ArticlePDF Available

The interplay of politics and space: How elected politicians shape place-based policies and outcomes

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

This paper explores how elected politicians' decisions impact place-based policies (PBPs) and the resulting consequences. It emphasises that understanding the political factors influencing PBPs offers insights into their effectiveness and potential pitfalls. The article draws upon the behavioural political economy theory, suggesting that political decisions often deviate from the purely rational due to cognitive biases and social influences. It examines the critical role of territorial intermediation, explores the potential discord between policy designs and ground realities, and investigates how broader political dynamics shape these trajectories. Additionally, the article probes the obstacles, including psychological, institutional and contextual factors, that may hinder policy implementation. In conclusion, the article proposes new avenues of research in regional, urban and planning studies that highlight the complexity of the political processes influencing these policies and calls for a multidimensional analysis of these processes.
Content may be subject to copyright.
https://doi.org/10.1111/geoj.12591
Abstract:
This paper explores how elected policians’ decisions impact place-based policies (PBPs) and the
resulng consequences. It emphasizes that understanding the polical factors inuencing PBPs oers
insights into their eecveness and potenal pialls. The arcle draws upon the behavioural polical
economy theory, suggesng that polical decisions oen deviate from the purely raonal due to
cognive biases and social inuences. It examines the crical role of territorial intermediaon, explores
the potenal discord between policy designs and ground realies, and invesgates how broader polical
dynamics shape these trajectories. Addionally, the arcle probes the obstacles, including psychological,
instuonal and contextual factors, that may hinder policy implementaon. In conclusion, the arcle
proposes new avenues of research in regional, urban and planning studies that highlight the complexity
of the polical processes inuencing these policies and call for a muldimensional analysis of these
processes.
Key words: polical economy; place-based policies; NIMEY; territorial intermediaon; polics
JEL: P00; O38, R38
1. Introducon
Place-based policies (PBPs) have emerged as pivotal tools for policymakers seeking economic
development and spaal jusce in diverse territorial contexts (Barca et al., 2012; Glaeser & Golieb,
2008). These policies, designed to address the unique potenal and challenges of specic areas (Pike et
al., 2007), can range from boosng local businesses through nancial incenves (Neumark & Simpson,
2015; Rodríguez-Pose et al., 2022), to urban regeneraon (Galster, 2010) and infrastructure
enhancement (Heres et al., 2014; Vasilakos et al., 2023). Their place-centered approach disnguishes
them from uniform ‘space-blind’ strategies, reecng a commitment to tailored, local soluons (Barca
et al., 2012; Bachtler, 2019). In aiming for spaal jusce, PBPs aempt to balance regional disparies
and local agglomeraon eects (Soja, 2010; Neumark & Simpson, 2015; Weck et al., 2022). They
underscore the imperave of equitable resource distribuon across regions (Fainstein, 2009), evolving
beyond mere economic objecves to recfying spaal inequalies and ensuring a more balanced
development landscape (Brenner et al., 2012; Ausn et al., 2018; Ehrlich & Overman, 2020).
The applicaon of polical economy, which broadly encompasses the study of the inuence of polical
forces on the shaping of economic policies and outcomes, provides a valuable perspecve for analysing
the formaon and implicaons of these PBPs (Bardhan, 1997; Ehrlich & Seidel, 2018). Over the years,
considerable research eorts have been devoted to understanding the eciency of PBPs through
rigorous impact analyses (Kline and More, 2014a, 2014b; Neumark and Simpson, 2015; Brachert et
al., 2019). Scholars have also sought to unravel the complex movaons and mechanisms that underpin
the implementaon of these policies (Rodríguez-Pose, 2013; Do, 2016; Morisson & Doussineau, 2019;
Duranton & Venables, 2021). Nonetheless, a comprehensive exploraon of the interplay between
polical economy and local polics deserves to be undertaken. Such an exercise could deepen our
understanding of how the entwined polical and economic forces shape regional development
strategies and outcomes.
In this context, it is essenal to further explore the polical economy of local policies by examining the
role of polical processes in shaping these policies and the consequences that ow from them. This
paper seeks to answer the following queson: How are PBPs inuenced by the decisions of elected
policians, and what are the consequences? This paper takes a reecve approach, providing a synthesis
of the explanatory factors relang to polics in the literature. It further suggests underexplored avenues
for future research. Drawing on literature from both polical economy and regional science, we argue
that a deeper understanding of the polical factors inuencing PBPs can provide fresh insights into their
eecveness and potenal drawbacks. The polical economy’s intersecon with PBPs invites novel
research into how spaal inequality and regional economic disparies inuence polical decision-
making (Rodríguez-Pose, 2018; Ehrlich & Overman, 2020). From this perspecve, this arcle proposes a
muldimensional analysis that underlines the complexies and potenal future direcons for
understanding the polical processes that inuence PBPs.
In this paper, we begin with an introducon on how behavioural polical economy theory can help to
understand the decisions of elected policians. Then we propose a discussion on the role of territorial
intermediaon in facilitang the implementaon of PBPs. Conversely, we explore how elected policians
can hinder the implementaon of these policies. Finally, we conclude with a reecon on avenues for
future research.
2. Seng the scene: behavioural polical economy theory and place-based
policies
To beer understand place-based policies in the light of behavioural polical economy theory, it is
necessary to consider both internal dynamics, such as individual preferences and interacons between
various actors, and external inuences, such as cultural and spaal characteriscs, in order to eecvely
evaluate policies and their impacts. This allows us to highlight the challenges inherent in implemenng
and evaluang PBPs, and the diversity of factors that inuence policy decisions and outcomes. It is
necessary to also consider the role of instuons as mediators between the internal and external
dynamics that inuence the formulaon and impact of these policies.
2.1. The factors inuencing decision-making of elected policians
Jonas & Ward (2007) are among the pioneers who highlighted the role of polical and economic elites
and how their behaviors inuence the governance and structure of urban regions. In their paper, they
emphasize how elected policians shape cies through successive policies implemented. Drawing from
raonal choice theory (Downs, 1957), they suggest that it is individual preferences that have led to the
current urban situaon. Our arcle is in line with their work. For this, we lean on the behavioural polical
economy (Schnellenbach & Schubert, 2015), a theory that is tradionally used in polical economy to
explain polical behaviours in terms of policy making and polical arrangements (Olson, 1965; Shepsle
& Bonchek, 1997). At its core, behavioural polical economy seeks to integrate insights from behavioural
economics into the study of polical decision-making. Unlike classical polical economy, which assumes
that polical actors are fully raonal, and act based on straighorward ulity maximizaon, behavioural
polical economy recognizes that policians oen deviate from this raonal model due to cognive
biases, heuriscs, and social inuences.
From this point of view, Lee’s study (2017) is enlightening because it highlights the signicant impact
that personality traits and psychological disposions (such as openness to experience, neurocism,
extraversion, agreeableness, and conscienousness) have on patenng acvity and contribute to
regional innovaon paerns. Lee suggests that individual preferences, oen inuenced by cognive
biases and social pressures, play a crucial role in shaping policies that promote or hinder innovaon
within regions. This perspecve aligns with our thinking in behavioral polical economy as it emphasizes
the need to move beyond the classical view of polical actors as purely raonal. By drawing on this
approach, we can beer understand how place-based policies are conceptualized, negoated, and
implemented, while recognizing the pivotal role of individual and collecve characteriscs in regional
development dynamics. From this perspecve, Lee’s study can help us beer understand how cognive
biases and social inuences shape the decision-making of elected policians.
The choices made by elected policians are also based on social inuences, resulng from interacons
between various stakeholders involved in the formulaon of place-based policies. Indeed, the processes
of decision-making and policy formulaon are complex and involve a multude of actors beyond elected
policians. While elected policians occupy prominent and visible posions in the nal decision-making
(Mansbridge, 1990), they do not make decisions in isolaon (Alesina and Rodrik, 1994; Partridge et al.,
2015; Beer et al., 2020). Contemporary place leadership studies emphasize that the eecveness of
PBPs is not solely rooted in the formal processes of governance but is intrinsically ed to the intricate
web of relaonships between actors within specic regions (Collinge & Gibney, 2010; Beer et al., 2019).
Such leadership emerges not just from governmental structures but also from the community, private
sectors, and inuenal individuals who act as agents of change, somemes even against the tradional
status quo (OECD, 2009; Gray, 1991; Sotarauta et al., 2017). This perspecve underscores the
importance of ‘framing’ and the role it plays in facilitang or inhibing regional transformaons
(Sotarauta, 2016; Sotarauta & Beer, 2017).
PBPs are oen embedded within a complex web of polical, economic and social inuences that can
signicantly shape policy outcomes (Sotarauta, 2009; Tomaney, 2010; Shenoy, 2018). The policy-making
ecosystem of PBPs oen encompasses elected policians, sectoral experts, economic and commercial
actors, interest groups, unions, as well as third-sector and volunteer organizaons (Barca, 2019). These
enes play diverse roles, ranging from consultaon to direct inuence, from allocaon of resources
and benets to the actual implementaon of policies. In the decision-making framework, elected
policians oen negoate among various stakeholders to arrive at consensual policies (Heernan,
2002). We posit that, by virtue of their democrac legimacy, elected policians hold posions that not
only allow them to make choices with a tangible inuence (posive or negave) on policy orientaon
and formulaon, but also that their individual preferences play a pivotal role in the design and
implementaon of place-based policies. As a testament to their unique leadership posion with formally
constuted power (Sotarauta, 2009), these elected policians frequently emerge as primary agents of
transformave leadership within regional development dynamics.
