ArticlePDF Available

Synergizing Stakeholder Collaboration for Value Co-creation in China's Prefabricated Decoration Diffusion: A Tripartite Evolutionary Game Perspective

Authors:

Abstract

The emerging prefabricated decoration (PD) sector in China offers a compelling avenue for revolutionizing the construction industry, aligning with the imperatives of sustainability and industrialization. However, the outlook for the diffusion of PD in China's construction industry is less than promising. The development of PD is closely related to its value creation and the intricate interplay of stakeholder strategies and their ramifications on PD's value co-creation necessitates thorough exploration. Based on evolutionary game theory, this study elucidates the dynamic interactions among local governments, developers, and decoration contractors in China's evolving PD landscape. A tripartite evolutionary game model was established, investigating the evolutionary stable equilibriums and the corresponding strategies. Then, an empirical analysis in Chongqing City validates the game models and primary conclusions. Scrutinizing subsidy thresholds, local subsidy biases, PD proportion in prefabrication, and binary innovation allocation, the research unveils nuanced insights pertinent to boosting PD's value co-creation. Findings advocate an assembly rate threshold of subsidy (65%–70 %) and a shift towards incentivizing decoration contractors to catalyze PD adoption. Additionally, excessive PD proportion and immature product investments may hinder industry development, prompting stakeholders to recalibrate strategies dynamically. These findings characterize the mechanisms of stakeholder value co-creation during the PD diffusion, enriching the implications of value co-creation theory in the emerging industry of the construction sector. They also furnish stakeholders committed to promoting the diffusion of PD in the domestic and international construction sectors with practical strategic guidance, particularly tailored for cities in the early stages of PD development.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
Available online 17 July 2024
2405-8440/© 2024 Published by Elsevier Ltd. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license
(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).
Research article
Synergizing stakeholder collaboration for value co-creation in
Chinas prefabricated decoration diffusion: A tripartite
evolutionary game perspective
Hongjuan Wu
a
, Yipin Huang
b
, Guiwen Liu
c
,
*
, Lizi Luo
d
, Yuhang Luo
e
a
School of Management Science and Real Estate, Chongqing University, No.174 Shazheng Street, Shapingba District, 400044, Chongqing, China
b
School of Management Science and Real Estate, Chongqing University, No.174 Shazheng Street, Shapingba District, 400044, Chongqing, China
c
School of Management Science and Real Estate, Chongqing University, No.174 Shazheng Street, Shapingba District, 400044, Chongqing, China
d
School of Economics and Management, Wuhan University, 430072, Wuhan, China
e
School of Management Science and Real Estate, Chongqing University, No.174 Shazheng Street, Shapingba District, 400044, Chongqing, China
ARTICLE INFO
Keywords:
Prefabricated decoration
Value co-creation
Tripartite evolutionary game model
Stakeholdersstrategies
ABSTRACT
The emerging prefabricated decoration (PD) sector in China offers a compelling avenue for
revolutionizing the construction industry, aligning with the imperatives of sustainability and
industrialization. However, the outlook for the diffusion of PD in Chinas construction industry is
less than promising. The development of PD is closely related to its value creation and the
intricate interplay of stakeholder strategies and their ramications on PDs value co-creation
necessitates thorough exploration. Based on evolutionary game theory, this study elucidates
the dynamic interactions among local governments, developers, and decoration contractors in
Chinas evolving PD landscape. A tripartite evolutionary game model was established, investi-
gating the evolutionary stable equilibriums and the corresponding strategies. Then, an empirical
analysis in Chongqing City validates the game models and primary conclusions. Scrutinizing
subsidy thresholds, local subsidy biases, PD proportion in prefabrication, and binary innovation
allocation, the research unveils nuanced insights pertinent to boosting PDs value co-creation.
Findings advocate an assembly rate threshold of subsidy (65%70 %) and a shift towards
incentivizing decoration contractors to catalyze PD adoption. Additionally, excessive PD pro-
portion and immature product investments may hinder industry development, prompting
stakeholders to recalibrate strategies dynamically. These ndings characterize the mechanisms of
stakeholder value co-creation during the PD diffusion, enriching the implications of value co-
creation theory in the emerging industry of the construction sector. They also furnish stake-
holders committed to promoting the diffusion of PD in the domestic and international con-
struction sectors with practical strategic guidance, particularly tailored for cities in the early
stages of PD development.
* Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: hongjuanwu@cqu.edu.cn (H. Wu), yipin@stu.cqu.edu.cn (Y. Huang), gwliu@cqu.edu.cn (G. Liu), lizi.luo@whu.edu.cn
(L. Luo), yuhangluo@stu.cqu.edu.cn (Y. Luo).
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect
Heliyon
journal homepage: www.cell.com/heliyon
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.heliyon.2024.e34775
Received 29 February 2024; Received in revised form 8 July 2024; Accepted 16 July 2024
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
2
1. Introduction
Globally, the construction industry is shifting towards sustainability, energy efciency, and intelligent practices, with a focus on
industrialization as a key strategy for achieving these goals [1]. Prefabrication serves as an effective means for industrializing the
construction industry, initially pioneered by developed countries [2]. With advancements in technology and the growing global de-
mand for sustainable construction, prefabrication has extended beyond structural construction to the decoration phase, giving rise to
an emerging practice known as prefabricated decoration (PD) [3]. PD involves the on-site installation of factory-produced decoration
components and modules [4]. This approach extends prefabricated construction into decoration, exhibiting several advantages over
traditional decoration. PD surpasses traditional decoration, reducing carbon emissions by 48 % [5], construction waste by 50 %, and
construction time by 70 % [6]. The numerous benets of PD have contributed to its extensive adoption in both developing and
developed countries with large-scale construction industries. China, facing the challenges such as the disappearance of demographic
dividends [7], escalating resource costs [8] and an aging population [9], is one of the representatives. Consequently, PD has garnered
signicant attention and investment within the Chinese context, prompting authorities to issue a series of supportive policies, such as
the Opinions on Accelerating the Development of New Type of Building Industrialization and the 14th Five-Year Plan for the
Development of the Construction Industry [10,11]. Nevertheless, PDs current implementation is mostly limited to prefabricated
bathrooms and kitchens [12], indicating that PD in China is still in an early developmental stage.
The signicant resistance encountered in PD diffusion can manifest in several aspects. From a holistic perspective of industry, the
PD industry involves multiple stakeholders, including decoration contractors, developers, and local governments, among others. In
cases lacking a cooperative purpose, stakeholders may lean towards independent operations rather than collectively striving for value
co-creation [13]. From the perspective of private stakeholders, stakeholders often operate within limited information, exhibiting a
deciency in comprehending industry dynamics and trends among other stakeholders. This information asymmetry poses a hindrance
to effective communication and collaborative efforts [14]. From the perspective of public stakeholders, the industry grapples with
further exploration of unied standards and regulations, and the lack of standardized protocols may impede consensus on design,
production, and transportation, thereby adversely affecting the efciency and quality of the PD project [15]. These real-world chal-
lenges impede PD diffusion, collectively underscoring the absence of concerted efforts among PD stakeholders, namely the lack of
value co-creation. In emerging industries, value co-creation necessitates stakeholders to collaboratively engage without compromising
the interests of others, thereby fostering a more optimal realization of economic, environmental and social values realization [16].
Therefore, it is imperative to establish a conducive environment for value co-creation to facilitate the PD diffusion in Chinas con-
struction industry.
Existing studies focus on PD diffusion via technological advancements and economic considerations. Technological approaches in
China adhere to the principle of separating piping and structure while coordinating various systems, including partition and wall
systems, ceiling systems, oor systems, kitchen systems, etc [17]. Exploratory efforts have also been made to incorporate green
building materials in integrated suspended ceilings [18] and to integrate roof wall modules to enhance the quality and efciency of
healthcare spaces [19]. Other researchers have investigated the economic factors, such as production cost and labor productivity, that
impede the value co-creation of PD in China [18]. However, existing studies overlook the crucial management aspect: the lack of
strategic alignment among key stakeholders, leading to a collective inability to achieve concerted efforts in value co-creation, which is
the essence of PD diffusion. In the context of China, local governments, developers, and decoration contractors exert their signicant
inuence on the dissemination and diffusion of PD. Usually, these diverse stakeholders individually pursued varied values based on
their own interests, which is rooted in their confusion to collaborate in generating value aligned with the diffusion of PD. Resolving this
issue necessitates the application of a dynamic multi-stakeholder game approach tailored to the intricacies of the emerging PD
industry.
Evolutionary game theory, with its mature theoretical foundation and effective tools, provides a valuable framework for under-
standing multi-stakeholder game relationships [20,21]. It serves as a key guide for cultivating value co-creation and studying
stakeholder dynamics, especially for emerging industries [22]. Building upon it, this study seeks to offer pragmatic value co-creation
strategies through the lens of evolutionary game theory, investigating stakeholders optimal strategies for maximizing the value
creation in PD projects, thereby expediting the diffusion of the PD industry in China. Specically, this study is expected to address the
following questions systematically: 1) What are the evolutionary stable equilibriums and the corresponding strategies for the value
co-creation of PD? 2) How do specic interests embedded in stakeholdersstrategies inuence the evolutionary equilibrium within the
dynamic evolution of the PD industry? 3) How can each stakeholder contribute to boosting PDs value co-creation by taking appro-
priate strategies through their crucial behaviors? Based on insights from China, this study extends the applicability of evolutionary
game theory in emerging industries and provides more effective strategies for promoting PD in the global construction industry,
especially in regions where PD is in the early stages of development.
2. Literature review
2.1. Emerging of prefabricated decoration in China
Prefabricated decoration (PD) in China refers to the on-site installation of factory-produced decoration components and modules,
encompassing various building systems such as partition and wall, ceiling, oor, kitchen, bathroom, storage, internal door and
window, and equipment and piping systems [17]. In developed countries with advanced construction industrialization practices like
the United States, Japan and Sweden, modular building and prefabricated building have integrated structure and decoration without
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
3
distinct separation [23,24].
In China, the emergence of PD responds to the evolution of prefabricated building and the upgrading of traditional decoration
practices. Historically, prefabrication has primarily focused on the building structure, with separate contractors handling decoration
[25]. However, this fragmented approach has limited the realization of prefabrications full production efciency. With the
advancement of Building Information Modeling (BIM), integrating structure and decoration has become feasible, and facilitating the
application of PD [26]. PD has been emerging as an extending area of prefabricated construction, with its rst technical standard
published in 2021 [17]. Fig. 1 illustrates the emergence of PD along with the development of prefabricated building in China.
Furthermore, the demand for high-quality homes has driven the popularity of PD. Previously, individual homeowners would un-
dertake decoration themselves, leading to time-consuming processes, pollution and resource waste [12]. The integration of PD
technology eliminates labor-intensive tasks such as cutting, grooving, and coating at the construction site [3]. This results in a
reduction in carbon emissions, noise, and waste, making PD more environmentally friendly than traditional cast-in-place concrete
buildings. Given the needs and motivations of both suppliers and consumers, PD has emerged as a promising and necessary industry for
promoting green production practices.
