ArticlePublisher preview available

Strategic analysis of green technology unilateral licensing under carbon cap‐and‐trade policy

Wiley
Managerial and Decision Economics
Authors:
To read the full-text of this research, you can request a copy directly from the authors.

Abstract and Figures

We investigate green technology unilateral licensing strategies between two competing manufacturers under carbon cap‐and‐trade policy. We construct Nash game models and compare the optimal strategies in the unilateral licensing situation with the no‐licensing situation. Comprehensive numerical experiments are taken to investigate the influence of some key parameters on optimal decisions. Our findings show that the green technology unilateral licensing strategy may benefit consumers; when green technology improvement is high, manufacturers tend to take the unilateral licensing strategy to obtain more profits; when initial unit carbon emission difference is moderate or large, the optimal strategy is that the manufacturer with lower level of green technology acts as the licensor; green technology unilateral licensing strategy may not necessarily reduce all manufacturers' total carbon emissions; only when green technology improvement is high, the unilateral licensing strategy is beneficial to environmental protection.
This content is subject to copyright. Terms and conditions apply.
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Strategic analysis of green technology unilateral licensing
under carbon cap-and-trade policy
Gui-Hua Lin | Yang-Ping Liu | Qi Zhang
School of Management, Shanghai University,
Shanghai, China
Correspondence
Qi Zhang, School of Management, Shanghai
University, Shanghai, China.
Email: qizhang9669@shu.edu.cn
Funding information
This research was funded by the National
Natural Science Foundation of China, grant
number no. 12071280.
Abstract
We investigate green technology unilateral licensing strategies between two compet-
ing manufacturers under carbon cap-and-trade policy. We construct Nash game
models and compare the optimal strategies in the unilateral licensing situation with
the no-licensing situation. Comprehensive numerical experiments are taken to inves-
tigate the influence of some key parameters on optimal decisions. Our findings show
that the green technology unilateral licensing strategy may benefit consumers; when
green technology improvement is high, manufacturers tend to take the unilateral
licensing strategy to obtain more profits; when initial unit carbon emission difference
is moderate or large, the optimal strategy is that the manufacturer with lower level of
green technology acts as the licensor; green technology unilateral licensing strategy
may not necessarily reduce all manufacturers' total carbon emissions; only when
green technology improvement is high, the unilateral licensing strategy is beneficial
to environmental protection.
1|INTRODUCTION
The environmental crisis caused by global climate change is intensify-
ing and global carbon emissions are still rising gradually in recent
years, which makes the environmental issue become a major problem.
The global CO
2
emissions from human activities are still at a high level
in history (Global Carbon Project, 2022). Global energy-related CO
2
emissions grew by 0.9% or 321 Mt in 2022 to reach a new high of
over 36.8 Gt (IEA, 2023). In response to this increasingly urgent cli-
mate crisis, many countries have set new climate targets and made
commitments to reduce carbon emissions. For instance, the
United Kingdom proposed to achieve carbon neutrality by 2050 in
2019. China issued a 30 60dual carbon target in 2020. Japan com-
mitted to achieving carbon neutrality as early as possible in the sec-
ond half of this century. Canada announced a target to achieve
carbon neutrality by 2050. In 2021, the United States announced a
new target for reducing emissions, that is, the United States plans to
reduce greenhouse gas emissions by 50% to 52% from 2005 level by
2030 and to achieve carbon neutrality by 2050. In 2022, Australia
updated its National Autonomous Contribution (NDC) target by com-
mitting to net-zero emissions by 2050 and passed climate target
legislation. Chile passed a climate framework law with net-zero emis-
sions commitments and policies. India updated its NDC target and
committed to a net-zero emissions goal by 2070 (World Bank, 2023).
More and more countries have undertaken several specific emissions
reduction policies to achieve their carbon reduction targets. For exam-
ple, China is adopting strong policies to meet its NDC target on cli-
mate issues, including policies to promote the construction of a
national carbon emissions trading market, vigorously develop solar
and wind energy, and limit the growth of coal consumption (United
Nations Environment Programme, 2022). In particular, carbon cap-
and-trade policy is one of the core tools for national carbon emission
reduction.