Alongside analyzing the polical and social dynamics that underlie PBPs, it is crucial to acknowledge the
impact of spaal and environmental factors on the behavior of individuals within these contexts. Eveline
S. van Leeuwen (2020) provides an insighul perspecve on this maer, advocang for disnguishing
between the relave eects of spaal composional and contextual factors on the environmental
behavior of cizens in urban and rural areas. Van Leeuwen suggests that the clustering of individuals
with similar proles in specic areas, as well as external social and environmental factors, can explain
regional variaons in pro-environmental behavior. This approach highlights the fact that pro-
environmental values or atudes do not always translate into expected behavior, revealing a behavioral
‘gap’. Similarly, when applied to elected policians, we incorporate this perspecve to underscore how
spaal and environmental factors can inuence their implementaon of PBPs.
When considering the external factors that inuence decision-making by elected policians, the work
by Robert Huggins and Piers Thompson (2015) on place-based development and culture is a signicant
contribuon. Their study conceptualizes and operaonalizes a framework for place-based culture,
examining the relaonship between economic culture and local community culture. They highlight the
presence of place-based culture and emphasize how these cultures interact in shaping the development
trajectories of regions and localies. The authors demonstrate that cultural characteriscs vary
signicantly between Welsh regions and localies, but disnguishing between community culture and
economic culture is challenging because each reinforces the characteriscs of the other. Therefore,
taking local culture into account is an addional factor that can inuence the behavior of policy-makers.
2.2. Instuons as a mediator of the factors inuencing decision-making
When examining place-based policies from the perspecve of behavioral polical economy, it is essenal
to acknowledge the crucial role that instuons play in mediang between the internal and external
dynamics that aect the formulaon and impact of these policies (Raco & Flint, 2001; Barca et al., 2012).
Instuons not only act as guardians of the norms and regulaons that guide the decisions of elected
policians but also are shaped by these same interacons. The decisions made by instuons are
grounded in specic instuonal contexts that, in turn, inuence the available opons and strategies
adopted by elected policians. By viewing instuons as acve parcipants in the polical decision-
making process rather than stac enes, we recognize that place-based policies are the result of an
ongoing balance between individual preferences, external factors, and exisng regulatory frameworks.
Thus, by applying instuonal theory to regional development issues, we can gain insight into how
organizaonal structures and norms impact the formulaon and implementaon of policies. From this
perspecve, the work of Andrés Rodríguez-Pose (2013 & 2020) oers an interesng insight into this
queson. He argues that the quality and adaptability of local instuons are crucial for economic
development and the outcomes of regional development policies. Rodríguez-Pose’s argument, that
development strategies tailored to the specic instuonal environments of dierent regions are likely
to produce beer results, aligns with the recognion in behavioral polical economy of the interacon
between the choices of polical actors and the local context. Furthermore, the authors emphasis on
the instuonal dimension as a key factor in regional development eorts corresponds to our strategy
of highlighng the signicant role played by elected policians in shaping urban and regional policies.
Frank Moulaert, Bob Jessop, and Abid Mehmood (2016) also emphasize the interacon between human
agency, structural constraints and opportunies, organized norms and pracces, and the creaon of
shared meaning and signicance in the implementaon of local and regional policies. Therefore, the
authors explain how the relaonship between structure and agency creates both possibilies and
limitaons for acon, such as rounes, organizaonal pracces, convenons, and rules, that both
maintain and transform the instuons themselves. Thus, polical acon is seen as an intervenon
within a complex network of structural constraints and opportunies, guided or hindered by instuons
that are themselves shaped and reshaped by collecve and individual agency.
Finally, studies in polical geography and polical analysis have also shown how instuonal frameworks,
such as electoral systems, forms of local and regional governance, and mechanisms of public
parcipaon, shape polical decisions and public policy outcomes. For example, Aboal (2020) bridges
the gap between literature on the eects of electoral systems on public policy and the eects of public
policy on economic growth. Mansuri & Rao (2012) demonstrate how parcipatory processes with the
populaon inuence the way elected policians implement their policies locally. Pike et al (2007) explore
how regional development strategies are designed and implemented within dierent instuonal
frameworks, and how they aim to respond to specic territorial challenges. Thus, by integrang these
dimensions, our analysis not only recognizes the acve role of instuons in the polical decision-
making process but also broadens our understanding of territorial development dynamics, illustrang
the importance of governance in the design and implementaon of regionaal and local policies tailored
to the specicies of each territory (Torre, 2023).
3. When policians facilitate the implementaon of place-based policies
In this secon secon, we propose to analyse how elected policians can encourage the implementaon
of PBPs by mobilising the concept of territorial intermediaon. Understanding the development of PBPs
through the lens of behavioral polical economy brings to light the importance of territorial
intermediaon. This perspecve emphasizes how individual and group behaviors, movated by various
socio-polical factors, shape policy outcomes by brokering, networking, facilitang.
3.1. Elected policians as territorial intermediaries
The development of PBPs is a process that engages various stakeholders at mulple levels of governance.
The interplay and collaboraon among these enes are pivotal not only in the planning but also in the
implementaon and management of these programmes. However, aligning the interests and eorts of
these dierent stakeholders poses a signicant challenge. From this perspecve, local elected policians
are oen viewed as intermediaries who act as brokers and facilitate the deployment of PBPs. By
examining territorial intermediaon in light of behavioral polical economy, one can decode the
underlying movaons and behaviors that drive these intermediaon processes. In this secon, we
provide a denion of territorial intermediaon and the various forms it can take before proposing
territorial intermediaon as an analycal framework for examining the role of elected policians in
facilitang the design and execuon of PBPs.
The concept of intermediaon has been widely studied in management science and generally refers to
the process of acng as a link or facilitator between two pares who are not directly in a relaonship
(Howells, 2006). Applied to regional, urban and planning studies, territorial intermediaon refers to the
role played by certain enes or individuals in facilitang communicaon, collaboraon and interacon
between dierent actors in the same territory (horizontal territorial intermediaon) or evolving at
dierent scales (vercal territorial intermediaon) in the implementaon of local projects or policies
(Bourdin et al., 2020; Wang & Bourdin, 2024). Interpreted through the behavioral polical economy, this
role is inuenced by a range of cognive biases, percepons, and individual interests that elected
policians harbor. We therefore use this conceptual framework to study the roles played by elected
policians in facilitang the deployment of PBPs.
Beer and Clower (2014) emphasize the importance of facilitave leadership, one that leverages
collaboraon, power-sharing, and trust among mulple agencies in a complex policy environment. This
is in line with their understanding that leadership is about seng visions, implemenng plans, insgang
change, adjusng strategies, and monitoring performance. From this point of view, territorial
intermediaries have to be place leaders to navigate between these dierent roles. By connecng to
Sotarauta’s descripon of “policy networks” (Sotarauta, 2010), several roles can emerge in these policy
networks, such as boundary spanners, networkers, or brokers. In a behavioral polical economy context,
these roles might be inuenced by various external factors, including electoral incenves, peer
pressures, and cognive biases. Such posions can play a pivotal role in ensuring that there’s a
harmonizaon of interests and acons among stakeholders.
Territorial intermediaries can be instuons, organisaons or individuals (such as mayors) who act as
mediators or facilitators between various stakeholders in a specic territory. They seek to establish close
links between stakeholders. The behavioral dynamics that drive these intermediaries are of keen interest
in the behavioral polical economy, given that they inuence policy outcomes. This is how the concept
of intermediaon is closely linked to that of proximity. Torre (2014) established this connecon by
menoning intermediaries who are responsible for smulang the networking of actors and who behave
in a way that gives them internal legimacy when they facilitate the emergence of local iniaves. For
example, based on a comparison between France and Quebec, Wang and Bourdin (2024) demonstrate
how the involvement of territorial intermediaries as “trusted” facilitators and mediators, contribute to
enhancing innovaon and regional compeveness through fostering exchanges and collaboraons.
Consequently, this legimacy is fundamental when establishing governance for the development of
PBPs. Elected policians have legimacy because they have been elected by the local populaon.
The formulaon of PBPs is a process that mobilises mulple stakeholders at dierent levels of
governance (Morisson & Doussineau, 2019). Synergy and collaboraon between these actors are
essenal not only in the design but also in the implementaon and management of these programmes
(Bachtler, 2019). However, harmonising the interests and acons of these dierent stakeholders is a
major challenge (Niang et al., 2022b; Torre, 2023). Conicts of interest can arise and hamper the
eecveness of local policies (Niang et al., 2022a). In line with the emphasis on the role of agency in
collaborave governance, it is thus crucial to have an actor capable of facilitang the coordinaon of the
system during all phases. Recent studies suggest that local governments can play a crucial role in
facilitang this coordinaon (Gustafsson & Mignon, 2020). For instance, Bourdin & Nadou (2020)
analyzed the role of the mayor as a key actor in implemenng biogas projects. Most of the me, these
projects encounter issues with social acceptability and the project leader requires local support. As these
authors argue, elected policians are in an ideal posion to promote the networking of stakeholders,
facilitate communicaon, share informaon, and establish support mechanisms for implemenng policy
at the local level.
