ArticlePDF Available

Regional Innovation and Sustainable Development Interplay: Analyzing the Spatial Externalities of Domestic Demand in the New Development Paradigm

MDPI
Sustainability
Authors:

Abstract and Figures

Building a great modern socialist country in all respects requires enhancing innovation capacity and establishing a new development pattern, especially in the context of sustainable development. This paper begins by analyzing the theoretical relationship between innovation and the spatial externality of domestic demand, constructing a theoretical model, and then empirically testing this model using provincial panel data from 2012 to 2020 through the Spatial Durbin model. The study underscores the importance of innovation in promoting sustainable economic growth, highlighting how it expands domestic demand through both supply and demand sides and positively affects the domestic demand in surrounding areas through spatial spillover effects. The empirical results reveal that innovation significantly boosts the level of domestic demand in the region and its environs, with the spatial spillover effect of domestic demand constituting 66.92% of the total effect. This underscores the relevance of spatial externality in sustainable economic planning. Innovation mainly stimulates domestic demand through consumption, aligning with sustainable consumption patterns, while exerting a moderate inhibitory effect on investment demand. The spatial externality of investment demand appears less significant. Overall, innovation drives the spatial externality of China’s domestic demand and significantly contributes to establishing a new development pattern of “dual circulation”, primarily focusing on the domestic cycle, within a framework of sustainable development. The paper concludes with policy recommendations that align innovation strategies with sustainable development goals.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Citation: Shi, Y.; Jiang, Y.; Xie, C.; Li,
C. Regional Innovation and
Sustainable Development Interplay:
Analyzing the Spatial Externalities of
Domestic Demand in the New
Development Paradigm. Sustainability
2024,16, 2365. https://doi.org/
10.3390/su16062365
Academic Editors: Fabio Carlucci and
Chengpeng Lu
Received: 24 January 2024
Revised: 29 February 2024
Accepted: 11 March 2024
Published: 13 March 2024
Copyright: © 2024 by the authors.
Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland.
This article is an open access article
distributed under the terms and
conditions of the Creative Commons
Attribution (CC BY) license (https://
creativecommons.org/licenses/by/
4.0/).
sustainability
Article
Regional Innovation and Sustainable Development Interplay:
Analyzing the Spatial Externalities of Domestic Demand in the
New Development Paradigm
Yufang Shi, Yufeng Jiang * , Can Xie and Cong Li
School of Management, Xi’an University of Science and Technology, Xi’an 710054, China;
shiyufangguoguo@163.com (Y.S.); 22202001002@stu.xust.edu.cn (C.X.); lionlee0826@126.com (C.L.)
*Correspondence: jiangyf0219@163.com
Abstract: Building a great modern socialist country in all respects requires enhancing innovation
capacity and establishing a new development pattern, especially in the context of sustainable de-
velopment. This paper begins by analyzing the theoretical relationship between innovation and
the spatial externality of domestic demand, constructing a theoretical model, and then empirically
testing this model using provincial panel data from 2012 to 2020 through the Spatial Durbin model.
The study underscores the importance of innovation in promoting sustainable economic growth,
highlighting how it expands domestic demand through both supply and demand sides and positively
affects the domestic demand in surrounding areas through spatial spillover effects. The empirical
results reveal that innovation significantly boosts the level of domestic demand in the region and its
environs, with the spatial spillover effect of domestic demand constituting 66.92% of the total effect.
This underscores the relevance of spatial externality in sustainable economic planning. Innovation
mainly stimulates domestic demand through consumption, aligning with sustainable consumption
patterns, while exerting a moderate inhibitory effect on investment demand. The spatial externality
of investment demand appears less significant. Overall, innovation drives the spatial externality of
China’s domestic demand and significantly contributes to establishing a new development pattern
of “dual circulation”, primarily focusing on the domestic cycle, within a framework of sustainable
development. The paper concludes with policy recommendations that align innovation strategies
with sustainable development goals.
Keywords: regional innovation; domestic demand; new development paradigm; spatial spillover
effects; spatial Durbin model; new economic geography
1. Introduction
As China’s economy enters a new development stage, the report of the 20th National
Congress of the Communist Party of China sets out the overall goal of “achieving high-
level technological self-reliance, entering the forefront of innovative countries; building a
modern economic system and forming a new development pattern”. This goal not only
emphasizes the importance of independent innovation but also proposes the strategic
direction of constructing a new development pattern with domestic circulation as the main
focus and the mutual promotion of domestic and international circulations. In light of this
context, investigating how innovation can stimulate domestic demand and generate spatial
externalities within the framework of innovation-driven development holds significant
importance for China in realizing the new dual circulation development pattern.
The early discussions on the concept of “dual circulation” can be traced back to 2008,
when perspectives suggested that China should reconsider its “catch-up” industrializa-
tion strategy. The proposal emphasized reshaping the industrial landscape, enhancing
innovation capabilities, and utilizing the domestic market as a driving force for economic
growth. It strategically advocated forming a mutually beneficial division of labor with
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365. https://doi.org/10.3390/su16062365 https://www.mdpi.com/journal/sustainability
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365 2 of 15
resource-supplying countries. These viewpoints laid the foundation for the later develop-
ment paradigm of “placing domestic circulation as the mainstay”. This strategic emphasis
on high-level technological self-reliance and the development of a new dual circulation de-
velopment pattern not only signifies a shift towards enhancing China’s innovation-driven
economic growth but also aligns with the global imperative for sustainable development.
By fostering an innovation-led economy, China aims to reduce its environmental footprint,
promote green technologies, and ensure economic resilience, thus contributing to the envi-
ronmental, cultural, and economic dimensions of sustainability. The pursuit of self-reliance
in technology and innovation, coupled with the emphasis on domestic circulation, presents
a unique opportunity to harmonize economic growth with environmental conservation
and social well-being. This approach underscores the necessity of integrating sustain-
able practices into the heart of China’s development strategy, aiming to create a balanced
and sustainable future that addresses the dual challenges of economic development and
sustainability.
Against this development background, our research revolves around the following
core question: how does innovation affect domestic demand within the large domestic
cycle, and can this effect be transmitted to surrounding regions through spatial spillover
effects, thereby promoting the overall uplift of regional economies? Based on this, we
propose the following hypothesis: innovation activities can not only directly enhance the
consumption and investment demand within a region but can also generate positive spatial
spillover effects by improving economic links and interactions between regions, further
promoting the expansion of domestic demand and comprehensive economic development.
This study aims to verify the direct role of innovation in promoting domestic demand and
its indirect role in inter-regional dissemination, which is of great theoretical and practical
significance for understanding and optimizing the large domestic cycle and promoting the
mutual reinforcement of domestic and international dual circulations.
2. Literature Review
(1)
Innovation’s Role in Economic and Social Advancement
Recently, with the increasing emphasis of the Chinese government on the role of
innovation in economic and social development, innovation has become a hot topic in the
academic community. It is well-known that innovation in knowledge and technology is a
key driving force for economic development and is considered one of the core elements of
national and corporate competitiveness [
1
,
2
]. At the national level, there are also diverse
factors influencing innovation performance. Ding, using the NCA analysis method, reveals
that research and development investment, globalization, and national wealth are neces-
sary conditions for innovation performance [
3
]. Shi’s research focuses on seven fiscally
decentralized countries, such as the United Kingdom and the United States, and finds
that targeted fiscal policies, such as research and development expenditures and public
debt management, have greatly changed the technological innovation landscape of these
countries [
4
]. Mao’s research finds that industrial innovation affects carbon prices, which
are directly related to socioeconomic development [
5
]. Appiah, using 29 emerging countries
as samples, finds a negative correlation between a country’s innovation input and carbon
emissions, highlighting the importance of innovation in environmental governance [
6
].
Xie’s research on coal mining enterprises shows that innovation can reduce the cost of
safety rectification, which is of great significance for maintaining social stability [
7
]. Litina
et al. investigates the impact of product market policies on innovation and concludes that
regulations that clarify negative behaviors have a positive impact on innovation, while
those that clarify negative behaviors have a negative impact on innovation [
8
]. Shi be-
lieves that the digital economy has enhanced the resilience of cities through technological
innovation and has generated positive spatial spillover effects, bringing many benefits to
society [
9
]. Through the analysis above, it can be seen that whether at the enterprise level or
the national level, a deep understanding and effective management of innovation are cru-
cial for promoting economic development and social progress. However, there is currently
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365 3 of 15
limited scholarly exploration into the relationship between innovation and the construction
of a new development pattern. Exploring this field is essential for understanding and
promoting the role of innovation in future socioeconomic development.