Currently, PD is still in its early stages of development in China, primarily applied in public housing, hotels and buildings with less
personalized decoration requirements [3]. Despite its promising benets, consumer demand, and technological advancements, the
wider adoption of PD faces signicant challenges and decision-making frictions. Stakeholders in the PD industry include developers,
decoration contractors, local governments, prefabricated component manufacturers, logistics companies, and consumers [27]. Local
governments serve as market regulators, ensuring compliance with policies and regulations [28]. They play a crucial role in guiding
the transformation of the decoration market by encouraging PD adoption through policies and regulations, which have proven
effective in stimulating prefabrication development [29]. Developers, as the ultimate decision-makers in PD implementation, engage
private stakeholders for construction activities [30]. Decoration contractors are responsible for designing, procuring prefabricated
products, and assembling components. Their strategies directly impact the quality, productivity, and technological advancements in
PD projects [31]. Thus, the decisions and strategies of local governments, developers, and decoration contractors are pivotal in the
success of PDs value co-creation. The dynamic interactions among these stakeholders signicantly inuence PDs wider adoption and
sustainable growth in China. In addressing this issue, it is crucial to identify the values of key stakeholders and quantify the specic
interests therein.
2.2. Values of PD and interests of the key stakeholders
The value co-creation in the PD context signies the collaborative endeavors of stakeholders to collectively generate and distribute
additional benets. This process involves key stakeholders, including local governments, developers, and decoration contractors,
integrating their respective resources, knowledge, and skills to collectively achieve more efcient, comprehensive, and sustainable
benets, thereby driving the diffusion of the PD industry [27]. Nevertheless, existing studies have yet to comprehensively discern the
precise interests stakeholders seek when engaging in value creation, leaving a gap in understanding how these varied interests
motivate stakeholders to adopt specic behaviors. Therefore, as depicted in Fig. 2, motivated by diverse interests, key stakeholders
contribute to the creation of social, economic, and environmental value.
Local governments (LGs): are primarily engaged in actively creating social and environmental values. Social values include the
growth of the local economy driven by PD and increased tax revenue [32]. Environmental values are related to PDs contribution to
low-carbon and energy-efcient sustainable development, leading to reduced environmental management costs [33]. To obtain these
Fig. 1. The emergence of PD along with the development of prefabricated building in China.
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
4
values, LGs implement regulations and subsidy policies to promote PD [34]. However, despite these policies, some developers and
decoration contractors remain hesitant to embrace PD, thereby hindering LGs access to core values. Thus, governments need to
evaluate the effectiveness of incentive policies and consider applying, stopping, or increasing policy support efforts.
Developers: take the economic value as a priority, emphasizing income maximization and cost minimization in PD projects. In
addition to project prots, government subsidies serve as a signicant source of income [35]. PD projects can also bring additional
social values to developers, such as enhanced reputation and increased brand value [33]. However, in the initial stage of PD devel-
opment, developers may need to incur additional costs when working with contractors due to the increased expenses associated with
PD construction [22]. Consequently, developers may be hesitant to adopt PD.
Decoration contractors (DCs): also prioritize the economic value, highlighting the prot generation [36]. Based on their pro-
jections of costs and revenues, DCs have the discretion to choose whether to engage in PD projects [22]. In the initial stage of PD
development, DCs bear additional costs for technology research and development as well as marketing [33]. As a result, contractors
may demand higher contract prices from developers to compensate for these expenses. And in this process, government subsidies can
play a role in encouraging contractors to embrace PD. Furthermore, DCs must carry out technology innovation to keep competitiveness
in the market. Dual innovation theory introduces an enterprises technology innovation capability into two distinct categories:
exploitative innovation and exploratory innovation [37]. Exploitative innovation involves leveraging existing technology to enhance
products or processes, while exploratory innovation concentrates on novel technology, introducing new value propositions, in-
novations, and inventions with potential long-term benets [31]. In the PD industry, the six product systems exhibit two different types
of innovation in the PD guideline [27]. The integrated ceiling, prefabricated panel, and kitchen systems are categorized as exploitative
innovations, as they are relatively mature in the market and have fewer pain points. On the other hand, prefabricated partitions,
prefabricated oors, and integrated bathrooms represent exploratory innovations, as they have signicant differences in craftsmanship
from traditional decoration and there is still a tonne of potential for innovation.
As summarized in Table 1, while LGs focus on social and environmental values, developers are dedicated to the creation of eco-
nomic value by prioritizing maximizing prots and avoiding penalties associated with traditional construction practices. DCs, akin to
developers in the pursuit of economic value creation, seek favorable nancial outcomes and consider the costs and revenues of PD
projects. Stakeholdersdivergent interests give rise to disparate attitudes towards PD, consequently impeding collaborative efforts to
realize the creation of PDs value, namely, hindering the attainment of PDs value co-creation. Therefore, in navigating the intricate
Fig. 2. Values of PD and interests of the key stakeholders.
Table 1
The values and interests of the three key stakeholders in PD projects.
Stakeholders Values Interests References
Local governments Social value, environmental value Social benets [32,33]
Environment benets [38,39]
Scientic subsidy standards [33,34]
Developers Economic value Contract prots [32,39]
Subsidies [22,39]
Social benets [32,40]
Decoration contractors Economic value Contracting price [32,36]
Subsidies [22,32]
Decoration costs [3,33]
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
5
dynamics of interest relationships to achieve the value co-creation of PD, the utilization of evolutionary game theory becomes
imperative.
2.3. Evolutionary game theory
Evolutionary game theory (EGT) originates from the concept of Evolutionary Stable Strategy, which was rst introduced by Smith
and Price [20,41]. The core concepts of EGT are evolutionary stable strategy and replicator dynamic equation [42]. Unlike traditional
game theory, EGT acknowledges bounded rationality and information asymmetry, recognizing that individuals may not be entirely
rational and possess complete information. This realism makes evolutionary games more suitable for modeling real-world situations
[43].
Evolutionary Game Theory (EGT) has been extensively applied to examine the dynamics of value co-creation among stakeholders
in industries marked by rapid iteration and large-scale development. In the agricultural sector, researchers have examined the game
relationships among governments, farmers [44], manufacturers [45], e-commerce retailers [46], and urban residents to identify
optimal value co-creation strategies that facilitate the transformation and upgrading of the agricultural industry chain. In the
manufacturing sector, scholars have explored the game relationships among local governments, green suppliers [47], manufacturers
[48], and retailers [40] to derive ideal co-creation strategies for the green and low-carbon transformation of the manufacturing in-
dustry chain. Similarly, in the construction eld, researchers have investigated the game relationships among governments, developers
[38], contractors [49], consumers [22] to identify optimum value co-creation strategies that promote the industrialization of con-
struction. These studies demonstrate the wide application of EGT in analyzing stakeholder relationships and understanding key factors
inuencing transformation and upgrading processes. By providing guidance to stakeholders, EGT enables them to make informed
decisions and judgments, thereby promoting value co-creation and development in the industry.
In the emerging context of Chinas PD industry, the relationships between key stakeholders remain unclear, and stakeholders lack a
comprehensive understanding of the impact of their strategies on value co-creation. In such a scenario, the application of EGT becomes
highly relevant as it allows for the depiction of dynamic market cooperation mechanisms and the clarication of complex game re-
lationships among stakeholders from the perspective of PDs values. ETG possesses the capacity to elucidate the interests of all
stakeholders, establish effective policies and support mechanisms, foster value co-creation, and drive sustainable growth in Chinas PD
industries.
3. Methods
3.1. Model assumptions
PD industry characterizes a high degree of integration and collaboration of multiple stakeholders. Among them, local governments,
developers and decoration contractors are the key stakeholders in the development process of the PD industry. Hence, based on EGT,
this study constructs a tripartite evolutionary game model of LGs, developers and DCs to analyse the gaming process of them to co-
Table 2
Description of major Parameters.
Stakeholders Strategies Parameters Descriptions
Local Governments Incentive GB1 Social benets when developers and DCs choose to execute PD projects.
GB2 Environmental benets when developers and DCs choose to execute PD projects.
GC1 Subsidies when the developer meets the subsidy requirements for prefabricated building.
GC2 Subsidies when the DC chooses to supply prefabricated technologies.
GC3 Incremental costs (excluding economic subsidies) brought by the LGs implementation of incentive
policies.
α
Assembly rate threshold of subsidy (
α
(0,1)).
Developers Prefabricated DB1 Economic benets of executing PD project.
DB2 Subsidiesbenets by the LG, DB2=GC1.
DC1 Incremental costs when making full use of prefabricated structure in achieving projectsassembly rate (β
=0.650.6 =0.05).
DC2 Incremental costs when making full use of PD in achieving projectsassembly rate (β =0.4).
β Contribution of PD for projectsprefabrication [50]
Traditional DB3 Economic benets of executing traditional decoration projects.
DC3 Costs when both the structure and decoration are traditionally constructed.
Decoration
contractors
Prefabricated CB1 Incremental benets when the DC supplies PD technologies.
CB2 Subsidiesbenets by the LG, CB2=GC2.
CB3 Incremental benets when the PD technologies supplied purely rely on exploratory innovation.
CB4 Incremental benets when the PD technologies supplied purely rely on exploitative innovation.
CC1 Incremental costs when the DC supplies PD technologies compared with the traditional counterpart.
CC2 Incremental costs when the PD technologies supplied purely rely on exploratory innovation.
CC3 Incremental costs when the PD technologies supplied purely rely on exploitative innovation.
γ Proportion of exploratory technologies in PD implementation (γ (0,1)).
Traditional CB5 Benets when the DC supplies traditional decoration technologies.
CC4 Costs when the DC supplies traditional decoration technologies.
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
6
create values to promote the PD industry in the context of Chinas construction industry, and the three basic assumptions are as
follows.
Assumption 1. Asymmetric Information. Given the intricate nature of the PD industry chain, characterized by its extensive
network of stakeholders, each stakeholder possesses varying degrees of industry information, leading to information asymmetry
among them. Consequently, the inter-stakeholder strategies are subject to dynamic changes inuenced by their respective infor-
mation asymmetry proles.
Assumption 2. Bounded rationality. Compared to developers and DCs, LGs have relatively comprehensive information and clear
strategic objectives and are therefore relatively more rational. The developers and DCs, on the other hand, need to learn and adjust
their strategies constantly before they can nd their optimal ones.
Assumption 3. Strategic space. (1) The LGs inuence the process of promoting PD through policy instruments, with two strategies
of (non-incentive, incentive) policies. The probability that LGs choose to implement incentive policies is x (0x 1), and the
probability that LGs choose not to implement incentive policies is 1 x. If LGs opt for implementing incentive policies, they
formulate relevant policies and regulations and subsidize developers and DCs. (2) The strategy set available to developers is to
execute (traditional, prefabricated) decoration projects. The probability that developers choose to execute PD projects is y (0y
1), and the probability that developers choose to execute traditional decoration projects is 1y. Developers execute PD projects by
signing a contract with DCs. The application of PD objectives and construction plans is specied in the project contract. To obtain
the LG subsidies, the developer must execute PD projects and allocate the proportion of prefabrication in the structure and the
decoration to ensure that the assembly rate of the whole project meets the minimum requirements settled by the LG. In this game, it
is assumed that all developers who choose to execute PD projects meet the requirements and receive subsidies. Furthermore, the
social benets that developers can receive during the initial stages of PD are modest, hence they are not taken into account in this
study. (3) The strategy set available to the DCs is to supply (traditional, prefabricated) decoration technologies. The probability that
DCs choose to supply PD technologies is z (0z 1), and the probability that DCs choose to supply traditional technologies is 1z.
If DCs opt for PD technologies, they are engaged in PD technology innovation when adopting specic technologies in PD projects.
Based on the above assumptions, parameters for describing the strategies of the three key stakeholders are dened, as shown in
Table 2.
