ArticlePDF Available

Critique on a Sugar Tax Policy

Authors:

Abstract

This article discusses the proposal and responses to sugar taxation, as well as techniques for reducing sugar-sweetened beverage (SSB) consumption. Leveraging the theory of changes, implementing a sugar tax is demonstrated to lower SSB consumption, particularly among low-income groups, so that improving public health. This interpretation is supported by evidence from Mexico, Chile, and the United Kingdom following the imposition of a sugar tax. This article also assesses unexpected outcomes in Berkeley and Mexico following the implementation of sugar taxes, providing insight into the efficacy of these policies. Future strategies to reducing the consumption of sugar have been proposed with a focus on the significance of public health measures other than taxation.
Critique on a Sugar Tax Policy
Xiaowen Dou1,a,*
1Department of Food Science and Nutrition, The Hong Kong Polytechnic University, Hong Kong,
Hong Kong SAR, China
a. xiaowen.dou@connect.polyu.hk
*corresponding author
Abstract: This article discusses the proposal and responses to sugar taxation, as well as
techniques for reducing sugar-sweetened beverage (SSB) consumption. Leveraging the
theory of changes, implementing a sugar tax is demonstrated to lower SSB consumption,
particularly among low-income groups, so that improving public health. This interpretation
is supported by evidence from Mexico, Chile, and the United Kingdom following the
imposition of a sugar tax. This article also assesses unexpected outcomes in Berkeley and
Mexico following the implementation of sugar taxes, providing insight into the efficacy of
these policies. Future strategies to reducing the consumption of sugar have been proposed
with a focus on the significance of public health measures other than taxation.
Keywords: Sugar Taxation, Sugar-Sweetened Beverages, Public Health Intervention, Policy
Analysis
1. Introduction
Sugar-sweetened beverages (SSBs) are drinks with caloric sweeteners [1] that may lead to various
diseases and there is evidence suggests the necessity for upstream policy actions [2]. The issue of
sugar consumption and its impact on public health has been a topic of significant debate in recent
years. Sugar-sweetened beverages (SSBs) are known to contribute to various health issues such as
obesity, type 2 diabetes, and cardiovascular disease. In response to this growing concern, many
countries have implemented sugar tax policies as a means of reducing SSB consumption and
improving public health outcomes. This paper aims to provide a comprehensive analysis of the
proposal and responses to sugar taxation, as well as explore the effectiveness of these policies in
different contexts. The paper will first discuss the theory of changes proposed by Hawkes et al., which
suggests that the implementation of a sugar tax can lead to a decline in SSB consumption, particularly
among low-income groups. This theory will be supported by evidence from countries such as Mexico,
Chile, and the United Kingdom, where sugar taxes have been successfully implemented. The paper
will also assess unexpected outcomes in Berkeley and Mexico following the introduction of sugar
taxes, providing insight into the efficacy of these policies. Furthermore, the paper will examine the
various arguments for and against sugar taxes, exploring their potential impact on consumer behavior,
pricing strategies, and public health outcomes. By analyzing the experiences of different countries
with sugar taxation, the paper aims to provide valuable insights into the effectiveness of these policies
as a public health intervention.
Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Management Research and Economic Development
DOI: 10.54254/2754-1169/87/20241008
© 2024 The Authors. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License 4.0
(https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
238
2. Summary
According to the theory of changes proposed by Hawkes, Corinna, et al., the implementation of sugar
tax will result in a decline in SSBs consumption, especially among low-income groups. Therefore,
the sugar tax will provide new vitality on public health. This report utilizes variations in SSB in
Mexico, Chile and the UK following the enactment of sugar taxes as support. Then assesses the
unexpected outcomes of Berkeley and Mexico's introduction of sugar taxes. Also, evaluates the
effectiveness of sugar taxes while showing the author's concepts and suggestions.
3. Critique
3.1. Theory of Changes
Producers and distributors are forced to make decisions by an implemented sugar tax policy [3]:
specifications remain unchanged while prices increase, or prices remain unchanged while
specifications shrink. In either case, part of the impact of the policy is indirectly passed on through
producers to consumers. Therefore, high prices tempt people to forgo the beverages they might
otherwise choose which lowers the desire of parents (families) and teachers (schools) to buy sugary
drinks. Caregivers and parents potentially exert a major impact on children’s food preferences
through the foods they offer, which may promote the formation of wholesome eating habits.
