PreprintPDF Available

The Job Guarantee Program and the Kaleckian Dilemma: Lessons from the Rehn-Meidner Plan

Authors:
Preprints and early-stage research may not have been peer reviewed yet.

Abstract and Figures

Minsky (1965) has presented the Job Guarantee program as a recommendation in the war against unemployment and poverty. Kalecki (1943), on the other hand, argued that the full employment situation could be technically feasible but politically hard to implement due to the class struggle, resulting in what we will refer to as the "kaleckian dilemma". Based on this contradiction, this paper aims to extract lessons from the Rehn-Meidner Swedish plan, which successfully combined low unemployment rates and creeping inflation for over three decades, as a means to study the chances of a Job Guarantee overcoming the kaleckian dilemma. From these lessons, this piece highlights the importance of a tripartite council bargaining board at the national level to settle the Job Guarantee's wage level. In addition, we highly recommended other desirable features, such as international capital control and taxation on extraordinary profits, to raise the chances of the program successfully dealing with the kaleckian dilemma, just as Rehn-Meidner did.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Working Paper Series
Open Society University Network Economic Democracy Initiative
WP 10 | November 2023
Caio Vilella
Professor in Economics, Catholic University of Santos
Eduardo F. Bastian
Associate Professor, Federal University of Rio de Janeiro (UFRJ)
The Job Guarantee Program and
the Kaleckian Dilemma: Lessons
from the Rehn-Meidner Plan
,
The Job Guarantee Program and the Kaleckian
Dilemma: Lessons from the Rehn-Meidner plan
Caio Vilella 1and Eduardo F. Bastian2
Abstract
Minsky (1965) has presented the Job Guarantee program as a recommendation in the war against unemployment and
poverty. Kalecki (1943), on the other hand, argued that the full employment situation could be technically feasible but
politically hard to implement due to the class struggle, resulting in what we will refer to as the “kaleckian dilemma”.
Based on this contradiction, this paper aims to extract lessons from the Rehn-Meidner Swedish plan, which successfully
combined low unemployment rates and creeping inflation for over three decades, as a means to study the chances of
a Job Guarantee overcoming the kaleckian dilemma. From these lessons, this piece highlights the importance of a
tripartite council bargaining board at the national level to settle the Job Guarantee’s wage level. In addition, we highly
recommended other desirable features, such as international capital control and taxation on extraordinary profits, to
raise the chances of the program successfully dealing with the kaleckian dilemma, just as Rehn-Meidner did.
JEL classification: E11, E31, H53, I30
Keywords: Kaleckian dilemma Job Guarantee Rehn-Meidner plan
1. Introduction
Kalecki’s theory points out full employment 1as theoretically reachable but politically hard to obtain. Kalecki
(1944) suggested three alternative ways to achieve full employment and concluded that a combination of budget
deficit and income redistribution policies would be able to eliminate economic cycles. However, Kalecki (1943)
also suggested the existence of political aspects explaining capitalists’ objection to such an outcome. Hence, the
challenge lies in simultaneously achieving full employment and attenuating the distributive conflict. In a nutshell,
this challenge is what we call the “kaleckian dilemma”2.
Despite being widely known for his “Financial Instability Hypotesis”, Minsky (1965) is another 20th-century
intellectual to worry about unemployment elimination. In Minsky’s proposal, the Government would be re-
sponsible for hiring everyone willing and able to work for a living wage. After some studies about the theme,
1Professor in Economics at Catholic University of Santos. PhD in Economics at Federal University of Rio de Janeiro
(UFRJ). Contact:caio.vilella@hotmail.com
2Associate Professor at Federal University of Rio de Janeiro (UFRJ). Contact: eduardobastian@ie.ufrj.br
1In our understanding, full employment means a state where job vacancies outnumber job seekers regardless of the
current unemployment rate.
2The “kaleckian dilemma” was first addressed by Harcourt (2006), who expressed it as the difference between
the political economy of achieving full employment and the political economy related to the sustainability of such
level. The capitalists’ opposition to full employment would rise due to workers’ growing economic and bargaining
power (Harcourt 2006, 147). However, according to Kalecki (1943), reaching full employment as well as keeping the
economy at full employment are both challenging because of such a rise in workers’ bargaining power. In this paper,
we are going to use the “kaleckian dilemma” in a broader sense than Harcourt (2006) - and more faithful to Kalecki -
once it captures the idea that pushing the economy to full employment and keeping it at this level are two challenges of
the same dilemma which Governments have to deal with.
2
Tcherneva (2018, 2020) refer to this proposal as Job Guarantee and defends this program as a weapon in the
war against poverty and also as a tool to promote the welfare state, where not only income and jobs would be
provided but also goods and services for those most needed.
The Job Guarantee political aspects have been getting a great deal of public attention since Wray (1997).3For
instance, Kriesler et al. (2020) argue that Job Guarantee would eliminate any risk of unemployment. Because
of this, this policy would find it particularly hard to deal with the political aspects compared to other policies of
unemployment elimination. However, at the same time that Kriesler et al. (2020) point out that a Job Guarantee
would reduce unemployment costs, they highlight that a change in the social bargain index could balance this fact.
According to the authors, this index measures the degree of workers’ participation in the terms and conditions
of employment (Kriesler et al. 2020, p.18). Tymoigne (2013) and Tcherneva (2018) also examined the politi-
cal aspects of a Job Guarantee scheme and provided insights from historical cases that offer valuable lessons.
Tymoigne (2013) recognizes the challenge of implementing a Job Guarantee in a context that underestimates
the importance of government interventions. However, he also points out the American work programs of the
New Deal (in the 1930s) to conclude that such challenges are not insurmountable. Tcherneva (2018, p.62) dives
deeper into the historical examples of how to deal with the kaleckian dilemma and mentions the Scandinavian
model as a case of success in conciliating full employment and price stability for a long period of time.
Following the research agenda set forth by Kriesler et al. (2020) and Tcherneva (2018), this paper revisits the
leading institutions of an economic plan that successfully addressed the kaleckian dilemma to identify possible
factors that influenced the social bargain index. The Rehn-Meidner plan (developed in the 1950s and 1960s)
reconciled full employment with price stability for over two decades in post-World War II Sweden. Thus, this
article aims to draw lessons from the success of the Rehn-Meidner plan in addressing the Kaleckian dilemma
in the second half of the 20th century and apply them to successfully implement a Job Guarantee program in
contemporary times.
This paper identifies three institutional features that, despite cultural and geopolitical Swedish idiosyncrasies,
have played a crucial role in addressing the kaleckian dilemma, namely: 1) a universal welfare state model, 2)
a wage cooperation policy, and 3) reduction in the degree of external vulnerability. We actually trace the roots
of the Kaleckian dilemma to the antagonism between classes, making any attempt to overcome it once and for
all unattainable. Building upon the analytical approach presented by Kriesler et al. (2020), we argue that the
Job Guarantee, unlike other full employment policies, has the potential to be an economic tool to replicate these
institutions and, thus, to effectively deal with the Kaleckian dilemma. Doing so improves the chances that the
distributive conflict does not become unruly.
The paper has four more sections besides this introduction. The following section introduces the kaleckian
dilemma. The third section explores the factors that allowed Sweden to be a historical case of an economy that
was able to deal with the kaleckian dilemma over decades. In the fourth section, the paper presents the Job
Guarantee scheme as a way to full employment not mentioned by Kalecki (1944) and which can replicate some
lessons taken from Rehn-Meidner plan in order to ease the conflict claims. Finally, the fifth section brings the
final remarks of the authors.