In this regard, we argue that policians, driven by a desire to maximize their chances of re-elecon and
bolster their polical posion, have a pronounced incenve to collaborate with other place-leaders in
the design and implementaon of PBPs (Ayres et al., 2018). This movaon can be deeply understood
and predicted using principles from behavioral polical economy, which analyzes how policians weigh
their personal interests against broader societal goals. In pursuit of this, they engage in consultaons,
exert inuence, and negoate with various stakeholders involved in PBPs, aiming for consensual policies
(Heernan, 2002). These eorts not only serve their individual interest in re-elecon but also promote
the well-being of the local community—a broader societal benet. This viewpoint underscores the idea
that elected policians might be parcularly movated to work alongside other place-leaders (Sotarauta
et al., 2017), especially if such collaboraons align with the aspiraons and requirements of their
constuents, potenally boosng their public standing and chances of electoral success. In Portland,
Oregon, the “20-minute neighborhoods” iniave stands out as an example of place-based policy. This
iniave involves policians collaborang with community leaders to align societal benets with their
polical interests (Mackness et al., 2023). This innovave urban planning approach ensures that
residents have access to essenal services within a 20-minute walk from their homes. It promotes
sustainability, reduces car dependence, and strengthens community es. The city’s government,
including mayors and city council members, champions this policy and implements it in partnership with
urban planners, local businesses, and residents. The success of Portland in advancing the 20-minute
neighborhoods concept demonstrates the potenal for elected ocials to strategically engage with
place-based policies. This engagement can help secure electoral support while fostering urban
development strategies that priorize sustainability, health, and accessibility.
3.2. Territorial intermediaon as an analycal framework
In the context of PBPs, territorial intermediaon can provide a useful analycal framework for
understanding the processes and outcomes of policy design and implementaon. This framework can
be applied to dierent stages of PBPs. First, territorial intermediaon involves various actors who play
crucial roles in designing PBPs. As territorial intermediaries, elected policians can bring their unique
perspecves, local knowledge and understanding of the territory’s needs, helping to create policies that
are more responsive and relevant to the unique characteriscs and challenges of the place. Second, the
eecveness of PBPs oen relies on eecve coordinaon and collaboraon among various actors
(Bourdin & Nadou, 2020). Through territorial intermediaon, these actors can work together to
implement policies, mediate conicts and facilitate cooperaon. Territorial intermediaon can also
enable more eecve ‘boom-upand ‘top-down’ interacons in policy implementaon. Third, it can
contribute to the eecveness of PBPs by ensuring that they are tailored to the specic needs and
contexts of dierent places. It can also enhance policy adaptability by facilitang connuous dialogue
and negoaon among actors, allowing policies to be adjusted in response to changing circumstances
or emerging challenges (Bachtler, 2019).
Figure 1: The territorial intermediaon roles played by elected policians
Source: Author
There are three main roles that elected policians can play (Figure 1): (i) the role of ‘matchmaker’, (ii)
the role of ‘mediator’ and (iii) the role of orchestrator’. First, local elected policians can play an
essenal ‘matchmaker’ role in the deployment of territorialised policies. According to Howells (2006),
one of the main roles of intermediaon is to link the players in a network or system. In the context of
PBPs, this can involve bringing together key players, such as policymakers at dierent levels, community
organisaons, local businesses and cizens. By acng as a broker, the matchmaker facilitates the creaon
of links and exchanges between these actors, which can lead to greater cohesion and commitment in
the implementaon of PBPs (Bourdin and Nadou, 2020). As brokers (Sigler et al., 2023), intermediaries
can help bring together stakeholders who might otherwise have been isolated or overlooked in the
design of PBPs. This is parcularly important in light of recent studies on the smart specialisaon
strategy, which found that the lack of inclusion of stakeholders in the design of Smart Specialisaon
Strategy aects the implementaon and eecveness of these local policies (Estensoro & Larrea, 2016;
Capello & Kroll, 2016).
Second, the role of mediator is also essenal in the design and implementaon of territorialised policies.
According to Howells (2006) and Bakici et al. (2013), this role involves represenng one or more pares
in a transacon. For local authories, this may mean represenng the interests of local cizens or other
stakeholders in negoaons about the design and implementaon of PBPs. The role of the mediator is
also crucial for building trust, which is a determining factor in PBPs (Weck et al., 2022). Michels and De
Graaf’s (2010) work on partnerships between local governments and local communies also highlights
the essenal role of trust in the delivery of local development iniaves. They found that mutual trust
between local authories and cizens can facilitate the decision-making process and lead to more
eecve policy outcomes.
Third, as orchestrators, the role of an intermediary can further include the idencaon and integraon
of partners who are able to contribute knowledge and resources that are not available locally but are
necessary for the implementaon of PBPs (Agogué et al., 2013). In this way, local authories can idenfy
and select relevant and eecve stakeholders be they individuals, organisaons or businesses to
parcipate in the design and implementaon of PBPs. These actors can bring valuable resources, such
as specialist knowledge, technical skills, networks of contacts, nancial capital or project management
skills (Torre, 2023). The introducon of these new partners can enrich the pool of resources available to
the project, which can increase the eecveness of the implementaon of PBPs. In addion, the
orchestrator can play an important role in ensuring that the PBP implemented ts well with other
possible policies, such as sector policies. Finally, as orchestrators, local policians oen have detailed
knowledge of the resources available (tangible and intangible) and the expectaons of local
stakeholders. Therefore, they are in a beer posion to design appropriate policies.
In addion, in the context of PBPs, elected policians can play an essenal role in ensuring that resources
are allocated in a way that meets the specic needs of their regions. Elected policians have in-depth
knowledge of the challenges and opportunies facing their regions, which can enable them to design
policies and allocate resources more eecvely. Rodden’s (2002) work conrms this hypothesis, showing
that local governments are oen more eecve than central governments in allocang resources to
meet local needs.
4. When elected policians hinder the implementaon of place-based policies
Elected policians can be seen as facilitators in the implementaon of PBPs, but somemes, they can
alter their implementaon and reduce their eecveness. In this secon, we propose a theorecal
framework for pinpoinng the potenal reasons why elected policians could obstruct the formulaon
and execuon of PBPs, as well as how these explanatory factors are interconnected. Three main types
of factors are idened in this framework. These factors are all related to the behavioural polical
economy (Schnellenbach & Schubert, 2015): psychological variables, polical variables and contextual
variables. This framework takes into account the empirical ndings from an extensive literature survey,
arranging these elements and processes based on theorecal insights and incorporang components
that are theorecally inferred but have yet to be empirically examined in the context of PBPs.
4.1. Psychological variables
Among the factors that can be put forward to explain why policians are reluctant to implement a place-
based policy are intrinsic to the individual. The rst factor refers to cognive biases, i.e. the way in which
individuals perceive and interpret informaon (Ajzen, 1996; Forgas et al., 2015). Thus, elected policians
may be subject to systemac errors of judgement, such as conrmaon bias (the tendency to favour
informaon that conrms their pre-exisng beliefs) or status quo bias (the tendency to prefer
maintaining the current state of aairs) (Arceneaux, 2012). In concrete terms, elected policians may
minimise the seriousness of a problem in their areas, underesmate the benets of implemenng PBPs
to resolve these problems or overesmate their cost and complexity. This is also what Jones (2022)
showed when he explained that the outgoing mayor had denied the problem of gentricaon in his city.
In his example, elected policians downplayed the negave impact of luxury real estate projects on local
communies and ignored studies or reports that highlighted the negave consequences on low-income
residents.
A second factor is the inuence of emoons and feelings. Local elected policians, as representaves of
the local community and holders of decision-making power, can also be inuenced by emoonal
reacons when considering whether or not to implement a place-based policy. For example, they may
posively associate improved transport infrastructure with increased connecvity and accessibility,
economic growth and job creaon in their areas. However, they may also associate such projects
negavely with disrupon to local communies, increased polluon and noise and inequity in the
distribuon of benets and costs. This is what Torre (2023) explained using the example of airport
construcon, renewable energies and freeways. Similarly to cizens, local elected policians might have
varying percepons of the implementaon process for transport infrastructure projects, inuenced by
their sense of the process’s fairness (Bourdin & Nadou, 2020). If an elected polician perceives the
process as unfair (e.g. if they feel they have not been suciently consulted or involved in the decision-
making process), this may elicit a negave emoonal response and reinforce their opposion to the
project. As Beer et al. (2020) explained, the implementaon of PBPs oen involves mul-level
governance, which does not guarantee that all levels are fairly involved in decision-making. This can be
explained by the fact that the “policy network” (Sotarauta, 2010) is complex.
4.2. The Not in My Electoral Year Eect
In addion to their personal feelings, elected policians may also be inuenced by their peers, polical
pares or electors. If these groups are hosle to certain PBPs, elected policians may be reluctant to
implement them. Elected policians are likely to weigh the potenal advantages and disadvantages
before making a decision (Slovic et al., 1977; Pollack, 2007). For example, an elected policians might
perceive the risk of high costs, administrave complexity or negave polical fallout as outweighing the
potenal benets. They might also downplay the potenal benets if they are not immediately visible
or tangible, parcularly in the context of a potenal re-elecon.