3.2. Model establishment and equilibrium solution
In this game model, there is a contractual relationship between the developer and the DC. If the developer and DC have conicting
attitudes towards PD, the contract cannot be achieved, leading to the inability to develop the PD project. Thus, only the situations
when both developers and contractors are willing to develop PD projects were considered in this study. According to the above-
Fig. 3. The strategy combinations of the tripartite game model.
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
7
mentioned analysis and assumptions, the expected payoffs for the LGs, developers and DCs under different combinations of their
strategies are presented in Fig. 3. Based on the above payoff matrix, the expected payoffs of each stakeholder under different strategies
and the replicated dynamic equation can be calculated. Here uses Gi, Di and Ci to denote the payoffs when i is chosen respectively,
where i =1, 2 denotes the different strategy choices of each stakeholder, e.g. G1 denotes the payoffs when the LG chooses the strategy
of incentive".
(1) Local governments:
The expected payoffs function for LGs choosing the incentivestrategy is:
G1=yz(GB1+GB2GC1GC2GC3) + (1y)(1z)(− GC3)(1)
The expected payoffs function for LGs choosing the non-incentivestrategy is:
G2=yz(GB1+GB2)(2)
The average expected payoffs for the LGs is:
G=xG1+ (1x)G2(3)
From equation (1)(2)(3), the replicated dynamic equation for LGschoice of the incentivestrategy is:
F(x) = dx
dt =x(G1G) = x(1x)(G1G2)
=x(1x)[ yz(GC1+GC2+2GC3) + yGC3+zGC3GC3](4)
Based on the stable theorem of the differential equation (4), when F(x) = 0 and F(x)ʹ<0, the LGsstrategy is stable. Let dx
dt =0,
x
1=0, and x
2=1. Therefore,
y=(1z)GC3
z(GC1+GC2+2GC3) + GC3
(5)
Based on equation (5), when y=y, F(x) 0. It indicates that whether or not LGs implement incentive policies, they will gain the
same benets. When yy, the probability of ‘incentiveexceeds y. To ensure F(x) 0, x
2=1 must be satised and a stable strategy
of ‘incentiveis obtained. In this circumstance, the local governments strategy shifts from ‘non-incentiveto ‘incentive. When yy,
the probability of ‘incentive is less than y. As a result, x
1=0 is required and a stable strategy of ‘non-incentive is achieved. LGs
strategy shifts from ‘incentiveto ‘non-incentive. Based on the calculation above, the evolution trend for the LGsstrategy regarding
the promotion of the PD is illustrated in Fig. 4.
(2) Developers:
Fig. 4. Evolution trend of the LGsstrategies.
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
8
Similarly, the expected payoffs function for developers choosing the prefabricatedstrategy is:
D1=xz(DB1+DB2
α
β
60% DC1β
40%DC2DC3)
+(1x)z(DB1
α
β
60% DC1β
40%DC2DC3)(6)
The expected payoffs function for developers choosing the traditionalstrategy is:
D2=x(1z)(DB3DC3) + (1x)(1z)(DB3DC3)(7)
The average expected payoffs for developers is:
D=yD1+ (1y)D2(8)
From equation (6)(7)(8), replicated dynamic equation for the developerschoice of " prefabricated " strategy is:
F(y) = dy
dt =y(D1D) = y(1y)(D1D2)
=y(1y)[xzDB2+z(DB1+DB32DC3
α
β
60% DC1β
40%DC2)DB3+DC3](9)
Based on the stable theorem of the differential equation (9), when F(y) = 0 and F(y)ʹ<0, the LGs strategy is stable. Let dy
dt =0,
y
1=0, and y
2=1.Therefore,
z=DB3DC3
xDB2+DB1+DB32DC3
α
β
60% DC1β
40%DC2
(10)
Based on equation (10), when z=z, F(y) 0. It indicates that whether or not developers execute PD projects, they will gain the
same benets. When zz, the probability of ‘prefabricated exceeds z. To ensure F(y) 0, y
2=1 must be satised and a stable
strategy of ‘prefabricatedis obtained. In this circumstance, the developersstrategy shifts from ‘traditionalto ‘prefabricated. When
zz, the probability of ‘prefabricatedis less than z. As a result, y
1=0 is required and a stable strategy of ‘traditionalis achieved.
Developersstrategy shifts from ‘prefabricated to ‘traditional. The trend of the evolution of developers is shown in Fig. 5.
(3) Decoration contractors:
Fig. 5. Evolution trend of the developersstrategies.
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
9
Similarly, the expected payoffs function for DCs when they choose the prefabricated strategy is:
C1=xy[CB5+CB2CC4+γ(CB3CC2) + (1γ)(CB4CC3)]
+(1x)y[CB5CC4+ +γ(CB3CC2) + (1γ)(CB4CC3)] (11)
The expected payoffs function for DCs choosing the traditionalstrategy is:
C2=x(1y)(CB5CC4+ (1x)(1y)(CB5CC4)) (12)
The average expected payoffs for the DCs is:
C=yC1+ (1y)C2(13)
From equation (11)(12)(13), the replicated dynamic equation for the DCs choice of the prefabricatedstrategy is:
F(z) = dz
dt =z(C1C) = z(1z)(C1C2)
=z(1z)[xyCB2+y(2CB52CC4+γ(CB3CC2) + (1γ)(CB4CC3)) CB5+CC4](14)
Based on the stable theorem of the differential equation (14), when F(z) = 0 and F(z)ʹ<0, the LGs strategy is stable. Let dz
dt =0,
z
1=0, and z
2=1.Therefore,
y∗∗ =CB5CC4
xCB2+2CB52CC4+γ(CB3CC2) + (1γ)(CB4CC3)(15)
Based on equation (15), when y=y∗∗, F(z) 0. It indicates that whether or not DCs supply PD technologies, they will gain the same
benets. When yy∗∗, the probability of ‘prefabricatedexceeds y∗∗. To ensure F(y) 0, z
2=1 must be satised and a stable strategy
of ‘prefabricated is obtained. In this circumstance, the DCs strategy shifts from ‘traditional to ‘prefabricated. When yy∗∗ , the
probability of ‘prefabricated is less than y∗∗ . As a result, z
1=0 is required and a stable strategy of ‘traditional is achieved. DCs
strategy shifts from ‘prefabricatedto ‘traditional. The trend of the evolution of DCs is shown in Fig. 6.
Based on (4)(9)(14), the replication dynamic equations for the LGs, developers and DCs are:
F(x) = x(1x)[ yz(GC1+GC2+2GC3) + yGC3+zGC3GC3]
F(y) = y(1y)[xzDB2+z(DB1+DB32DC3
α
β
60% DC1β
40%DC2)DB3+DC3]
F(z) = z(1z)[xyCB2+y(2CB52CC4+γ(CB3CC2) + (1γ)(CB4CC3)) CB5+CC4]
(16)
The equilibrium points and stability of the strategies of the tripartite evolutionary game are analysed. When the rate of change of
Fig. 6. Evolution trend of the DCsstrategies.
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
10
the strategy choice of the tripartite evolutionary game system is 0, there are dx
dt =0, dy
dt =0, and dz
dt =0 , and according to equation (16),
four pure strategy equilibrium points of the evolutionary game model can be identied: E1 (0, 0, 0), E2 (1, 0, 0), E3 (1, 1, 1) and E4 (0, 1,
1).
3.3. Stability analysis of the equilibrium point in the tripartite game
To assess the stability of the equilibrium point in the tripartite game of PD, we employ Lyapunovs stability theory [51], which
establishes that an equilibrium can only be an deemed asymptotically stable. Under this condition, the equilibrium qualies as an
Evolutionary Stable Strategy (ESS). As the equilibrium point, denoted as e*, represents a mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium, this study
focuses on analyzing the asymptotic stability of eight pure-strategy equilibria. Verication of their stability can be accomplished by
scrutinizing the eigenvalues of the systems Jacobi matrix [41]. According to Lyapunovs stability discriminant, the following criterion
on the Jacobi matrix can be used to determine whether the Nash equilibrium point is an ESS [52].
1. When all eigenvalues λ0 are present, the equilibrium point is classied as an ESS, indicating stability.
2. When all eigenvalues λ0 are present, the equilibrium point is deemed unstable.
3. When both positive and negative eigenvalues are present, the equilibrium point is a saddle point and remains unstable.
Based on Equation (16), the Jacobi matrix for this tripartite evolutionary game model is described as follows:
J=
J11 J12 J13
J21 J22 J23
J31 J32 J33
where
J11 = (12x)[ yz(GC1+GC2+2GC3) + yGC3+zGC3GC3]
J12 =x(1x)[ z(GC1+GC2+2GC3) + GC3]
J13 =x(1x)[ y(GC1+GC2+2GC3) + GC3]
J21 =y(1y)(zDB2)
J22 = (12y)[xzDB2+z(DB1+DB32DC3
α
β
60% DC1β
40%DC2)DB3+DC3]
J23 =y(1y)(xDB2+DB1+DB32DC3
α
β
60% DC1β
40%DC2)
J31 =z(1z)(yCB2)
J32 =z(1z)(xCB2+2CB52CC4+γ(CB3CC2) + (1γ)(CB4CC3))
J33 = (12z)[xyCB2+y(2CB52CC4+γ(CB3CC2) + (1γ)(CB4CC3)) CB5+CC4]
Based on assumption 5, the developer executing traditional decoration projects has greater economic benets than costs and the
DC supply traditional technologies has greater economic benets than costs, which indicates that DC3DB3<0 and CC4CB5<0.
There are two Scenarios corresponding to different ESS.
Scenario 1. The benets of the developer in executing PD projects are less than the costs of that. The benets of the DC in supplying
Table 3
The analysis table for adjudging the stability of equilibrium points.
Equilibrium
points
Eigenvalue Sign Stability
λ1 λ2 λ3
E1 (0, 0, 0) GC3 DC3DB3 CC4CB5 −−− ESS
E2 (1, 0, 0) GC3 DC3DB3 CC4CB5 + Unstable
E3 (1, 1, 1) GC1+GC2+GC3 DC3DB2DB1+5
α
3DC15β
3DC1+
5β
2DC2
CC4CB2CB5γ(CB3CC2) (1
γ)(CB4CC3)
+++ Unstable
E4 (0, 1, 1) GC1GC2
GC3
DC3DB1+5
α
3DC15β
3DC1+5β
2DC2 CC4CB5γ(CB3CC2) (1γ)(CB4CC3) + + Unstable
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
11
PD technologies are less than the costs of that. The inequality (17) and inequality (18) are established.
DC3DB1+5
α
3DC15β
3DC1+5β
2DC2>0(17)
CC4CB5γ(CB3CC2) (1γ)(CB4CC3)>0 (18)
The local stability of each equilibrium point is summarized in Table 3. +means the values of λi are more than 0, and "-" means the
values are less than 0. If the value of λi0(i=1,2,3)
,
an ESS exists. Otherwise, there is not an ESS. Therefore, the evolutionary stability
point is E1 (0, 0, 0) and a nal equilibrium state of (non-incentive, traditional, traditional) would be obtained.
Scenario 2. The benets of the developer in executing PD projects are greater than the costs of that. The benets of the DC in
supplying PD technologies are greater than the costs of that. The inequality (19) and (20) are established.
DC3DB1+5
α
3DC15β
3DC1+5β
2DC2<0(19)
CC4CB5γ(CB3CC2) (1γ)(CB4CC3)<0 (20)
The local stability of each equilibrium point is summarized in Table 4. The evolutionary stability point is E1 (0, 0, 0) and E4 (0, 1, 1).