(2)
How Innovation Influences China’s Construction of a New Development Pattern
In exploring how innovation influences the topic of China constructing a new de-
velopment pattern, Chinese scholars have conducted extensive and in-depth research.
The prevailing view is that enhancing regional innovation capacity and achieving innova-
tive development are the key paths to building the “dual-cycle” new development pattern.
This perspective is based on the notion that the improvement in innovation capacity will
establish a foundation for high-quality mutual promotion and a dynamic balance between
domestic demand and supply, thereby enhancing the dynamism of China’s economic
cycles. Jiang and Meng emphasize that accelerating independent innovation is a necessary
path to drive high-quality domestic cycles [
10
]. They point out that this involves not only
the enhancement of the demand side but also the strengthening of the real economy on
the supply side through the cultivation of emerging industrial chains, thereby providing
impetus for the sustained and healthy development of the socioeconomic system [11,12].
From the perspective of political economics, economic cycles are defined as the process
of the movement of a country’s material and service products in the stages of production,
distribution, circulation, and consumption [
13
] to achieve value increment and enhance
the well-being of national consumption. In this framework, technological innovation is
regarded as the foundation for achieving these goals [
14
,
15
]. Therefore, by enhancing
regional innovation capacity and improving people’s well-being, it ultimately promotes
the realization of the “dual-cycle” new development pattern. On this basis, another group
of scholars believes that innovation plays a promoting role in domestic demand through
enterprises providing new products to the market and raising the national income level.
They explore the impact of innovation on the domestic cycle from the perspective of do-
mestic demand. The overall idea is that the improvement in innovation capacity can lead
to the expansion of domestic demand by improving the circulation effect of the internal
cycle [
16
,
17
]. Qian and Xiang argue that innovation can stimulate the potential of domestic
demand by creating high-quality products and services, thus expanding the domestic
cycle [
18
].
Ren and Gong
emphasize that core technological innovation is crucial for con-
structing a secure and independent domestic cycle [
19
]. Domestic demand, including
consumption demand and investment demand, is a core element of this process [
20
]. From
the perspective of consumption demand, Wang and Meng argue, from the perspective
of supply-side reform, that technological innovation promotes cultural consumption in
China [
21
], while Xu and Song find that corporate innovation behavior positively drives
consumer behavior [
22
]. Wang also points out, from the perspective of rural service indus-
tries, that innovative service formats have a significant positive impact on consumption
upgrading [
23
]. From the perspective of investment demand, Ye, starting from the mi-
cro perspective of manufacturing enterprises, finds that enterprises with higher levels of
technological innovation bring about greater investment demand [24].
(3)
Innovation’s Spatial Externality on Domestic Demand
Although the mechanism by which innovation promotes domestic demand is widely
recognized, there has not been in-depth research on the spatial externality of innovation
in promoting domestic demand. This indicates that, despite the valuable insights pro-
vided by the existing literature on the impact of innovation on China’s new development
pattern, there is still room for further exploration in this field. The existence of spatial
externality is mainly due to imperfect competition, increasing returns, financial externality
under market interaction, and market imperfections and coordination failures in spatial
economics. The spatial externality of domestic demand refers to the influence of domestic
demand in a local area on the domestic demand of surrounding areas during the expansion
process. In the research field of the spatial externality of consumption demand, scholars
have achieved a series of significant results covering various scenarios, demonstrating
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365 4 of 15
the impact and importance of the spatial externality of consumption demand in different
contexts. Firstly, Burlig’s research focuses on the spatial externality of groundwater ex-
traction in California agriculture, highlighting the critical role of externality in resource
management. This study not only reveals the potential impact of groundwater extraction
on surrounding regions but also provides empirical evidence for understanding spatial
externality in natural resource utilization [
25
]. Next, Ten Kate proposes an innovative
framework for understanding the dynamics of consumer demand in bilateral markets. By
modeling the externality between customer groups and its impact on the demand and
price sensitivity of both sides of the market, this framework provides a new theoretical
perspective for analyzing consumer behavior in complex market structures [
26
]. Vitali’s
research focuses on how consumer information friction drives businesses to choose loca-
tions within a city. This study combines various data from Uganda’s clothing industry,
including transaction, customer, and mystery shopper data, revealing the significant role of
information friction in influencing market positioning and consumer decision-making [
27
].
Additionally, Cohen provides a theoretical and empirical framework focusing on measuring
and evaluating the impact of agglomeration economies and industry location decisions.
In particular, this research focuses on spillover effects related to knowledge or other types
of horizontal and vertical externality, providing profound insights into understanding
industry agglomeration and its mechanisms’ impact on the market [
28
]. Zhang and Liu
use the spatial Durbin model to study the impact of specialization and diversification
agglomeration in the service industry on consumption structure. They find that both forms
of agglomeration show a significant positive correlation with consumption structure in
space, providing important empirical evidence for understanding the impact of service
industry development on consumer behavior [
29
]. Finally, Qi and Zhang’s research focuses
on the impact of the common prosperity goal on China, specifically the spatial spillover
effects of consumption growth in the initially prosperous regions on the consumption
growth rate in the later prosperous regions. This finding emphasizes the impact of regional
development imbalances on consumption demand, providing an important perspective for
understanding and addressing regional economic disparities [
30
]. Overall, these studies
deepen our understanding of the spatial externality of consumption demand from multiple
perspectives and offer valuable insights for policy-making and business strategies.
Regarding the research on the spatial externality of investment demand, another
group of scholars has achieved certain research results. Bertinelli’s study tests the positive
spatial autocorrelation of R&D investment and how the local environment influences firms’
decisions in R&D investment [
31
]. Häckner’s research extends the Hotelling spatial duopoly
competition model to include R&D investment, analyzing how cost reduction through
individual investment and spillover effects from competitors affect firms’ location choices
and agglomeration [
32
]. Bode employs the System Generalized Method of Moments (GMM)
estimation method to consider the potential endogeneity and spatial lags of foreign direct
investment. Using data from U.S. states from 1977 to 2003, the results indicate positive
external effects from foreign direct investment, while domestic firms’ external effects are
negative [
33
]. In summary, the existing research results indicate the existence of spatial
externality in China’s consumption and investment demands. However, the mechanisms
through which innovation influences the spatial externality of domestic demand still need
further clarification, and specific mechanisms need to be constructed. Additionally, the
above-mentioned studies have not examined the spatial externality of China’s domestic
demand from the perspective of the new development pattern. Based on this, building
on existing research outcomes, this paper may contribute by: (1) examining the spatial
externality of China’s domestic demand under innovation from a spatial econometrics
perspective. Compared to existing research, this paper (2) enriches theoretical achievements
and empirically verifies the promoting role of innovation in constructing a domestic large
cycle when examining the spatial externality of domestic demand, further refining the
concept of domestic demand, systematically explaining the promoting effect of innovation
on consumption and investment demands, and constructing a theoretical model that
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365 5 of 15
expands the research perspectives and models of both, thus broadening the understanding
of the interaction between innovation and domestic demand expansion.
3. Theoretical Modeling
The new double-cycle development pattern is an economic modernization strategy,
characterized by innovation-driven unimpeded economic circulation, with scientific and
technological self-reliance and independent innovation as its essential features. In August
2020, General Secretary Xi Jinping emphasized the urgent need to strengthen our capacity
for independent innovation and achieve breakthroughs in key core technologies as soon as
possible. This is a major issue related to the overall situation of our country’s development
and it is also the key to the formation of a domestic macrocycle as the main body. The above
discussion provides a theoretical basis for this paper to construct an evolutionary model of
regional innovation and domestic general circulation. Regional innovation capacity serves
as a basis for building a new development pattern. The specific theoretical model is shown
in Figure 1.