Information like advertising, media and education can also affect consumer food preferences. As
brand preferences can last over time and space, so the implementation of the sugar tax policy has
altered the environment in which individuals acquire information and encouraged them to switch
from costly sugary drinks to cheaper drinks with no/less added sugar. Therefore, the implementation
of the sugar tax policy is particularly apparent and effective for individuals to change the long-term
behavior on SSBs consumption. Sugar taxes influence the processes in the food system, such as
production, processing, distribution and marketing, which result in higher costs for consumers, so
people with low incomes are more likely to alter their purchasing habits in reaction to sugar taxes. In
conclusion, sugar taxes directly raise the cost of consuming sugar-sweetened beverages, affecting the
costs, presentation(choice architecture) and availability of SSBs, then indirectly encourage consumers
to reassess and cut back on SSB consumption by looking for sugar-free or low-sugar substitutes.
These modify their eating habits, improve BMI and health status, which then reinforce consumers'
affirmation of their purchase behavior, triggering systemic dynamic positive feedback in the food
system. As a result, manufacturers take steps to reduce their sugar content by reformulation, and thus
to promote the development of the public health system.
3.2. Make the case for sugar taxes
High sugar consumption raises the risk of a number of diseases or health issues, including obesity,
tooth decay, type 2 diabetes [4] and cardiovascular disease [1]. So SSB through taxing has been
advocated as a public health intervention to lower calorie intake and population weight, address the
rising burden of obesity and diabetes [5] as well as improve diets and prevent noncommunicable
diseases [6].
3.3. Cases of implementing the sugar taxes
3.3.1. Mexico
The Mexican government placed the SSB tax on all sugar-added beverages in January 2014, which
resulted in a 10% increase in shelf-price. A study used purchasing data to estimate that the levy caused
an average 6.1% decrease in SSB consumption [7]. The evidence of Mexico indicates that taxes are
Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Management Research and Economic Development
DOI: 10.54254/2754-1169/87/20241008
239
effective at reducing SSBs consumption and resulting in significant reductions in weight and diabetes
[5].
3.3.2. Chile
An observational study conducted by Nakamura et al. found that, although the tax incentive is
relatively modest, there is evidence that purchasing of SSBs with higher sugar contents has decreased
among upper socioeconomic segments of the population [8].
3.3.3. The UK
The enactment of a sugar tax of the SSBs in 2018, having a banding structure [9]. The impact of the
policy intervention is probably greatest on those who are segments classified as less affluent as they
tend to be more sensitive to price and are limiting their expenditures of SSBs to a larger extent than
more wealthy consumers [10].
3.4. Against the sugar taxes
3.4.1. Cases of Berkeley, California and Mexico
The demand curve in Berkeley would be more elastic if cross-border shopping could be used to avoid
a city-level tax [11]. Although SSB sales decreased in Berkeley, they grew in the surrounding area,
indicating that taxes can increase consumption outside of the taxed district where goods are less
expensive [12].
Another factor is the passing-through of taxes on SSBs to retail prices. Berkeley merchants may
pass on less of the tax to consumers out of a concern of losing sales. However, research conducted
within Mexico compared pricing before and after the tax and found that it was overshifted a 9%
tax increased caloric beverage prices by 12% [13].
3.5. Effectiveness
The consumer's substitution choices and consumption are affected by the decisions and actions of
the producers and the government, which mutually determine the effectiveness of sugar taxes.
Overwhelming data indicated that sugar taxes are an effective strategy for decreasing the general
consumption of SSBs [14]. SSB taxation might be more effective at inducing behavioral changes in
adults, according to accumulating data. Furthermore, sugar taxes are sometimes criticized as being
regressive, disproportionately affecting low-income people, therefore consumers in lower
socioeconomic brackets typically benefit more from SSB taxation in terms of their health [14].
4. Conclusion
In conclusion, the implementation of sugar tax policies has shown promising results in reducing SSB
consumption and improving public health outcomes in various countries. The SSB tax is anticipated
to have two effects: to stimulate industry reformulation, thereby decreasing the amount of sugar in
the beverages supply, and to motivate consumers to buy less of these drinks [12]. The theory of
changes proposed by Hawkes et al. has provided a valuable framework for understanding how sugar
taxes can influence consumer behavior and ultimately lead to healthier dietary choices as SSB
consumers reported making fewer deliberate attempts to eat healthily than non-SSB consumers,
which raises significant concerns about the efficacy of soft intervention strategies like depending
solely on industry self-regulation [15].
Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Management Research and Economic Development
DOI: 10.54254/2754-1169/87/20241008
240
Evidence from Mexico, Chile, and the United Kingdom supports the effectiveness of sugar taxes
in reducing SSB consumption and addressing the growing burden of obesity and diabetes. While there
are some challenges and criticisms associated with sugar taxes, such as potential cross-border
shopping and passing through of taxes to retail prices, the overall impact of these policies on public
health has been positive. Additionally, a sugar tax is merely one potential element of a public strategy
to lower overall sugar consumption. Information which would encourage parents and individual
consumers to choose more healthful beverages might come first. It need a front-of-pack labeling
system for SSBs that is easily visible and understandable by consumers for all SSB kinds. Also, there
should be more campaigns to educate children and their parents about the accumulated and possibly
irreversible health hazards associated with consuming excessively sugar [4]. Moving forward, it is
important to continue exploring alternative strategies for reducing sugar consumption and promoting
healthy diets, while also considering the potential unintended consequences of sugar tax policies. By
leveraging the lessons learned from different countries' experiences with sugar taxation, policymakers
can develop more effective and sustainable interventions to improve public health outcomes and
combat the global epidemic of diet-related diseases.
References
[1] Allcott, H., Lockwood, B. B., & Taubinsky, D. (2019). Should we tax sugar-sweetened beverages? an overview of
theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 33(3), 202-227. doi:10.1257/jep.33.3.202
[2] Buckton, C. H., Fergie, G., Leifeld, P., & Hilton, S. (2019). A discourse network analysis of UK newspaper coverage
of the “Sugar Tax” debate before and after the announcement of the Soft Drinks Industry levy. BMC Public Health,
19(1). doi:10.1186/s12889-019-6799-9
[3] Hawkes, C., Smith, T. G., Jewell, J., Wardle, J., Hammond, R. A., Friel, S., . . . Kain, J. (2015). Smart Food Policies
for obesity prevention. The Lancet, 385(9985), 2410-2421. doi:10.1016/s0140-6736(14)61745-1
[4] Lloyd, P., & MacLaren, D. (2018). Should we tax sugar and if so how? Australian Economic Review, 52(1), 19-40.
doi:10.1111/1467-8462.12299
[5] Barrientos-Gutierrez, T., Zepeda-Tello, R., Rodrigues, E. R., Colchero-Aragonés, A., Rojas-Martínez, R., Lazcano-
Ponce, E., . . . Meza, R. (2017). Expected population weight and diabetes impact of the 1-peso-per-litre tax to sugar
sweetened beverages in Mexico. PLOS ONE, 12(5). doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0176336
[6] Thow, A. M., Downs, S. M., Mayes, C., Trevena, H., Waqanivalu, T., & Cawley, J. (2018). Fiscal policy to improve
diets and prevent noncommunicable diseases: From recommendations to action. Bulletin of the World Health
Organization, 96(3), 201-210. doi:10.2471/blt.17.195982
[7] Colchero, M. A., Popkin, B. M., Rivera, J. A., & Ng, S. W. (2016). Beverage purchases from stores in Mexico under
the excise tax on sugar sweetened beverages: Observational study. BMJ. doi:10.1136/bmj.h6704
[8] Nakamura, R., Mirelman, A. J., Cuadrado, C., Silva-Illanes, N., Dunstan, J., & Suhrcke, M. (2018). Evaluating the
2014 sugar-sweetened beverage tax in Chile: An observational study in urban areas. PLOS Medicine, 15(7).
doi:10.1371/journal.pmed.1002596
[9] Jones, C. M. (2016). The UK sugar tax a healthy start? British Dental Journal, 221(2), 59-60.