According to the different initial points, two nal equilibrium state would be obtained, which are (non-incentive, prefabricated,
prefabricated) and (non-incentive, traditional, traditional).
4. Empirical study and simulation results
To provide a comprehensive validation of the tripartite evolutionary game model and ascertain the correlation between stake-
holdersstrategies and system stability, a numerical analysis is conducted within the specic context of Chongqing. This verication
involves assigning numerical values to the model and simulating the game process using MATLAB2016b, thus capturing the evolu-
tionary trajectory from the initial state to the nal equilibrium in its entirety. Through this numerical simulation, the effectiveness and
reliability of the proposed model are thoroughly examined, shedding light on the intricate dynamics among three key stakeholders and
their impact on system stability.
4.1. Empirical study in Chongqing
4.1.1. Study area
This study selected Chongqing as the focal area for exploring the rational promotion strategies of stakeholders in the PD industry
with the consideration of three aspects: a supportive development foundation, a promising market with considerable potential, and a
strong motivation from the local government to promote PD. Firstly, as a demonstration city for prefabricated buildings [10],
Chongqings experience in terms of PD, extending and completing the prefabrication industrial chain, can apply to other cities as well.
Secondly, with the introduction of many PD policies and standards by Chongqings government, the market has paid more attention to
PD, which has great development potential in Chongqing [53]. Lastly, as of 2020, the proportion of new prefabricated building
construction in Chongqing accounted for only 15 % of new buildings [54], which is comparatively lower than in other demonstration
cities for prefabricated buildings. This indicates a strong motivation from the government to promote PD and bridge the gap between
the current state and the desired level of adoption. Based on these considerations, the study utilizes Chongqing as a case for a detailed
PD industry analysis, aiming to uncover reasons for stagnation and propose solutions, fostering industry progress locally and globally.
Table 4
The analysis table for adjudging the stability of equilibrium points.
Equilibrium
points
Eigenvalue Sign Stability
λ1 λ2 λ3
E1 (0, 0, 0) GC3 DC3DB3 CC4CB5 −−− ESS
E2 (1, 0, 0) GC3 DC3DB3 CC4CB5 + Unstable
E3 (1, 1, 1) GC1+GC2+GC3 DC3DB2DB1+5
α
3DC15β
3DC1+
5β
2DC2
CC4CB2CB5γ(CB3CC2) (1
γ)(CB4CC3)
+ Unstable
E4 (0, 1, 1) GC1GC2
GC3
DC3DB1+5
α
3DC15β
3DC1+5β
2DC2 CC4CB5γ(CB3CC2) (1γ)(CB4CC3) ESS
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
12
4.1.2. Data collection
Data for the cost and benets parameters of the PD tripartite game model were unavailable from the ofcial statistics in its initial
stage of promotion in China, either not able to be procured on the project level owing to the commercial sensitivity. In this circum-
stance, a mixed method of data acquisition is adopted in this study, including literature analysis, policy analysis, and expert interview
to collect the practical data that reects the current application of PD in Chongqing. By means of literature analysis, this study gathered
a wide range of scholarly articles about the eld of PD in China, by which the evolutionary trajectory, technical attributes, and
prevailing market dynamics in the realm of PD were comprehensively understood. In the pursuit of policy analysis, we delved into an
assortment of policy documents, regulations, and governmental reports that bear relevance to the domain of PD, spanning both na-
tional and provincial echelons. Within the connes of these cogent materials, we scrutinized the multifaceted facets of supporting
policies, exacting market entry prerequisites, and stringent quality standards. Expert interviews were conducted with 12 experts and
scholars from various sectors to obtain quantitative evaluations of payoff information related to PD. At the beginning of the interview,
the interviewer explained the purpose and the expected duration of the interview, and asked for the interviewees consent to
participate. After obtaining the interviewees consent, they also acknowledged and agreed that all interview content would be used
solely for academic research and publication. The specic list of expert interviews is described in Table 5, and the payoff data is
summarized in Table 6.
Local Government: The benets indicators for LGs are GB1and GB2.This study represents GB1 with the time saved by imple-
menting PD projects. Based on experience from the Chongqing Sheltered Housing Centre, a 50m2 public rental housing unit takes only
6 days to renovate using PD, compared to 30 days for traditional interiors, i.e., a saving of 24 days in construction time. According to
the Chinese real estate rental and sales service platform ANJUKE(https://cc.anjuke.com/) and LIANJIA"(https://cq.lianjia.com/),
the average price of a two-room apartment in Chongqing in 2023 is 1541 CNY/m2, thus GB1 is 1541*24/30/50 =24.66 CNY/m2. GB2
is represented with the excremental cost of the carbon emission governance cost. The carbon emissions per unit m
2
for PD and the
carbon emissions per unit m
2
for traditional decoration are 35.8 kg and 134.7 kg respectively [6]. The unit carbon emission control cost
is 0.97 CNY/kg [55], so GB2 is (134.735.8)*0.97 =95.93 CNY/m2.
The cost indicators for LGs are GC1,GC2and GC3. The LG will provide a subsidy of 200 CNY/m2 to demonstration projects with an
assembly rate greater than 65 % [56], so GC1 is 200 CNY/m2. The LG will reduce the corporate income tax at a rate of 15 % for the DC
that satises the relevant requirements (the corporate income tax should have been levied at 25 % [56]) To simplify the calculation,
this study takes YASHA, a representative PD enterprise, as an example. Based on expert research of the enterprises southwest branch
and analysis of its nancial statements for 2021, it is known that the enterprises corporate income tax in 2021 is approximately 130
million CNY, and the business revenue of the PD segment accounts for approximately 60 % of its total revenue and the total area for the
implementation of the segments projects is about 5 million m2, so GC2 is 130,000,000*0.6/5,000,000*(25%15 %) =1.56 CNY/m2.
GC3 are derived from the specic experiences of experts in the expert interview method.
Developers: The benets indicators for developers are DB1,DB2and DB3. DB2 refers to the benets from government subsidies of
executing PD projects ( DB2=GC1). The cost indicators for the developers are DC1,DC2and DC3. According to the add cost analysis
for prefabricated structure construction, DC1 is 483.3 CNY/m2 and DC2 is 900 CNY/m2 [57]. DB1,DB2,DB3 and DC3 are all derived
from the specic experiences of experts in the expert interview method.
Decoration Contractors: The benets indicators for decorators are CB1,CB2,CB3,CB4and CB5. CB1 refers to the incremental
benets when the DC supplying PD technologies(CB1=CB5+γCB3+ (1γ)CB4). CB2 refers to the benets from government
subsidies of supplying PD projects(CB2=GC2). The cost indicators for decorators are CC1,CC2,CC3and CC4. CC1 refers to the in-
cremental costs when the DC supplying PD technologies (CC1=CC4+γCC2+ (1γ)CC3). CB1,CB3,CB4,CB5,CC1,CC2,CC3and CC4
all are derived from the specic experiences of experts in the expert interview method.
Table 5
List of expert interviews.
No. Stakeholder Position Department unit
1 LG Clerk Marketing Housing and Urban-Rural Construction Commission
2 LG Clerk Marketing Housing and Urban-Rural Construction Commission
3 LG Clerk Marketing Housing and Urban-Rural Construction Commission
4 D Regional Sales Manager Sales China Vanke Co., Ltd.
5 D Regional Sales Manager Sales China Vanke Co., Ltd.
6 D Regional Marketing Director Marketing Longfor Properties Co. Ltd.
7 DC Regional Marketing Director Marketing Zhejiang Yasha Decoration Co., Ltd.
8 DC Regional Marketing Adviser Marketing Zhejiang Yasha Decoration Co., Ltd.
9 DC General Manager South West Region Zhejiang Yasha Decoration Co., Ltd.
10 Designer Deputy President Architectural Design Institute
11 Researchers Associate Professor Chongqing university
12 Researchers Research Assistant Institute of Urban-Rural Construction and Development
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
13
Table 6
The initial values of all parameters (unit =CNY/m2).
Parameters Values
(Mean.)
Description Sources
GB1 24.66 Time saved by implementing PD:1541*24/30/50 =24.66 Interviewees (No.1, No.3), literature [27]
GB2 95.93 Environmental governance excremental costs:(134.735.8) *0.97 =95.93 Literature [6,55]
GC1 200 Subsidy for developers. Policy [58]
GC2 1.56 Subsidy for DCs: 130,000,000*0.6/500,000,000*(25%15 %) =1.56 Interviewees (No.4, No.5), policy [58]
GC3 20 Government-incurred promotion costs. Interviewees (No.2)
α
0.65 Assembly rate threshold of subsidy. Policy [58]
DB1 11,000 Sales price of commercial housing. Interviewees (No.6, No.10)
DB2 200 DB2=GC1 Policy [58]
DC1 483.30 Incremental costs when all structures are constructed using prefabricated
construction
Literature [57]
DC2 900 Incremental costs when all decoration is constructed using prefabricated
construction
Interviewees (No.7, No.8, No.9)
β 0.20 Contribution of PD for projectsprefabrication. Interviewees (No.4, No.5, No.6)
DB3 11000 Sales price of commercial housing. Interviewees (No.4, No.5, No.6)
DC3 3390 Cost of traditional construction of commercial housing. Interviewees (No.4, No.6, No.11)
CB1 =CB5+γCB3+ (1γ)CB4
CB2 1.56 CB2 =GC2 Interviewees (No.4, No.6, No.12), policy
[58]
CB3 390 Incremental benets of PDs exploratory innovation. Interviewees (No.7, No.8, No.9)
CB4 240 Incremental benets of PDs exploitative innovation. Interviewees (No.7, No.8, No.9)
CC1 =CC4+γCC2+ (1γ)CC3
CC2 360 Incremental costs of PDs exploratory innovation. Interviewees (No.7, No.8, No.9)
CC3 190 Incremental costs of PDs exploitative innovation. Interviewees (No.7, No.8, No.9)
γ 0.50 Proportion of exploratory technologies in PD implementation. Interviewees (No.7, No.8, No.9)
CB5 2400 Contract price for traditional decoration. Interviewees (No.7, No.8, No.9)
CC4 1500 Costs for traditional decoration. Interviewees (No.7, No.8, No.9)
Fig. 7. Evolution results of different initial values of (x, y, z).
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
14
4.2. Dynamic evolution results
The practical data of Chongqing (as presented in Table 6) were assigned to the parameters of strategies in meet the inequality (19)
and (20) of Scenario 2 to validate the tripartite game model and conrm the stability of equilibrium points. The simulation process
involved setting a step size of 0.1 and generating 100 sets of initial participation proportion values (x, y, z) to observe the trajectory of
evolution from various starting points to equilibrium. Through these simulations, it was veried that the equilibrium points E1 (0, 0, 0)
and E4 (0, 1, 1) are both asymptotically stable equilibrium points in the dynamic system, as illustrated by the convergence of the
different colored lines in Fig. 7. The resulting ESS for local governments, developers, and decoration contractors were identied as
(non-incentive, prefabricated, prefabricated) and (non-incentive, traditional, traditional), respectively. This dynamic evolution
simulation diagram strongly supports the theoretical analysis conducted earlier, conrming the effectiveness of the previous ndings.
Specically, in Scenario 2, regardless of the initial proportion of developers and DCs both choosing the strategy of ‘prefabricated, the
strategy of LGs ultimately stabilizes at ‘non-incentive(x =0). This observation implies that the benets associated with not imple-
menting incentive policies outweigh those of implementing incentive policies, thereby establishing ‘non-incentiveas the stable
strategy for LGs.