Sustainability 2024, 16, x FOR PEER REVIEW 5 of 15
constructing a domestic large cycle when examining the spatial externality of domestic
demand, further rening the concept of domestic demand, systematically explaining the
promoting eect of innovation on consumption and investment demands, and construct-
ing a theoretical model that expands the research perspectives and models of both, thus
broadening the understanding of the interaction between innovation and domestic de-
mand expansion.
3. Theoretical Modeling
The new double-cycle development paern is an economic modernization strategy,
characterized by innovation-driven unimpeded economic circulation, with scientic and
technological self-reliance and independent innovation as its essential features. In August
2020, General Secretary Xi Jinping emphasized the urgent need to strengthen our capacity
for independent innovation and achieve breakthroughs in key core technologies as soon
as possible. This is a major issue related to the overall situation of our country’s develop-
ment and it is also the key to the formation of a domestic macrocycle as the main body.
The above discussion provides a theoretical basis for this paper to construct an evolution-
ary model of regional innovation and domestic general circulation. Regional innovation
capacity serves as a basis for building a new development paern. The specic theoretical
model is shown in Figure 1.
Figure 1. Theoretical model of regional innovation impact on domestic demand.
The new economic geography believes that current regional economic activities have
surpassed the traditional assumption in theories where interregional trade transportation
costs are zero. It considers the existence of transportation costs and spatial spillovers in
interregional economic activities. That is, the development of transportation infrastruc-
ture will not only aect the local economy but also have an impact on surrounding areas
along the transportation infrastructure network. Therefore, only by comprehensively con-
sidering the eects of economic activities on both the local area and surrounding areas
can the operational mode of economic activities be more fully revealed. As shown in Fig-
ure 1, within the theoretical framework of the impact of regional innovation on domestic
demand, the operational mode of regional innovation includes the impact on both domes-
tic demand in the local area and domestic demand in surrounding areas through spatial
externalities. This impact is based on the high-level development of Chinas transporta-
tion infrastructure. The impact of the improvement in regional innovation capacity on do-
mestic demand in the local area can be examined from both the supply side and the de-
mand side. On the supply side, innovation activities expand the market size by providing
new products to the market, nurturing the industrial chain, and strengthening the real
economy, laying the foundation for building a unied domestic market and providing
impetus for promoting internal circulation. On the demand side, innovation increases res-
idents’ income levels and utilizes China’s advantage of having the world’s largest middle-
income group, unleashing the huge potential of China’s domestic demand market. Under
Figure 1. Theoretical model of regional innovation impact on domestic demand.
The new economic geography believes that current regional economic activities have
surpassed the traditional assumption in theories where interregional trade transportation
costs are zero. It considers the existence of transportation costs and spatial spillovers in
interregional economic activities. That is, the development of transportation infrastructure
will not only affect the local economy but also have an impact on surrounding areas along
the transportation infrastructure network. Therefore, only by comprehensively considering
the effects of economic activities on both the local area and surrounding areas can the
operational mode of economic activities be more fully revealed. As shown in Figure 1,
within the theoretical framework of the impact of regional innovation on domestic demand,
the operational mode of regional innovation includes the impact on both domestic demand
in the local area and domestic demand in surrounding areas through spatial externalities.
This impact is based on the high-level development of China’s transportation infrastructure.
The impact of the improvement in regional innovation capacity on domestic demand in
the local area can be examined from both the supply side and the demand side. On the
supply side, innovation activities expand the market size by providing new products to
the market, nurturing the industrial chain, and strengthening the real economy, laying the
foundation for building a unified domestic market and providing impetus for promoting
internal circulation. On the demand side, innovation increases residents’ income levels and
utilizes China’s advantage of having the world’s largest middle-income group, unleashing
the huge potential of China’s domestic demand market. Under the dual effects of the
supply side and the demand side, consumption demand and investment demand in China
are driven to expand, ultimately leading to the expansion of domestic demand in the local
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365 6 of 15
area. Meanwhile, due to the rapid development of China’s transportation infrastructure,
the costs of the cross-regional flow of various production and innovation factors have
been significantly reduced. Therefore, when domestic demand in surrounding areas
cannot be met by the local market, it will spread to surrounding areas to seek release
channels. The products provided by local innovation activities and the increased income
not only meet the domestic demand of the local area but also provide direction for the
release of domestic demand in surrounding areas. That is, the improvement in local
innovation capacity spreads along interregional transportation networks to surrounding
areas, generating externalities for domestic demand in surrounding areas. In summary,
within the framework of new economic geography, considering the combined impact of
regional innovation on domestic demand in both the local area and surrounding areas
helps to more comprehensively reveal the spatial externalities of innovation demand.
4. Research Design
4.1. Selection of Variables
Explained variable: Domestic demand (DD) serves as the foundation of the domestic
macrocycle, aiming to unleash the potential of China’s domestic demand and achieve
high-quality economic development. During benchmark regression analysis, the level of
regional GDP is utilized to represent the level of domestic demand. Furthermore, in the
mechanism test, consumption demand and investment demand are examined separately
to assess the mechanism of promoting domestic demand through innovation capacity.
Consumption demand (cons) is quantified by per capita consumption expenditure, while
investment demand (invest) is quantified by social investment in fixed assets.
Explanatory variable: This study focuses on regional innovation (inno) and its rela-
tionship with internal circulation. Within the framework of the new development pattern,
innovation stimulates internal circulation by introducing new products to the market.
As such, the sales of new products are used to assess regional innovation capacity, with
technology market turnover serving as the measurement.
Control variables: Various factors influence the construction of the domestic macro-
cycle, including the impact of the foreign cycle. Import and export levels (inandout) are
measured by the total import and export volumes of each province, while foreign direct
investment (FDI) levels are determined by the amount of FDI in each province. Urbaniza-
tion levels (urban) are quantified by the proportion of the urban population to the total
population at the end of each province’s year, and government support levels (gov) are
assessed by each province’s government’s financial expenditures.
4.2. Data Sources and Processing
A sample of 31 provinces (autonomous regions and municipalities directly under the
central government) in China from 2011 to 2020 was selected, excluding Hong Kong, Macao,
and Taiwan. Meanwhile, to ensure the authenticity of the data, the study adopts all the data
from the China Statistical Yearbook of each year, and part of the missing data is made up
by looking up the Provincial Statistical Yearbook of each province in that year, as well as by
using the linear interpolation method. Given the varied sources of data acquisition in this
paper, both the scale and significance differ. Therefore, to calculate the levels of common
prosperity and high-quality economic development, normalization is necessary to eliminate
differences in the quantitative representation of each indicator. The data normalization
formula is presented in the following equation:
a
xy =
axy min
xaxy
max
xaxy min
xaxy
×99 +1 (1)
4.3. Description of Spatial Matrix
The first theorem of geography posits a correlation among all phenomena, with
proximity generally indicating stronger correlations. Therefore, in spatial measurement
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365 7 of 15
research, it is common practice to establish a spatial weight matrix to quantify the distances
between phenomena. This paper adopts the adjacency matrix, geographic distance matrix,
and economic distance matrix as the spatial weighting matrices for empirical research,
respectively. The adjacency matrix considers that there is a connection between subjects
with common boundaries or vertices, and there is no connection between subjects without
common boundaries or vertices.
The specific elements of the matrix are set, as shown in Table 1below:
Table 1. Spatial weight matrix.
Matrix Name Element Setting Explanation
Adjacency Matri (w1)If there is a common border between province iand
province j, the element is set to 1; otherwise, it is set to 0.
When i=j,wij = 0
Geographic Distance Matrix (w2)The reciprocal of the geographic distance between
province iand province j.
Economic Distance Matrix (w3)The reciprocal of the absolute difference in GDP
between province iand province jin the current year.
4.4. Spatial Correlation Test
To test the spatial autocorrelation of China’s domestic demand, this paper selects the
domestic cycles of 31 provinces (cities and districts) in China from 2011 to 2020, which are
discriminated by Moran’s Iindex with the following formula:
Iict=
n×n
i=1n
j=1wij iciticicjtic
n
i=1n
j=1wij n
i=1icitic2(2)
Formula,
Iict
represents the Moran’s Iindex of domestic demand in 31 provinces (cities
and districts) of China in year t;t= 2011, 2012, . . ., 2020.
i, j are defined as above.
wij
represents the elements of the spatial matrix for province i
and province j. The element settings are shown in Table 1, and
ic
represents the average of
the domestic demand in each province in year t. The results of the Moran’s Iindex test for
domestic demand for each year are shown in Table 2below:
Table 2. Moran’s Iindex of domestic demand in China for each year.