2. The ways to full employment and the Kaleckian Dilemma
Skeptical about the business cycle control in the absence of the help of an “external factor”, Kalecki (1944) list
three ways to push the economy into full employment: 1) government spending, 2) stimulating private spending,
and; 3) redistribution of income from higher- to lower-income classes. Unconvinced about the effectiveness
of promoting full employment through private spending, the author argues in favor of a mix of policies that
combine government deficits with up-bottom income redistribution. Hence, to make his point, Kalecki (1944)
developed an argument that issues such as the public deficit, the rise in the interest rate, or inflation could not
pose a theoretical limit to the government’s capacity of pursuing full employment.
To overcome the false argument that Government would run out of money to pursue such a goal, Kalecki
3After a long time of ostracism, it was due to the Wray (1997) review that Minsky’s proposal is back in the limelight.
3
(1944) highlights that Government’s budget deficits always finance themselves. Following the principle of effec-
tive demand, the author establishes that every volume of government spending not covered by taxes will compose
the private gross savings. In Kalecki’s (1944, p.360) words:
[..]net savings are always equal to budget deficit plus net investment: whatever the general economic
situation, whatever the level of prices, wages, or the rate of interest, any level of private investment
and budget deficit will always produce an equal amount of saving to finance these two items. Thus
the question of how it is possible to increase government expenditure if expenditure on private
investment and personal consumption is cut is answered by the fact that there will always be such
an increase in incomes as to create an increase in savings equal to the increase in the budget deficit.
In addition, Kalecki (1944) also dismisses the possibility of the interest rate and inflation eroding the Govern-
ment’s capacity to maintain full employment. Instead, Kalecki treated interest rates as completely exogenous and
settled by the Government4. Finally, regarding demand-led inflation, Kalecki (1944) argues that higher demand
will induce firms to invest and push the production’s limits further. So, Kalecki suggests that public demand
should be carefully handled to match the aggregate demand with the production capacity, which we could con-
sider to be disinflationary spending.
Nevertheless, Kalecki (1944) draws attention to the risk of cost-push inflation when the economy approaches
full employment. Conflict claims might become more intense in the immediacy of full employment in the labor
market. In this context, if wages increase faster than productivity, firms will be induced to readjust prices and
foster a new round of wage increases, causing an inflation spiral. According to Kalecki (1944, p.362):
If, however, wage rates increase more than the productivity of labour, arrangements must be made
to prevent prices running away. If no such steps are taken, the workers as a whole do not benefit;
for the increase in money wage rates will be offset by the consequent rise in prices. In addition, a
quick upward movement of prices will be a disturbing feature in an economy of full employment.
Even though budget deficits consist of a feasible way to full employment, Kalecki (1944) introduces the
possibility of promoting full employment by income redistribution. Given the higher propensity to consume from
the worse-off households, a distributive policy that transfers income from capitalists to workers could increase
the society’s average marginal propensity to consume. Such an outcome would be associated with a higher fiscal
multiplier, making the income closer to full employment for a given level of autonomous expenditure. Kalecki
(1944) also mentions the capital taxes and the incentives on mass consumption as policies that could support the
total taxes level for a given tax rate, thus, not affecting the multiplier.
Hence, in a few words, the full employment situation is technically feasible and leads to increasing mass wages
and profits and, under the right circumstances, increasing even the firms’ profit rate (depending on the productiv-
ity growth). Nonetheless, capitalists would still oppose such a situation due to political reasons. Kalecki (1943)
list three reasons: capitalists’ dislike of government interference, their dislike of the direction of government
spending, and their dislike of the social changes due to full employment maintenance.
Economic liberalism amplifies the dependence of the employment level upon the so-called entrepreneurs’ state
of confidence. In a liberal context5, any economic policy that goes against the market interests might reduce the
market’s confidence and, thus, private investment and employment level. Hence, Kalecki (1943, p.350) suggests
that capitalists dislike government interference in the economy in order to keep the highest level of influence on
the business cycles.
Alexander (1948), for instance, has studied the full employment bill of 19456that aimed to ensure the Gov-
ernment’s duty to promote full employment. The author identified that the opponents of this project used to argue
4In defense of his argument, Kalecki (1944) mentions that the English Central Bank during wartime ensured enough
demand for public bonds in order to keep interest rates down despite the higher level of the budget deficit. According
to the author, there is nothing preventing the Government from doing this policy during peacetime.
5We understand the liberal context as minimal government intervention in business affairs.
6Which became the Employment Act of 1946 after some changes.
4
that they were not willing to finance spending that would foster social disorder. Despite its lack of theoretical
support, the argument brings the notion that private agents wished to keep control of the Government’s spending
destination. Sotiropoulos (2011) highlights that regardless of the individual entrepreneurial activity, the laissez-
faire can coalesce all interests against the same goal: ending the budget deficit. According to Kalecki (1943),
this opposition might easily be explained by the fact that the laissez-faire amplifies the economic dependence on
entrepreneurs’ state of confidence.
The second reason capitalists oppose full employment is also a kind of opposition to the budget deficit, but
Kalecki (1943) emphasizes that business leaders resist even harder when the deficit comes from public investment
and subsidies to mass consumption. Unlike deficits that result from capital subsidies, business leaders defy
deficits that arise from job-creating policies. Beyond any technical issue, the reason behind the opposition is
moral: It relies upon the fact that this kind of public intervention attacks the primary capitalist ethic that notably
”you shall earn your bread in sweat” (Kalecki 1943, p.351). In the entrepreneurs’ eyes, it was like the Government
would take away from them the power to decide who and when to hire.
Both reasons mentioned above draw attention to the challenge of reaching full employment, from now on,
we will discuss the challenge of staying at a full employment level. Kalecki (1943) argues that unemployment
gives discipline to workers, something business leaders would appreciate even more than the eventual rise in
profits. Moreover, when the unemployment rate keeps low for a long time, there is a reaction in the costs of
unemployment for workers. This might induce them to bargain for better labor conditions by means of strikes,
for instance.
According to Kriesler et al. (2020, p.13) the unemployment cost described above could be expressed as:
c=(PD+PR)n(w)(1)
Where PDdenotes the probability of job destruction (exogenously given), PRis the probability of replacing
a worker inside the labor market with another worker out of the labor market, nis the unemployment duration, w
is the real wage paid by private firms, and represents the income that workers receive once unemployed, such
as unemployment insurance or some equivalent. If the low unemployment rate situation persists, the average
unemployment duration (n) drops and the distributive conflict rises due to the fall in unemployment cost (c).
The equation 2 is the Kriesler et al. (2020, p.18) representation of the kaleckian dilemma, wherein Z denotes
the intensity of the distributive conflict, and is negatively related to the unemployment cost (c) and with the social
bargain index (B):
Z=Z(c, B)(2)
Zc,Z
B<0
The lower the cost of workers losing their jobs (c), the higher the degree of distributive conflict (Z). The lower
cost implies less financial risk associated with unemployment and induces workers to adopt a more conflictive
behavior. On the other hand, the workforce’s participation in employment terms and conditions will affect B,
and hence, Z(Kriesler et al. 2020, p.18). The increase in Bfostering a fall in Zrepresents the idea that workers
would avoid intensifying conflict with capital owners if they agreed with the bargained terms, even if their
unemployment cost has fallen.
The RM plan in post-war Sweden is a historical example of success in dealing with the kaleckian dilemma.
Unsurprisingly, the literature7often mentions the RM plan as the ideal type of institution that was able to handle
distributive conflict at full employment, meaning the ability to expand Bto compensate for the fall in c. In other
words, Sweden compensated for the low unemployment cost with a high social bargaining index. The following
section will list what we understand to be the three main factors that sustained the high social bargain index
during the RM plan.
7see for instance Crouch (1985) and Tcherneva (2018).
