economies,International Journal of Finance &
Economics, vol. 20, no. 3 (2015), pp. 22041.
32
C. M. Reinhart and K. S. Rogoff, Growth in a Time of Debt,American Economic Review,
vol. 100, no. 2 (2010), pp. 57378.
33
C. Checherita-Westphal and P. Rother, The Impact of High Government Debt on Economic
Growth and Its Channels: An Empirical Investigation for the Euro Area,European Economic
Review, vol. 56, no. 7 (2012), pp. 1392405.
34
U. Panizza and A. F. Presbitero, Public Debt and Economic Growth: Is There a Causal
Effect?Journal of Macroeconomics, vol. 41 (2014), pp. 2141.
35
J. Mencinger, A. Aristovnik, and M. Verbic, The Impact of Growing Public Debt on
Economic Growth in the European Union,Amfiteatru Economic Journal, vol. 16, no. 35 (2014),
pp. 40314.
36
H. O. Zapata and A. N. Rambaldi, Monte Carlo Evidence on Cointegration and Causation,
Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, vol. 59, no. 2 (1997), pp. 28598.
37
C. Checherita-Westphal and P. Rother, op. cit.
38
U. Panizza and A. F. Presbitero, op. cit.
39
M. C. Ferreira, op. cit.
257ENERGY SUPPLY, PUBLIC DEBT, & ECONOMIC GROWTH
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
This content downloaded from
193.51.154.162 on Wed, 13 Nov 2024 14:53:09 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
This paper investigates the dynamic causal relationships between energy consumption, economic growth and carbone dioxide emissions in Morocco. We use a Johansen multivariate cointegration approach and incorporate the investment rate as a control variable. The results indicate that there exists at least a long-run relationship between energy consumption, economic growth, and CO2 emissions. Furthermore, empirical estimation allowed us to confirm the existence of a long-run bidirectional causality between energy consumption and economic growth, in addition to a long-run bidirectional causality between energy consumption and carbone dioxide emissions. In this case, the economic theory assumes that the feedback hypothesis is verified in Morocco. This would encourage policymakers to jointly implement the economic, energy and environmental measures in order t o create growth and to minimize carbone dioxide emissions.
Article
Full-text available
This paper analyses the Granger-causality relationship between the growth of the real GDP per capita and the public debt, here represented by the ratio of the current primary surplus/GDP and the ratio of the gross Government debt/GDP. Using OECD annual data for 20 countries between 1988 and 2001, we adapt the methodology recently applied by Erdil and Yetkiner (2008) and we conclude that there is clear Granger causality and that it is always bi-directional. In addition, our findings point to a heterogeneous behaviour across the different countries. These results have important policy implications since not only does public debt restrain economic growth, but also real GDP per capita growth influences the evolution of public debt.
Article
I use the valuation equation of government debt to understand fiscal and monetary policy in and following the great recession of 2008-2009, to think about fiscal pressures on US inflation, and what sequence of events might surround such an inflation. I emphasize that a fiscal inflation can come well before large deficits or monetization are realized, and is likely to come with stagnation rather than a boom.
Chapter
Additionality. in the sense that debt relief should supplement, not replace, the flow of development aid is a key concept underlying the HIPC Initiative. But assessing the additionality of HIPC debt relief is extremely difficult, if not outright impossible. Some writers (e.g. Birdsall and Williamson, 2002), expect only modest additionality from bilateral donors while they doubt that debt relief from the World Bank can be additional. This leaves the IMF as the main contributor of additional resources.
Article
New evidence is presented on the possible existence of bi-directional causal relationships between public debt and economic growth in both central and peripheral countries of the European Economic and Monetary Union. We test for heterogeneity in the bi-directional Granger-causality across both time and space during the period between 1980 and 2013. The results suggest evidence of a “diabolic loop” between low economic growth and high public debt levels in Spain after 2009. For Belgium, Greece, Italy and the Netherlands debt has a negative effect over growth from an endogenously determined breakpoint and above a debt threshold ranging from 56% to 103% depending on the country.
Article
The problem of sovereign default is a tricky one for bankers, policy makers, politicians and investors alike. Purely financial models are likely to miss nuance and cultural idiosyncrasies. Nonetheless, risk metrics must play a role. Using a stochastic growth model in an open economy, we propose a Kealhofer, McQuown and Vasicek (KMV)-style approach for assessing sovereign default risk in resource-rich emerging economies. As is well known, financial effects, specifically external debt, can make a country vulnerable to economic shocks. Excessive external debt is, thus, a prime indicator for financial health in both resource-poor and resource-rich countries; yet, safe ratios are difficult to determine. Using a straightforward and easily implementable methodology, we show how optimal debt ratios may be used to define a ‘distance from default’ indicator variable. Further, we demonstrate that this is a plausible risk metric for a number of different developing countries, including representatives from Latin America, Africa and Asia. Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.