Thus, elected policians can obstruct PBPs for polical reasons. To illustrate this, we refer here to the
expression ‘Not In My Electoral year eect’ (NIMEY), a variant of the beer-known phrase ‘Not In My
Back Yard’, which is used to describe opposion by residents to a proposal for a new development
because it is close to them, oen with the implicaon that such developments are needed but should
be further away (Van der Horst, 2007; Bourdin et al., 2020). Applied to the polical realm, NIMEY refers
to a phenomenon in which policians avoid controversial decisions or policies in the run-up to an
elecon year to prevent any potenal backlash from voters. They might avoid taking stances on hot-
buon issues, pushing for major policy changes or undertaking other acons that could be polically
risky. This could lead to a delay in decision-making and policy implementaon and could potenally
impact the eecveness and eciency of government.
Thus, the NIMEY eect can be used to analyse PBPs by examining how electoral cycles and polical
consideraons inuence the implementaon and outcomes of these policies. This can involve studying
PBPs, such as infrastructure projects, tax incenves for businesses or social programmes targeted at
specic neighbourhoods or communies, and asking whether policians tend to propose or implement
these policies more oen in non-elecon years or whether controversial or potenally unpopular
policies are delayed unl aer elecons. An example might be a mayor postponing the construcon of
a controversial new industrial complex or wind farm unl aer the elecons. The mayor fears that public
discontent will harm his re-elecon, even though the project could have boosted the local economy in
the long term. It may also involve comparing the outcomes (e.g. in terms of ambion) of policies
implemented in elecon years versus non-elecon years. The inuence of the NIMEY eect can vary
depending on the specic context, including the type of policy, the polical dynamics in the area and the
characteriscs of the local electorate.
In addion, other factors besides the electoral cycle, such as economic condions (Bendor et al., 2010)
or changes in government (Jones, 2022), can also inuence policy implementaon and outcomes. An
appropriate example is New York State in the United States, where the ‘Start-Up NY’ economic
development programme was launched in 2014. This is a typically place-based policy, as it creates tax-
free zones for new businesses on or near New York State university campuses. However, its eecveness
and popularity were called into queson during the 2018 elecons. Indeed, despite inial promises to
create several thousand jobs, a 2016 report
1
revealed that it had only created 408 jobs. As a result, faced
with these disappoinng results, several policians were reluctant to support the programme during the
elecon campaign for fear of suering a backlash from voters. This probably slowed down decision-
making and policy adaptaon (Jean-Snarr et al., 2017). Another example to illustrate another type of
1
hps://taxfoundaon.org/new-york-reports-raise-quesons-about-excelsior-and-start-ny-job-programs/
phenomenon related to the NIMEY eect can be found in Olfert et al.’s (2014) arcle. The authors
highlight that regions that are polically controversial or sensive may be neglected in favour of regions
that are more likely to bring polical advantage to elected policians.
Sll referring to the behavioural polical economy framework, NIMEY can appear in two situaons in
parcular. First, the elected polician may be in a situaon of dissonance (Yahya & Sukmayadi, 2020).
This is when they are faced with a dicult choice, for example, between implemenng a PBP that is
benecial in the long term but unpopular in the short term and maintaining the status quo. Let us take
the example of an elected policians who supports a wind farm project or the installaon of a biogas
unit in his locality to ensure local energy autonomy. This could create a renewable energy source and
bring jobs to the area in the long term, which would be benecial for the enre community. However,
this project could face opposion from some local residents who are concerned about the impact on
the landscape, noise or the potenal reducon in the value of their properes (Bourdin et al. 2020;
Torre, 2023). The elected policians is then faced with a situaon of dissonance between the desire to
do what is benecial for the local community in the long term and the desire to respond to the
immediate concerns of certain constuents. Second, elected policians may face sunk costs (Cornelio et
al., 2021). They may have invested a signicant amount of me, eort and money in supporng a project
to build a new motorway in their region, with the aim of opening it up and making it more aracve.
The project has been underway for several years and has involved environmental studies, land
acquision and inial construcon work. However, a recent study suggests that the project will have a
negave impact on the local environment and that alternave soluons are available that are less costly
and less damaging to the environment. Despite this new informaon, the elected policians may be
reluctant to stop the project because of the resources already invested. This is known as sunk cost (Roth
et al., 2015); the elected policians does not want to lose the investment already made in the project,
even if the new informaon suggests that connuing the project is not the best decision. A concrete
example of the sunk cost eect is the Belo Monte dam project in Brazil (Mayer et al., 2021). Started in
the 2010s, this hydroelectric project was meant to boost economic growth by providing energy.
However, subsequent studies uncovered considerable adverse environmental eects, including
deforestaon and the impact on indigenous communies. Despite these ndings and the availability of
less harmful energy alternaves, the Brazilian government proceeded with the project, partly due to the
substanal investments already made.
Finally, referring to the seminal work of Sotarauta (2010) on “policy networks”, elected policians can
also fail in negoang with stakeholders of a regional development project. This failure in negoaon
may stem from the ocial opng for a decision that maximizes their personal interest rather than that
of other place-based leaders with whom they negoate. Consequently, these choices made by the
polician may undermine collecve eorts, erode trust among stakeholders, and ulmately jeopardize
the overall success and sustainability of the regional development iniave. Such decisions can create a
ri between elected policians and other place-based leaders, leading to fragmentaon in strategic
direcon and objecves. This can result in the inecient allocaon of resources, missed opportunies
for synergies, and a lack of cohesive vision for regional development (Sotarauta & Beer, 2017).
Furthermore, when stakeholders perceive a misalignment of interests, it may deter them from fully
invesng their eorts, resources, and commitment in future collaboraons (Beer et al., 2019). Over me,
this can erode the very foundaon of cooperave frameworks and dilute the potency of collecve acon
in driving regional development forward (Sotarauta, 2016).
4.3. Contextual variables
Contextual variables refer to external factors that can inuence policy decisions and the acons of
elected policians. In behavioural polical economy, these determinants can play an important role in
aecng the decision-making of an elected policians (Schnellenbach & Schubert, 2015). A disncon
can be made between variables relang to the socioeconomic environment and those relang to
informaon and media contexts. First, the economic resources of a local authority will necessarily
inuence the policies that are implemented (Oulasvirta & Turala, 2009). In many countries, the nancial
autonomy of local authories is precarious and, following the example of France, Torre and Bourdin
(2022) explained that the decentralisaon policy in many European countries has not always been
accompanied by the nancial resources that go with it. As a result, the ability of regional and subregional
authories to implement PBPs may be called into queson or, at least, limited. Indeed, the addionality
principle of many PBPs implies that the local authority must be able to co-nance the projects (Del Bo &
Sirtori, 2016). This is parcularly the case for Cohesion Policy (Bachtler et al., 2017). Consequently, if the
local authority is unable to provide its own funds, it may decide not to implement a project.
The socioeconomic and geographical environment of the local authority will also inuence an elected
policians’s ability to implement a PBP. First, the global economic environment must be taken into
account. Several studies have shown that the 2008 nancial crisis and the pandemic may have limited
the investment capacity of local governments, although for dierent reasons (Marn, 2011; Gray &
Barford, 2018; Bourdin et al., 2023). Thus, elected policians may not have all the informaon they need
to fully understand the implicaons of these global crises on their investment capacies. As a result,
they may decide to delay or avoid certain PBPs that require signicant investment, even though these
policies could be benecial in the long term. On the other hand, the local socioeconomic environment
and more specically the existence of localised crises can aect policy decisions. In the event of a local
crisis, elected policians may focus on immediate crisis management, neglecng long-term policies that
may not bring immediate benets but are essenal for long-term resilience (Wink et al., 2016). Recently,
some authors showed that many local authories have focused on short-term measures to address the
economic and social consequences of the global health crisis (ESPON, 2021 & 2022; Bourdin et al., 2023).
Finally, the informaon environment is likely to inuence the commitment of elected policians
(Entman, 2007). Cook (2012) explained that with the rise in power of the media, elected policians were
led to govern with the news. This line of argument refers to agenda-seng theory in behavioural polical
economy (Weaver et al., 2004; Protess & McCombs, 2013). Thus, elected policians will make decisions
that will somemes hinder the design and implementaon of PBPs because they will have assessed that
a policy could have a negave impact on their media image. It would therefore be a queson of social
pressure in the media (newspapers, radio and social media), which would lead to the slowing down or
even the abandonment of a policy. One example at the local level involves the bid by Boston for the 2024
Summer Games (Lauermann & Vogelpohl, 2017). Inially, the proposal was presented as a way to
smulate urban development and improve infrastructure. However, as public scruny and media
coverage intensied, raising concerns about costs, environmental impact, and displacement, local
elected policians began to express doubts. Faced with increasing opposion fueled by social media
campaigns and negave press, Mayor Marn J. Walsh and other ocials became more cauous about
supporng the bid, ulmately leading to its withdrawal. This case demonstrates how public pressure
driven by the media can result in a retreat from large-scale urban projects (Andranovich & Burbank,
2021).