doi:10.1038/sj.bdj.2016.522
[10] Fearne, A., Borzino, N., De La Iglesia, B., Moffatt, P., & Robbins, M. (2021). Using supermarket loyalty card
data to measure the differential impact of the UK soft drink sugar tax on buyer behaviour. Journal of Agricultural
Economics, 73(2), 321-337. doi:10.1111/1477-9552.12462
[11] Cawley, J., & Frisvold, D. E. (2016). The pass-through of taxes on sugar-sweetened beverages to retail prices: The
case of Berkeley, California. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 36(2), 303-326. doi:10.1002/pam.21960
[12] liz, C., Maslen, H., Essman, M., Taillie, L. S., & Savulescu, J. (2019). Sugar, taxes, & choice. Hastings Center
Report, 49(6), 22-31. doi:10.1002/hast.1067
[13] Harding, M., & Lovenheim, M. (2017). The effect of prices on nutrition: Comparing the impact of product- and
nutrient-specific taxes. Journal of Health Economics, 53, 53-71. doi:10.1016/j.jhealeco.2017.02.003
[14] Claudy, M., Doyle, G., Marriott, L., Campbell, N., & O’Malley, G. (2020). Are sugar-sweetened beverage taxes
effective? reviewing the evidence through a marketing systems lens. Journal of Public Policy & Marketing, 40(3),
403-418. doi:10.1177/0743915620965153
[15] Robertson, K., Thyne, M., & Green, J. A. (2018). Supporting a sugar tax in New Zealand: Sugar sweetened beverage
(‘fizzy drink’) consumption as a normal behaviour within the obesogenic environment. PeerJ, 6.
doi:10.7717/peerj.5821
Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Management Research and Economic Development
DOI: 10.54254/2754-1169/87/20241008
241
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
This paper explores the impact of the soft drinks sugar tax introduced in the UK in 2018 on the purchasing behaviours of different geo‐demographic consumer segments. We analyse data for a composite good comprising the most popular sugar‐sweetened drinks (SSDs) using loyalty card data from one of the UK’s largest supermarkets. We use pre‐levy data to predict the effect of the tax and corroborate our predictions by analysing actual consumption of the composite good in the first 5 months post‐levy. The results show that the impact of the sugar tax is likely to have the desired effect of reducing the purchase of SSDs. Moreover, though the impact of the tax is likely to vary across different geo‐demographic segments, the evidence suggests that its impact is likely to be greatest on the most vulnerable market segments – families on low incomes – who are among the highest consumers of SSDs in the UK.
Article
Full-text available
The overconsumption of sugar-sweetened beverages (SSBs) is associated with non-communicable diseases such as obesity, type 2 diabetes and cancer. While voluntary industry codes have largely failed to curb the overconsumption of sugar, governments globally are increasingly willing to impose taxes on SSBs. Yet effectiveness of SSB taxation varies significantly. Based on a systematic review of the most recent literature ( N=79), we find that heterogeneity in outcomes is likely to result from idiosyncratic conditions within marketing systems. Building on marketing systems theory, we identify and critically evaluate (omitted) factors within the marketing environment that impact the effectiveness of SSB taxation. Findings reveal that most studies to date focus on demand-side issues, often omitting supply-side responses such as reformulation or pass-through rates. Furthermore, studies largely disregard evidence from marketing and behavioral sciences which shows that taxation works through psychological mechanisms other than price. Finally, we find that few studies have systematically evaluated the complementary effects of SSB taxation and other health-promoting policies. By highlighting these blind spots in current knowledge of SSB taxation, we provide fruitful avenues for future research at the nexus of marketing and public policy.
Article
Full-text available
Population obesity and associated morbidities pose significant public health and economic burdens in the United Kingdom, United States, and globally. As a response, public health initiatives often seek to change individuals’ unhealthy behavior, with the dual aims of improving their health and conserving health care resources. One such initiative—taxes on sugar‐sweetened beverages—has sparked considerable ethical debate. Prominent in the debate are arguments seeking to demonstrate the supposed impermissibility of SSB taxes and similar policies on the grounds that they interfere with individuals’ freedom and autonomy. Commentators have often assumed that a policy intended to restrict or change private individuals’ consumption behavior will necessarily curtail freedom and, as a corollary, will undermine individuals’ autonomy with respect to their consumption choices. Yet this assumption involves a conceptual mistake. To address the misunderstanding, it’s necessary to attend to the differences between negative liberty, freedom of options, and autonomy. Ultimately, concerns about negative liberty, freedom, and autonomy do not provide strong grounds for opposing SSB taxes.