The stable strategies observed in the simulation results reect the dynamic decision-making process inuenced by the trade-off
between benets and costs in PD projects. Developers and DCs adapt their strategies based on market conditions and perceived ad-
vantages of prefabricated construction, while LGs incentive policies gradually phase out, indicating a transition to a market-driven
environment. This withdrawal can be attributed to industry maturation, increased competition, and the emergence of self-
sustaining mechanisms. This trend aligns with the experience of other industries, where incentive policies gradually phase out as
Fig. 8. The effect of the assembly rate threshold of subsidy (
α
) on (a) the evolution trajectories of three stakeholders, (b) local governments, (c)
developers, and (d) decoration contractors.
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
15
the industry matures [48]. As the PD industry matures, reliance on LGs incentive policies diminishes, emphasizing the need for a
gradual shift towards a self-sustaining market where project benets and advantages drive adoption and innovation.
4.3. Sensitivity analysis for the critical strategies
To gain valuable insights into the dynamics of stakeholdersstrategies and provide deeper managerial signicance for diffusion of
PD, a sensitivity analysis was conducted based on empirical analysis. The threshold of the assembly rate for subsidy, the LGssubsidy
inclination, the proportion of PD in prefabricated projects, and the proportion of exploratory technologies were analysed. These four
indicators are the curtail strategies of key stakeholders that have a certain degree of subjective variability and can be adjusted
independently by stakeholders. In-depth research on these core strategies can identify the fundamental barriers to the development of
the PD industry, providing a foundation for developing targeted development plans and policies.
4.3.1. Assembly rate threshold of subsidy (
α
)
As shown in Fig. 8(a), higher values of assembly rate threshold of subsidy tend to direct both developers and DCs towards adopting
the ‘traditionalstrategy. The results, as depicted in Fig. 8(c) and (d), demonstrate that when
α
is relatively low (<65 %), both de-
velopers and DCs tend to adopt the ‘prefabricatedstrategy in their evolutionary paths. However, as the value of ɑ exceeds 65 %, their
strategies toward the ‘traditionaland developers are evolving faster than DCs. Additionally, Fig. 8(b) reveals that the stable strategy of
LGs consistently reaches ‘non-incentive, while when
α
exceeds 70 %, the speed of evolution slows down signicantly.
Fig. 9. The effect of the local governmentssubsidy allocation bias on (a) the evolution trajectories of three stakeholders, (b) local governments, (c)
developers, and (d) decoration contractors.
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
16
4.3.2. Local governments subsidy allocation bias
Taking into account the practical bias in LGs subsidy allocation, the PD tripartite evolutionary game model was explored under
three inclination situations between GC1 and GC2 most subsidies favor developers (GC1 =200, GC2 =50), fair subsidies (GC1 =125,
GC2 =125), and most subsidies favor DCs (GC1 =50, GC2 =200). It is observed from Fig. 9(a) that when the predominant subsidies are
allocated to DCs (GC1 <GC2), the evolutionary paths of developers and DCs tend to shift towards the ‘prefabricatedstrategy (x, y =1).
However, when GC1>GC2 instead, the developersand the DCsevolutionary paths all change toward the ‘traditionalstrategy. Fig. 9
(b) indicates that the stable strategy of LGs consistently leans towards ‘non-incentive, yet this evolution speed slows down signi-
cantly when subsidies are focused on developers. Fig. 9(c) and (d) demonstrate that the stable strategies of developers and DCs tend
towards ‘traditional when LGs grant most subsidies to developers. Conversely, the stable strategy of developers and DCs reaches
‘prefabricatedwhen subsidies are allocated fairly or mainly favor DCs, with developers exhibiting a slightly faster evolutionary speed
than DCs.
4.3.3. Contribution of PD for projectsprefabrication (β)
As depicted in Fig. 10(a), high values of β steer both developers and DCs towards the ‘traditionalstrategy (x, y =0). Fig. 10(b)
indicates that the stable strategy of LGs consistently approaches ‘non-incentive, with a slower decline when β is above 20 %. Moreover,
Fig. 10(c) and (d) demonstrate that the stable strategies of developers and DCs reach ‘prefabricatedfor β values at 15 % and 20 %.
However, as β increases to 25 %, the stable strategy of developers ultimately decreases to ‘traditional.
Fig. 10. The effect of the contribution of PD for projects prefabrication (β) on (a) the evolution trajectories of three stakeholders, (b) local gov-
ernments, (c) developers, and (d) decoration contractors.
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
17
4.3.4. Proportion of exploratory technologies in PD (γ)
To illuminate the imperative of technological innovation in the context of PD and offer actionable insights to contractors, this study
delved into the impact of the proportion of exploratory technologies (γ) within PD projects through comprehensive sensitivity sim-
ulations. Fig. 11(a) shows that high values of γ drive all stakeholders towards adopting the ‘traditional strategy (x, y, z =0). The
outcomes, as depicted in Fig. 11(b), underscore a consistent trend in the stable strategy of LGs converging towards ‘non-incentive.
Notably, this decline slows down when γ is higher than 50 %. Turning attention to Fig. 11(c) and (d), it becomes evident that for γ
values 30 % and 50 %, the stable strategy of both developers and DCs align towards the ‘prefabricatedapproach. In contrast, with the
escalation of γ to 70 %, the stable strategy them regresses to ‘traditional, with the period for the contractors to abandon PD longer than
the developers.
5. Discussion
5.1. Local governments optimal strategies for value co-creation
This study underscores the signicance of subsidies in achieving PDs value co-creation and challenge the notion that higher
subsidy thresholds always lead to better outcomes. While it is understandable that LGs link subsidies to the assembly rate to attract
developers to adopt PD, this study argues against an excessively high threshold (>70 %) for subsidy allocation. Such an excessive
threshold of the assembly rate can deter the developers and DCs from adopting PD. On the one hand, the heightened use of pre-
fabricated components escalates project costs, thereby reducing the attractiveness of PD projects [32]. On the other hand, excessive
Fig. 11. The effect of the proportion of exploratory technologies in PD (γ) on (a) the evolution trajectories of three stakeholders, (b) local gov-
ernments, (c) developers, and (d) decoration contractors.
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
18
government intervention and a high baseline for subsidies may limit the autonomy of the market, as developers may exclusively pursue
PD methods eligible for subsidies, disregarding other potentially more suitable construction approaches. This rigidity can impede
market vitality [35]. In contrast, a low threshold of prefabricated rate (
α
<60 %) falls short of achieving the PD development goals.
Hence, determining an optimal assembly rate threshold that unlocks the benets of prefabrication while motivating private stake-
holders to embrace PD is of paramount importance. This study recommends a reasonable range for the subsidy threshold that is slightly
higher than Chongqings actual threshold (65 % <
α
<70 %) [56]. This range represents a delicate equilibrium where developers and
contractors are incentivized to undertake PD projects while still aligning with the governments PD diffusion goals.
Prioritizing subsidies towards decoration contractors rather than developers, the local governments subsidy allocation bias proves
more advantageous for advancing value co-creation of PD. Currently, local subsidy policies tend to prioritize developers based on their
experience of prefabricated construction development, and this trend extends beyond Chongqing [34]. However, while subsidies do
encourage developers to adopt PD [22], this study reveals that establishing a stable relationship among key stakeholders takes time.
Unfortunately, a signicant portion of the subsidies compensates for developersprot loss, not beneting the industrys technical
growth. Conversely, focusing subsidies on DCs encourage advanced knowledge and technology exploration for PD, fostering
commitment and expansion, as seen in emerging industries [59]. However, the current subsidy policies in Chongqing exhibit a clear
preference for subsidizing developers to promote PD development (GC1 =200 and GC2 =1.56 approximately). Given the studys
ndings, shifting focus to DCs is recommended for maximizing industry potential and achieving value co-creation.
5.2. Developersoptimal strategies for value co-creation
This study unveiled a latent resistance to boosting PDs value co-creation among private stakeholders, as indicated by simulation
results showing a negative correlation between the proportion of PD in prefabricated projects and the willingness of developers and
contractors to embrace PD. This is rooted in Chinese prefabricated building policies focusing on both structure and decoration [56].
With mature structural prefabricated technologies compared to decoration [60], developers prefer structure due to ease. Nonetheless,
this study proposes a gradual integration of PD into prefabricated building projects, offering two pertinent considerations. Firstly, PD
could augment developers competitiveness by allowing them to achieve higher assembly rates to qualify for incentives (
α
>65 %),
particularly when the maximum structure portion (60 %) is conned by current prefabricated building evaluation standards. Secondly,
PDs utilization of manufactured materials facilitates expedited project completion with ecologically sustainable practices, making it a
pivotal avenue for green and low-carbon transformation [3]. For practicality, a recommended PD portion (<20 %) in prefabricated
projects is suggested, which holds signicant value for promoting PD in cities during the early stage of its development.
5.3. Decoration contractors optimal strategies for value co-creation
During the incubation period of PD new technologies, while both developers and DCs exhibit a proclivity for established techniques
that have already gained maturity in the market, the application of emerging technologies cannot be ignored. The sensitivity analysis
results underscore the fact that an excessive proportion of exploratory technologies substantially dampens the enthusiasm of both
developers and DCs for PD engagement. This aligns with project management literature in China and globally [61,62], where de-
velopers prioritize proven products, and contractors stick to mature systems for stable prots. However, contractors have exhibited
more patience in embracing emerging technologies, highlighting exploratory innovations role in maintaining a competitive edge and
capitalizing on emerging market prospects [63]. Consequently, while prioritizing innovations in established products such as ceiling,
wall, and kitchen systems, DCs, especially those with weaker product competitiveness, should learn from similar enterprises in other
industries and place due importance to fostering innovation in less mature aspects of PD [31]. This perspective is also echoed by
designers and researchers in Chongqing, as reected in Interviews 10 and 11 in Table 5. Hence, DCs should strike a balance between
binary innovations and controlled exploratory technology (50 % of the total scope) for sustained values creation.
5.4. Practical implementations for stakeholders in boosting value co-creation of PD
In the process of diffusing PD in Chinas construction sector, addressing the balance of interests among key stakeholders and
boosting value co-creation emerges as a prioritized challenge. Drawing from the insights of this study, the following strategic im-
plications are proposed to facilitate the diffusion of PD in China.
Local government. This study offers two recommendations for LGsPD policies: Firstly, adjusting the inclination objectives of
incentive policies from developers to DCs. This approach entails allocating a portion of incentive resources to DCs to recognize their
contributions. This shift enhances the contractors enthusiasm, technological innovation, and market position. To ensure proper
allocation, LGs can establish thresholds based on technical strength, qualications, and project experience, sieving out capable en-
terprises for incentives. Secondly, appropriately regulating the subsidy threshold for prefabricated construction, thus fostering room
for the development of PD. To align with industry growth, LGs should adopt a staged approach for these thresholds. Initially, a modest
reduction encourages broader participation, technology accumulation, and market entry. As the industry matures, gradually raising
the threshold encourages continuous enhancement of technical capabilities and project quality. Engaging industry stakeholders in
setting these thresholds fosters consensus and policy viability. Moreover, establishing a robust monitoring system is essential [64],
allowing for data-driven evaluation and timely adjustments to maintain policy relevance.