5. Implicaons and reecons on future avenues of research
5.1. Implicaons and recommendaons
In our arcle, we explore the inuence of internal and external dynamics on the decision-making of
elected policians, which in turn aects the eecveness of PBPs. We have idened the roles of elected
policians as intermediaries, as well as the psychological, polical, and contextual obstacles that can
impede policy implementaon. Given these challenges, it is crucial to enhance the capacity of elected
policians, as they are tasked with making complex decisions while considering mulple parameters and
facing uncertainty. Therefore, training programs for elected policians should focus on (i) managing
biases, (ii) mediaon, and (iii) territorial leadership. Bias management training would involve raising
awareness among elected policians about dierent forms of cognive and aecve biases that can
inuence their decisions, and providing techniques to idenfy and overcome them. Mediaon training
aims to develop the skills of elected policians in managing conicts, promong dialogue, and fostering
collaboraon among stakeholders. Territorial leadership training would concentrate on developing and
implemenng strategic visions for regional development, encouraging a forward-thinking and
parcipatory approach. Addionally, it is vital to consider the systemac introducon of rigorous
monitoring and evaluaon mechanisms, and to provide beer support to elected policians in order to
measure the impact and eecveness of these policies in advance (to inform decision-making), during
(to allow policy adjustments), and aerwards (to learn from any mistakes and improve).
Another crucial aspect is to consider cizen parcipaon. While cizen parcipaon has become
popular and may redene democracy (Michels, A., & De Graaf, 2017), it is important to acknowledge
that involving cizens in decision-making is not without challenges and can be a source of concern for
elected policians. Royo et al. (2011) explain that our ndings reveal how elected policians primarily
mobilize cizen parcipaon to enhance their perceived legimacy or to meet basic legal requirements,
rather than ulizing cizen parcipaon to improve decision-making processes. Parcipaon is oen
perceived as lacking the power to bring about change (Koch, F., & Sanchez Steiner, 2017), which can lead
to frustraon among residents and failure from the perspecve of elected policians. However, when
parcipaon is eecvely implemented, it can lead to tangible soluons for local issues and assist
elected policians in making informed decisions (Rosen & Painter, 2019).
5.2. Avenues of research
The future of PBPs looks both promising and full of challenges. Considering potenal changes in polical
or economic condions, emerging problems or new ideas in the eld, a number of avenues for reecon
emerge, based on the frameworks we mobilised in this arcle (see Figure 2). In this paper, we
emphasised that PBPs need to be analysed without forgeng polical aspects.
Figure 2: A behavioural polical economy approach to analysing place-based policies
Source: Author
First, the role of territorial intermediaries in the implementaon of PBPs should be further explored.
What funcons do they assume in their design and implementaon (facilitator, orchestrator, mediator,
etc.)? As Coano and Foray (2014) argued, the implementaon of PBPs requires good instuons and
strong polical capacity at the regional level. Analysing the involvement of territorial intermediaries as
agents capable of acvang the networking of local actors and having internal legimacy when PBPs
emerge could be a promising avenue for research. In our arcle, territorial intermediaries are considered
facilitators, mediators or orchestrators. However, this vision may be limited and may fail to capture the
full potenal of these actors. As locally rooted agents with a deep understanding of local dynamics,
elected policians are in a unique posion to ancipate the changing needs of the region and idenfy
opportunies for implemenng PBPs. Other roles could be assigned to them. It would also be interesng
to analyse how these roles evolve over the course of a PBP (from its design to its operaonalisaon).
However, the legimacy of elected policians as intermediaries has been debated in the literature. Bakici
et al (2013) have emphasized the issues related to conicts of interest that elected ocials may have,
as well as the challenges posed by bureaucracy and budget constraints. These factors not only make the
role of intermediary more dicult but also raise concerns about the trust and legimacy bestowed upon
them by the public. For example, Mastens et al (2016) emphasize the dicules caused by budget
limitaons and bureaucrac processes in the management of drinking water. Choices made based on
economic factors, without sucient regard for the impact on public health, resulted in a signicant
health crisis. The handling of this crisis exposed conicts of interest and a lack of eecve oversight,
greatly diminishing public trust in elected ocials and underscoring the limitaons of their role as
mediators in safeguarding the well-being of the populaon.
Second, the NIMEY eect presents an interesng line of enquiry. Future research could invesgate how
the proximity of an elecon inuences policians’ willingness to support or oppose controversial
policies. It could also idenfy factors that might inuence the NIMEY eect in the design and
implementaon of PBPs. This could include polical factors (e.g. popularity of policians and
compeveness of the elecon) but also territorial factors (economic health of the region, local
resources, path dependency, etc.). Finally, it would be interesng to study how the NIMEY eect can
inuence the implementaon of PBPs. This could involve an analysis of how the NIMEY eect can delay,
modify or hinder the implementaon of territory-based policies. In the same vein, it would be
appropriate to study how stakeholders in PBPs implement strategies to overcome the NIMEY eect,
notably through stakeholder engagement, the use of appropriate governance mechanisms or the
adopon of measures to migate the impact of the NIMEY eect.
In conclusion, regional, urban and planning studies, enriched by the theorecal framework of
behavioural polical economy, can connue to oer a substanal eld of invesgaon for the analysis of
PBPs. Exploring these research perspecves could deepen our understanding of the entanglements
between polical and economic mechanisms, and also guide the design of more eecve policies
tailored to local specicies in order to avoid leading to regional disparies or other unintended eects
(Telle et al., 2019; Grossman, 2019).
References
Aboal, D. (2020). Electoral systems and economic growth. Economia Polica, 37(3), 781-805.
hps://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-020-00185-6
Agogué, M., Yström, A., & Le Masson, P. (2013). Rethinking the role of intermediaries as an architect of
collecve exploraon and creaon of knowledge in open innovaon. Internaonal Journal of Innovaon
Management, 17(02), 1350007. hps://doi.org/10.1142/s1363919613500072
Ajzen, I. (1996). The social psychology of decision making. Social psychology: Handbook of basic
principles, 297-325.
Alesina, A., & Rodrik, D. (1994). Distribuve Polics and Economic Growth. The Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 109(2), 465-490. hps://doi.org/10.2307/2118470
Andranovich, G., & Burbank, M. J. (2021). Contesng the Olympics in American Cies: Chicago 2016,
Boston 2024, Los Angeles 2028. hps://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-16-5094-9
Arceneaux, K. (2012). Cognive biases and the strength of polical arguments." American Journal of
Polical Science, 56(2), 271-285 hps://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5907.2011.00573.x
Ausn, B. A., Glaeser, E. L., & Summers, L. H. (2018). Jobs for the Heartland: Place-based policies in 21st
century America. Brookings Papers on Economic Acvity 49 (1): 151–232.
hps://doi.org/10.1353/eca.2018.0002
Ayres, S. (2014). Place-based leadership: reecons on scale, agency and theory. Regional Studies,
Regional Science, 1(1), 21-24. hps://doi.org/10.1080/21681376.2013.869424
Ayres, S., Flinders, M., & Sandford, M. (2018). Territory, power and statecra: understanding English
devoluon. Regional Studies, 52(6), 853-864. hps://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2017.1360486
Bachtler, J. (2019). Reshaping regional development policy in Europe: Place-based, smart,
transformave?. In A Research Agenda for Regional Economic Development (pp. 53-70). Edward Elgar
Publishing.
Bachtler, J., Begg, I., Charles, D., & Polvari, L. (2017). The long-term eecveness of EU cohesion policy.
EU Cohesion Policy, 11. hps://doi.org/10.1111/1468-2427.12719
Bakici, T., Almirall, E., & Wareham, J. (2013). The role of public open innovaon intermediaries in local
government and the public sector. Technology Analysis & Strategic Management, 25(3), 311-327.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/09537325.2013.764983
Barca, F. (2019). Place-based policy and polics. Renewal: A Journal of Social Democracy, 27(1), 84-95.
Barca, F., McCann, P., & Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2012). The case for regional development intervenon:
place-based versus place-neutral approaches. Journal of Regional Science, 52(1), 134-152.
hps://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9787.2011.00756.x
Bardhan, P. (1997). The Role of Governance in Economic Development: A Polical Economy Approach.
OECD Development Centre.
Beer, A., & Clower, T. (2014). Mobilizing leadership in cies and regions. Regional Studies, Regional
Science, 1(1), 5-20. hps://doi.org/10.1080/21681376.2013.869428
Beer, A., Ayres, S., Clower, T., Faller, F., Sancino, A., & Sotarauta, M. (2019). Place leadership and regional
economic development: a framework for cross-regional analysis. Regional studies, 53(2), 171-182.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2018.1447662
Beer, A., McKenzie, F., Blažek, J., Sotarauta, M., & Ayres, S. (2020). Every place maers: Towards eecve
place-based policy. Routledge. hps://doi.org/10.4324/9781003110118
Boschma, R. (2005). Proximity and innovaon: a crical assessment. Regional studies, 39(1), 61-74.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/0034340052000320887
Boschma, R. (2014). Construcng regional advantage and smart specialisaon: Comparison of two
European policy concepts. Italian Journal of Regional Science (Scienze Regionali), 13(1), 51-68.
hps://doi.org/10.3280/scre2014-001004
Bourdin, S. (2019). Does the cohesion policy have the same inuence on growth everywhere? A
geographically weighted regression approach in Central and Eastern Europe. Economic Geography,
95(3), 256-287. hps://doi.org/10.1080/00130095.2018.1526074
Bourdin, S., & Nadou, F. (2020). The role of a local authority as a stakeholder encouraging the
development of biogas: a study on territorial intermediaon. Journal of Environmental Management,
258, 110009. hps://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2019.110009
Bourdin, S., Colas, M., & Raulin, F. (2020). Understanding the problems of biogas producon deployment
in dierent regions: territorial governance maers too. Journal of Environmental Planning and
Management, 63(9), 1655-1673. hps://doi.org/10.1080/09640568.2019.1680158
Bourdin, S., Moodie, J., Gassen, N. S., Evers, D., Adoba, F., Amdaoud, M., ... & Remete, Z. (2023). COVID-
19 as a systemic shock: curb or catalyst for proacve policies towards territorial cohesion?. Regional
Studies, 1-14. hps://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2023.2242387
Bourdin, S., Nadou, F., & Obermöller, A. (2020). Comment les poliques publiques favorisent-elles les
dynamiques collaboraves d’innovaon? Analyse du management de l’intermédiaon territoriale.