Article
Full-text available
Background: On 6th April 2018, the UK Government introduced the Soft Drinks Industry Levy (SDIL) as a mechanism designed to address increasing prevalence of obesity and associated ill health by reducing sugar consumption. Given that the successful introduction of upstream food and nutrition policies is a highly political enterprise involving multiple interested parties, understanding the complex network of stakeholders seeking to influence such policy decisions is imperative. Methods: Media content analysis was used to build a dataset of relevant newspaper articles, which were analysed to identify stakeholder agreement or disagreement with defined concept statements. We used discourse network analysis to produce visual representations of the network of stakeholders and coalitions evident in the debate as it was presented in UK newspapers, in the lead up to and following the announcement of the Soft Drinks Industry Levy in the UK, from May 2015 to November 2016. Results: Coding identified 3883 statements made by 214 individuals from 176 organisations, relating to 47 concepts. Network visualisations revealed a complex network of stakeholders with clear sceptical and supportive coalitions. Industry stakeholders appeared less united in the network than anticipated, particularly before the SDIL announcement. Some key industry actors appeared in the supportive coalition, possibly due to the use of corporate social responsibility rhetoric. Jamie Oliver appeared as a dominant stakeholder, firmly embedded with public health advocates. Conclusion: This study highlights the complexity of the network of stakeholders involved in the public debate on food policies such as sugar tax and the SDIL. Polarisation of stakeholders arose from differences in ideology, focus on a specific policy and statements about the weight of evidence. Vocal celebrity policy entrepreneurs may be instrumental in gaining public and policy makers’ support for future upstream regulation to promote population health, to facilitate alignment around a clear ideology.
Article
Full-text available
Background Excessive intake of sugar sweetened beverages (SSBs) is a preventable cause of death. While some countries have implemented a tax on SSBs, other countries, such as New Zealand, rely on industry self-regulation and individual responsibility, such as referring to labels, to control one’s own sugar intake from SSBs. The present study examines whether SSB consumers consciously control their diet and therefore interventions such as better labelling might be effective, or alternatively, whether SSB consumers engage in a general pattern of unhealthy eating, and in which case government regulation would be advisable. Aim To explore self-reported dietary consumption and conscious healthy eating behaviours of New Zealand consumers who had consumed SSBs over a 24 hour period. Method A cross-sectional survey of a representative sample of 2007 New Zealanders, measuring their food and beverage intake over a 24 hour period and self-reported intentions to eat healthily. Within this was a measurement of SSB consumption in the 24 hour period. Results Multivariable logistic regression revealed that compared to non-SSB consumers, SSB consumers were more likely to have eaten the following: confectionery; fast food; pre-prepared food; biscuits, cakes or pastries; takeaways; ice-cream/dessert. SSB consumption was also associated with a lower likelihood of referring to food labels, less conscious effort to eat healthily, and to less likely to avoid: sugar; fat; calories; food additives; pre-prepared food. SSB consumers were also less likely to have eaten breakfast, or made a meal at home made from scratch. Conclusion SSB consumers were more likely than non-SSB consumers to demonstrate a general pattern of unhealthy eating and were less likely to report consciously controlling their diet. The findings raise significant concerns regarding the efficacy of individual and industry self-regulation and lend support to stronger government targeted interventions.
Article
Full-text available
This article reviews empirical studies of proposals to tax sugary products in Australia. A corrective tax must be designed carefully if it is to increase national welfare. There is an underlying problem in designing such a tax because consumers are heterogeneous. The best choice of goods to be taxed is the group of sugar‐sweetened‐beverages, the best tax base is the sugar content and the best tax form is a progressive specific tax with two or more levels. We recommend initial rates that are equal to those of the UK tax on SSBs.