5
3. The Rehn-Meidner Model and the Kaleckian Dilemma
Although stability in distributive conflict was a widely spread characteristic of the post-war era in global north
nations, Sweden excelled in this aspect. Between 1950 and 1955, the average unemployment and inflation rates
in Sweden were 1.8% and 5.4%, respectively. While the unemployment rate average was the same for the 1955-
1960 period, the inflation fell to 3.7%. Afterward, the first half of the 1960s data showed a 1.5% unemployment
rate and 3.7% inflation rate on average against 1.8% (unemployment) and 4.4% (inflation) in the second half. Due
to the oil shocks, the 1970s was one of the most challenging periods for inflation control, especially for small
open economies such as Sweden. As a result, the average unemployment and inflation rate rose respectively to
2.1% and 8% in the first half and to 1.9% and 10.5% in the second half (Bohlin 2014, p.123). After comparing the
data for eighteen countries, Crouch (1985) identifies the Swedish exceptionality in combining low unemployment
rates with price stability, something only comparable to Norwegian and Austrian results.
Gosta Rehn and Rudolf Meidner were intellectually responsible for formulating a plan in Sweden 1951 that
guided the economic policies for the next three decades (the RM plan). However, despite the relative success of
the plan, according to Meidner (1993), the rise in neoliberal ideology shifted the primary economic goal from
full employment to price stability alone. Hence, since the 1970s, low inflation has grown increasingly important
as a goal of public policies. After the balance of payment crisis in 1992 and 1993, the unemployment rate went
above 5% and never returned.
From Meidner’s (1969) perspective, economic stability should be beyond price stability, even though a sound
domestic economic environment might suffer from external shocks affecting the price index regardless of any
change in the national policy. The resilience to price shocks depends on the international competitiveness of
national exports and the impact of such shocks on domestic distributive conflict. Therefore, even in an inflation-
ary period, if foreign competitiveness of domestic products and income distribution are under control, Meidner
(1969) would consider this situation as a stable economic scenario. Understanding this approach is essential to
comprehend the main goals of the RM plan (competitiveness and distribution), which changed after the 1970s
when economic stability became only price stability.
Meidner (1969) did not follow any of Kalecki’s three ways to full employment. He considered that effective
demand spurs should stop just before the productive capacity boundaries and active workforce policies should end
the reminiscent labor force unemployment. Meidner (1993) referred to this strategy as the ”third-way” between
the US laissez-faire and Soviet central planning. In Meidner’s (1993, p.220) words:“ The Swedish system [...]
with an economy that had managed to reconcile market principles with socialist values such as full employment,
equality and solidarity, was hailed as the prototype of a ’Third-Way’ Society.
Meidner (1986, 1993, 1997) suggests that the RM construction began just after the end of the war. In the
1960s, it was already possible to notice the first impacts of the plan that stood until the 1990s, despite the fact
that some features of the plan have been disappearing since the 1970s. Cultural and geopolitical features were
indeed crucial for the plan’s success. However, as previously noted, the kaleckian literature suggests some
institutional aspects that can theoretically reduce distributive conflict. The following section draws attention to a
specific plan characteristic that could explain the favorable social bargain index behavior in the case study.
3.1. The welfare state of the Rehn-Meidner plan
The Swedish welfare model possesses a crucial characteristic that sets it apart from other contemporary models:
universality. In the post-war period, Esping-Andersen (1990) identified three types of welfare models. The first
type, implemented in Canada and the United States, often stigmatizes its beneficiaries, creating an environment
of charity rather than providing necessary assistance. The second category of welfare state models is found in
Western Europe, particularly in countries such as France and Germany. These models tie eligibility for social
benefits to participation in the labor market, thus exacerbating pre-existing inequalities. Finally, the RM welfare
model belongs to a third group in which social benefits are regarded as a fundamental human right that the state
must guarantee for the benefit of all members of society.
According to Hilson (2008), the pursuit of equality in society was based on the notion that economic growth
and the welfare state should be interdependent. Economic growth was deemed necessary for achieving social
6
harmony and providing the foundation for a generous and universal welfare system. Simultaneously, the welfare
system was an essential component of growth policies. Consequently, the Swedish welfare system has consis-
tently aimed at increasing labor productivity since its inception. By combining demand spurs with productivity
growth, the system effectively integrated economic growth with social harmony, as noted by Hilson (2008, p.57).
However, other elements compose this system.
The Swedish Government initiated the ”Million Homes Programme” as a key element of its urbanization
strategy and welfare system. In collaboration with regional authorities, the program aimed to construct one
million homes between 1960 and 1974 (Hall and Vid´
en 2005). The primary objective was to eliminate the
housing deficit, something it achieved within a decade, resulting in a housing surplus. The program was not
limited to the construction of new housing but also included renovation of existing residences, subsidized credit
for financing homes, subsidies for private construction, and government-funded construction of houses. The
residences were incorporated into regional urbanization plans and were designed to meet similar quality standards
but with unique sizes and styles based on regional needs and preferences.
According to Ahnland (2020, p.233), regional entities played a crucial role in executing the welfare plan:
In a modernistic leap, SAP thus realized the visionary ideas of social engineering that had emerged
in previous decades. The party launched an ambitious welfare program where the municipalities
had a central role in providing facilities such as daycare centers, schools, retirement homes and
housing for the general public.
This social engineering required a great Government labor demand to provide public welfare services. Ahn-
land (2020) highlights that the creation of employment by the Government kept the wage share attached to the
housing public investment variation (Ahnland 2020, p.235). This paper provides pieces of evidence that full
employment in Sweden increased wage share with the workers’ bargaining power, which was accommodated by
Government interference in the bargaining level instead of rising distributive conflict.
Rather than the distributive conflict mentioned by Kalecki (1944), some institutional features of the RM plan
draw attention to the importance of a welfare state model with widely popular participation and decentralized
decisions. In a nutshell, we can list some features we deem as crucial to understanding the RM welfare plan:
universality, union participation, municipality, and harmony between growth and welfare.
Shifting the focus from wage-earners to profit-earners, we can also observe significant public interference in
the form of taxing extraordinary profits to compensate for the deficit spending required by the welfare system.
This system would work as a rights-ensuring component of a comprehensive scheme that also moderates wage
demands. The following section will provide more details about the fund created for taxing extraordinary profits.
3.2. Wage Cooperation policy
Meidner (1997) suggests that the RM plan has two main concerns: full employment and equality. As noted by
Meidner (1969), wage readjustments required by unions tend to be higher as the labor market approaches full
employment, given that these entities must represent the workers’ interests (Meidner 1989). An economy aiming
to approach full employment must count on the Government to avoid wage bargains skyrocketing, and conflict
claims out of control.
Perraton (2018) corroborates Meidner’s (1969, 1989) perception by emphasizing the role of the Government
as an intermediary in conflict claims. Moreover, Perraton (2018) points out that the competitive logic does not
hold in Sweden, meaning the prevalence of the cooperative bargaining process. After a bilateral agreement, there
are incentives for both parties to break the terms, as mentioned by the author. If firms break the deal first, they
will enjoy real extraordinary profits until workers raise wages again. Conversely, if workers move first and break
the agreement by increasing wages more than agreed, the real wages will be higher until all industries correct
their prices. This competition could foster higher inflation rate. Therefore, Sweden relies on the Government
to mediate this arrangement, providing more credibility to such a contract. The Government has instruments
to ensure that those deviating from the terms bear the burden, such as taxing extraordinary profits or imposing
penalties on unions that attempt to break the deal.
7
In 1950, the first wage negotiation occurred at the national level between the Swedish Employers’ Confedera-
tion (SAF) and the Labor Organization (LO). The rise in wages gained by one group of workers may affect other
workers and their real wages, thus mitigating the aggregate real wage gain8. Hence, Perraton (2018) suggests that
a centralized negotiation may include the negative externalities of one group on another and, therefore, moderate
partial wage demands to ensure gains at the aggregate level (Calmfors 1993; Calmfors and Driffill 1988). In this
context, firms and workers would avoid intensifying the distributive conflict, shifting the ”market invisible hand”
to what Storm and Naastepad (2012) call the ”visible handshake”, meaning a mediated agreement between firms
and workers in the wage settlement9.