Revue d’Économie Régionale & Urbaine, (2), 311-335. hps://doi.org/10.3917/reru.202.0311
Brachert, M., Demann, E., & Titze, M. (2019). The regional eects of a place-based policy–Causal
evidence from Germany. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 79, 103483.
hps://doi.org/10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2019.103483
Brenner, N., Marcuse, P., & Mayer, M. (Eds.). (2012). Cies for people, not for prot: Crical urban theory
and the right to the city. Routledge. hps://doi.org/10.1111/jors.12006_13
Capello, R., & Kroll, H. (2016). From theory to pracce in smart specializaon strategy: Emerging limits
and possible future trajectories. European planning studies, 24(8), 1393-1406.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/09654313.2016.1156058
Carozzi, F. (2020). Pork Barrel Polics and Electoral Returns. American Economic Journal: Economic
Policy, 12(3), 376-404.
Collinge, C., & Gibney, J. (2010). Connecng place, policy and leadership. Policy studies, 31(4), 379-391.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/01442871003723259
Cook, T. E. (2012). Governing with the news: The news media as a polical instuon. University of
Chicago press. hps://doi.org/10.2307/2585858
Cornelio, J. R. J., Saina, T., & Locatelli, G. (2021). What does it take to kill a megaproject? The reverse
escalaon of commitment. Internaonal Journal of Project Management, 39(7), 774-787.
hps://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2021.07.004
Del Bo, C. F., & Sirtori, E. (2016). Addionality and regional public nance–Evidence from Italy.
Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 34(5), 855-878.
hps://doi.org/10.1177/0263774X1561468
Do, N. F. (2016). Unwrien factors aecng structural funds: The inuence of regional polical
behaviours on the implementaon of EU cohesion policy. European Planning Studies, 24(3), 530-550.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/09654313.2015.1047328
Duranton, G., & Venables, A. J. (2021). Place-based policies: Principles and developing country
applicaons. In Handbook of regional science (pp. 1009-1030). Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin
Heidelberg. hps://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-60723-7_142
Ehrlich, M. V., & Overman, H. G. (2020). Place-based policies and spaal disparies across European
cies. Journal of economic perspecves, 34(3), 128-149. hps://doi.org/10.1257/jep.34.3.128
Ehrlich, M. V., & Seidel, T. (2018). The persistent eects of place-based policy: Evidence from the West-
German Zonenrandgebiet. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 10(4), 344-374.
hps://doi.org/10.1257/pol.20160395
Entman, R. M. (2007). Framing bias: Media in the distribuon of power. Journal of communicaon, 57(1),
163-173. hps://doi.org/10.1111/j.1460-2466.2006.00336.x
ESPON. (2021). Geography of COVID-19 outbreak and rst policy answers. Final Report. Luxembourg.
hps://doi.org/10.13140/RG.2.2.22799.30888
ESPON. (2022). Territorial impacts of Covid-19 and policy answers in European regions and cies. Final
Report. Luxembourg. hps://doi.org/10.13140/RG.2.2.23435.98084
Estensoro, M., & Larrea, M. (2016). Overcoming policy making problems in smart specializaon
strategies: Engaging subregional governments. European Planning Studies, 24(7), 1319-1335.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/09654313.2016.1174670
Fainstein, S. (2009). Spaal jusce and planning. Jusce Spaale/Spaal Jusce, 1(1), 1-13.
hp://doi.wiley.com/10.1002/9781119084679.ch13
Forgas, J. P., Fiedler, K., & Crano, W. D. (Eds.). (2015). Social psychology and polics. Psychology Press.
hps://doi.org/10.4324/9781315717104
Galster, G. (2010). The Mechanism(s) of Neighborhood Eects Theory, Evidence, and Policy Implicaons.
In Neighbourhood eects research: New perspecves (pp. 23-56). Springer, Dordrecht.
hps://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-2309-2_2
Glaeser, E. L., & Golieb, J. D. (2008). The economics of place-making policies. Brookings Papers on
Economic Acvity, 1: 155-239. hps://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1299046
Gray, I. (1991). Polics in place. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Gray, M., & Barford, A. (2018). The depths of the cuts: the uneven geography of local government
austerity. Cambridge journal of regions, economy and society, 11(3), 541-563.
hps://doi.org/10.1093/cjres/rsy019
Grossman, D. (2019). The unintended eects of place based programs: ferlity and health eects of
urban empowerment zones. Journal of Health Economics, 63, 114-127.
hps://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2018.11.005
Gustafsson, S., & Mignon, I. (2020). Municipalies as intermediaries for the design and local
implementaon of climate visions. European Planning Studies, 28(6), 1161-1182.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/09654313.2019.1612327
Heernan, R. (2002). The Possible as the Art of Polics’: Understanding Consensus Polics. Polical
Studies, 50(4), 742-760. hps://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9248.00005
Heres, D. R., Jack, D., & Salon, D. (2014). Do public transport investments promote urban economic
development? Evidence from bus rapid transit in Bogotá, Colombia. Transportaon, 41, 57-74.
hps://doi.org/10.1007/s11116-013-9471-8
Howells, J. (2006). Intermediaon and the role of intermediaries in innovaon. Research policy, 35(5),
715-728. hps://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2006.03.005
Huggins, R., & Thompson, P. (2015). Culture and place-based development: A socio-economic analysis.
Regional Studies, 49(1), 130-159. hps://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2014.889817
Jean-Snarr, L. B., Snarr, H., & Friesner, D. L. (2017). Is “START-UP NY” Starng Up NY?: A Post-Keynesian
Case Study Analysis. Internaonal Journal of Sustainable Entrepreneurship and Corporate Social
Responsibility (IJSECSR), 2(1), 1-12.
Jonas, A. E., & Ward, K. (2007). There’s more than one way to be serious’ about city-regions.
Internaonal Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 31(3), 647-656. hps://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-
2427.2007.00744.x
Jones, C. E. (2022). Does a mayor maer? Gentricaon, land use policy, and the 2018 mayoral elecon
in Burnaby, BC. The Canadian Geographer/Le Géographe canadien, 66(3), 581-594.
hps://doi.org/10.1111/cag.12759
Kline, P., & More, E. (2014a). Local economic development, agglomeraon economies, and the big
push: 100 years of evidence from the Tennessee Valley Authority. The Quarterly journal of economics,
129(1), 275-331. hps://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjt034
Kline, P., & More, E. (2014b). People, places, and public policy: Some simple welfare economics of local
economic development programs. Annu. Rev. Econ., 6(1), 629-662. hps://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-
economics-080213-041024
Koch, F., & Sanchez Steiner, L. M. (2017). Parcipaon without power: The failure of cizen parcipaon
in Barranquilla. Lan American Perspecves, 44(2), 168-183.
hps://doi.org/10.1177/0094582X16668312
Kroll, H. (2015). Eorts to implement smart specializaon in pracce—leading unlike horses to the water.
European Planning Studies, 23(10), 2079-2098. hps://doi.org/10.1080/09654313.2014.1003036
Lauermann, J., & Vogelpohl, A. (2017). Fragile growth coalions or powerful contestaons? Cancelled
Olympic bids in Boston and Hamburg. Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space, 49(8), 1887-
1904. hps://doi.org/10.1177/0308518X17711447
Lee, N. (2017). Psychology and the geography of innovaon. Economic Geography, 93(2), 106-130.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/00130095.2016.1249845
Mackness, K., White, I., & Barre, P. (2023). 20-Minute Neighborhoods: Opportunies and Challenges.
Handbook of Sustainability Science in the Future: Policies, Technologies and Educaon by 2050, 1-22.
hps://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-68074-9_172-1
Mansbridge, J. (1990). The Rise and Fall of Self-Interest in the Explanaon of Polical Life. In Beyond Self-
Interest (pp. 3-22). University of Chicago Press.
Mansuri, G., & Rao, V. (2012). Localizing development: Does parcipaon work?. A World Bank Research
Report. hps://doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-8256-1
Marn, R. (2011). The local geographies of the nancial crisis: from the housing bubble to economic
recession and beyond. Journal of economic geography, 11(4), 587-618.
hps://doi.org/10.1093/jeg/lbq024
Masten, S. J., Davies, S. H., & Mcelmurry, S. P. (2016). Flint water crisis: what happened and why?.
Journal-American Water Works Associaon, 108(12), 22-34.
hps://doi.org/10.5942/jawwa.2016.108.0195
Mayer, A., Castro-Diaz, L., Lopez, M. C., Leturcq, G., & Moran, E. F. (2021). Is hydropower worth it?
