ArticlePublisher preview available

When norm change hurts

The Royal Society
Philosophical Transactions B
Authors:
To read the full-text of this research, you can request a copy directly from the authors.

Abstract

Applied cultural evolution includes any effort to mobilize social learning and cultural evolution to promote behaviour change. Social tipping is one version of this idea based on conformity and coordination. Conformity and coordination can reinforce a harmful social norm, but they can also accelerate change from a harmful norm to a beneficial alternative. Perhaps unfortunately, the link between the size of an intervention and social tipping is complex in heterogeneous populations. A small intervention targeted at one segment of society can induce tipping better than a large intervention targeted at a different segment. We develop and examine two models showing that the link between social tipping and social welfare is also complex in heterogeneous populations. An intervention strategy that creates persistent miscoordination, exactly the opposite of tipping, can lead to higher social welfare than another strategy that leads to tipping. We show that the potential benefits of miscoordination often hinge specifically on the preferences of people most resistant to behaviour change. Altogether, ordinary forms of heterogeneity complicate applied cultural evolution considerably. Heterogeneity weakens both the link between the size of a social planner’s intervention and behaviour change and the link between behaviour change and the well-being of society. This article is part of the theme issue ‘Social norm change: drivers and consequences’.
royalsocietypublishing.org/journal/rstb
Research
Cite this article: Efferson C, Ehret S, von Flüe
L, Vogt S. 2024 When norm change hurts. Phil.
Trans. R. Soc. B 379: 20230039.
https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2023.0039
Received: 30 June 2023
Accepted: 21 November 2023
One contribution of 15 to a theme issue Social
norm change: drivers and consequences.
Subject Areas:
behaviour, evolution
Keywords:
social tipping, behaviour change, coordination,
conformity, social norms
Authors for correspondence:
Charles Efferson
e-mail: charles.efferson@unil.ch
Sonja Vogt
e-mail: sonja.vogt@unil.ch
Electronic supplementary material is available
online at https://doi.org/10.6084/m9.figshare.
c.6980739.
When norm change hurts
Charles Efferson, Sönke Ehret, Lukas von Flüe and Sonja Vogt
University of Lausanne, Faculty of Business and Economics, University of Lausanne, 1015 Lausanne, Switzerland
CE, 0000-0001-8244-4497; LvF, 0000-0001-5134-8128; SV, 0000-0001-8217-8272
Applied cultural evolution includes any effort to mobilize social learning
and cultural evolution to promote behaviour change. Social tipping is one
version of this idea based on conformity and coordination. Conformity
and coordination can reinforce a harmful social norm, but they can also
accelerate change from a harmful norm to a beneficial alternative. Perhaps
unfortunately, the link between the size of an intervention and social tipping
is complex in heterogeneous populations. A small intervention targeted at
one segment of society can induce tipping better than a large intervention
targeted at a different segment. We develop and examine two models show-
ing that the link between social tipping and social welfare is also complex in
heterogeneous populations. An intervention strategy that creates persistent
miscoordination, exactly the opposite of tipping, can lead to higher social
welfare than another strategy that leads to tipping. We show that the poten-
tial benefits of miscoordination often hinge specifically on the preferences of
people most resistant to behaviour change. Altogether, ordinary forms of
heterogeneity complicate applied cultural evolution considerably. Hetero-
geneity weakens both the link between the size of a social planners
intervention and behaviour change and the link between behaviour
change and the well-being of society.
This article is part of the theme issue Social norm change: drivers and
consequences.
1. Introduction
Applied cultural evolution is, to shun euphemism, an attempt to engineer
culture. A social planner wants people to behave differently, and she intervenes
in society in pursuit of this objective. The interesting twist is that, once people
exposed to the intervention start to change behaviour, endogenous cultural
evolutionary processes can take effect. Some people change behaviour because
they have direct experience with the intervention. Some people change behav-
iour because they observe others doing so. If the social planner knows how this
second process works, she can implement her intervention in a way that maxi-
mizes the sum of both the direct effect and the associated indirect cultural
evolutionary effect. In particular, the indirect effect might far outstrip the
direct effect, in which case cultural evolutionary dynamics dramatically amplify
the interventions consequences. This idea is the essence of applied cultural
evolution as an attempt to engineer culture [1].