Together with the ”visible handshake,” the Rehn-Meidner plan has implemented an active workforce policy to
address sectoral imbalances that may arise in the labor market (Meidner 1969). Graph 1 depicts the labor supply
in five sectors of an economy, where each bar represents a sector. Assuming that the horizontal axis indicates
the current level of effective demand, an economic policy seeking to increase demand towards the dashed black
line would fail to eliminate unemployment in sector A and exert pressure on all other sectors. Hence, Meidner’s
(1969, 1993) recommendation was to stimulate aggregate demand below full employment in the labor market,
represented by the continuous gray line, and tackle unemployment through active workforce policies. At this
juncture, surplus labor in sectors A and B should be redirected to other industries through training programs.
Figure 1. Unemployment by production’s sector.
A B C D E
Excess of Labor Suply and Aggregate Demand
Industries
Source: Meidner (1969, p.173)
Assuming that the sectors are arranged in ascending order of technological complexity, from the lowest (A)
to the highest (E), the reallocation of the labor force will necessitate the creation of job positions and training
capacity. In addition to spurring demand, the RM plan also included a labor force training program designed to
shift workers to strategic sectors, particularly those with higher technological sophistication, to mitigate import
and inflationary pressures (Meidner 1969). The reallocation of labor across sectors enjoyed the support of the
entire society, including workers, even if some local job positions were eliminated. Workers viewed these policies
as essential for enhancing productivity and, in turn, increasing real wages. Meidner (1986) observes that workers’
backing was part of an implicit pact that guaranteed that the Government would ensure full employment and a
welfare state as long as industrial competitiveness was maintained.
8There is a theoretical issue of whether the centralization in the wage negotiation is indeed able to moderate wage
demand. However, we are focusing on the Swedish case, wherein the literature converges that centralization works (for
more details about this issue, see, for instance, Calmfors (1993); Crouch (1985); Wallerstein (1990)).
9The cooperation would avoid what Lavoie (2014, chap.8) refers as wage-wage inflation.
8
In addition to the visible handshake and active workforce policy, the third noteworthy factor in this section is
the ”wage policy of solidarity,” which can be described as the principle of ”equal pay for equal work” (Meidner
1989, p.17). The concept of wage policy of solidarity is based on the notion that firms should not settle wages
based on their profitability or market conditions but on the value of the work to be done, taking into account
specific skills or time spent working for the company. This policy of equality aims to reduce wage disparities
across various firms.
The wage policy of solidarity had differing impacts on firms with higher and lower productivity levels. The
latter group typically paid lower wages, and as a result of the reduction in the wage gap, they had to increase their
productivity to raise the wage bill and maintain profitability. When productivity growth did not keep pace with
the average wage increase, these firms went bankrupt, creating opportunities for new entrants to pay fair wages.
In contrast, firms with high productivity rates were already conditioned to paying wages above the average, and
moderation allowed them to pay less than before, leading to extraordinary profits resulting from the wage policy
(Meidner 1969). All extraordinary profits not reinvested in productive investments were subject to taxation, with
the collected funds going to a financial fund managed by the LO (Meidner 1989).
Erixon (2008, p.374-375) highlights that in the mid-1980s, the wage policy of solidarity in Sweden was
affected by labor market liberalization. Consequently, this led to greater wage discrepancies among workers of
varying skills and industries during the 1990s. Despite the continuous rise in labor productivity, the profit share in
Sweden has remained exceptionally high since the 1990s compared to both domestic and international historical
norms. Despite functional income concentration and the currency crisis in the 1990s, Swedish wage equality still
ranks high among its peers (Erixon 2008, p.375).
To sum up, this subsection has discussed the visible handshake, active workforce policy, and the combination
of wage policy of solidarity with taxation on extraordinary profit as critical features of the RM model. These
features, however, are not solely linked to Swedish cultural aspects and can be understood through the Kaleck-
ian literature presented in the previous section. A Kaleckian economist may view extraordinary profit taxation
destined for the LO’s fund as a type of capital taxation and incentive for mass consumption, one potential way to
achieve full employment, as proposed by Kalecki (1944).
In conclusion, we emphasize that Sweden has employed a combination of the visible handshake, active work-
force policy, wage policy of solidarity, and profit taxation to enhance the social bargaining index (B). As these
policies extend beyond wage policies, we will refer to them as the ”wage cooperation policy.”
3.3. Reduction of External vulnerability
In the RM model, the reduction of external vulnerability holds paramount importance, yet it is an aspect that is
not frequently mentioned upon in the literature. Even in the mid-1970s, Sweden maintained low unemployment
rates while sustaining an inflation rate that was consistent with that of other countries. This was demonstrated
in table 1, which reveals that while the Swedish average unemployment rate between 1974-1983 was 2.3%, it
was 8.2% in Belgium, 7.2% in Italy, and 7.3% in the Netherlands (Maddison 2007). Furthermore, the price
index for the period (1974-1983) exhibited a variation of 10.2% in Sweden, below the Western Europe average
computed by Maddison (2007, p.134) at 11.2%. This scenario provides concrete evidence of the significance of
characterizing Sweden as a unique country resilient to external upheavals.
The Bretton Woods agreement in the 1940s led many countries to adopt capital controls to prevent exchange
rate instability until the mid-1970s and 1980s. Sweden, however, took additional measures to protect itself
against foreign capital flight and currency crises, which is why the country adhered to the fixed exchange rate
regime until 1993 (Erixon 2008, p.374). In addition to capital controls and exchange rate management, measures
also employed by other countries, Sweden’s protection strategy included the implementation of RM plan policies
aimed at promoting industrial structural changes to strengthen the balance of payments (Meidner 1986).
The Swedish industry during the RM plan period can be represented by dividing it into an exposed and
shielded (from external competition) sectors, which is a characteristic that many peripheral countries still exhibit
today. This division highlights the need for the exposed sector to increase productivity and maintain the external
competitiveness of its products. Nonetheless, the shielded sector bears the burden of reduced labor demand by
9
Table 1. Unemployment and Consumer Price Index Variation in the period 1973-1984
Country Unemployment CPI Variation (%)
Sweden 2.30% 10.20%
Belgium 8.20% 8.10%
Finland 4.70% 10.50%
France 5.70% 11.20%
Germany 4.10% 4.90%
Italy 7.20% 16.70%
Netherlands 7.30% 6.50%
Norway 2.10% 9.70%
United Kingdom 7.00% 13.50%
Ireland 8.80% 15.70%
Spain 9.10% 16.40%
Western Europe Average 6.05% 11.22%
Australia 5.90% 11.30%
Canada 8.10% 9.40%
United Kingdom 7.40% 8.20%
Japan 2.10% 7.60%
Source: Maddison (2007, p.134).
the other sector. Meidner (1986, p.91) mentions the price of foods (Swedish shielded sector) increasing above
the consumer price index for years, for instance. However, the unions’ report of 1960 emphasized that workers’
support for policies that stimulate innovation in the exporter sector was fastened to a public policy that reduces
the balance in the back of workers. Furthermore, the report recommended that the public sector ensure sufficient
availability of good quality food in a variety that matches the domestic consumers’ preferences. In other words,
the export encouragement policy was followed by other policies that aimed to ensure the domestic supply of
products that matched the residents’ demand, especially those worse off.