The carbon cap-and-trade policy is an effective policy for reduc-
ing greenhouse gas emissions (World Bank, 2022). Generally, the gov-
ernment or other designated agency determines a cap on greenhouse
gas emissions for carbon market participants during a specific period
and allocates it to individual firms. Carbon market participants with
excess emissions can buy quotas that they need to emit in carbon
markets, while the ones with surplus emissions quotas can sell their
remaining quotas in carbon markets. Carbon cap-and-trade policy pro-
vides an effective incentive for manufacturers to reduce their carbon
Received: 12 October 2023 Revised: 20 January 2024 Accepted: 30 January 2024
DOI: 10.1002/mde.4148
2646 © 2024 John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Manage Decis Econ. 2024;45:26462665.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/mde
Article
The market‐oriented trading of resource and environmental elements is a key mechanism for optimizing the efficiency of environmental rights allocation. This study, based on the technology–organization–environment (TOE) framework, selects 30 resource and environmental element trading platforms in China as a research sample. Using the fuzzy‐set qualitative comparative analysis method, we explore the effective path combination driving resource and environmental element trading. The research results reveal five paths that can achieve high‐level resource and environmental element trading, which can be classified into three types: technology–organization, organization–environment, and rule‐based. Organizational regulatory factors play an indispensable role, regardless of path type. The conclusion of this study provides a useful reference for incentivizing resource and environmental elements transactions, helping improve the market operation efficiency of environmental rights and interests.
Chapter
The research aims to determine the impact of big data and AI on creating green jobs and making environmental decisions in Asian countries. By employing correlation and regression analysis methods, the authors developed an econometric model for environmental management in the top 15 Asian countries with the most favorable opportunities for developing a green economy in 2023. According to the model, the use of big data and AI has a significant yet contradictory influence on environmental decision-making in these countries. While it promotes more active green investments and job creation, it simultaneously limits green trade and restrains green innovations. The theoretical significance of the developed model lies in its pioneering revelation of the causal relationships between the use of big data and AI and the effectiveness of environmental decision-making in Asia, a unique region of the world. The practical significance stems from the identified potential to increase the number of green jobs and optimize environmental decision-making through the more active use of big data and AI in Kyrgyzstan. This approach enables the development of corporate plans and the implementation of programs for the green development of Kyrgyz enterprises. The managerial significance is reflected in the fact that the organizational scheme developed for creating green jobs and making environmental decisions using big data and AI will enhance contemporary environmental management practices for enterprises in Kyrgyzstan and other Asian countries.
Article
Full-text available
We consider consumers' loss aversion in environmental quality and develop a two‐period game theoretical model to investigate the optimal pricing and environmental quality decisions for a green supply chain where a manufacturer sells products to consumers through a retailer. We then introduce a two‐part tariff contract to coordinate the supply chain for both periods. We suggest that optimal decisions in the second period depend on the reference point of the first period in the decentralized supply chain. A higher reference point leads to the increased environmental quality of products, prices, and profits of supply chain members in the second period. However, when the reference point is sufficiently high, the environmental quality will be lower to avoid excessive environmental investment costs. Furthermore, consumers' loss aversion reduces the environmental quality of products when the reference point is low. As consumers' loss aversion increases, the manufacturer's profit rises, while the wholesale and retail prices and the retailer's profit show a decreasing and then increasing trend. Finally, we find that a two‐part tariff contract enables the two‐period supply chain to be coordinated and achieve Pareto improvements in profit and environmental quality. This study sheds valuable light on understanding consumer environmental preferences and irrational behavior for supply chain decision‐making and green product design.
Article
Full-text available
Green finance contributes significantly to the openness and transparency of carbon quota trading prices, which is conducive to the development of green technology innovation. With known carbon quota trading prices, we construct game-based operational research models to analyze fixed-fee and mixed-fee cross-licensing strategies for green technologies between two competing firms under the cap-and-trade policy. We compare the equilibrium outcomes of no-licensing, fixed-fee, and mixed-fee cross-licensing strategies. The findings reveal that product pricing under the fixed-fee cross-licensing strategy is beneficial to consumers. The mixed-fee cross-licensing strategy is optimal in terms of firms' total profits. When the degree of product substitutions is large and the improvement in carbon emissions is small, firms are more inclined to the no-licensing strategy. We further introduce the revenue-sharing contract, which can extend the Pareto improvement domain and improve the performance of green technology cross-licensing strategies.