The indirect cultural evolutionary effect occurs because we influence, teach
and learn from each other, and we do not do so randomly [2]. We pay attention
to some people and ignore others [3,4]. Sometimes we follow the majority, and
sometimes we do not [5,6]. Some people provide examples of how to behave,
and some people provide examples of how not to behave [79]. Some beha-
viours we simply like, and others we do not [10]. Whatever the details, the
necessary result is some kind of cultural evolution at the aggregate level
[1,11,12]. If we want to know what kind of cultural evolution, the details are
crucial [1,11,13,14]. If we discriminate when we learn from each other in one
way, cultural evolution unfolds accordingly. If we discriminate in some other
way, we can expect cultural evolution to unfold quite differently.
Engineering culture sounds unpleasant, even imperialistic, and sometimes it
is [1517]. However, because most people live in a society, any attempt to
© 2024 The Author(s) Published by the Royal Society. All rights reserved.
... Contributions examine, for instance, the welfare consequences of engineering norm change and how crosscultural variation in norm enforcement systems impacts the dynamics of social norm change. Interventions for norm change do not come without limitations and some contributions show how norm-based interventions might have backfiring effects [29,30]. This section starts with a review article on punishment as a bottom-up means of norm enforcement across cultures and societies [31]. ...
... This section starts with a review article on punishment as a bottom-up means of norm enforcement across cultures and societies [31]. It proceeds with four research articles that design and test norm interventions to change behavioural intentions in both online [32] and offline settings and in different cultural contexts [33], for norms and meta norms [29], to assess both individual and welfare consequences [30]. ...
... Finally, Efferson et al. [30] develop two theoretical models that predict when interventions that engineer norm change may be successful and when instead they would backfire. Based on the notion of tipping points, they argue that conformity and coordination can reinforce a harmful social norm, but they can also accelerate change from a harmful norm to a beneficial alternative. ...
Article
Full-text available
Social norms research is booming. In recent years, several experts have recommended using social norms (unwritten rules that prescribe what people ought or ought not to do) to confront the societal, environmental and health challenges our societies face. If we are to do so, a better understanding is required of how social norms themselves emerge, evolve and respond to these challenges. Social norms have long been used as post hoc explanations of behaviour or are seen as stable social constructs. Yet norms evolve dynamically with the changing group processes (e.g. political polarization, kinship structures) and societal challenges (e.g. pandemics, climate change) for which they are presented as solutions. The Theme Issue ‘Social norm change: drivers and consequences' contains 14 contributions that present state-of-the-art approaches to understand what generates social norm change and how this impacts our societies. Contributions give insight into (i) the identification of norms, norm change and their effect on behaviour; (ii) drivers and consequences of spontaneous norm change; and (iii) how norm change can be engineered to promote desired behavioural change. This article is part of the theme issue ‘Social norm change: drivers and consequences’.
... Some people provide biased responses, whereas others do not. In general, ordinary forms of heterogeneity make applied cultural evolution much more challenging than it would otherwise be (Andreoni et al., 2021;Efferson et al., 2020Efferson et al., , 2023Efferson et al., , 2024Ehret et al., 2022;Platteau et al., 2018). This is true when people differ in terms of their preferences and in terms of whom they know. ...
... We distinguish cases of information about the network and information about individuals' preferences. We do not consider push-back effects from the interventions or differential responses to interventions, effects observed in real-world social norm interventions [9,35]. ...