According to Esping-Andersen (1990), wage growth moderation was even more pronounced during peri-
ods of the higher balance of payment constraints aimed at increasing the external competitiveness of domestic
production. However, in addition to compensatory policies for workers’ sacrifices, training programs played a
significant role in raising productivity and reducing firms’ costs. Moreover, the active workforce policy was
crucial in reallocating workers to a different function while reducing the training costs of export firms, making
them even more competitive (Meidner 1986).
Swedish unions were aware of the importance of fostering the external competitiveness of the domestic in-
dustry and created an institutional structure of R&D divided into three levels: Central, Regional, and Local (Mei-
dner 1986, p.94). At the central level, unions contacted universities and research institutes to collect proposals
for structural change policies to discuss with unionists at the regional level through conferences and workshops.
The discussions at the regional level became strategies to offer to firms at the local level to participate actively
in the development of work and production. In a complementary manner, there was a targeted credit policy for
R&D projects based on the fund composed of extraordinary profit taxation. Furthermore, in the late 1960s, the
Government also began subsidizing long-term credit for export companies from underdeveloped regions through
state credit companies created for this purpose(Quintas and Ianoni 2021).
Regarding external vulnerability, Sweden distinguishes itself from other countries of that era by utilizing the
welfare system and wage cooperation policy as tactical tools to improve its balance of payments situation. This
broader strategy allowed the country to navigate the two oil shocks in the 1970s and the 1980s at a more leisurely
pace compared to most countries with a parallel framework, which had to convert before 1993 to a flexible
exchange rate regime (see Crouch (1985) for instance). The delay in letting the currency fluctuate is crucial to
avoid exchange rate shocks that can propagate the conflict distributive for the economy and breed an inflationary
shock even higher than the immediate impact, as pointed out by Bastian and Setterfield (2020). Consequently,
10
it is notable from the perspective outlined here that the reduction of external vulnerability is a pivotal factor for
economic stability, as defined in Meidner’s (1969) terms. Despite the inflationary increase in Sweden after the
oil shocks, the foreign competitiveness of domestic production and income distribution remained stable.
Hence, we read the reduction of external vulnerability as the third factor Sweden used to increase its social
bargain index when the economy stayed at full employment. As previously mentioned, this was achieved through
a combination of five elements: 1) Foreign capital controls; 2) Matching the domestic supply structure with the
domestic demand; 3) training program of the labor force; 4) an institutional structure of R&D; and 5) target credit
to finance the R&D projects and export sector. In addition, the wage cooperation policy was closely linked to this
reduction in external vulnerability in three distinct ways. Firstly, wage moderation in the most challenging times
gave the required competitiveness to the exporting industries. Secondly, profit taxation, enabled by the cooper-
ation policy, raise the necessary fund to beneficiate strategic sectors regarding the balance of payment concerns.
Finally, the training program played a crucial role in the labor force reallocation to more technologically complex
sectors, reducing the costs of these firms to hire workers that have never worked in this area.
Table 2 summarizes the main RM model characteristics discussed in this section:
Table 2. Main Characteristics of Institutions
Institutions Welfare System Wage Cooperation Policy External Vulnerability Reduction
Universal “Visible handshake” Foreign Capital Control
Main Characteristics
Harmony between economic growth
and welfare system Active workforce policies Supply structure and domestic de-
mand match
Active participation of unions wage policy of solidarity plus ex-
traordinary profit taxation Training program
Building of homes Institutional structure for R&D
Strong role of municipalities Targeted credit for strategic sectors
High participation of public jobs
Source: Authors’ elaboration
This section summarized some institutional elements responsible for the success of the RM plan in deal-
ing with the kaleckian dilemma. The following section will investigate how the Job Guarantee program could
reproduce these features.
4. Job Guarantee Program: The “fourth way” to full employment.
Hyman Minsky was an economist whose ideas were greatly influenced by Kaleckian theories 10. His concerns
about the impact of economic cycles on the underprivileged led him to develop an alternative approach to achiev-
ing full employment. Similar to Meidner (1997), who advocated for ”full employment and equality, Minsky
argued in his 1965 work that full employment was a weapon in the ”war on poverty.” Recognizing the adverse
effects of economic crises on the poor, Minsky (1965, p.1) stated that only a job creation program that “accepts
individuals as they are” could ultimately win this war. In sum, since the Government is the only entity that can
separate the decision to hire from job profitability, it should be responsible for maintaining a constant and totally
elastic labor demand.
In addition to achieving full employment, Minsky (1969a, p.53) was also concerned with regulating it. He
aimed to reduce the wage gap between the highest and lowest earners in the labor market. According to Minsky
(1969b), the Employer of Last Resort should play a regulatory role by setting a wage floor that private companies
should match. The program’s wage should increase above the labor productivity rate, while the highest wages
10 For further details on the influence of Kaleckian theories on Minsky, see Minsky (2013).
11
in the labor market should increase compensatorily below this rate in order to maintain some form of ”social
harmony” (Minsky 1969c, p.56). In other words, the creation of new jobs should not intensify conflicting claim
and harm workers already in the market.
In the early 1990s, Hyman Minsky was mostly recognized for his “Financial Instability Hypothesis.” How-
ever, it was not until the mid-1990s that his proposal for an ”Employer of Last Resort” program received renewed
attention in academic circles. One of Minsky’s students, Randall Wray (1997), revisited the proposal and made
significant progress in exploring the financing of such a program, which Minsky himself had not investigated.
Despite Wray’s contributions, the evolution of Minsky’s proposal did not cease, and in light of Tcherneva’s recent
work (2018, 2020), the program is now referred to as the “Job Guarantee. This relabeling is likely an attempt to
mitigate any stigma associated with the term “last resort.
Although Tcherneva (2018, p.62) makes reference to the Swedish case as a straightforward illustration of the
coexistence between full employment and price stability, there exist a multitude of similarities between the RM
model and the Job Guarantee. Wray (2007a, p.3), explaining the rationale behind the implementation of a Job
Guarantee scheme, argues that it would operate as an active workforce policy bearing a striking resemblance to
those expounded upon in the last section by the figure 1:
Economic growth can raise demand and output in the leading sectors, inducing rising prices that
feed through to CPI-measured inflation, even with substantial unemployment across the economy;
conversely, employment can rise without raising prices if it occurs in lagging sectors that operate
below capacity (Wray 2007a, p.3).
Based on these points, we contend that the Job Guarantee is a “fourth way” to full employment once it
mixes the budget deficit proposal with the income distribution one, plus an active workforce policy. Unlike
the three ways to full employment described by Kalecki (1944), the Job Guarantee has the particularity of not
depending exclusively on traditional demand spurs. Like the RM plan, the Program could open the possibility of
demand spurs ceasing just before the full capacity stage, and the Government would demand the excess labor not
employed so far. Furthermore, the Program’s institutions would have to ensure workforce reallocation among
sectors as previously described.
The literature that followed Minsky’s work on the Job Guarantee (Minsky 1965, 1969a,b,c, 1986) has identi-
fied several additional desirable features to achieve its expected outcomes. Of these, three stand out: the creation
of local job positions, the promotion of production geared towards local consumption, and the establishment of
training programs (Tcherneva 2018)11.
The first desirable feature to highlight is the creation of local job positions with wages settled at the federal
level. Despite this fact, the jobs’ destination should be a regional choice regarding the local necessities and the
community’s understanding of what would be its best use (Tcherneva 2018; Wray 1997). This desirable feature
echoes two of the characteristics identified in table 2: the welfare program’s universality and the role of the
municipalities. The decentralization of the Program administration increases the political cost of putting an end
to it, as demonstrated by the example of the one million homes program, which was ended only in the 1990s,
despite the Workers’ Party leaving the Government in the 1970s. As the Job Guarantee program’s implementation
requires coordination across different levels of public administration, lessons from the Swedish example suggest
that this coordination could be used to align local policies with the country’s strategic interests. Firstly, job
creation should meet local public service and goods production needs, and secondly, it should introduce workers
to labor activities that are strategically important for the country. The supply of labor with more technological
complexity, for instance, could help the labor force reallocation suggested in figure 1.