Developers. Within the context of safeguarding their own prots, Chinese developers should be conservative but progressively
integrate PD into construction projects by augmenting its share in prefabrication for each project. This endeavor necessitates two
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
19
pivotal strategies. Firstly, fostering close communication with DCs during the design stages is recommended to ensure that only the
most reliable PD components are designed as part of the decoration, which will help to achieve a higher assembly rate. Secondly,
developers are advised to establish stable collaborations with architects in the realm of PD technology development, thereby facili-
tating the seamless expansion of PD applications across future projects. In sum, the incremental integration of mature PD technologies,
coupled with the exploration of innovative PD technologies, ensures developers engagement in the promising PD sector. This
approach paves the way for an extended prefabricated supply chain that yields signicant dividends, including monetary gains, time
efciencies, energy conservation, and enhanced market competitiveness for developers [65].
Decoration contractors. In the current phase, DCs are advised to prioritize matured PD products and well-established technology
offerings, with a supplementary allocation of resources towards exploratory technology innovation. To anchor mature technologies
and exploit innovative advancements as the primary tenets of PD implementation, it becomes imperative for DCs to distinctly dene
their unique PD attributes. This can be achieved through the cultivation of stable collaborations with component suppliers and the
continual enhancement of a comprehensive dataset comprising popular PD components that align with market demands [12].
Moreover, DCs are encouraged to undertake judicious exploratory innovation endeavors, capitalizing on their industry acumen and
forming synergistic partnerships with research institutions, technology providers and labor. This collaborative approach fosters
knowledge exchange and provides access to cutting-edge technologies. By fostering a culture of innovation within their organizations
and building strategic partnerships, DCs can position themselves at the forefront of technological advancements, thus ensuring sus-
tainable growth over the long term.
6. Conclusions
Prefabricated decoration (PD) has emerged as a pivotal avenue for ushering in industrialization within Chinas construction sector,
offering substantial integration, energy efciency, and sustainability benets across the entire construction industry. The diffusion of
PD necessitates value co-creation among diverse stakeholders, yet prior studies have largely overlooked the intricate dynamics of
stakeholder relationships and the evolving cooperative mechanisms within this nascent sector from the value perspective. This study
takes a pioneering step by developing a tripartite evolutionary game model encompassing the key stakeholders - local governments,
developers, and decoration contractors. Through a rigorous analysis of the evolutionary process and the intricate strategic interplays
among these stakeholders, this study unveils the complex collaborative mechanisms driving PDs value co-creation, thus providing
invaluable guidance to forward-thinking stakeholders navigating this evolutionary trajectory. This endeavor yields noteworthy
conclusions.
In scenarios where PD benets outweigh costs, two evolutionary stable strategies emerge: E1 (0, 0, 0) (non-incentive, traditional,
traditional) and E4 (0, 1, 1) (non-incentive, prefabricated, prefabricated). Irrespective of developersand DCsstable strategies,
LGsincentive policies will eventually phase out from the market. Interestingly, if both adopt ‘traditionalstrategies, LGs shift to
‘non-incentive more slowly, extending incentives to encourage private stakeholders to embrace PD. Conversely, with ‘pre-
fabricatedstrategies, signifying industry maturity, governments reduce intervention, phasing out incentives gradually.
For PD-related incentive policies, maintaining an optimal subsidy threshold and prioritizing subsidy allocation to DCs over de-
velopers are advocated. Firstly, a reasonable subsidy baseline is crucial to strike a harmony between industry diffusion imperatives
and developers participation, preventing an excessively high subsidy threshold from dampening developer interest and con-
straining market autonomy. For early-stage emerging PD markets, such as Chongqing, a recommended threshold assembly rate
range of 65%70 % is proposed. Secondly, directing incentives primarily toward DCs signicantly stimulates PD adoption. Hence, a
recalibration of Chongqings current incentive approach is advised, shifting focus from developers to DCs for more effective PD
promotion.
Amplifying the share of PD in prefabricated projects signicantly dampens developersand contractorswillingness to embrace PD
during its initial development phase. However, its imperative to acknowledge that a certain proportion of PD in prefabrication
(<20 % in the case of Chongqing) offers distinct advantages, including shortened project timelines and the opportunity to attain a
higher assembly rate for securing incentives. Consequently, this study underscores the recommendation that Chinese developers
contemplate incorporating a dened proportion of PD within their construction endeavours, rather than dismissing it outright
during the nascent stages of PD implementation.
Binary technology innovation is advocated in the Chinese PD market, with an accentuated emphasis on exploitative innovation
based on mature products. This entails pursuing technology innovation pertaining to preassembled ceiling, wall, and kitchen
systems, expected to yield stable returns and notable success. Nonetheless, the signicance of exploratory innovation within less
mature technological domains should not be underestimated by DCs. A judicious equilibrium between innovation in mature and
nascent areas stands as pivotal for advancing and disseminating the PD sector holistically.
Its worth noting that, when pivotal game player strategies shift, developers consistently outpace DCs in evolutionary speed. This
phenomenon can be attributed to developersrole as sponsors within Chinese PD projects, granting them access to more infor-
mation and the agility to make swift decisions in response to dynamic circumstances, preserving their prot-generation
capabilities.
This study offers signicant contributions to academia and industry by uncovering the complex value co-creation mechanism
among stakeholders in the PD industry. Through a tripartite evolutionary game model, it reveals dynamic interactions among LGs,
developers, and DCs, and simulates the evolution process of PDs value co-creation under diverse interests, providing profound insights
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
20
into the value co-creation of PD. Furthermore, ndings from Chongqing provides a valuable template for cities globally that are in the
emerging stages of PD diffusion. Although the goal of this study was achieved, some limitations it persists. Choosing Chongqing city as
a case study inevitably entails regional limitations. Being a specic region, China possesses unique economic, cultural, and political
environments, potentially limiting the generalizability of research ndings to some extent. Further investigation should be conducted
in conjunction with local situations, when extending research outcomes to other regions. Besides, the analysis focuses on governments,
developers, and contractors, omitting other key stakeholders such as architects, prefabricated component manufacturers, and logistics.
Furthermore, simplied incentive policies might not fully capture diverse government schemes. Future research could explore
nuanced models considering varied subsidy structures, thereby providing a more detailed understanding of the PD industrys effects.
Ethics statement
This study was reviewed and approved by the Academic Committee of School of Management Science and Real Estate, Chongqing
University with the approval number: MSRECQU-ETH-09, dated March 3, 2023. All participants were informed that consent to
participate in the study and publish their data would be assumed on completion and submission of the study survey.
Data availability statement
The data associated with this study has not been deposited into a publicly available repository. Some or all data, models, or code
that support the ndings of this study are available from the corresponding author upon reasonable request.
Funding
This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No.72301044), National Natural Science
Foundation of China (Grant No.72271035), Chongqing Social Sciences Planning ProjectYouth Fund (2022NDQN43), and National
Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No.72101190).
CRediT authorship contribution statement
Hongjuan Wu: Writing review & editing, Supervision, Investigation, Funding acquisition. Yipin Huang: Writing original draft,
Visualization, Validation, Methodology, Formal analysis. Guiwen Liu: Writing review & editing, Writing original draft, Funding
acquisition. Lizi Luo: Writing review & editing, Funding acquisition. Yuhang Luo: Writing original draft, Investigation, Data
curation.
Declaration of competing interest
The authors declare that they have no known competing nancial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to
inuence the work reported in this paper.
Appendix A. Supplementary data
Supplementary data to this article can be found online at https://doi.org/10.1016/j.heliyon.2024.e34775.
References
[1] Y.H. Han, X.Y. Yan, P. Piroozfar, An overall review of research on prefabricated construction supply chain management, ENG CONSTR ARCHIT MA (2022),
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2021.149158.
[2] Z. Zhang, Y. Tan, L. Shi, L. Hou, G. Zhang, Current state of using prefabricated construction in Australia, Buildings 12 (9) (2022), https://doi.org/10.3390/
buildings12091355.
[3] J. Bian, C. Liu, C. Zuo, J. Hao, W. Ma, B. Duan, C. Chen, J. Liu, Reducing carbon emissions from prefabricated decoration: a case study of residential buildings in
China, Buildings 14 (2) (2024), https://doi.org/10.3390/buildings14020550.
[4] L. Jaillon, C.S. Poon, The evolution of prefabricated residential building systems in Hong Kong: a review of the public and the private sector, Autom. ConStruct.
18 (3) (2009) 239248, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.autcon.2008.09.002.
[5] J.J. Wang, Y. Teng, Z. Chen, J. Bai, Y.N. Niu, H.B. Duan, Assessment of carbon emissions of building interior decoration and renovation waste disposal in the
fast-growing Greater Bay Area, China, Sci. Total Environ. (2021) 798, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2021.149158.
[6] Q. Wang, W. Wang, L.R. Shi, Y. Wang, Research on the Low Carbonisation and the Lmportance of the Basic Components of Prefabricated Lnterior Decoration,
World Architecture, 2021, pp. 5257+128, https://doi.org/10.16414/j.wa.2021.07.010. In Chinese.
[7] X. Yu, P. Wang, Economic effects analysis of environmental regulation policy in the process of industrial structure upgrading: evidence from Chinese provincial
panel data, Sci. Total Environ. 753 (2021), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2020.142004.
[8] F. Chien, The mediating role of energy efciency on the relationship between sharing economy benets and sustainable development goals (Case of China),
J INNOV KNOWL. 7 (4) (2022), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jik.2022.100270.
[9] J. Fan, L. Zhou, Y. Zhang, S. Shao, M. Ma, How does population aging affect household carbon emissions? Evidence from Chinese urban and rural areas, ENERG
ECON 100 (2021), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2021.105356.
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
21
[10] MOHURD, Guiding opinions on promoting the coordinated development of intelligent construction and building industrialization, Available from, http://www.
gov.cn/zhengce/zhengceku/2020-09/04/content_5540357.htm, 2020. (Accessed 7 May 2024).
[11] MOHURD, "14th Five-Year Plan" for the development of the construction industry, Available from, http://www.gov.cn/zhengce/zhengceku/2022-01/27/
content_5670687.htm, 2022. (Accessed 7 May 2024).
[12] C. Liu, Y. Yang, X. Zhao, X. Xu, J. Li Hao, W. Ma, Reducing carbon emissions by using prefabricated decoration oor systems, J GREEN BUILD 18 (1) (2023)
119145, https://doi.org/10.3992/jgb.18.1.119.
[13] D.-Y. Wang, X. Wang, Supply chain consequences of government subsidies for promoting prefabricated construction and emissions abatement, J. Manag. Eng. 39
(5) (2023), https://doi.org/10.1061/JMENEA.MEENG-5285.
[14] L. Luo, G.Q. Shen, G. Xu, Y. Liu, Y. Wang, Stakeholder-associated supply chain risks and their interactions in a prefabricated building project in Hong Kong,
J. Manag. Eng. 35 (2) (2019), https://doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)ME.1943-5479.0000675.
[15] L. Luo, X. Jin, G.Q. Shen, Y. Wang, X. Liang, X. Li, C.Z. Li, Supply chain management for prefabricated building projects in Hong Kong, J. Manag. Eng. 36 (2)
(2020), https://doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)ME.1943-5479.0000739.
[16] M. Matarazzo, L. Penco, G. Profumo, R. Quaglia, Digital transformation and customer value creation in Made in Italy SMEs: a dynamic capabilities perspective,
J. Bus. Res. 123 (2021) 642656, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2020.10.033.
[17] MOHURD, Technical Standards for Prefabricated Decoration JGJ/T491-2021, China Architecture & Building Press, 2021.