Year
Adjacency Matrix
w1
Geographic Distance Matrix
w2
Economic Distance Matrix
w3
IZp I Zp I Zp
2011 0.279 2.816 0.002 0.037 2.108 0.018 0.227 3.219 0.001
2012 0.275 2.776 0.003 0.036 2.075 0.019 0.227 3.210 0.001
2013 0.275 2.776 0.003 0.035 2.061 0.020 0.224 3.186 0.001
2014 0.275 2.783 0.003 0.035 2.060 0.020 0.215 3.078 0.001
2015 0.282 2.846 0.002 0.036 2.102 0.018 0.204 2.944 0.002
2016 0.296 2.985 0.001 0.041 2.241 0.013 0.146 2.232 0.013
2017 0.296 2.987 0.001 0.041 2.265 0.012 0.135 2.102 0.018
2018 0.295 2.976 0.001 0.043 2.306 0.011 0.312 2.062 0.020
2019 0.309 3.101 0.001 0.056 2.697 0.003 0.112 1.805 0.036
2020 0.312 3.135 0.001 0.055 2.685 0.004 0.110 1.791 0.037
As shown in Table 2, Moran’s Iindex, calculated with three kinds of spatial weight
matrices, is significantly positive, indicating that there is a positive spatial correlation in
China’s domestic demand, i.e., the domestic demand of each region shows a “high-high”
agglomeration or “low-low” agglomeration, and the gap in the domestic demand between
the neighboring regions is relatively small. In this case, the Moran’s Iindex calculated by
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365 8 of 15
constructing a spatial matrix based on geographic location criteria increased over time,
and the Moran’s Iindex calculated by constructing a spatial weighting matrix based on
the level of economic development decreased slightly over time. This shows that in recent
years, economic exchanges among regions in China have predominantly been influenced
by geographic proximity. Closer geographic distances between regions correlate with
more frequent exchanges, leading to a decreased significance of inter-regional economic
disparities in these exchanges.
4.5. Model Setup
This paper sets up the spatial measurement model as follows:
ic =α0+β0×innoit +β1×w×innoit +δ0×Cit +δ1×w×Cit +µi+θt+λit (3)
In Equation (3), ic is the explanatory variable; inno is the explanatory variable,
β0
is the
coefficient of the explanatory variable, and
β1
is the spatial coefficient of the explanatory
variable; wis the spatial weight matrix; Cis the control variable,
δ0
is the control variable
coefficient, and
δ1
is the control variable spatial coefficient;
µi
stands for individual fixed
effects;
θt
stands for time fixed effects; and
λit
stands for double fixed effects. In practical
tests, specific spatial econometric models also need to be identified through Wald tests and
LM tests.
5. Model Regression and Analysis of Results
5.1. Model Selection
The presence of spatial effects was first determined by the LM test and Robust LM test,
and the use of the spatial Durbin model was determined by the Wald test. The results of
the tests are shown in Table 3.
Table 3. Spatial econometric model selection results.
Test Statistic W1 W2 W3
Test Value p-Value Test Value p-Value Test Value p-Value
LM Error 0.186 0.666 0.221 0.638 0.204 0.651
Robust LM Error 0.280 0.597 0.725 0.394 7.266 0.007
LM Lag 6.844 0.009 3.349 0.067 5.340 0.021
Robust LM Lag 6.937 0.008 3.853 0.050 12.402 0.000
Wald Spatial Lag 23.37 0.0015 47.52 0.0000 58.21 0.0000
Wald Spatial Error
124.78 0.0000 39.28 0.0000 37.66 0.0000
From Table 2above, the comprehensive three spatial weight matrix results, the LM
test, and the Robust LM test indicate that spatial econometric analysis should be carried
out, and the Wald test results indicate that the test results of the spatial lag model and
spatial error model satisfy the requirement of 1% significance, i.e., spatial Durbin model
will not degenerate into the spatial lag model and spatial error model; therefore, this paper
chooses the spatial Durbin model to test the data.
5.2. Baseline Regression Results
The results of benchmark regression are shown in Table 4below.
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365 9 of 15
Table 4. Spatial Durbin model benchmark regression results.
Variables
W1 W2 W3
SDM SDM SDM
DD DD DD
Inno 0.1811 ***
(0.0321)
0.1813 ***
(0.0328)
0.1081***
(0.0333)
Inandout 0.1765 ***
(0.0619)
0.1706 ***
(0.0594)
0.2295 ***
(0.0617)
Fdi 0.0451 ***
(0.0103)
0.0442 ***
(0.0104)
0.0190 *
(0.0109)
Urban 0.3334 ***
(0.0680)
0.2409 ***
(0.6677)
0.3604 ***
(0.0709)
Gov 0.6064 ***
(0.0313)
0.6519 ***
(0.0298)
0.6585 ***
(0.0322)
W×Inno 0.1161 *
(0.0631)
0.4085 **
(0.2007)
0.2565 **
(0.1052)
W×Inandout 0.2389 **
(0.1138)
0.5501 *
(0.3222)
0.2284
(0.1647)
W×Fdi 0.0678 ***
(0.0207)
0.0660
(0.0669)
0.0602 **
(0.0248)
W×Urban 0.2698 ***
(0.0932)
0.0328
(0.3789)
0.9321 ***
(0.2109)
W×gov 0.2462 ***
(0.0857)
1.5310 ***
(0.2757)
0.0298
(0.1531)
ϱ0.1156
(0.0777)
0.2808
(0.2232)
0.2284 **
(0.1095)
σ23.4777 ***
(0.2783)
3.3262 ***
(0.2651)
3.5222 ***
(0.2838)
Fixed/Random Fixed Fixed Fixed
OBS 310 310 310
R20.7222 0.6299 0.6300
Note: *, **, and *** indicate that the variables are significant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively, with
standard errors in parentheses. W1 is the adjacency matrix, W2 is the geographic distance matrix, and W3 is the
economic distance matrix, as follows.
As shown in Table 4, the regression results of the model using the adjacency matrix
and the geographic distance matrix as the spatial weight matrix show that the coefficient
of the impact of innovation on the promotion effect of domestic demand in the region is
significantly positive at the 1% level. In contrast, the coefficient of the spatial spillover
effect of innovation on domestic demand is negative.
The results show that innovation significantly contributes to the level of domestic
demand in the region under the conditions of the adjacency matrix and the geographic
distance matrix as a spatial weighting matrix, while innovative activities in the neighboring
regions have a certain inhibiting effect on the domestic demand in the region. For the
economic distance matrix, it can be seen that the promotion effect of innovation on domestic
demand is significantly positive at the 1% level, and innovation significantly enhances the
level of domestic demand in the region, while the coefficient of the spatial spillover effect
of innovation on domestic demand meets the requirement of significance and is positive,
which indicates that the innovation behavior of the surrounding areas also has a significant
effect on the promotion of the level of domestic demand in the region.
The above results show that when the spatial externality of innovation on domestic
demand is measured by geographic location, the spatial externality of innovation on
domestic demand is negative under the adjacency matrix and the geographic distance
matrix, because when the innovation results of the region have a positive effect on the
domestic demand of the region, they will generate spatial spillover effects along the
transportation network to the surrounding regions, attracting the domestic demand of the
surrounding regions to be transferred to the region, thereby inhibiting the domestic demand
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365 10 of 15
of the surrounding regions, which mainly unfolds along the transportation infrastructure
network.
When economic development levels serve as the spatial weighting matrix, inter-
regional exchanges primarily depend on economic development levels. Closer exchanges
occur between regions with similar economic development levels. Innovation drives
domestic demand expansion within regions, attracting the introduction of innovative
technologies from similarly developed regions, thus further stimulating domestic demand.
5.3. Decomposition of Spatial Effects
The analysis results indicate that innovation plays a significant role in promoting
domestic demand within a region, and there is considerable spatial externality present.
Here, partial differential equations are used to further calculate the direct, indirect, and total
effects of innovation on domestic demand. Due to space constraints, only the decomposed
effects under the economic distance matrix are listed, as shown in Table 5.