According to Tcherneva (2018, 2020), the Job Guarantee program should focus on meeting the needs of
disadvantaged neighborhoods. To this end, the program should provide a range of public services, such as child
and elder care, after-school activities, educational classes, artistic and recreational projects, maintenance of public
spaces, community safety, production of organic food, and other services as required by the local community.
11 In Tcherneva (2018, 2020) the reader might find a detailed list of features that program can present. Here we
picked up only the features that we consider useful to deal with the kaleckian dilemma.
12
The provision of such services would constitute a non-monetary benefit in the form of public welfare services for
those participating in the program, as well as for members of the wider community living in the areas benefiting
from the program. The availability of these services would reduce the financial burden on low-income individuals
who would otherwise have to pay out of their own pockets for such services.
The provision of goods and services under the Job Guarantee program has the potential to enhance labor
productivity and promote social harmony through economic growth and welfare policies, as presented in Table
2. This program offers services such as child and elder care, which can reduce the unpaid work burden of
low-income workers who lack access to paid care services, thereby positively impacting their work behavior.
Furthermore, the Job Guarantee program may offer non-monetary benefits such as organic food production and
artistic and recreational projects that improve the quality of life of workers (Tcherneva 2018). Another potential
benefit of the program is the buffer stock of employment operated in housing construction, similar to the Swedish
“one million home“ project. These benefits are part of a broader welfare system that aims to function as a
counterpart to wage coordination policies that can moderate wage growth.
Thus far, we have delineated two features of the Job Guarantee program: the creation of local job positions and
the provision of goods and services for the local community. These features address five characteristics presented
in Table 2, namely: the programs’ universality, harmony between growth and welfare system, the strong role of
municipalities, the high participation of public jobs, and the meeting between supply structure and the domestic
demand.
Finally, the Job Guarantee proposal emphasizes the significance of the training program, as highlighted by
Wray (2020). The workers enrolled in the program must spend an equal amount of time in both labor and
training activities. The training component should prepare these workers with the necessary skills to compete
with others regardless of the time spent unemployed (Kaboub 2007). In the RM plan, the training program was
part of the active workforce policy that aims to increase labor productivity, reallocate labor supply, and reduce
firms’ hiring costs associated with training, all of these seeking to moderate wage bargain and reduce the external
vulnerability (Meidner 1969).
Therefore, table 3 summarizes the characteristics listed in table 2 and distinguishes between those intrinsic
to the Job Guarantee program and those that can be replicated through three desirable features identified in the
current literature. Thus, the characteristics not classified as intrinsic or listed by the desirable features constitute
lessons from the RM model this piece proposes to incorporate.
Thus, according to table 3, the wage cooperation policy is one crucial lesson stemming from the RM model.
As previously argued, the wage cooperation policy must come together with a central bargaining council whether
the Government plays an intermediary role in the wage settling bargain between firms and unions. Although not
an inherent characteristic of the Job Guarantee program, we strongly recommend the adoption of a central bar-
gaining council based on the lessons from the RM plan. In this council, the Government could meet employer’s
associations of each sector, unions, and other class entities interested in the matter to negotiate wage readjust-
ments for each category, with the aim of achieving fair remuneration according to the job profile, similar to the
wage solidarity policy of the RM plan.
In accordance with the wage cooperation policy, we see extraordinary profit taxation as another desirable
feature to include. This type of policy has historically led to a wage moderation that may adversely affect
firms with lower productivity rates while simultaneously benefiting those with higher productivity rates. The
latter group may then register extraordinary profits that can only be achieved through public intervention in the
bargaining process. Therefore, it is suggested that some level of taxation be imposed on these profits, aiming to
support the program’s administrative costs. Although the Federal Government does not need taxes to finance its
spending, as argued by Kalecki (1944) and Wray (2020, 1997), the budget deficit might assemble private interests
against the Job Guarantee expenses. Conversely, taxing those highly productive firms will split the interests into
two parts: one part of the capitalists will benefit from the taxes that aim to put them compete on equal footing
with another part, which will oppose them. Hence, such taxation will break the bias of the budget deficit in
assembling capitalists’ interests.
In conclusion, the third and final essential lesson that can be learned from the RM plan relates to foreign
13
Table 3. Rm Plan vs Job Guarantee
Main characteristics of the RM plan Job Guarantee (JG) program’s characteristics
Universality Intrinsic to JG.
Active workforce policies Intrinsic to JG, according to Wray (2007b).
High participation of public jobs Intrinsic to JG.
Strong role of municipalities Replicated by regionally defined job posts.
Meeting productive structure with domestic de-
mand
Replicated both by production aimed at serving
the local population and by the training program
enabling labor reallocation.
Training of the workforce Replicated by the training program highlighted
in Wray (2020) and Tcherneva (2018)
Harmony between economic growth and the wel-
fare system
Replicated by the institutionalization of local job
posts producing services to meet local workers’
needs.
Housing construction Possible to be incorporated by the generated jobs.
Active participation of unions Not replicated in the current literature.
”Visible handshake” Not replicated in the current literature.
Foreign Capital Control Not replicated in the current literature.
Wage solidarity with profit taxation Not replicated in the current literature.
R&D institutional structure Not replicated in the current literature.
Targeted credit to export sectors of the economy Not replicated in the current literature.
Source: Authors’ elaboration
capital controls, which prioritize long-term investments rather than short-term ones. By implementing sanctions
on speculative capital inflows, the risk of significant overnight currency depreciation due to the flight of foreign
capital to core countries can be reduced. The low external vulnerability of Sweden during the RM era enabled the
country to be better protected against abrupt changes in the social bargain index due to external shocks than its
peers. Although it is acknowledged that the current may turn impossible to replicate the exact degree of external
exposure present during the Bretton Woods period, a combination of policies, such as the provision of goods
and services focused on domestic consumption, workforce reallocation through training programs, and capital
controls, could alleviate the Balance of Payment constraints, especially in the case of peripheral countries.
Now suppose that the above list of desirable features is fully integrated into a Job Guarantee program. In
that case, it would enhance the program’s capacity to manage the intensity of distributive conflict (Z) whilst
simultaneously reducing the cost of unemployment (c) of equations 1 and 2. Graphically, this effect can be
represented by a downward shift in the Bcurve from Bto B0, given that Bhas a negative impact on Z.
In this context, the convergence of a welfare state, wage cooperation policy, and a reduction in external vulner-
ability could potentially sustain the equivalent level of distributive conflict intensity (Z) while simultaneously
upholding a lower unemployment cost (c1<c
0). Most likely, the specific Swedish political environment preced-
ing the RM plan, along with the geopolitical circumstances of that era, rendered a certain degree of distributive
conflict intensity feasible, a level that is currently challenging to reproduce. Nonetheless, the replication of its in-
stitutional framework may replicate its outcomes, albeit to a lesser extent12. Whether the new Z level can trigger
an uncontrollable conflict assertion hinges on the response of capitalists. However, the Job Guarantee Program
mitigates the probability of such an occurrence by curtailing the Z level. When we consider full employment as
a target, the Kaleckian dilemma indicates that pushing the economy towards this target sets off forces that work
against it, primarily due to political factors. Thus far, we have highlighted some factors that, when activated,
12 This concept can be visually represented as a curve between B and B’.
14
Figure 2. Conflict intensity (Z).
C
Z
B
B'
!!
!"
"
Source: Authors’ elaboration based on Kriesler et al. (2020)
might act as resistance against these political forces, preventing the economy from deviating further from the
full employment target. The Job Guarantee could render the full employment level less conflict-prone than it
presently is within the current labor-capital relationship. This capability could enhance the program’s resilience
when confronting the political barriers inherent in implementing a full employment policy in a capitalist society,
as advocated by Tymoigne (2013, p.85).