Preprint
Full-text available
Many societal challenges, such as climate change or disease outbreaks, require coordinated behavioral changes. For many behaviors, the tendency of individuals to adhere to social norms can reinforce the status quo. However, these same social processes can also result in rapid, self-reinforcing change. Interventions may be strategically targeted to initiate endogenous social change processes, often referred to as social tipping. While recent research has considered how the size and targeting of such interventions impact their effectiveness at bringing about change, they tend to overlook constraints faced by policymakers, including the cost, speed, and distributional consequences of interventions. To address this complexity, we introduce a game-theoretic framework that includes heterogeneous agents and networks of local influence. We implement various targeting heuristics based on information about individual preferences and commonly used local network properties to identify individuals to incentivize. Analytical and simulation results suggest that there is a trade-off between preventing backsliding among targeted individuals and promoting change among non-targeted individuals. Thus, where the change is initiated in the population and the direction in which it propagates is essential to the effectiveness of interventions. We identify cost-optimal strategies under different scenarios, such as varying levels of resistance to change, preference heterogeneity, and homophily. These results provide insights that can be experimentally tested and help policymakers to better direct incentives.
... Exposure to media interventions, such as advertising, prompts behavioral changes among individuals, thereby affecting cultural evolution processes. Some individuals adapt their behavior directly due to media exposure, while others do so by observing peers (Efferson et al., 2024). Notably, the indirect influence often outweighs the direct impact, echoing Bandura's insights in social learning theory, wherein individuals learn by observing others in their social milieu, with media serving as a significant source of such observations. ...
... Strengthening the norm may in fact lead people to believe that others already sanction, thus reducing the personal willingness to enforce it. In other words, there is a risk that norm-based interventions may backfire (see also [44] of this theme issue) royalsocietypublishing.org/journal/rstb Phil. Trans. ...
Article
Full-text available
Global challenges like the climate crisis and pandemic outbreaks require collective responses where people quickly adapt to changing circumstances. Social norms are potential solutions, but only if they themselves are flexible enough. The COVID-19 pandemic provided a unique opportunity to study norm formation and decay in real-world contexts. We tracked empirical and normative expectations about social distancing and empirical and normative expectations of sanctioning from June 2021 to February 2022 to explore how norms and meta norms evolved as COVID-19 risk decreased and increased. We found that norms and meta norms partially coevolve with risk dynamics, although they recover with some delay. This implies that norms should be enforced as soon as risk increases. We therefore tested how sanctioning intentions vary for different hypothetical norms and find them to increase with a clear meta norm of sanctioning, yet decrease with a clear social norm of distance. In conclusion, social norms evolve spontaneously with changing risk, but might not be adaptive enough when the lack of meta norms of sanctioning introduce tolerance for norm violations. Moreover, norm nudges can potentially have negative externalities if strengthening the social norm increases tolerance for norm violations. These results put some limits to social norms as solutions to guide behaviour under risk. This article is part of the theme issue ‘Social norm change: drivers and consequences’.
... This is because they fail to reach the high threshold at which sending costly signals becomes beneficial. Developing a signalling norm in majority groups might, thus, require a stronger stochastic shock to introduce sufficiently wide signal recognition, for instance, via a centralized or persuasive intervention [9,[50][51][52]. ...
Article
Full-text available
Mechanisms of social control reinforce norms that appear harmful or wasteful, such as mutilation practises or extensive body tattoos. We suggest such norms arise to serve as signals that distinguish between ingroup ‘friends' and outgroup ‘foes', facilitating parochial cooperation. Combining insights from research on signalling and parochial cooperation, we incorporate a trust game with signalling in an agent-based model to study the dynamics of signalling norm emergence in groups with conflicting interests. Our results show that costly signalling norms emerge from random acts of signalling in minority groups that benefit most from parochial cooperation. Majority groups are less likely to develop costly signalling norms. Yet, norms that prescribe sending costless group identity signals can easily emerge in groups of all sizes—albeit, at times, at the expense of minority group members. Further, the dynamics of signalling norm emergence differ across signal costs, relative group sizes, and levels of ingroup assortment. Our findings provide theoretical insights into norm evolution in contexts where groups develop identity markers in response to environmental challenges that put their interests at odds with the interests of other groups. Such contexts arise in zones of ethnic conflict or during contestations of existing power relations. This article is part of the theme issue ‘Social norm change: drivers and consequences’.