Exploring amazonian reselement, human development and environmental costs with the Belo Monte
project in Brazil. Energy Research & Social Science, 78, 102129.
hps://doi.org/10.1016/j.erss.2021.102129
Michels, A., & De Graaf, L. (2010). Examining cizen parcipaon: Local parcipatory policy making and
democracy. Local Government Studies, 36(4), 477-491.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/03003930.2010.494101
Michels, A., & De Graaf, L. (2017). Examining cizen parcipaon: local parcipatory policymaking and
democracy revisited. Local government studies, 43(6), 875-881.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/03003930.2017.1365712
Morisson, A., & Doussineau, M. (2019). Regional innovaon governance and place-based policies:
design, implementaon and implicaons. Regional Studies, Regional Science, 6(1), 101-116.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/21681376.2019.1578257
Moulaert, F., Jessop, B., & Mehmood, A. (2016). Agency, structure, instuons, discourse (ASID) in urban
and regional development. Internaonal Journal of Urban Sciences, 20(2), 167-187.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/12265934.2016.1182054
Neumark, D. (2020). Place-based policies: can we do beer than enterprise zones. Journal of Policy
Analysis and Management, 39(3), 836-844. hps://doi.org/10.1002/pam.22225
Neumark, D., & Simpson, H. (2015). Place-Based Policies. In Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics
(Vol. 5, pp. 1197-1287). Elsevier. hps://doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-444-59531-7.00018-1
Niang, A., Torre, A., & Bourdin, S. (2022). Territorial governance and actors’ coordinaon in a local project
of anaerobic digeson. A social network analysis. European Planning Studies, 30(7), 1251-1270.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/09654313.2021.1891208
Niang, A., Torre, A., & Bourdin, S. (2022a). How do local actors coordinate to implement a successful
biogas project?. Environmental Science & Policy, 136, 337-347.
hps://doi.org/10.1016/j.envsci.2022.06.019
OECD. (2009). How regions grow: Trends and analysis. Paris: OECD."
hps://doi.org/10.1787/9789264039469-en
Olfert, M. R., Partridge, M., Berdegué, J., Escobal, J., Jara, B., & Modrego, F. (2014). Places for place-
based policy. Development Policy Review, 32(1), 5-32. hps://doi.org/10.1111/dpr.12041
Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collecve acon Harvard University Press. Cambridge, MA.
Oulasvirta, L., & Turala, M. (2009). Financial autonomy and consistency of central government policy
towards local governments. Internaonal Review of Administrave Sciences, 75(2), 311-332.
hps://doi.org/10.1177/0020852309104178
Partridge, M. D., Rickman, D. S., Olfert, M. R., & Tan, Y. (2015). When spaal equilibrium fails: Is place-
based policy second best?. Regional Studies, 49(8), 1303-1325.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2013.837999
Petrakos, G., Topaloglou, L., Anagnostou, A., & Cupcea, V. (2022). Geographies of (in) jusce and the (in)
eecveness of place-based policies in Greece. European Planning Studies, 30(5),
hps://doi.org/10.1080/09654313.2021.1928050
Pike, A., Rodríguez-Pose, A., & Tomaney, J. (2007). What kind of local and regional development and for
whom?. Regional studies, 41(9), 1253-1269. hps://doi.org/10.1080/00343400701543355
Pike, A., Rodríguez-Pose, A., & Tomaney, J. (2016). Local and regional development. Routledge.
hps://doi.org/10.4324/9781315767673
Pollack, M. A. (2007). Raonal choice and EU polics. Handbook of European Union Polics, 31-55.
hps://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1011326
Prewi, K. (2005). Polical ideas and a polical science for policy. The Annals of the American Academy
of Polical and Social Science, 600(1), 14-29. hps://doi.org/10.1177/0002716205276660
Protess, D., & McCombs, M. E. (Eds.). (2016). Agenda seng: Readings on media, public opinion, and
policymaking. Routledge. hps://doi.org/10.4324/9781315538389
Raco, M., & Flint, J. (2001). Communies, places and instuonal relaons: assessing the role of area-
based community representaon in local governance. Polical geography, 20(5), 585-612.
hps://doi.org/10.1016/S0962-6298(01)00012-9
Rodden, J. (2002). The Dilemma of Fiscal Federalism: Grants and Fiscal Performance around the World.
American Journal of Polical Science, 46(3), 670-687. hps://doi.org/10.2307/3088407
Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2013). Do Instuons Maer for Regional Development? Regional Studies, 47(7),
1034-1047. hps://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2012.748978
Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2018). The revenge of the places that don’t maer (and what to do about it).
Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, 11(1), 189-209.
hps://doi.org/10.1093/cjres/rsx024
Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2020). Instuons and the fortunes of territories. Regional Science Policy & Pracce,
12(3), 371-386. hps://doi.org/10.1111/rsp3.12277
Rodríguez-Pose, A., Bartalucci, F., Frick, S. A., Santos-Paulino, A. U., & Bolwijn, R. (2022). The challenge
of developing special economic zones in Africa: Evidence and lessons learnt. Regional Science Policy &
Pracce, 14(2), 456-481. hps://doi.org/10.1111/rsp3.12535
Rodríguez-Pose, A., Psycharis, Y., & Tselios, V. (2016). Polics and investment: Examining the territorial
allocaon of public investment in Greece. Regional Studies, 50(7), 1097-1112.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2015.1009027
Rosen, J., & Painter, G. (2019). From cizen control to co-producon: Moving beyond a linear concepon
of cizen parcipaon. Journal of the American planning associaon, 85(3), 335-347.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/01944363.2019.1618727
Roth, S., Robbert, T., & Straus, L. (2015). On the sunk-cost eect in economic decision-making: a meta-
analyc review. Business research, 8, 99-138. hps://doi.org/10.1007/s40685-014-0014-8
Royo, S., Yetano, A., & Acerete, B. (2011). Cizen parcipaon in German and Spanish local governments:
A comparave study. Internaonal Journal of Public Administraon, 34(3), 139-150.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/01900692.2010.533070
Schnellenbach, J., & Schubert, C. (2015). Behavioral polical economy: A survey. European Journal of
Polical Economy, 40, 395-417. hps://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2015.05.002
Shenoy, A. (2018). Regional development through place-based policies: Evidence from a spaal
disconnuity. Journal of Development Economics, 130, 173-189.
hps://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2017.10.001
Shepsle, K. A. et Bonchek, M. S. (1997). Analyzing Polics: Raonality, Behavior and Instuons. New
York: W.W. Norton & Company.
Sigler, T., Neal, Z., & Marnus, K. (2023). Brokerage as an urban and regional process between systems
and scales. Regional Studies, 57(2), 209-214. hps://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2022.2093343
Slovic, P., Fischho, B., & Lichtenstein, S. (1977). Behavioral decision theory. Annual review of psychology,
28(1), 1-39. hps://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.ps.28.020177.000245
Soja, E. W. (2010). Seeking spaal jusce. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
hps://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9663.2011.00655.x
Solé-Ollé, A., & Sorribas-Navarro, P. (2008). The eects of parsan alignment on the allocaon of
intergovernmental transfers. Dierences-in-dierences esmates for Spain. Journal of Public Economics,
92(12), 2302-2319. hps://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.06.014
Sotarauta, M. (2009). Power and inuence taccs in the promoon of regional development: An
empirical analysis of the work of Finnish regional development ocers. Geoforum, 40(5), 895-905.
hps://doi.org/10.1016/j.geoforum.2009.06.005
Sotarauta, M. (2010). Regional development and regional networks: The role of regional development
ocers in Finland. European Urban and Regional Studies, 17(4), 387-400.
hps://doi.org/10.1177/0969776409352581
Sotarauta, M. (2016). Leadership and the city. Abingdon: Routledge
hps://doi.org/10.4324/9781315753256
Sotarauta, M., & Beer, A. (2017). Governance, agency and place leadership: Lessons from a cross-
naonal analysis. Regional Studies, 51(2), 210-223. hps://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2015.1119265
Sotarauta, M., Beer, A., & Gibney, J. (2017). Making sense of leadership in urban and regional
development. Regional Studies, 51(2), 187-193. hps://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2016.1267340
Telle, S., Špaček, M., & Crăciun, D. (2019). Divergent Paths to Cohesion: The (Unintended) Consequences
of a Place-Based Cohesion Policy. Regional and Local Development in Times of Polarisaon: Re-thinking
Spaal Policies in Europe, 149-172. hps://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-1190-1_7
Tomaney, J. (2010). Place-based approaches to regional development: global trends and Australian
implicaons. Sydney: Australian Business Foundaon.
Torre, A. (2014). Proximity relaons at the heart of territorial development processes: from clusters,
spaal conicts and temporary geographical proximity to territorial governance. In Regional
development and proximity relaons (pp. 94-134). Edward Elgar Publishing.
hps://doi.org/10.4337/9781781002896.00009
Torre, A. (2023). Contribuon to the theory of territorial development: a territorial innovaons
approach. Regional Studies, 1-16. hps://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2023.2193218
Torre, A., & Bourdin, S. (2022). The French territorial reform of the regions: objecves, risks and
challenges for some forgoen territories. Internaonal Journal of Public Administraon, 1-12.
hps://doi.org/10.1080/01900692.2021.2018456
Van der Horst, D. (2007). NIMBY or not? Exploring the relevance of locaon and the polics of voiced
opinions in renewable energy sing controversies. Energy policy, 35(5), 2705-2714.
hps://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2006.12.012
Van Leeuwen, E. S. (2020). Place-based behavior and environmental policies. In A research agenda for
environmental economics (pp. 143-158). Edward Elgar Publishing.
hps://doi.org/10.4337/9781789900057.00013
Vasilakos, N., Pitelis, A. T., Horsewood, N., & Pitelis, C. (2023). Place-based public investment in regional
infrastructure, the locaonal choice of rms and regional performance: the case of India. Regional
Studies, 1-14. hps://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2022.2146666
Wang, Y. & Bourdin, S. (2024) Coordinaon maers - Territorial governance in innovaon clusters:
Comparison of Cité Biotech (Canada) and Polepharma (France). Management Internaonal.