It is worth noting that a possible limitation could arise in the case of a low aggregate demand level, in which
only the Job Guarantee would be implemented to foster full employment. We can see this situation by a line
below the x-axis in figure 1. Meidner (1969) contended that a positive growth rate at a stable level is necessary
for the active workforce to deliver the desired outcome, as illustrated in Figure 2. Otherwise, the degrowth
burden’s distribution among society could intensify the conflict claims and decline the union coverage rate and
the agents’ adhesion to the agreed terms. In such circumstances, the policy could not ensure a positive effect
on B. It bears mentioning that Minsky’s (1986) recommendation of a Job Guarantee program was part of a
broader set of economic policy proposals. Initially, Minsky (1986) proposed that the Central Bank should serve
as the Lender of Last Resort (Big-Bank), avoiding asset deflation during a crisis and ensuring adequate liquidity
for the system’s healthy functioning. Second, the Government should act as the Big-Government to bolster
effective demand through its fiscal policy. In this framework, the Job Guarantee program would be a practical
policy suggestion within the Big-Government role. Hence, although the Job Guarantee stays in the spotlight in
this paper, the traditional monetary and fiscal policies are essential features of a broader economic plan to push
demand close to full employment and complement the strategy with a program like the one described here.
5. Final Remarks
Kalecki not only demonstrated the technical procedures for achieving and maintaining full employment but also
identified three reasons that would dissuade capitalists from supporting this situation, though both workers and
capitalists would benefit from it. This conundrum, known as the kaleckian dilemma, lies in the capitalist’s class
antagonism due to the level of the distributive conflict.
Nevertheless, despite the fact that class antagonism is a constant in capitalist societies, the Swedish RM plan
(1951-1980) could deal with such a dilemma for over three decades. In this context, even though workers’ eco-
nomic and social bargaining power has risen, their wage demand was contained through government mediation,
15
and the benefits came in the form of a welfare state. As Kriesler et al. (2020) explains, the Swedish model
lowered the intensity of distributive conflict by increasing the social bargain index.
The third section of this piece outlines the main characteristics of the three institutions that enabled Sweden
to handle the social bargain index to overcome the kaleckian dilemma. The first institution was the welfare
system which was marked by its universality, regional structure, generation of public job positions, and working
as the counterpart of the wage growth moderation that made it possible for the working class to get its demands
satisfied by a mechanism out of the private labor market, enabling a harmony between economic growth and
welfare system. Secondly, we introduced the wage cooperation policy as a Swedish institution that combined
the policy of wage solidarity, which allowed extraordinary profit taxation, with the “visible handshake” and the
active workforce policy. According to this institution, wages were settled by a council at the national level with
a high coverage rate and widely accepted by workers of all sorts. Lastly, we also list the reduction of external
vulnerability as an institution erected by the RM plan. Although the plan was situated in the Bretton Woods era,
which was marked by capital controls and less exchange rate variability, Sweden went further and used active
workforce policies, targeted credit, and R&D structure to put its exports to compete on equal footing in the global
market. Each of these institutions played some role in increasing the social bargain index that enabled stabilizing
the conflict claims even in a full employment situation over three decades.
In the section that followed the lessons from the RM plan, we revisited the Minsky proposal of an Employer of
Last Resort as a “fourth way” to full employment. Minsky’s scheme, also defended by Kaboub (2007); Tcherneva
(2018); Wray (2007b) as Job Guarantee, would combine the Kaleckian policies of the budget deficit and income
distribution with an active workforce policy. The Kaleckian policies (budget deficit with income distribution)
would stop just before full employment to avoid overheating specific sectors. Meanwhile, an infinitely elastic
public demand for jobs ends once and for all with involuntary unemployment, mitigating the impact of economic
cycles on vulnerable workers. Besides working as an automatic stabilizer, which contrasts with a discretionary
fiscal policy that can easily be reverted from a political viewpoint, Job Guarantee could incorporate the desired
features highlighted in this work to address the Kaleckian dilemma.
Thus, the fourth section examined whether the Job Guarantee’s desirable features could reproduce the RM
model characteristics. Among the six desirable features listed to reproduce the RM’s outcome, three of them
have already been mentioned by the current literature: local jobs, training programs, and production targeted
at serving local consumption. Nevertheless, seeking to reproduce all the lessons from the RM plan, this paper
suggested three other desirable features: wage cooperation policy, extraordinary profit taxation, and foreign
capital control.
It is important to note our recognition of the weight of the kaleckian dilemma within a capitalist monetary pro-
duction system. Our objective was to provide some theoretical institutional elements that have previously enabled
a country in such a system to better manage the distributive conflict arising from full employment. Therefore, this
paper contributes theoretically by proposing a Minskian full employment scheme that has the potential to repli-
cate these institutional elements. The next step would be for each country to determine whether such institutions
align with their goals, and the rest, as Meidner used to say, would be a matter of ”social engineering.
References
Ahnland, L. 2020. “The wage share and government job creation in Sweden, 1900–2016.”. Labor History 61 (3-4).
Alexander, S. S. 1948. “Opposition to Deficit Spending for the Prevention of Unemployment.”. In Income, Employment and
Public Policy. Essays in Honour of Alvin H. Hansen, Chapter II. New York: W . W. Norton Company.
Bastian, E. F., and M. Setterfield. 2020. “Nominal exchange rate shocks and inflation in an open economy: Towards a struc-
turalist inflation targeting agenda.”. Cambridge Journal of Economics 44 (6).
Bohlin, J. 2014. “Swedish industrial policy: From general policies to crisis management, 1950-1980.”. In Industrial Policy in
Europe after 1945: Wealth, Power and Economic Development in the Cold War, 113–133. Palgrave Macmillan.
Calmfors, L. 1993. “Centralisation of wage bargaining and macro economic performance. A survey..”. OECD Economic
Studies 21.
16
Calmfors, L., and J. Driffill. 1988. “Centralization of wage bargaining and macroeconomic performance.”. Economic Pol-
icy 3 (6).
Crouch, C. 1985. “Conditions for trade union wage restraint..”. In The politics of inflation and economic stagnation, edited by
L. Lindeberg and S. Charles, Chapter 5. Brookings Institution Press.
Erixon, L. 2008. “The Swedish third way: An assessment of the performance and validity of the Rehn-Meidner model.”.
Cambridge Journal of Economics 32 (3).
Esping-Andersen, G. 1990. The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Hall, T., and S. Vid´
en. 2005. “The million homes programme: A review of the great Swedish planning project.”. Planning
Perspectives 20 (3).
Harcourt, G. C. 2006. The structure of post-keynesian economics: The core contributions of the pioneers. Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.
Hilson, M. 2008. The nordic model: scandinavia since 1945. Reaktion books.
Kaboub, F. 2007. “Employment Guarantee Programs: A Survey of Theories and Policy Experiences.”.
Kalecki, M. 1943. “Political Aspects of Full Employment.”. The Political Quarterly 14 (4).
Kalecki, M. 1944. “Three ways to full employment.”. In Collected works of Michal Kalecki V.I. Capitalism: Business cycles
and full employment., edited by J. Osiatynski. Oxford University Press.
Kriesler, P., J. Halevi, and M. Setterfield. 2020. “Political Aspects of ‘Buffer Stock’ Employment: A Reconsideration.”. SSRN
Electronic Journal.
Lavoie, M. 2014. Post-Keynesian Economics: New foundations. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.
Maddison, A. 2007. The World Economy: A millenial perspective. Paris: DEVELOPMENT CENTRE OF THE ORGANISA-
TION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT.