Table 5. Spatial effects decomposition.
Variables Direct Effect Indirect Effect Total Effect
W3 W3 W3
Inno 0.1020 ***
(0.0341)
0.2045 **
(0.0928)
0.3065 ***
(0.1004)
Inandout 0.2212 ***
(0.0596)
0.1399
(0.1398)
0.3611 **
(0.1516)
Fdi 0.0198 *
(0.0106)
0.0546 ***
(0.0209)
0.0349
(0.0231)
Urban 0.3909 ***
(0.0702)
0.8455 ***
(0.1819)
0.4545 ***
(0.1703)
Gov 0.6623 ***
(0.0298)
0.1033
(0.0951)
0.5590 ***
(0.1060)
Note: *, **, and *** signify that the variables are significant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively, with
standard errors in parentheses. W1 represents the adjacency matrix, W2 is the geographic distance matrix, and
W3 is the economic distance matrix, as stated below.
From the perspective of the core explanatory variables, the direct effect coefficient of
regional innovation is 0.1020, which is significant at the 1% confidence level, indicating
that innovation significantly promotes domestic demand in the region. The indirect effect
coefficient of regional innovation is 0.2045, which is significant at the 5% confidence level,
suggesting that innovation also has significant spatial externality on the domestic demand
of surrounding areas. Further analysis reveals that the total effect coefficient of regional
innovation is 0.3065, with the spillover effect of innovation on domestic demand accounting
for 66.92% of the total effect, indicating that the indirect effects are predominant. The spatial
spillover effect of innovation on domestic demand should be taken into account.
In terms of control variables, the direct effects of the levels of import/export, urban-
ization, and government policy are 0.2212, 0.3909, and 0.6623, respectively, which are all
significant at the 1% confidence level, indicating that all three also significantly promote
domestic demand in the region. However, the direct effect coefficient of the level of exter-
nal investment is
0.0198, which is significant at the 10% level, suggesting a significant
inhibitory effect on domestic demand. The indirect effect coefficient for the level of external
investment is 0.0546, which is significant at the 1% level, indicating significant spatial exter-
nality on the domestic demand of neighboring areas. The indirect effect coefficients for the
levels of import/export and government policy are 0.1399 and
0.1033, respectively, with
no significant indirect effects. The total effect coefficients for the levels of import/export
and government policy are 0.3611 and 0.5590, respectively, with both predominantly con-
tributed by direct effects, where the level of import/export accounts for 61.26% of the total
effect, indicating that the direct impact of import/export levels and government policy on
domestic demand should be considered. The total effect coefficient for urbanization level is
0.4545, with the indirect effects being predominant, suggesting that the inhibitory effect
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365 11 of 15
of urbanization level on the spatial spillover of domestic demand should be considered.
The total effect coefficient for the level of external investment is 0.0349, but it not significant,
indicating that the direct effects are predominant (Figure 2).
Sustainability 2024, 16, x FOR PEER REVIEW 11 of 15
level is 0.4545, with the indirect eects being predominant, suggesting that the inhibitory
eect of urbanization level on the spatial spillover of domestic demand should be consid-
ered. The total eect coecient for the level of external investment is 0.0349, but it not
signicant, indicating that the direct eects are predominant (Figure 2).
Figure 2. Spatial eects decomposition.
5.4. Mechanism Testing
To further illustrate the promotion mechanism of innovation on domestic demand,
this paper renes the concept of domestic demand into consumption demand and invest-
ment demand and examines the promotion eect of innovation on consumption demand
and investment demand, respectively.
The results of the mechanism test are presented in Table 6.
Table 6. Spatial Durbin model mechanism test results.
Variables
W1 W2 W3 W1 W2 W3
SDM SDM SDM SDM SDM SDM
Cons Cons Cons Invest Invest Invest
Inno 0.1441 ***
(0.0281)
0.1653 ***
(0.0309)
0.0674 **
(0.0315)
0.0670
(0.0610)
0.0150
(0.0629)
0.1265 *
(0.0651)
Inandout 0.13905 ***
(0.0523)
0.1480 ***
(0.0544)
0.2257 ***
(0.0586)
0.1583
(0.1123)
0.1881 *
(0.1077)
0.1778
(0.1223)
Fdi 0.0128
(0.0089)
0.0228 **
(0.0097)
0.0161
(0.0102)
0.1338 ***
(0.0191)
0.1407 ***
(0.0190)
0.0916 ***
(0.0211)
Urban 0.6636 ***
(0.0591)
0.7631 ***
(0.0613)
0.6577 ***
(0.0678)
1.2157 ***
(0.1268)
1.2986 ***
(0.1211)
0.6458 ***
(0.1427)
Gov 0.0154
(0.0388)
0.0017
(0.0444)
0.0295
(0.0113)
0.5302 ***
(0.0829)
0.5106 ***
(0.0874)
0.3056 ***
(0.0954)
W×nno 0.0009
(0.0568)
0.1905
(0.1824)
0.3865 ***
(0.0973)
0.7334 ***
(0.1130)
2.4150 ***
(0.3598)
0.0376
(0.2033)
W×Inandout 0.0577
(0.0984)
0.1970
(0.2990)
0.0680
(0.1550)
0.6354 ***
(0.2112)
1.3379 **
(0.5913)
0.2310
(0.3223)
W×Fdi 0.0345 **
(0.0177)
0.2591 ***
(0.0616)
0.0368
(0.0232)
0.0371
(0.0384)
0.0517
(0.1208)
0.1186 **
(0.0512)
W×Urban 0.1641 ** 0.3549 0.4432 ** 0.7182 *** 0.4316 0.3242
Figure 2. Spatial effects decomposition.
5.4. Mechanism Testing
To further illustrate the promotion mechanism of innovation on domestic demand, this
paper refines the concept of domestic demand into consumption demand and investment
demand and examines the promotion effect of innovation on consumption demand and
investment demand, respectively.
The results of the mechanism test are presented in Table 6.
The results of the economic distance matrix regression are analyzed here, since the
level of model fit is better under the economic distance matrix. The regression results with
consumption demand as the explanatory variable show that the enhancement of innovation
ability significantly promotes the level of consumption demand in the region, and from the
perspective of spatial spillover effect, the spatial lag coefficient
ϱ
passes the test of the 1%
significance level and is positive, which indicates that there is significant positive spatial
externality in inter-regional consumption demand, and there is a significant spatial spillover
effect of innovation on consumption demand. The reason for this is that when innovative
behavior in the region produces innovative results, on the one hand, it will provide high-
quality products to the local market and stimulate the consumption demand of the region’s
residents. On the other hand, the benefits brought by the output of innovation results
will raise the income level of the residents and increase the consumption enthusiasm
of the residents in the region. This leads to the expansion of consumer demand in the
region, both in terms of product supply and market demand. The spatial externalities of
innovation on consumer demand come mainly from the cross-regional sales of innovations;
when innovations are sold in markets outside the region through transportation networks,
they push to unleash the potential of domestic demand in neighboring regions, which,
in turn, expands domestic demand in neighboring regions. With investment demand
as the explanatory variable, innovation has a dampening effect on regional investment
demand, and the spatial coefficient of innovation turns out to be insignificant. This may
be because the innovation process requires a large amount of capital and manpower,
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365 12 of 15
among other innovative factors. Therefore, when the innovation capacity of the local area
improves, it will obtain high-quality innovation resources from various aspects through
China’s transportation infrastructure, rather than just obtaining single innovation resources
from the local area. Therefore, innovation will, to some extent, suppress local investment
demand while also generating negative spatial externalities for investment behavior in
surrounding areas.
Table 6. Spatial Durbin model mechanism test results.