Article
Full-text available
With the release of the national energy-saving emission reduction policy and the improvement of consumers’ awareness of environmental protection, the demand for low-carbon products is growing rapidly. In a retailer-led low-carbon supply chain, the increased cost of carbon emission reduction puts manufacturers at a disadvantage. Under the carbon quota policy, to improve manufacturers’ profits as well as enhance carbon emission reduction, this paper studies the players’ decisions in a low-carbon supply chain consisting of one dominant retailer and one manufacturer. To maintain the supply chain’s stability and sustainability, the dominant retailer tends to employ altruistic preference policies towards the manufacturer. The optimal decision, carbon emission reduction and supply chain profit are compared and analyzed under three decision models: (i) centralized decision, (ii) decentralized decision without altruistic preference and (iii) decentralized decision with altruistic preference. The results indicate that the carbon emission reduction rate, market demand and profit in the centralized model are higher than in the decentralized model. The retailer’s altruistic preference is beneficial to the improvement of carbon emission reduction, market demand and the profit of the manufacturer and the supply chain. Under certain conditions, carbon trading can effectively reduce the cost pressure of manufacturers and improve the level of carbon emission reduction and the overall profit of the supply chain. These results will guide low-carbon supply chain decision-making and provide insight into the research of irrational behaviors in supply chain decision-making under carbon policies.
Article
Full-text available
This paper studies a green manufacturer’s strategic licensing of its green technology to a brown rival under the consideration of the green manufacturer’s environmental concerns. Consumers in the market have green awareness. Adopting the green technology not only helps manufacturers to reduce carbon emissions, but also to increase market sizes. The green manufacturer can choose from three technology licensing strategies, i.e., no licensing (N), royalty licensing (R) or fixed-fee licensing (F). The equilibrium licensing strategy can be derived by comparing the respective payoff after adopting the three strategies. It is found that the green manufacturer should choose fixed-fee licensing strategy when the market size expansion effect is strong, and the competition intensity is moderate; otherwise, the green manufacturer should choose royalty licensing strategy. Furthermore, it is found that when the green manufacturer is more concerned about environmental impacts, it will be more willing to choose fixed-fee licensing strategy, rather than royalty licensing strategy. Through numerical tests, some interesting results are also found. For example, the brown manufacturer might be hurt even if the cost reduction effect of technology licensing is relatively stronger. Moreover, it is found that consumer surplus and social welfare nonmonotonically change with the substitution level. In summary, this research tries to provide some guidelines to the industry and the society on better managing green technology diffusions.
Article
Full-text available
We consider the problem of patent licensing in a Cournot duopoly in which the innovator (patentee) is one of the firms and it is capacity constrained. We show that when the patentee can produce a relatively small (relatively large) quantity, it prefers licensing by means of a fixed fee (unit royalty). When the patentee can set two-part tariffs in the form of combinations of fixed fees and unit royalties, it charges a positive fixed fee if and only if it is limited to producing a relatively small quantity. We also show that with combinations of fixed fees and royalties, the royalty rate is lower than is true for the standard case.
Article
Full-text available
Accurate assessment of anthropogenic carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions and their redistribution among the atmosphere, ocean, and terrestrial biosphere in a changing climate is critical to better understand the global carbon cycle, support the development of climate policies, and project future climate change. Here we describe and synthesize data sets and methodologies to quantify the five major components of the global carbon budget and their uncertainties. Fossil CO2 emissions (EFOS) are based on energy statistics and cement production data, while emissions from land-use change (ELUC), mainly deforestation, are based on land use and land-use change data and bookkeeping models. Atmospheric CO2 concentration is measured directly, and its growth rate (GATM) is computed from the annual changes in concentration. The ocean CO2 sink (SOCEAN) is estimated with global ocean biogeochemistry models and observation-based data products. The terrestrial CO2 sink (SLAND) is estimated with dynamic global vegetation models. The resulting carbon budget imbalance (BIM), the difference between the estimated total emissions and the estimated changes in the atmosphere, ocean, and terrestrial biosphere, is a measure of imperfect data and understanding of the contemporary carbon cycle. All uncertainties are reported as ±1σ. For the year 2021, EFOS increased by 5.1 % relative to 2020, with fossil emissions at 10.1 ± 0.5 GtC yr-1 (9.9 ± 0.5 GtC yr-1 when the cement carbonation sink is included), and ELUC was 1.1 ± 0.7 GtC yr-1, for a total anthropogenic CO2 emission (including the cement carbonation sink) of 10.9 ± 0.8 GtC yr-1 (40.0 ± 2.9 GtCO2). Also, for 2021, GATM was 5.2 ± 0.2 GtC yr-1 (2.5 ± 0.1 ppm yr-1), SOCEAN was 2.9 ± 0.4 GtC yr-1, and SLAND was 3.5 ± 0.9 GtC yr-1, with a BIM of -0.6 GtC yr-1 (i.e. the total estimated sources were too low or sinks were too high). The global atmospheric CO2 concentration averaged over 2021 reached 414.71 ± 0.1 ppm. Preliminary data for 2022 suggest an increase in EFOS relative to 2021 of +1.0 % (0.1 % to 1.9 %) globally and atmospheric CO2 concentration reaching 417.2 ppm, more than 50 % above pre-industrial levels (around 278 ppm). Overall, the mean and trend in the components of the global carbon budget are consistently estimated over the period 1959–2021, but discrepancies of up to 1 GtC yr-1 persist for the representation of annual to semi-decadal variability in CO2 fluxes. Comparison of estimates from multiple approaches and observations shows (1) a persistent large uncertainty in the estimate of land-use change emissions, (2) a low agreement between the different methods on the magnitude of the land CO2 flux in the northern extratropics, and (3) a discrepancy between the different methods on the strength of the ocean sink over the last decade. This living data update documents changes in the methods and data sets used in this new global carbon budget and the progress in understanding of the global carbon cycle compared with previous publications of this data set. The data presented in this work are available at 10.18160/GCP-2022 (Friedlingstein et al., 2022b).