Article
Full-text available
Background In October 2014, Chile implemented a tax modification on sugar-sweetened beverages (SSBs) called the Impuesto Adicional a las Bebidas Analcohólicas (IABA). The design of the tax was unique, increasing the tax on soft drinks above 6.25 grams of added sugar per 100 mL and decreasing the tax for those below this threshold. Methods and findings This study evaluates Chile’s SSB tax, which was announced in March 2014 and implemented in October 2014. We used household-level grocery-purchasing data from 2011 to 2015 for 2,836 households living in cities representative of the urban population of Chile. We employed a fixed-effects econometric approach and estimated the before–after change in purchasing of SSBs controlling for seasonality, general time trend, temperature, and economic fluctuations as well as time-invariant household characteristics. Results showed significant changes in purchasing for the statistically preferred model: while there was a barely significant decrease in the volume of all soft drinks, there was a highly significant decrease in the monthly purchased volume of the higher-taxed, sugary soft drinks by 21.6%. The direction of this reduction was robust to different empirical modelling approaches, but the statistical significance and the magnitude of the changes varied considerably. The reduction in soft drink purchasing was most evident amongst higher socioeconomic groups and higher pretax purchasers of sugary soft drinks. There was no systematic, robust pattern in the estimates by household obesity status. After tax implementation, the purchase prices of soft drinks decreased for the items for which the tax rate was reduced, but they remained unchanged for sugary items, for which the tax was increased. However, the purchase prices increased for sugary soft drinks at the time of the policy announcement. The main limitations include a lack of a randomised design, limiting the extent of causal inference possible, and the focus on purchasing data rather than consumption or health outcomes. Conclusions The results of subgroup analyses suggest that the policy may have been partially effective, though not necessarily in ways that are likely to reduce socioeconomic inequalities in diet-related health. It remains unclear whether the policy has had a major, overall population-level impact. Additionally, because the present study examined purchasing of soft drinks for only 1 year, a longer-term evaluation—ideally including an assessment of consumption and health impacts—should be conducted in future research. Trial registration ClinicalTrials.gov Identifier: NCT02926001
Article
Full-text available
The World Health Organization has recommended that Member States consider taxing energy-dense beverages and foods and/ or subsidizing nutrient-rich foods to improve diets and prevent noncommunicable diseases. Numerous countries have either implemented taxes on energy-dense beverages and foods or are considering the implementation of such taxes. However, several major challenges to the implementation of fiscal policies to improve diets and prevent noncommunicable diseases remain. Some of these challenges relate to the cross-sectoral nature of the relevant interventions. For example, as health and economic policy-makers have different administrative concerns, performance indicators and priorities, they often consider different forms of evidence in their decision-making. In this paper, we describe the evidence base for diet-related interventions based on fiscal policies and consider the key questions that need to be asked by both health and economic policy-makers. From the health sector’s perspective, there is most evidence for the impact of taxes and subsidies on diets, with less evidence on their impacts on body weight or health. We highlight the importance of scope, the role of industry, the use of revenue and regressive taxes in informing policy decisions.
Article
Full-text available
Study question What effect on body mass index, obesity and diabetes can we expect from the 1-peso-per-litre tax to sugar sweetened beverages in Mexico? Methods Using recently published estimates of the reductions in beverage purchases due to the tax, we modelled its expected long-term impacts on body mass index (BMI), obesity and diabetes. Microsimulations based on a nationally representative dataset were used to estimate the impact of the tax on BMI and obesity. A Markov population model, built upon an age-period-cohort model of diabetes incidence, was used to estimate the impact on diagnosed diabetes in Mexico. To analyse the potential of tax increases we also modelled a 2-peso-per-litre tax scenario. Study answer and limitations Ten years after the implementation of the tax, we expect an average reduction of 0.15 kg/m² per person, which translates into a 2.54% reduction in obesity prevalence. People in the lowest level of socioeconomic status and those between 20 and 35 years of age showed the largest reductions in BMI and overweight and obesity prevalence. Simulations show that by 2030, under the current implementation of 1-peso-per-litre, the tax would prevent 86 to 134 thousand cases of diabetes. Overall, the 2-peso-per-litre scenario is expected to produce twice as much of a reduction. These estimates assume the tax effect on consumption remains stable over time. Sensitivity analyses were conducted to assess the robustness of findings; similar results were obtained with various parameter assumptions and alternative modelling approaches. What this study adds The sugar-sweetened beverages tax in Mexico is expected to produce sizable and sustained reductions in obesity and diabetes. Increasing the tax could produce larger benefits. While encouraging, estimates will need to be updated once data on direct changes in consumption becomes available.
Article
Taxes on sugar-sweetened beverages are growing in popularity and have generated an active public debate. Are they a good idea? If so, how high should they be? Are such taxes regressive? People in the United States and some other countries consume remarkable quantities of sugar-sweetened beverages, and the evidence suggests that this generates significant health costs. Building on recent work, we review the basic economic principles that determine the socially optimal sugar-sweetened beverage tax. The optimal tax depends on (1) externalities, or uninternalized health system costs from diseases caused by sugary drink consumption; (2) internalities, or costs consumers impose on themselves by consuming too many sugary drinks due to poor nutrition knowledge and/or lack of self-control; and (3) regressivity, or how much the financial burden and the internality benefits from the tax fall on the poor. We summarize the empirical evidence about the key parameters that determine how large the tax should be. Our calculations suggest that sugar-sweetened beverage taxes are welfare enhancing and indeed that the optimal sugar-sweetened beverage tax rate may be higher than the 1 cent per ounce rate most commonly used in US cities. We end with seven concrete suggestions for policymakers considering a sugar-sweetened beverage tax.