Weaver, D., McCombs, M., & Shaw, D. L. (2004). Agenda-seng research: Issues, aributes, and
inuences. Handbook of polical communicaon research, 257, 257-80.
Weck, S., Madanipour, A., & Schmi, P. (2022). Place-based development and spaal jusce. European
Planning Studies, 30(5), 791-806. hps://doi.org/10.1080/09654313.2021.1928038
Wink, R., Kirchner, L., Koch, F., & Speda, D. (2016). There are many roads to reindustrializaon and
resilience: Place-based approaches in three German urban regions. European Planning Studies, 24(3),
463-488. hps://doi.org/10.1080/09654313.2015.1046370
Yahya, A. H., & Sukmayadi, V. (2020). A Review of Cognive Dissonance Theory and Its Relevance to
Current Social Issues. MIMBAR: Jurnal Sosial Dan Pembangunan, 36(2), 480-488.
hps://doi.org/10.29313/mimbar.v36i2.6652
... To establish effective industrial symbiosis, which involves one company's waste or by-products becoming resources for another, an intermediary player is crucial in facilitating these exchanges . Often, this intermediary is a dedicated body within local government, or a specific entity created for this purpose, acting as a mediator and catalyst for collaboration between businesses, public institutions, and other entities (Bourdin, 2024). The active governance provided by this intermediary helps identify synergistic opportunities, resolve logistical challenges, and overcome regulatory or economic obstacles. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper investigates the territorial governance mechanisms of proximity-based cluster agglomerations and organized proximity-based cluster communities. We argue that the territorial governance mechanisms of clusters consist of the locations of members, the organizational logics, and the roles of institutional intermediaries. Based on the compared case studies of Cité Biotech (Canada) and Polepharma (France), we address the similarities of both types of clusters in terms of local agglomeration, diversity of cluster members, and institutional intermediaries' roles as brokers and facilitators. We also highlight their differences in external pipelines, logic of belonging, and intermediaries' roles as mediators, orchestrators, and innovators in the cluster community. Finally, we conclude with the strategic implications for innovation cluster territorial governance. Cet article a été accepté pour publication et a fait l'objet d'une évaluation complète par les pairs, mais il n'a pas été soumis au processus d'édition, de mise en page et de relecture, ce qui peut entraîner des différences entre cette version et la version publiée. Veuillez citer cet article comme suit This article has been accepted for publication and undergone full peer review but has not been through the copyediting, typesetting, pagination and proofreading process which may lead to differences between this version and the Version of Record. Please cite this article as : Este artículo fue aceptado para publicación y sometido a una revisión completa por parte de pares, pero aún no ha pasado por el proceso de edición, maquetación, paginación y corrección de pruebas lo cual podría dar lugar a diferencias entre esta versión y la versión publicada. Por favor, cite este artículo de la siguiente manera Abstract: This paper investigates the territorial governance mechanisms of proximity-based cluster agglomerations
Technical Report
Full-text available
What does the geographical pattern of the Covid-19 pandemic look like across European regions and cities and how has it evolved since the beginning of the pandemic? Are there specific territorial and/or socio-economic characteristics that can entail a higher risk of death/more severe course of disease and/or higher probabilities of negative socio-economic impacts? Which factors explain best the level of exposure of cities, regions and functional urban areas to the Covid-19 pandemic? How can different exposure levels in different types of territories be explained? To which degree have poverty, social inequalities and social exclusion been affected by the pandemic and subsequent lockdown measures? Can local wealth conditions, poverty or inequalities explain why territories are more or less affected by the virus diffusion? Which ‘proactive’ policy approaches to coping with the pandemic during and after the first wave have proved to be working well for European regions and cities? Has it been possible to use “windows of opportunities” opened by the pandemic? How important has multi-level and cross-sectoral governance been in responding to the pandemic? Have decisions taken by local authorities had an impact beyond their administrative borders? How has the pandemic affected cooperation at the metropolitan/functional regional level? How can territorial cooperation frameworks, tools and resources for cross–border regions be strengthened in times of crises? This final report is conducted within the framework of the ESPON 2020 Cooperation Programme, partly financed by the European Regional Development Fund. The ESPON EGTC is the single beneficiary of the ESPON 2020 Cooperation Programme. The single operation within the programme is implemented by the ESPON EGTC and co-financed by the European Regional Development Fund, the EU Member States and the Partner States, Iceland, Liechtenstein, Norway and Switzerland. This delivery does not necessarily reflect the opinions of members of the ESPON 2020 Monitoring Committee.
Article
The COVID-19 pandemic, originating as a health crisis but quickly expanding to other social spheres, had significant and asymmetric impacts across Europe, which potentially undermine territorial cohesion. Much has been written about the overall impact of the pandemic on the underlying thematic and budgetary focus of European Union-level policies with respect to territorial cohesion. However, it remains unclear to what extent policies implemented at regional and local levels in response to the crisis also contribute to territorial cohesion. To address this, we investigated the extent to which the pandemic constituted a ‘window of opportunity’ for developing innovative policies furthering territorial cohesion policy goals and objectives within member states, and assessed whether the crisis led to more collaborative, integrative and holistic policymaking. To this end, the research examined policy responses across 14 European regions by means of a mixed-method case study approach, including the analysis of relevant policy documents and over 100 semi-structured interviews with key stakeholders. We show that the pandemic led to the introduction of new short-term social policies to reduce socio-economic disparities produced by COVID-19 and accelerated the implementation of green and smart policies. Additionally, the crisis fostered greater collaboration between public authorities and key stakeholders, and between regional and municipal public authorities, although the long-term impact is uncertain. These findings could have policy implications for other crisis situations. Moreover, they suggest that territorial cohesion policies should be tailored to empower regions and local governments to use systemic shocks to draft and implement proactive social, economic and environmental policies.
Article
This paper provides a new definition of territorial development based on two engines, production and governance relations, and linked to a broader conception of territorial innovation. Starting with a short survey of previous works, it presents the two major building blocks, and proposes a detailed categorisation of territorial innovations, their origin, and their contribution to production and governance dynamics. It then draws a definition and a description of territorial development processes based on these two engines, and in conclusion opens the way for future researches on bifurcations and ruptures of trajectories emerging from territorial innovations.
Article
We discuss conceptual reasons for and propose public investment in regional infrastructure as a hybrid form of a place-based regional industrial policy aiming to foster the regional economic activity of lagging regions. We present and empirically test a baseline model using data for 14 Indian regions/states over a period of 39 years. Our results show that place-based regional infrastructure investments, particularly in electricity-generating capacity and width-adjusted length of national highways, positively impact the relative number of firms operating in a region and help foster its economic performance.
Book
In 1996, the Los Angeles Bus Riders Union, a grassroots advocacy organization, won a historic legal victory against the city’s Metropolitan Transit Authority. The resulting consent decree forced the MTA for a period of ten years to essentially reorient the mass transit system to better serve the city’s poorest residents. A stunning reversal of conventional governance and planning in urban America, which almost always favors wealthier residents, this decision is also a concrete example of spatial justice in action. This book argues that justice has a geography and that the equitable distribution of resources, services, and access is a basic human right. Building on current concerns in critical geography and the new spatial consciousness, the book interweaves theory and practice, offering new ways of understanding and changing the unjust geographies in which we live. After tracing the evolution of spatial justice and the closely related notion of the right to the city in the influential work of Henri Lefebvre, David Harvey, and others, it demonstrates how these ideas are now being applied through a series of case studies in Los Angeles, the city at the forefront of this movement. The book focuses on such innovative labor-community coalitions as Justice for Janitors, the Los Angeles Alliance for a New Economy, and the Right to the City Alliance; on struggles for rent control and environmental justice; and on the role that faculty and students in the UCLA Department of Urban Planning have played in both developing the theory of spatial justice and putting it into practice.
Article
Anaerobic digestion has recently gained interest in contributing to territorial strategy regarding the deployment of the circular economy and energy transition. Most projects bring together multiple actors from a wide variety of backgrounds. The article analyzes the evolution of synergies and cooperative behaviors between local stakeholders over the period 2010–2020 in an anaerobic digestion cluster in France. The study draws on social network analysis and proximity theory, which have recently been used for analyzing regional innovation systems, local clusters, territorial governance, and rural development. We reveal that local stakeholders develop dense relational networks that vary and evolve throughout the project. Different groups exist and behave in a semi-autonomous manner. All the actors are located in close geographical proximity. Still, their links in terms of organized proximities are related to various types of relations, resulting from cognitive resemblances or common origins. This explains the persistence and resilience of local relationships and how they maintain a collaborative dynamic over time.