Article
Full-text available
Existing studies on technology licensing for quality-improving technology neglect the licensee's absorptive capacity or assume the complete absorption of technology for product quality. However, the licensee's absorptive capacity may significantly impact the benefit of technology licensing and has received extensive attention in practice and research. To address this gap, this study analyzes the optimal licensing strategy of vertically differentiated products by considering patentor's innovation capability and licensee's absorptive capacity, giving three types of licensing including fixed-fee licensing contact, per-unit royalty licensing, and two-part ad valorem licensing. We find that not only the patentor's innovation capability but also the licensee's absorptive capacity can significantly influence the optimal licensing strategy. The patentor may prefer per-unit royalty licensing and two-part ad valorem licensing to fixed-fee licensing. Moreover, technology licensing always benefits customers and society. Our work specifies the decision space for the patentor in evaluating the value of different licensing contracts and provides a new decision tool for choosing the optimal licensing strategy. We provide interesting management insights into understanding the optimal licensing strategy from the perspective of the patentor, customers, and society.
Article
With the increasing requirements for environmental protection, authorities have enacted different carbon policies to promote sustainable practices. This study considers the competition among different manufacturers and multiple demand markets in the supply chain network. We examine and compare their equilibrium decision conditions under three common carbon policies: carbon cap, carbon cap‐and‐trade, and carbon tax. Results suggest that under lower carbon caps, manufacturers greatly reduce their carbon emissions by reducing production quantities, which causes a decrease in profits. However, an appropriate carbon cap size can not only motivate manufacturers to reduce carbon emissions but also improve their profits. Under a certain price for carbon credit, the effectiveness of a carbon cap‐and‐trade policy is similar to that of a carbon cap policy, but it has more flexibility. Carbon tax is effective, but it brings more tax burden to manufacturers. We provide implications for companies to optimize their production methods to achieve sustainability.
Article
In recent years, the rapid growth of electric vehicle (EV) ownership in China has led to the large-scale retirement of power batteries. Establishing an effective recycling system for spent power batteries is a critical task. Therefore, we investigate the recycling mode selection and the carbon abatement decision in a closed-loop supply chain (CLSC) of EV power batteries under the carbon cap-and-trade policy. We propose four mixed-channel recycling modes in which two or three parties from a retailer, a third-party recycler and an echelon utilization enterprise participate in the recycling business. In the reverse chain, the collected spent power batteries are classified, wherein the echelon-utilizable batteries are processed into echelon utilization products for sale by the echelon utilization enterprise, while both the non-echelon-utilizable batteries and the post-echelon-utilized batteries are transferred to the manufacturer for extracting raw materials to produce new power batteries. We obtain equilibrium results by solving Stackelberg game models. The results reveal that when the competition intensity among recycling channels is below a certain threshold and the recycling price sensitivity is above a certain threshold, the optimal mode is the simultaneous participation of the retailer, the third-party recycler, and the echelon utilization enterprise. Otherwise, the optimal mode is the echelon utilization enterprise recycling with the retailer or third-party recycler. Higher recycling channel competition and lower recycling price sensitivity reduce the total recycling quantity. Higher carbon trading price, a lower investment cost coefficient for carbon abatement and increased consumers' low-carbon awareness will encourage the manufacturer to implement carbon reduction activities, thus reducing total carbon emissions. In addition, the engagement of the echelon utilization enterprise in the recycling business has a positive effect on relieving the recycling pressure and improving the manufacturer's profit.