Variables
W1 W2 W3 W1 W2 W3
SDM SDM SDM SDM SDM SDM
Cons Cons Cons Invest Invest Invest
Inno 0.1441 ***
(0.0281)
0.1653 ***
(0.0309)
0.0674 **
(0.0315)
0.0670
(0.0610)
0.0150
(0.0629)
0.1265 *
(0.0651)
Inandout 0.13905 ***
(0.0523)
0.1480 ***
(0.0544)
0.2257 ***
(0.0586)
0.1583
(0.1123)
0.1881 *
(0.1077)
0.1778
(0.1223)
Fdi 0.0128
(0.0089)
0.0228 **
(0.0097)
0.0161
(0.0102)
0.1338 ***
(0.0191)
0.1407 ***
(0.0190)
0.0916 ***
(0.0211)
Urban 0.6636 ***
(0.0591)
0.7631 ***
(0.0613)
0.6577 ***
(0.0678)
1.2157 ***
(0.1268)
1.2986 ***
(0.1211)
0.6458 ***
(0.1427)
Gov 0.0154
(0.0388)
0.0017
(0.0444)
0.0295
(0.0113)
0.5302 ***
(0.0829)
0.5106 ***
(0.0874)
0.3056 ***
(0.0954)
W×nno 0.0009
(0.0568)
0.1905
(0.1824)
0.3865 ***
(0.0973)
0.7334 ***
(0.1130)
2.4150 ***
(0.3598)
0.0376
(0.2033)
W
×
Inandout
0.0577
(0.0984)
0.1970
(0.2990)
0.0680
(0.1550)
0.6354 ***
(0.2112)
1.3379 **
(0.5913)
0.2310
(0.3223)
W×Fdi 0.0345 **
(0.0177)
0.2591 ***
(0.0616)
0.0368
(0.0232)
0.0371
(0.0384)
0.0517
(0.1208)
0.1186 **
(0.0512)
W×Urban 0.1641 **
(0.0765)
0.3549
(0.3575)
0.4432 **
(0.2134)
0.7182 ***
(0.1644)
0.4316
(0.6860)
0.3242
(0.4619)
W×gov 0.3964 ***
(0.0872)
0.8910 **
(0.3526)
0.3665 **
(0.1712)
0.4044 **
(0.1864)
1.0570
(0.7304)
0.5452
(0.3628)
ϱ0.4519 ***
(0.0800)
0.3334 **
(0.1663)
0.2833 ***
(0.0997)
0.0320
(0.0817)
0.6104 **
(0.2616)
0.5151 ***
(0.1197)
σ22.4034 ***
(0.1982)
2.6842 ***
(0.2175)
2.9521 ***
(0.2416)
10.9567 ***
0.8813
10.4831 ***
(0.8451)
12.8695 ***
(1.0553)
Fixed/Random
Fixed Fixed Fixed Fixed Fixed Fixed
OBS 310 310 310 310 310 310
R20.5468 0.4299 0.6920 0.7398 0.6621 0.7615
Note: *, **, and *** indicate that the variables are significant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively, with
standard errors in parentheses, W1 is the adjacency matrix, W2 is the geographic distance matrix, and W3 is the
economic distance matrix.
In summary, innovation not only significantly promotes local consumption demand
but also generates significant spatial externalities for consumption demand in surrounding
areas. As for investment demand, innovation suppresses local investment demand, failing
to meet significant requirements for investment demand in surrounding areas.
6. Conclusions and Recommendations
6.1. Conclusions of the Study
The construction of a new development pattern of a double cycle, with “the domestic
macrocycle as the main focus and the domestic and international double cycle promoting
each other”, provides a suitable narrative background for the study of the influence mecha-
nism and spatial externality between regional innovation and domestic demand. Based on
absorbing the existing theoretical results on innovation and domestic demand, this paper
elaborates on the interactive mechanism of innovation to promote the spatial externality
of domestic demand from a macro perspective and constructs a theoretical model. At the
same time, using the spatial panel data of 31 provinces (cities and districts) in China from
2011 to 2020, the spatial Durbin model is used to carry out empirical tests and decompose
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365 13 of 15
its spatial spillover effects. Finally, the mechanism of innovation to promote the expansion
of domestic demand is tested.
The main conclusions are as follows: (1) theoretical research in new economic geog-
raphy indicates that innovation plays a dual role in boosting China’s domestic demand.
On the supply side, innovation drives internal circulation by introducing new products to
the market. On the demand side, it stimulates domestic demand by increasing population
income. Furthermore, innovation and domestic demand generate spatial externalities
in neighboring regions through spatial spillovers; (2) the empirical results demonstrate
that innovative behavior significantly stimulates domestic demand expansion within the
region under all three spatial weight matrices. While the adjacency matrix and geographic
distance matrix exhibit a certain inhibitory effect of innovation on neighboring regions’
domestic demand, the economic distance matrix shows a significant promotional effect of
innovation on neighboring regions’ domestic demand; (3) analyzing the spatial spillover
effect of innovation on domestic demand, the results reveal that the indirect effect, termed
spatial externality, contributes 66.92% to the total effect. This suggests that spatial spillover
plays a significant role in promoting domestic demand and warrants further emphasis in
research; (4) through the refinement of domestic demand into consumption demand and
investment demand and research on the mechanism of innovation to promote domestic
demand, the results show that the promotion effect of innovation on domestic demand is
mainly realized through consumption demand, and innovation has a significant promotion
effect on the consumption demand of the region and the surrounding areas, while innova-
tion has a certain inhibitory effect on the investment demand of the region, and the effect
on the investment demand of the surrounding areas is not significant. Overall, innovation
promotes the spatial externality of our domestic demand, which in turn has a positive effect
on our domestic demand.
6.2. Policy Recommendations
1.
Adhering to the innovation-driven development strategy: Continuously shaping new
momentum for development by adhering to the central position of innovation in
the overall situation of China’s modernization, we will enhance people’s well-being
through innovation, upgrade the industrial chain, ensure the stability of China’s
supply chain, provide the sustained impetus for China’s economic development, pro-
mote the expansion of domestic demand through the enhancement of the capacity for
innovation, and provide favorable support for the construction of a new development
pattern of the “double cycle”.
2.
Continuing to actively build a new development pattern that “focuses on the domestic
cycle”: Grasping the dominant position of the domestic cycle in the double cycle
and insisting on the expansion of domestic demand as the basis for development.
Governments at all levels and in all parts of the world, in the process of realizing the
expansion of domestic demand, will not only have a positive impact on the region but
also have a positive effect on neighboring regions. Specifically, governments should
face up to the differences in development between regions and implement innovative
strategies to promote the expansion of domestic demand in the region according to
local conditions, such as for the eastern region, because the level of innovation and
domestic demand have a great advantage over inland regions, so it is necessary to
pay attention to the spatial externality that arises from the process of expanding the
region’s domestic demand to promote the realization of the expansion of the inland
region’s domestic demand through spatial spillover effects.
3.
Emphasize the centrality of consumer demand to domestic demand: Although do-
mestic demand consists of consumption demand and investment demand, in practice,
the expansion of domestic demand is mainly realized through consumption demand,
so in the process of building the domestic cycle in the future, we should actively grasp
the role of consumption demand for the domestic cycle, taking advantage of the fact
that our country has the world’s largest middle-income group, and focus on unleash-
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365 14 of 15
ing China’s huge potential for domestic demand and realizing a two-way drive of the
demand side and the supply side through consumption demand to ultimately help
China’s domestic demand expansion.
7. Limitations of the Study and Future Research Directions
This study investigates the impact of regional innovation on China’s domestic demand,
facing limitations due to data availability only up to 2020. This restricts our ability to ana-
lyze recent global economic shifts and their influences comprehensively. While employing
provincial panel data and the spatial Durbin model offers a substantial overview, it may
not entirely encapsulate the intricate dynamics and externalities associated with regional
innovation. Future research should aim to broaden the temporal and spatial scope of
analysis, integrate more varied datasets, and delve into the implications of digitalization
and technological progress on innovation ecosystems. Furthermore, conducting compara-
tive analyses across diverse economic and policy landscapes would greatly enhance our
understanding of the universal relevance and consequences of our findings, facilitating
a deeper and more detailed perspective on the role of regional innovation in economic
development globally.
Author Contributions: Writing—original draft, Y.S.; Writing—review & editing, Y.J., C.X. and C.L.
All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding: This research was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Youth
Fund) Project (grant number 70901065).
Institutional Review Board Statement: Not applicable.
Informed Consent Statement: Not applicable.
Data Availability Statement: The data presented in this study are available on request from the
corresponding author.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.
References
1. Barro, R.J. Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogeneous Growth. J. Political Econ. 1990,98, S103–S125. [CrossRef]
2. Romer; Paul, M. Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth. J. Political Econ. 1986,94, 1002–1037. [CrossRef]
3.