[18] X.Y. Li, C.Y. Yu, Design and application of integrated assembly technology of FRG in residential ceiling, in: 4th International Conference on Energy Materials
and Environment Engineering (ICEMEE), vol. 38, Kuala Lumpur, MALAYSIA, 2018, https://doi.org/10.1051/e3sconf/20183802012.
[19] X.Y. Li, Upgrade application of roof and wall modules in medical construction based on prefabricated interior decoration technology, J. Architect. Eng. 27 (2)
(2021), https://doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)ae.1943-5568.0000455.
[20] J.M. Smith, G.R. Price, Logic of animal conict, Nature 246 (5427) (1973) 1518, https://doi.org/10.1038/246015a0.
[21] Y.Y. Li, M. Li, P.D. Sang, P.H. Chen, C.C. Li, Stakeholder studies of green buildings: a literature review, J. Build. Eng. 54 (2022), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jobe.2022.104667.
[22] J. Wang, Y.J. Qin, J.Y. Zhou, Incentive policies for prefabrication implementation of real estate enterprises: an evolutionary game theory-based analysis, Energy
Pol. 156 (2021), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2021.112434.
[23] M.R. Hosseini, I. Martek, E.K. Zavadskas, A.A. Aibinu, M. Arashpour, N. Chileshe, Critical evaluation of off-site construction research: a Scientometric analysis,
Autom. ConStruct. 87 (2018) 235247, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.autcon.2017.12.002.
[24] A.W. Lacey, W.S. Chen, H. Hao, K.M. Bi, Structural response of modular buildings - an overview, J. Build. Eng. 16 (2018) 4556, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jobe.2017.12.008.
[25] Y. Gao, X.L. Tian, Prefabrication policies and the performance of construction industry in China, J. Clean. Prod. 253 (2020), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jclepro.2020.120042.
[26] J. Zhang, F.H. Tao, T.Y. Su, Research on BlM-based prefabricated building system [In Chinese, Build. Sci. 34 (1) (2018) 97102+29, https://doi.org/10.13614/
j.cnki.11-1962/tu.2018.01.017.
[27] CSBMIE, Guideline for the Development of Chinas Prefabricated Decoration Industry, 2022.
[28] X.L. Gan, R.D. Chang, C. Langston, T. Wen, Exploring the interactions among factors impeding the diffusion of prefabricated building technologies Fuzzy
cognitive maps, Eng. Construct. Architect. Manag. 26 (3) (2019) 535553, https://doi.org/10.1108/ecam-05-2018-0198.
[29] A.M. Blayse, K. Manley, Key inuences on construction innovation, Construct. Innovat. 4 (3) (2004), https://doi.org/10.1108/14714170410815060.
[30] Y. Liu, R.D. Chang, J. Zuo, F. Xiong, N. Dong, What leads to the high capital cost of prefabricated construction in China: perspectives of stakeholders, ENG
CONSTR ARCHIT MA 30 (2) (2023) 805832, https://doi.org/10.1108/ecam-06-2021-0538.
[31] Z.H. Jiang, Z.Y. Liu, Policies and exploitative and exploratory innovations of the wind power industry in China: the role of technological path dependence,
Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change (2022) 177, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2022.121519.
[32] Y.D. Dou, X.L. Sun, A.K. Ji, Y.N. Wang, X.L. Xue, Development strategy for prefabricated construction projects: a tripartite evolutionary game based on prospect
theory, ENG CONSTR ARCHIT MA (2023), https://doi.org/10.1108/ECAM-05-2021-0455.
[33] C. Cohen, D. Pearlmutter, M. Schwartz, A game theory-based assessment of the implementation of green building in Israel, Build. Environ. 125 (2017) 122128,
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.buildenv.2017.08.027.
[34] Q.Y. Huang, J.W. Wang, M.W. Ye, S.M. Zhao, X. Si, A study on the incentive policy of Chinas prefabricated residential buildings based on evolutionary game
theory, Sustainability 14 (3) (2022), https://doi.org/10.3390/su14031926.
[35] M.Q. Yuan, Z.F. Li, X.D. Li, L. Li, S.X. Zhang, X.W. Luo, How to promote the sustainable development of prefabricated residential buildings in China: a tripartite
evolutionary game analysis, J. Clean. Prod. 349 (2022), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2022.131423.
[36] B.Q. Cheng, Y.H. Wei, W. Zhang, X.T. Zhou, H.H. Chen, L.P. Huang, J.L. Huang, X.F. Kang, Evolutionary game simulation on government incentive strategies of
prefabricated construction: a system dynamics approach, Complexity 2020 (2020), https://doi.org/10.1155/2020/8861146.
[37] D.A. Levinthal, J.G. March, THE MYOPIA of LEARNING, Strategic Mnage J, vol. 14, 1993, pp. 95112, https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.4250141009.
[38] S. Yin, B.Z. Li, Z.Y. Xing, The governance mechanism of the building material industry (BMI) in transformation to green BMI: the perspective of green building,
Sci. Total Environ. 677 (2019) 1933, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2019.04.317.
[39] Z.M. Yuan, Z.Y. Zhang, G.D. Ni, C. Chen, W.S. Wang, J.K. Hong, Cause analysis of hindering on-site lean construction for prefabricated buildings and
corresponding organizational capability evaluation, Adv. Civ. Eng. 2020 (2020), https://doi.org/10.1155/2020/8876102.
[40] K. Fan, E.C.M. Hui, Evolutionary game theory analysis for understanding the decision -making mechanisms of governments and developers on green building
incentives, Build. Environ. 179 (2020), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.buildenv.2020.106972.
[41] D. Friedman, Evolutionary games in economics, Econometrica 59 (3) (1991) 637666, https://doi.org/10.2307/2938222.
[42] R. Eissa, M.S. Eid, E. Elbeltagi, Current applications of game theory in construction engineering and management research: a social network analysis approach,
J. Construct. Eng. Manag. 147 (7) (2021), https://doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)co.1943-7862.0002085.
[43] Z. Yu, S.A.R. Khan, Evolutionary game analysis of green agricultural product supply chain nancing system: COVID-19 pandemic, Int. J. Logist. Res. Appl. 25 (7)
(2022) 11151135, https://doi.org/10.1080/13675567.2021.1879752.
[44] Y. Bai, M. Huang, M. Huang, J. Luo, Z. Yang, Research on immature wheat harvesting behavior of farmers from the perspective of food security: an evolutionary
game based analysis, Heliyon 9 (8) (2023) e18850, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.heliyon.2023.e18850.
[45] Z.Q. Ma, J.J. Chen, G. Tian, Y. Gong, B.H. Guo, F.X. Cheng, Regulations on the corporate social irresponsibility in the supply chain under the multiparty game:
taking Chinas organic food supply chain as an example, J. Clean. Prod. 317 (2021), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.128459.
[46] L.X. Liu, Y.C. Zhu, S.B. Guo, The evolutionary game analysis of multiple stakeholders in the low-carbon agricultural innovation diffusion, Complexity 2020
(2020), https://doi.org/10.1155/2020/6309545.
[47] K. Kang, Y.J. Zhao, J. Zhang, C. Qiang, Evolutionary game theoretic analysis on low-carbon strategy for supply chain enterprises, J. Clean. Prod. 230 (2019)
981994, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.05.118.
[48] S.F. Ji, D. Zhao, R.J. Luo, Evolutionary game analysis on local governments and manufacturers behavioral strategies: impact of phasing out subsidies for new
energy vehicles, Energy 189 (2019), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2019.116064.
[49] Y. Su, H. Si, J. Chen, G. Wu, Promoting the sustainable development of the recycling market of construction and demolition waste: a stakeholder game
perspective, J. Clean. Prod. 277 (2020) 122281, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.122281.
[50] MOHURD, Standard for Assessment of Prefabricated Building GB/T 51129-2017, China Architecture & Building Press, 2017.
[51] A.M. Lyapunov, The general problem of the stability of motion, Int. J. Control 55 (3) (1992) 531534, https://doi.org/10.1080/00207179208934253.
[52] Y.B. Su, Multi-agent evolutionary game in the recycling utilization of construction waste, Sci. Total Environ. 738 (2020) 139826, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
scitotenv.2020.139826.
H. Wu et al.
Heliyon 10 (2024) e34775
22
[53] CHURCC, Notice on the issuance of certain policy measures for promoting the modernisation of Chongqings construction industry and promoting the high-
quality development of the construction industry, Available from: http://www.cq.gov.cn/zwgk/zfxxgkzl/fdzdgknr/lzyj/xzgfxwj/szfbgt/202009/t20200909_
8837780.html, 2020. (Accessed 7 May 2024).
[54] Peoples Daily, The proportion of Prefabricated building in new buildings in Chongqing has exceeded 15, Available from, https://mcq.people.com.cn/news/
2021622/20216221751538879362.htm, 2020. (Accessed 7 May 2024).
[55] NBSPRC, China Statistical Yearbook on Environment, China Statistical Publishing House, 2021.
[56] CHURCC, Chongqing green and low carbon building demonstration project and Fund management measures, Available from: http://zfcxjw.cq.gov.cn/zwxx_
166/gsgg/202211/t20221104_11264938.html, 2022. (Accessed 7 May 2024).
[57] C. Mao, F.Y. Xie, L. Hou, P. Wu, J. Wang, X.Y. Wang, Cost analysis for sustainable off-site construction based on a multiple-case study in China, Habitat Int. 57
(2016) 215222, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.habitatint.2016.08.002.
[58] CHURCC, Chongqing green and low carbon building demonstration project and Fund management measures, Available from: http://zfcxjw.cq.gov.cn/zwxx_
166/gsgg/202211/t20221104_11264938.html, 2022. (Accessed 7 May 2024).
[59] S.D. Zhao, L.Y. Yu, Z.Y. Zhang, Photovoltaic supply chain and government subsidy decision-making based on Chinas industrial distributed photovoltaic policy:
a power perspective, J. Clean. Prod. 413 (2023), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2023.137438.
[60] Y.X. Hou, M. Li, Y.F. Li, Analvsis on inuencing factors of the prefabricated decoration development based on ISM model [In Chinese.], Constr Econ 42 (11)
(2021) 7884, https://doi.org/10.14181/j.cnki.1002-851x.202111078.
[61] L. Shen, Z. Zhang, Z. Long, Signicant barriers to green procurement in real estate development, Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 116 (2017) 160168, https://doi.org/
10.1016/j.resconrec.2016.10.004.
[62] H.W. Volberda, A.Y. Lewin, Guest editorsintroduction - Co-evolutionary dynamics within and between rms: from evolution to co-evolution, J MANAGE STUD
40 (8) (2003) 21112136, https://doi.org/10.1046/j.1467-6486.2003.00414.x.
[63] A. OCass, N. Heirati, N. Liem Viet, Achieving new product success via the synchronization of exploration and exploitation across multiple levels and functional
areas, Ind. Market. Manag. 43 (5) (2014) 862872, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.indmarman.2014.04.015.
[64] Y. Cai, Q. Ni, M.J. Zhao, Informal institutions moderate the relationship between environmental emotion and grassland governance behavior, Environ. Manag.
71 (2) (2023) 405420, https://doi.org/10.1007/s00267-022-01754-0.
[65] H.J. Wu, Q.K. Qian, A. Straub, H.J. Visscher, Factors inuencing transaction costs of prefabricated housing projects in China: developers perspective, ENG
CONSTR ARCHIT MA 29 (1) (2022) 476501, https://doi.org/10.1108/ecam-07-2020-0506.