Meidner, R. 1969. “Active Manpower Policy and the Inflation Unemployment-Dilemma.”. The Swedish Journal of Eco-
nomics 71 (3).
Meidner, R. 1986. “Swedish Union Strategies Towards Structural Change.”. Economic and Industrial Democracy 7 (1).
Meidner, R. 1989. “The Swedish Labour Movement at the Crossroads: Interview with Rudolf Meidner.”. Studies in Political
Economy 28 (1).
Meidner, R. 1993. “Why did the Swedish model fail?.”. Socialist Register 29.
Meidner, R. 1997. “The Swedish model in an era of mass unemployment.”. Economic and Industrial Democracy 18 (1).
Minsky, H. P. 1965. “Address Presented at a Conference on” Labor and the War Against Poverty.”.
Minsky, H. P. 1969a. “Policy and Poverty, Part I.”.
Minsky, H. P. 1969b. “Policy and Poverty, Part II.”.
Minsky, H. P. 1969c. “Policy and Pverty, Part III.”.
Minsky, H. P. 1986. Stabilizing an unstable economy. Yale University Press.
Minsky, H. P. 2013. “The relevance of Kalecki: The Useable Contribution.”. PSL Quartely Review 67 (265): 95–106.
Perraton, J. 2018. “Social corporatism and capital accumulation: The fate of the nordic model.”. Intereconomics 53 (4).
Quintas, F. M., and M. Ianoni. 2021. “The rehn-meidner plan and the Swedish development model in the golden years.”.
Brazilian Journal of Political Economy 41 (1).
Sotiropoulos, D. P. 2011. “Kalecki’s dilemma: Toward a Marxian political economy of neoliberalism.”. Rethinking Marx-
ism 23 (1).
Storm, S., and C. W. M. Naastepad. 2012. Macroeconomics Beyond the NAIRU. Harvard University Press.
Tcherneva, P. R. 2018. “The Job Guarantee: Design, Jobs, and Implementation.”. SSRN Electronic Journal.
Tcherneva, P. R. 2020. The Case for a Job Guarantee. Cambridge: Polity.
Tymoigne, E. 2013. “Job Guarantee and Its Critiques: Insights from the New Deal Experience.”. International Journal of
Political Economy 42 (2).
Wallerstein, M. 1990. “Centralized Bargaining and Wage Restraint.”. American Journal of Political Science 34 (4).
Wray, L. R. 2007a. “Minsky’s Approach to Employment Policy and Poverty: Employer of Last Resort and the War on
Poverty.”.
Wray, L. R. 2020. “The ’Kansas City’ Approach to Modern Money Theory.”.
Wray, R. L. 1997. “Government as Employer of Last Resort: Full Employment Without Inflation.”.
Wray, R. L. 2007b. “The Employer of Last Resort programme: Could it work for devoloping countries?.”. Technical report,
International Labour Office, Geneva.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
In general, the literature on the developmental state studies Asia and Latin America, not Scandinavia. This article examines the developmental character of the state in Sweden, distinguishing it as a specific case, because its institutions and policies combine the simultaneous promotion of industrialization and social equity. The paper analyzes the Swedish model of development, centered in Rehn-Meidner Plan (R-M), a political strategy of the national development headed by the Swedish Social Democratic Party (SAP). It is argued that in Sweden industrialization and the construction of the welfare state were two sides of the same coin. The R-M Plan played a key role in consolidating the Swedish model between 1945 and 1975. It combined and articulated economic development, centered on industrialization, reduction of social inequalities, and fiscal and monetary stability. It increased productive complexity and equality, unified economic policy and social policy, planned industrialization and income redistribution. It was structured through a broad power pact among workers, industry, farmers, political representatives elected by SAP and public bureaucracy. It was institutionalized, above all, by the democratic corporatist arrangement of centralized salary negotiations.
Article
Full-text available
This investigation explores the long-run relationship between the wage share in the non-construction private sector and government efforts to create jobs in public services and construction of infrastructure and houses, in Sweden in 1900 to 2016. In the present article, it is argued that the creation of employment with generous wages by the Swedish government has increased the bargaining power of workers outside of these sectors, thus raising the wage share, up to about 1980. Correspondingly, retrenchment from such policy has been detrimental for the wage share in recent decades. This argument is supported by the results of cointegration tests, estimation of long-run and short-run, speed of adjustment, coefficients, as well as by Impulse-response functions. While government consumption is often found to be an important determinant for the wage share, earlier research has neglected the full labor market effect of government job creation associated with an expansion of the welfare state. Sweden is an ideal case for studying the impact of welfare policy on the wage share, since it has been one of the most extensive welfare states and simultaneously has been one of the most egalitarian countries in the world.
Article
Full-text available
An extensive literature has examined whether corporatist national wage bargaining systems can deliver superior economic performance, but this has mostly focused on short run indicators. Such systems of industrial relations could provide incentives for investment if organized labour can credibly pre-commit to wage moderation. This paper examines this, building on monopoly union models that indicate the response of corporatist wage bargaining arrangements to investment. The paper estimates the response of wage bargaining to capital investment, conditional on outside options, in six key economies widely characterized as having sustained corporatist bargaining arrangements over 1970-2017. The econometric approach allows changes in regimes to be determined endogenously; these shifts appear consistent with wider evidence on changes in bargaining arrangements and financial integration of these economies.
Article
This paper develops a model of inflation in an open economy. The model permits analysis of the susceptibility of open economies to permanent inflationary consequences arising from transitory foreign exchange shocks. Sources of structural vulnerability to such events are identified, and means of addressing these structural vulnerabilities are discussed. Ultimately, the paper arrives at a ‘structuralist inflation targeting agenda’. Based on a proper conception of inflation dynamics, this involves ‘getting inflation targeting right’ rather than either accepting mainstream inflation targeting prescriptions or simply neglecting inflation altogether.
Chapter
This paper summarises the key elements of G. C. Harcourt’s (2006) book of the same title. Special emphasis is given to the contribution of the Cambridge pioneers, such as John Maynard Keynes, Richard Kahn, Joan Robinson, Nicholas Kaldor, Michał Kalecki, Richard Goodwin, Piero Sraffa, Luigi Pasinetti, and Dennis Robertson. The objective of their approaches is to comprehend the dynamics of an advanced capitalist economy, particularly in the context of a monetary system of production. Here, investment leads and saving follows, while the marginal propensity to save of capitalists is greater than that of workers. The economic surplus is produced in the consumption goods sector, and utilised in the capital goods sector. Mark-up pricing is important for the determination of the surplus, as is the trade off between profit-margins and sales. Kalecki’s principle of increasing risk plays a role in the cyclical dynamics, as does the two-sided relationship between profitability and accumulation. The prevailing business climate is important in determining future expectations, while endogenous money and credit help to finance investment. Growth is thus endogenous in these models of finance, accumulation and profit, while potential conflict plays a role in the pricing and investment decisions and in the process of inflation. A general policy vision emanates from these foundations.
Chapter
By industrial policy we may denote every type of policy intended to influence the pace and direction of structural change in the economy. Using this definition, we refer to not only the foreseeable and unforeseeable consequences of industrial policy measures, but also the unintended consequences of other policy measures, such as those in macroeconomic policy. As such, industrial policy is an elusive concept. In their introduction to European Industrial Policy, James Foreman-Peck and Giovanni Federico1 define three levels of industrial policy: a) ‘creating the landscape’, by which is meant the creation of clearly defined property rights; b) policies aiming at ‘modifying the ecological environment’, meaning growth policies which similarly affect all firms and sectors; and c) ‘changing the fauna’, that is policies aiming to further specific sectors or firms, which is often referred to as a ‘picking the winner policy’. Most policies followed in Sweden before the late 1960s fall into the second category. This does not, however, rule out that some firms or sectors benefitted from certain policies more so than did others.