Chapter
Full-text available
Human evolutionary demography is an emerging field blending natural science with social science. This edited volume provides a much-needed, interdisciplinary introduction to the field and highlights cutting-edge research for interested readers and researchers in demography, the evolutionary behavioural sciences, biology, and related disciplines. By bridging the boundaries between social and biological sciences, the volume stresses the importance of a unified understanding of both in order to grasp past and current demographic patterns. Demographic traits, and traits related to demographic outcomes, including fertility and mortality rates, marriage, parental care, menopause, and cooperative behavior are subject to evolutionary processes. Bringing an understanding of evolution into demography therefore incorporates valuable insights into this field; just as knowledge of demography is key to understanding evolutionary processes. By asking questions about old patterns from a new perspective, the volume—composed of contributions from established and early-career academics—demonstrates that a combination of social science research and evolutionary theory offers holistic understandings and approaches that benefit both fields. Human Evolutionary Demography introduces an emerging field in an accessible style. It is suitable for graduate courses in demography, as well as upper-level undergraduates. Its range of research is sure to be of interest to academics working on demographic topics (anthropologists, sociologists, demographers), natural scientists working on evolutionary processes, and disciplines which cross-cut natural and social science, such as evolutionary psychology, human behavioral ecology, cultural evolution, and evolutionary medicine. As an accessible introduction, it should interest readers whether or not they are currently familiar with human evolutionary demography.
Article
Full-text available
We review theoretical approaches for modelling the origin, persistence and change of social norms. The most comprehensive models describe the coevolution of behaviours, personal, descriptive and injunctive norms while considering influences of various authorities and accounting for cognitive processes and between-individual differences. Models show that social norms can improve individual and group well-being. Under some conditions though, deleterious norms can persist in the population through conformity, preference falsification and pluralistic ignorance. Polarization in behaviour and beliefs can be maintained, even when societal advantages of particular behaviours or belief systems over alternatives are clear. Attempts to change social norms can backfire through cognitive processes including cognitive dissonance and psychological reactance. Under some conditions social norms can change rapidly via tipping point dynamics. Norms can be highly susceptible to manipulation, and network structure influences their propagation. Future models should incorporate network structure more thoroughly, explicitly study online norms, consider cultural variations and be applied to real-world processes. This article is part of the theme issue ‘Social norm change: drivers and consequences’.
Article
Full-text available
Anthropogenic carbon emissions have the potential to trigger changes in climate and ecosystems that would be catastrophic for the well-being of humans and other species. Widespread shifts in production and consumption patterns are urgently needed to address climate change. Although transnational agreements and national policy are necessary for a transition to a fully decarbonized global economy, fluctuating political priorities and lobbying by vested interests have slowed these efforts. Against this backdrop, bottom-up pressure from social movements and shifting social norms may offer a complementary path to a more sustainable economy. Furthermore, norm change may be an important component of decarbonization policies by accelerating or strengthening the impacts of other demand-side measures. Individual actions and policy support are social processes-they are intimately linked to expectations about the actions and beliefs of others. Although prevailing social norms often reinforce the status quo and unsustainable development pathways, social dynamics can also create widespread and rapid shifts in cultural values and practices, including increasing pressure on politicians to enact ambitious policy. We synthesize literature on social-norm influence, measurement, and change from the perspectives of psychology, anthropology, sociology, and economics. We discuss the opportunities and challenges for the use of social-norm and social-tipping interventions to promote climate action. Social-norm interventions aimed at addressing climate change or other social dilemmas are promising but no panacea. They require in-depth contextual knowledge, ethical consideration, and situation-specific tailoring and testing to understand whether they can be effectively implemented at scale. Our review aims to provide practitioners with insights and tools to reflect on the promises and pitfalls of such interventions in diverse contexts.
Article
Full-text available
Social tipping can accelerate behaviour change consistent with policy objectives in diverse domains from social justice to climate change. Hypothetically, however, group identities might undermine tipping in ways that policymakers do not anticipate. To examine this, we implemented an experiment around the 2020 US federal elections. The participants faced consistent incentives to coordinate their choices. Once the participants had established a coordination norm, an intervention created pressure to tip to a new norm. Our control treatment used neutral labels for choices. Our identity treatment used partisan political images. This simple pay-off-irrelevant relabelling generated extreme differences. The control groups developed norms slowly before intervention but transitioned to new norms rapidly after intervention. The identity groups developed norms rapidly before intervention but persisted in a state of costly disagreement after intervention. Tipping was powerful but unreliable. It supported striking cultural changes when choice and identity were unlinked, but even a trivial link destroyed tipping entirely.