Ding, H. What kinds of countries have better innovation performance?–A country-level fsQCA and NCA study. J. Innov. Knowl.
2022,7, 100215. [CrossRef]
4.
Chi, M.; Muhammad, S.; Khan, Z.; Ali, S.; Li, R.Y.M. Is centralization killing innovation? The success story of technological
innovation in fiscally decentralized countries. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2021,168, 120731. [CrossRef]
5.
Mao, Y.; Yu, X. A hybrid forecasting approach for China’s national carbon emission allowance prices with balanced accuracy and
interpretability. J. Environ. Manag. 2024,351, 119873. [CrossRef]
6.
Afrifa, G.A.; Tingbani, I.; Yamoah, F.; Appiah, G. Innovation input, governance and climate change: Evidence from emerging
countries. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2020,161, 120256. [CrossRef]
7.
Xie, C.; Li, H.; Chen, L. A Three-Party Decision Evolution Game Analysis of Coal Companies and Miners under China’s
Government Safety Special Rectification Action. Mathematics 2023,11, 4750. [CrossRef]
8.
Litina, A.; Makridis, C.A.; Tsiachtsiras, G. Do product market reforms raise innovation? Evidence from Micro-data across
12 countries. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2021,169, 120841. [CrossRef]
9.
Shi, Y.; Zhang, T.; Jiang, Y. Digital Economy, Technological Innovation and Urban Resilience. Sustainability 2023,15, 9250.
[CrossRef]
10.
Jiang, X.; Meng, L. Mainly Inner Circulation, Outer Circulation Empowerment and Higher Level Double Circulation: International
Experience and Chinese Practice. Manag. World 2021,37, 31–36.
11.
Zhang, R. Thinking and Path of Constructing New Development Pattern of Double Circulation. Reg. Econ. Rev. 2020,6, 56–62.
[CrossRef]
12.
Wang, Y. Changes Unseen in a Century, High-Quality Development, and the Construction of a New Development Pattern. Manag.
World 2020,36, 14.
13. Weber, S. International political economy “after” the business cycle. J. Soc. Political Econ. Stud. 1996,21, 261.
14.
Campos, H. The quest for innovation: Addressing user needs and value creation. In The Innovation Revolution in Agriculture:
A Roadmap to Value Creation; Springer International Publishing: Cham, Switzerland, 2020; pp. 1–31.
Sustainability 2024,16, 2365 15 of 15
15.
Ru-Zhue, J.; Aujirapongpan, S.; Songkajorn, Y.; Jiraphanumes, K. The effect of technological organization on cost innovation and
value creation. Emerg. Sci. J. 2022,6, 322–336. [CrossRef]
16.
Jia, G. Independent innovation of capital goods industries: The key to the strategy of expanding domestic demand Jia Genliang.
Economist 2012,11, 8.
17.
Li, Z.; Zhao, C. Technological Innovation Driven Conditions under the New Development Paradigm of Dual Circulation:
Interpretation, Misunderstandings, and Pathways. Theory J. 2021,1, 32–41.
18.
Qian, X.; Xiang, B. New Development Paradigm Featuring “Dual Circulation”and Innovation. J. Beijing Technol. Bus. Univ. Soc.
Sci. 2022,37, 10.
19.
Reng, B.; Gong, Y. Operating Mechanism and Realization Path of China’s New Development Pattern Under the New Economic
Background. J. Shaanxi Norm. Univ. Philos. Soc. Sci. Ed. 2021,050, 57–64.
20. Zhang, Q. Give Mature Consideration to All Aspects for Expanding Internal Demands. Ind. Eng. J. 2000,3, 1–5.
21.
Wang, M.; Meng, C. The Interactive Mechanism of Scientific and Technological Innovation and Cultural Consumption and Its
Influence on the Transformation and Upgrading of Cultural Industry—An Analysis Based on Supply-side Reform. Tax. Econ.
2019,2, 6.
22.
Xu, H.; Song, Q. Driving Influence of Context—Based Business Model Innovation on Consumption Behavior—Empirical Analysis
Based on Xiaomi Corporation. J. Harbin Univ. Commer. Soc. Sci. Ed. 2021,6, 12.
23.
Wang, J.; Liu, J.; Zhang, Y. Service Industry Innovation and Consumption Upgrading of Rural Residents: Driving Mechanism and
Empirical Test. J. Xi’an Univ. Financ. Econ. 2022,35, 90–102.
24.
Ye, J. Enterprise Technological Innovation and Choice of Foreign Direct Investment—An Analysis Based on the Listed Manufac-
turing Companies in China. J. Ind. Technol. Econ. 2022,41, 106–114.
25.
Burlig, F.; Preonas, L.; Woerman, M. Spatial Externalities in Groundwater Extraction: Evidence from California Agriculture; Working
Paper; American Economic Association: Nashville, TN, USA, 2020.
26.
Ten Kate, A.; Niels, G. Consumer demand in two-sided markets and the platform-specific nature of externalities. SSRN Electron. J.
2019. [CrossRef]
27.
Vitali, A. Consumer Search and Firm Location: Theory and Evidence from the Garment Sector in Uganda. Job Mark. Pap. 2022,1,
16.
28.
Cohen, J.P.; Morrison Paul, C.J. Agglomeration economies and industry location decisions: The impacts of vertical and horizontal
spillovers. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 2005,35, 215–237. [CrossRef]
29.
Zhang, J.; Liu, W. Spatial Spillover Perspective on Service Industry Agglomeration and Consumption Structure Upgrade in the
Yangtze River Economic Belt—An Empirical Analysis Based on Asymmetric Matrix. Jiangxi Soc. Sci. 2022,42, 136–144.
30.
Qi, H.; Zhang, J. Spatial Spillover Effect of the First Prosperous Regions’ Consumption Growth in the Process of Common
Prosperity. J. Xi’an Jiaotong Univ. Soc. Sci. 2022,42, 10–22. [CrossRef]
31.
Bertinelli, L.; Nicolini, R. Investment Decision and the Spatial Dimension: Evidence from Firm Level Data; Universite Catholique de
Louvain: Ottignies-Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium, 2002.
32.
Häckner, J. The Effects of R&D Externalities in a Spatial Model; IUI Working Paper; The Research Institute of Industrial Economics
(IUI): Stockholm, Sweden, 1990.
33.
Bode, E.; Nunnenkamp, P.; Waldkirch, A. Spatial effects of foreign direct investment in US states. Can. J. Econ. 2012,45, 16–40.
[CrossRef]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual
author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to
people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.
... Ma et al. [24] demonstrate that the development of smart cities has a positive effect on regional economic growth by stimulating urban innovation capacity and entrepreneurship, being essential in regions with a high market degree. Additionally, Shi et al. [25] emphasize the importance of innovation for sustainable growth, highlighting spatial externalities and their impact on domestic demand. On the other hand, Pusz et al. [26] analyze the circular economy from a social and relational perspective, highlighting the role of social enterprises in local socio-economic integration, particularly through the activities of reuse and upcycling. ...
Article
Full-text available
This study aims to address the persistent regional economic disparities in Romania by evaluating economic performance through Panel Autoregressive Distributed Lag (pARDL) and panel quantile regression (PQR) models. The analysis focuses on the impact of key economic variables, including research and development expenditures (CTCRD), IT infrastructures (IT), the number of universities (FCL), and the average number of employees (NMSP), on regional gross domestic product (GDPR). Using data from the Romanian National Institute of Statistics for the period 2003–2022, this research seeks to understand how targeted investments and policy interventions can stimulate growth and reduce inequalities across regions. The findings highlight the important role of R&D, IT infrastructures, and technological advancements in driving economic growth, especially in less developed areas. The study also emphasizes the importance of region-specific strategies in fostering sustainable growth, promoting economic resilience, and bridging the gap between more and less prosperous regions.