H. Wu et al.
Article
Full-text available
With the rapid development of autonomous driving technology, the advent of the autonomous driving era has become inevitable. An in-depth study of consumers’ willingness to purchase autonomous vehicles is critical to accelerating the adoption and commercialization of autonomous vehicles. By constructing a tripartite evolutionary game model of governments, automobile manufacturers, and consumers, we analyze the stable choice of unilateral strategy and equilibrium strategy of autonomous vehicle purchase intention. The MATLAB2022b tool was used for data simulation analysis to verify the validity of the conclusion and the influence of related factors on the purchase intention toward autonomous vehicles. The results show the following: (1) The combination of government support, active R&D, and consumer purchasing is the evolutionary stability strategy (ESS) of the model. (2) With an increase in government support, the probability of automobile enterprises taking the initiative to participate in R&D also increases. However, the negative impact of risk can significantly reduce the incentive for firms to conduct R&D and reduce the effectiveness of government support. (3) Government subsidies to consumers and purchase incentives offered by automotive companies can significantly increase the likelihood that consumers will purchase an autonomous vehicle. Based on these findings, recommendations are made to strengthen government support, establish risk mitigation mechanisms, and strengthen market promotion efforts to promote the commercialization of autonomous vehicles. The study provides a new perspective for understanding multi-party interactions in the rollout of autonomous vehicles and provides valuable insights for policymakers and industry stakeholders.
Article
Full-text available
With the rapid development of smart grids, the strategic behavior evolution in user-side electricity market transactions has become increasingly complex. To explore the dynamic evolution mechanisms in this area, this paper systematically reviews the application of evolutionary game theory in user-side electricity markets, focusing on its unique advantages in modeling multi-agent interactions and dynamic strategy optimization. While evolutionary game theory excels in explaining the formation of long-term stable strategies, it faces limitations when dealing with real-time dynamic changes and high-dimensional state spaces. Thus, this paper further investigates the integration of deep reinforcement learning, particularly the deep Q-learning network (DQN), with evolutionary game theory, aiming to enhance its adaptability in electricity market applications. The introduction of the DQN enables market participants to perform adaptive strategy optimization in rapidly changing environments, thereby more effectively responding to supply–demand fluctuations in electricity markets. Through simulations based on a multi-agent model, this study reveals the dynamic characteristics of strategy evolution under different market conditions, highlighting the changing interaction patterns among participants in complex market environments. In summary, this comprehensive review not only demonstrates the broad applicability of evolutionary game theory in user-side electricity markets but also extends its potential in real-time decision making through the integration of modern algorithms, providing new theoretical foundations and practical insights for future market optimization and policy formulation.
Article
Full-text available
Since decoration is an essential part of buildings, the carbon emissions generated by decoration work should not be ignored. In recent years, prefabricated decoration has attracted much attention as efforts are made to pursue green, low-carbon, and waste-reducing buildings. However, research on carbon emissions assessment of prefabricated buildings has focused mainly on the structural aspect of prefabricated buildings, with few studies having considered prefabricated decoration. This study therefore focuses on assessing the carbon emissions of prefabricated decoration from the life cycle perspective of a case study residential building and explores the potential for reducing carbon emissions by decorating buildings with prefabricated components. The results show that using prefabricated decoration in the case study building reduced carbon emissions by 29.08% at the building material production stage compared to traditional decoration, and using an optimized design of prefabricated decoration, the building’s energy consumption over its design life could reduce carbon emissions by 1046 kgCO2/m2. These findings demonstrate the benefits of prefabrication decoration for reducing carbon emissions. This study provides decoration companies with robust data and insights to guide future decisions and practices, helping to transform and achieve the carbon neutrality goal for the building decoration industry.
Article
Full-text available
Food security constitutes a foundational cornerstone for social stability, with the achievement of sustainable agricultural production serving as a vital step towards this objective. Currently, the untimely harvesting of unripe wheat by farmers has led to a decline in food production, thereby posing a significant threat to the sustainability of China's food system and exacerbating food insecurity. Although the Chinese government has implemented various measures in response, their effectiveness has been limited. Limited scholarly literature exists on this particular issue. To advance food security in China, this study develops a tripartite evolutionary game model involving farmers, the government, and breeding enterprises. Adopting a systemic perspective, this study examines the interactions and impact mechanisms among these key actors during the wheat harvesting process. The findings indicate that the government should prioritize policies that enforce penalties. By implementing penalties within a reasonable range, the government can mitigate farmers' production costs and enhance the market price of grain. This approach discourages farmers from harvesting immature wheat and contributes to enhancing food security. Based on the research findings, this paper provides practical recommendations to guide the government in addressing food security governance issues.
Article
Full-text available
Clarifying the behavior motivation of herders participating in grassland governance has important theoretical and practical significance for the construction of ecological civilization and economic development in pastoral areas. Based on the data from 425 households in the Inner Mongolia Autonomous Region, this paper constructs a Double-Hurdle model to explore the impact of informal institutions and environmental emotion (individual emotion, collective emotion, and intergenerational dependence) on herders’ grassland governance. The results show that informal institutions promote herders’ willingness and payment for participating in grassland governance, and collective emotions hinder herders’ participation, showing a “free-ride” mentality. Informal institutions moderate the relationship between collective emotions and grassland governance behavior. Informal institutions also help herders understand the collective sense of responsibility and morality behind grassland protection, thereby reducing the “free-ride” mentality. Therefore, it is necessary to maintain the informal institutions’ role as a “glue” in the traditional culture of pastoral areas and to promote the realization of policy goals.
Article
Full-text available
The Australian prefabricated construction market has been developing rapidly in recent years. New prefabrication-related technologies, materials, systems and services are also emerging in the current Australian market. Although some studies have been undertaken to explore the benefits and challenges of implementing prefabrication in Australia over the past 15 years, they do not reflect the recent changes in the industry. Therefore, this study aims to fill this gap and identify the major changes in the current Australian prefabricated construction industry from industrial perceptions. Through literature reviews and industry interviews, factors reflecting major changes in the current Australian prefabricated construction, including prefabrication industry development, emerging benefits and challenges, were identified and discussed in this study. The challenges identified from interviews were classified into eight aspects related to feasibility, design, manufacturing, transportation, on-site construction, standardisation, skills and knowledge, finance and market. Furthermore, 21 recommendations and related key responsible parties were identified to tackle these challenges. The findings will provide useful references for various stakeholders to have a better understanding of the current prefabrication industry development in the Australian context and re-think how to adapt to future changes for the uptake of prefabricated construction in Australia.
Article
Full-text available
Purpose As a strand in industrialization movement in architecture, engineering and construction (AEC) industry, prefabricated construction (PC) has gained widespread popularity due to high efficiency, energy saving, low environmental impacts, safety and other advantages of PC. Well-managed supply chain can further leverage the advantages of PC. However, there is a lack of more systematically overview of the prefabricated construction supply chain (PCSC). This paper aims to comb the current status and look into the future direction of PCSC by reviewing the existing research. Design/methodology/approach In total, 131 articles related to prefabricated construction supply chain management (PCSCM) from 2000 to 2022 have been collated to (1) conduct a bibliometric analysis by using VOSviewer, including the literature sources, keywords co-occurrence, co-authorships, authorship citation and country active in the field of PCSCM; (2) classify and summarize the status of research in PCSCM through qualitative discussion and (3) point out the future research directions. Findings In total, 131 articles are carried out for bibliometric analysis and in-depth qualitative discussion, the visualization maps and the main research themes in the field of PCSCM are obtained. The results show that supply chain intelligentization and informatization are hot topics. Finally, future research directions that should be paid attention to in the field of PCSCM are pointed out. Practical implications This study can help project managers understand the current status and problems of PCSC operations and provide a basis for future management decisions. Originality/value Compared with previous studies, this study adds the dimension of “article authorship” to the quantitative analysis and discusses the research themes in the field of PCSCM in a comprehensive manner. In addition, this paper deeply discusses the main research topics from both the specific contents and research methods adopted.
Article
The construction industry is one of the three largest carbon emitting industries in the world, accounting for up to thirty percent of global greenhouse gas emissions each year. Since traditional cast-in-situ building operations significantly contribute to these emissions and cannot therefore meet green building requirements, prefabricated buildings have come in to their own as a construction method that effectively reduces carbon emissions. Although studies have been conducted in to reducing carbon emissions by using prefabricated techniques at the building construction stage, none have focused on the reduction of carbon emissions by using prefabricated instead of cast-in-situ decoration systems. This study therefore used a case study in China to evaluate the carbon reduction potential of prefabricated decoration floor systems compared with traditional cast-in-situ decoration floor systems, and to also consider the carbon reduction pathways of four different types of prefabricated floor system from the perspectives of work methods and materials. Since the case study results showed that the carbon emissions reduction of the prefabricated floor system was 69.7%, or 101.5 kg CO2e per cubic meter, it can be concluded that there is a significant carbon reduction potential for using a prefabricated decoration floor system compared with a traditional cast-in-situ decoration floor system. The key contribution of the study is that it provides valuable references for interior decoration practitioners and decision makers when considering ways to reduce carbon emissions through prefabricated decoration floor systems.
Article
Recently, sustainable development goals (SDGs) have become a global requirement, but a changing phenomenon which needs to be examined frequently and which is the focus of recent literature and regulation. Thus, the present study examines the impact of sharing economy benefits such as reasonable use of energy resources, enhanced energy resource efficiency, and reduced energy cost, based on the SDGs of the manufacturing industry in China. The study explores the role of improved energy efficiency as a mediator in the nexus of the reasonable use of energy resources, enhanced energy resource efficiency, reduced energy costs, and SDGs. The article uses the primary data collection method of questionnaires to collect data from selected respondents, the managers of the manufacturing companies. The study employs Smart-PLS to check the reliability of the items and evaluate whether the variables are associated. The results reveal that reasonable use of energy resources, enhanced energy resource efficiency, and reduced energy costs have positive links with SDGs in the manufacturing industry in China. The results show improved energy efficiency to be among the linkages of the reasonable use of energy resources, enhanced energy resource efficiency, reduced energy costs, and SDGs of the manufacturing industry in China. This study can help economists, environmental regulators, and commissions for sustainable development in designing policies to encourage the sharing economy within countries and achieve SDGs.
Article
Stakeholders' participation is an essential factor for the promotion of green building (GB) industry and various research studies have been conducted in this area. This paper visually analyzes the literatures on stakeholders’ studies of green buildings (GBs) from 2007 to 2021 with the assistance of CiteSpace, HistCite, and VOSviewer, to grasp present research hotspots and explore potential trends. 630 articles were analyzed to identify the most influential regions, institutions, authors, journals, keywords and references in the field. Cluster analysis illustrated that knowledge base focuses more on “evolutionary game”, “willingness to pay”, “occupant satisfaction”, “rehabilitation”, “AHP”, “safety risk”, “green apartments”, “stakeholder motivation”, “existing residential building” and “life cycle assessment”. Current hotspots were detected through citation analysis, including: (1) risks, drivers and obstacles of GB stakeholders, (2) occupants' satisfaction and willingness to pay for GBs, and (3) decision-making process of GB stakeholders. Future research directions are proposed as (1) extending studies to cover all GB stakeholders, (2) more emphasis shift to operation and demolition stages, (3) more investigation on green commercial buildings, and (4) more studies on innovative research methods. The findings in this paper would provide more valuable information for researchers and practitioners interested in this area.