Article
Full-text available
Models of frequency-dependent social learning posit that individuals respond to the commonality of behaviours without additional variables modifying this. Such strategies bring important trade-offs e.g., conformity is beneficial when observing people facing the same task but harmful when observing those facing a different task. Instead of rigidly responding to frequencies, however, social learners might modulate their response given additional information. To see, we ran an incentivised experiment where participants played either a game against nature or a coordination game. There were three types of information: (i) choice frequencies in a group of demonstrators, (ii) an indication of whether these demonstrators learned in a similar or different environment, and (iii) an indication about the reliability of this similarity information. Similarity information was either reliably correct, uninformative, or reliably incorrect, where reliably correct and reliably incorrect treatments provided participants with equivalent earning opportunities. Participants adjusted their decision-making to all three types of information. Adjustments, however, were asymmetric, with participants doing especially well when conforming to demonstrators who were reliably similar to them. The overall response, however, was more fluid and complex than this one case. This flexibility should attenuate the trade-offs commonly assumed to shape the evolution of frequency-dependent social learning strategies.
Article
Full-text available
Public health policy often involves implementing cost-efficient, large-scale interventions. When mandating or forbidding a specific behaviour is not permissible, public health professionals may draw on behaviour change interventions to achieve socially beneficial policy objectives. Interventions can have two main effects: (i) a direct effect on people initially targeted by the intervention; and (ii) an indirect effect mediated by social influence and by the observation of other people's behaviour. However, people's attitudes and beliefs can differ markedly throughout the population, with the result that these two effects can interact to produce unexpected, unhelpful and counterintuitive consequences. Public health professionals need to understand this interaction better. This paper illustrates the key principles of this interaction by examining two important areas of public health policy: tobacco smoking and vaccination. The example of antismoking campaigns shows when and how public health professionals can amplify the effects of a behaviour change intervention by taking advantage of the indirect pathway. The example of vaccination campaigns illustrates how underlying incentive structures, particularly anticoordination incentives, can interfere with the indirect effect of an intervention and stall efforts to scale up its implementation. Recommendations are presented on how public health professionals can maximize the total effect of behaviour change interventions in heterogeneous populations based on these concepts and examples.
Article
Full-text available
Sex ratios at birth favoring boys are being documented in a growing number of countries, a pattern indicating that families selectively abort females. Son bias also explains why, in many countries, girls have more siblings and are born at relatively earlier parities compared with their brothers. In this study, we develop novel methods for measuring son bias using both questionnaire items and implicit association tests, and we collect data on fertility preferences and outcomes from 2,700 participants in Armenia. We document highly skewed sex ratios, suggesting that selective abortions of females are widespread among parents in our sample. We also provide evidence that sex-selective abortions are underreported, which highlights the problem of social desirability bias. We validate our methods and demonstrate that conducting implicit association tests can be a successful strategy for measuring the relative preference for sons and daughters when social desirability is a concern. We investigate the structure of son-biased fertility preferences within households, across families, and between regions in Armenia, using measures of son bias at the level of the individual decision-maker. We find that men are, on average, considerably more son-biased than women. We also show that regional differences in son bias exist and that they appear unrelated to the socioeconomic composition of the population. Finally, we estimate the degree of spousal correlation in son bias and discuss whether husbands are reliably more son-biased than their wives.
Article
We provide experimental evidence on coordination within large groups that could proxy the atomistic nature of real-world markets. We use a bank run game where the two pure-strategy equilibria can be ranked by payoff and risk dominance and a sequence of public announcements introduces stochastic sunspot equilibria. We find systematic group size effects that theory fails to predict. When the payoff-dominant strategy is risky enough, the behavior of small groups is uninformative of the behavior in large groups: unlike smaller groups of size ten, larger groups exclusively coordinate on the Pareto-inferior strategy and never coordinate on sunspots. (JEL C92, D83, D91, G21)