Article
Full-text available
Research on the behavior of coal companies and miners under the government’s safety special rectification action is significant for maintaining social stability. In this paper, we constructed a dynamic evolutionary game model involving the government, coal companies, and miners. We analyzed the asymptotic stability conditions of the behavioral strategies of the participants in the game through phase diagrams and conducted a simulation analysis using Matlab R2021b to explore the impact of the key parameters in the model on the strategic choices of the game participants. The research findings indicated: (1) intricate interactive dynamics exist among the three stakeholders in safety rectification endeavors, with diverse intervention strategies manifesting varying impacts on participants’ conduct and outcomes; (2) setting reasonable reward and punishment mechanisms for safety behaviors by the government toward coal companies and miners helps to increase the probability of both choosing proactive safety behaviors. Coal companies that set reasonable reward and punishment mechanisms for the safety behaviors of miners can promote miners’ willingness to cooperate. Additionally, reducing safety rectification costs and enhancing the social reputation benefits of safety rectification can facilitate the optimal strategic choices of the three parties; and (3) the simulation analysis results corroborate the conclusions on the stability of strategies across all stakeholders, affirming the validity of the research outcomes and furnishing pertinent recommendations for enhancing the safety rectification framework.
Article
Full-text available
As an emerging economic form, the digital economy is a crucial force in promoting high-quality economic development, resolving regional development incoherence, and improving the level of urban resilience. In this paper, the urban resilience indicator system is composed of four dimensions: social resilience, economic resilience, infrastructure resilience, and ecological resilience. Meanwhile, the digital economy indicator system is composed of five dimensions: Internet penetration rate, number of Internet-related employees, Internet-related output, number of mobile Internet users, and digital financial inclusion development. The development level was measured using the entropy value method and principal component analysis. On this basis, the impact of the digital economy on the urban resilience of 185 prefecture-level cities in China from 2011 to 2019 was analyzed using a benchmark regression model, spatial econometric model, and mediating effect model. This study shows the following: (1) The development of the digital economy has a positive impact on improving urban resilience. (2) The digital economy affects urban resilience with positive spatial spillover effects, and the temporal heterogeneity and heterogeneity of external openness levels are significant, while the regional heterogeneity is not significant. (3) The digital economy can improve urban resilience through the intermediary role of technological innovation. In the future, we should strengthen digital construction, deeply integrate the relationship between the digital economy, technological innovation, and urban resilience, give full play to the engine role of the digital economy, and further promote the enhancement of sustainable urban development.
Article
Full-text available
Innovation is critical to boosting economic growth and combating social problems. Based on national innovation systems, this study investigates how combinations of multiple factors (i.e., R&D investment, human capital, social freedom, democracy, globalization, and country affluence) lead to high national innovation performance. This study adopts fuzzy-set qualitative comparative analysis (fsQCA) to explore multiple con-junctural causations of innovation performance using a multi-source dataset of 116 countries. It identifies two configurations for high innovation performance: leveraging human capital and leveraging R&D investment. It also adopts a necessary condition analysis (NCA) to examine the necessary relationships between every condition and the outcome. NCA finds that R&D investment, globalization, and country affluence are necessary conditions for innovation performance, although they have different degrees of importance. This study advances the knowledge on national innovation performance and demonstrates how NCA can add complementary insights to the findings of fsQCA.
Article
Full-text available
This research aims to study the effects of technological organization, management of cost innovation, and value creation. The population in this study was the canned and instant food export companies, which are crucial industries that earn incomes for Thailand. The quantitative research method was carried out using questionnaires sent to all companies (census) with the manufacturing managers as respondents. The survey revealed that these companies had a high level of technological organization, value creation, and cost innovation, except for reducing unnecessary functions at a moderate level because the products need to maintain customer demand; therefore, unnecessary adjustments may not be made. PLS-SEM assesses the reflective and structural models to test the research hypotheses. The findings revealed significant influences among three pairs of constructs: (1) technological organization had a positive effect on cost innovation, (2) cost innovation had a positive effect on value creation, and (3) technological organization had a positive effect on value creation. Thus, this research provides empirical information for the influences among the variables and presents the significance of being a technological organization and the inclusion of cost innovation management, to maintain their business during the COVID-19 pandemic and improve the organizational potential for preparation in future circumstances. Doi: 10.28991/ESJ-2022-06-02-09 Full Text: PDF
Book
Full-text available
This open access book is an important reframing of the role of innovation in agriculture. Dr. Campos and his distinguished coauthors address the need for agriculture to feed a growing global population with a reduced environmental footprint while adapting to and mitigating the effects of changing climate. The authors expand the customary discussion of innovation in terms of supply driven R&D to focus on the returns to investors and most importantly, the value to end-users. This is brought to life by exploring effective business models and many cases from agricultural systems across the globe. The focus on converting the results of innovation in R&D into adoption by farmers and other end-users is its greatest contribution. Many lessons from the book can be applied to private and public sectors across an array of agricultural systems. This book will be of enormous value to agri-business professionals, NGO leaders, agricultural and development researchers and those funding innovation and agriculture across the private and public sectors. Tony Cavalieri, Senior Program Officer, Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation Hugo Campos, Ph.D., MBA, has 20+ years of international corporate and development experience. His distinguished coauthors represent a rich collection of successful innovation practice in industry, consultancy, international development and academy, in both developed and developing countries.”
Chapter
Full-text available
In agricultural and agrifood systems, like in many other economic sectors, the main innovation drivers have traditionally been (1) technological advances and (2) research and development. When innovation fails to address the actual needs of clients and end-users, however, satisfaction gaps are created. The result is that investors receive insufficient returns and end-users receive less than expected value. The consequences of failure can be deeper than just financial, however. Successful innovation in agriculture and agrifood systems is critical to secure affordable, nutritious, and safe food for all people. Rapid innovation is needed to address the serious challenge of climate change and to reduce agriculture’s global environmental footprint. The overarching goal of agricultural innovation should be to deliver high value to end-users and improve their quality of life and well-being. To achieve this goal, organizations must first understand the jobs to be done concept for their end-users. They must take into account user satisfaction gaps and frustrations. Understanding user needs is as important as producing technology to finding innovative solutions. This is true around the globe; in industry and public sectors, and in both developed and developing countries. This chapter explains why investing in innovation is very different from succeeding at it. Ultimately, the examples, ideas, and guidelines in this chapter can be brought to bear on agricultural innovation efforts (and any other economic sector), to make them more productive and worthwhile for end-users and investors/funders. The information herein is meant to increase the likelihood of successful innovation efforts at both profit-seeking firms and nonprofit organizations.
Article
How does policy affect innovation and the digital economy? We revisit how product market regulation affects innovation and develop a novel framework for thinking about digital regulation. Using new company-level micro-data across 12 countries between 1998 and 2012, this paper first estimates the effect of competition policy on innovation. We find that a standard deviation rise in standardized index of product market regulation is associated with a 1.03% decline in innovation activities. These declines are a result of product market regulation on the incentives to invest in in-house R&D and make the appropriate capital acquisitions, as well as of the effects of regulation on the cost of innovation activities. We then theorize on the effect of digital regulation on innovation and we empirically explore it on a sub-sample of the years in our analysis. We find that “protective regulation”, i.e., regulation that creates predictability and scope for markets to work, confers a positive effect on innovation, while “restrictive regulation”, i.e., regulation that endeavors to spell out negative behaviors, confers a negative effect on innovation. We also find that the digital regulation results are more sensitive to the content of regulation. We attribute this ambiguity to the fact that markers require an enhanced level of trust to be operative.
Article
In the past, economic models and empirical evidence have extensively examined the possible determinants of technological innovation. However, researchers did not give much importance to the relationship between fiscal decentralization and technological innovation. Therefore, this study examines the effects of fiscal decentralization on technological innovation, in the presence of economic globalization, public debt, and research & development expenditures (R&DE) for seven decentralized countries of the world, which include Brazil, South Africa, Canada, Germany, Japan, UK, and the USA. In this regard, the Westerlund and Kao cointegration methods’ outcomes have provided ample evidence of a long-run equilibrium relationship among the variables associated with technological innovation and its determinants. The results of the common correlated effects mean group (CCEMG) support the hypothesized relationship between fiscal decentralization, and other technological innovation variables that have been taken into consideration. It is evident that an increase in fiscal decentralization, economic globalization, and R&D expenditures tends to improve the sample countries’ performance in terms of innovation. On the contrary, public debt is negatively associated with technological innovation. By employing the Dumitrescu Hurlin test, we also found that any policy aims to target fiscal decentralization, R&D expenditures, and public debt significantly changes the advent of technological innovation.