ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

We integrate Friedman’s plucking model and the gap version of Okun’s law by embedding output and the unemployment rate in a bivariate unobserved components model with Markov-switching to examine their asymmetric co-fluctuations in the U.S. economy. The results establish that output and unemployment are synchronously and proportionally characterized by the plucking property. Given that the labour market has been identified as the source of the plucking property, we suggest that the plucking property, through stable Okun’s law, transmits from unemployment to output. Our proposed asymmetric bivariate model provides two additional results regarding two specification aspects of trend-cycle decomposition: First, we identify an unprecedented deceleration in U.S. potential output in the aftermath of the 2007−09 financial crisis. Second, our model yields a robust estimation of parameters and components with insignificant correlations between shocks.
Asymmetric Co-fluctuations of U.S. Output and Unemployment:
Friedman’s Plucking Model and Okun’s Law
Mohammad Dehghani†,* Sungjun Cho Stuart Hyde
30 October 2023
Abstract
We integrate Friedman’s plucking model and the gap version of Okun’s law by embedding output
and the unemployment rate in a bivariate unobserved components model with Markov-switching to
examine their asymmetric co-fluctuations in the U.S. economy. The results establish that output and
unemployment are synchronously and proportionally characterized by the plucking property. Given
that the labour market has been identified as the source of the plucking property, we suggest that the
plucking property, through stable Okun’s law, transmits from unemployment to output. Our proposed
asymmetric bivariate model provides two additional results regarding two specification aspects of
trend-cycle decomposition: First, we identify an unprecedented deceleration in U.S. potential output
in the aftermath of the 2007−09 global financial crisis. Second, our model yields a robust estimation
of parameters and components with insignificant correlations between shocks.
Keywords: Business Cycle Asymmetries, Friedman’s Plucking Model, Okun’s Law, Structural Break,
Trend-Cycle Decomposition.
JEL Classification: C32, E32, F44, O47.
† Alliance Manchester Business School, The University of Manchester, Booth Street, Manchester M15 6PB, U.K.
Emails: mohammad.dehghani@manchester.ac.uk, sungjun.cho@manchester.ac.uk, stuart.hyde@manchester.ac.uk.
* Mohammad Dehghani is the corresponding author. We express our gratitude to Prof. Klaus Reiner Schenk-Hoppê
and Prof. Ivan Petrella for all the useful comments they provided. See the data and replicating code on the following
website: sites.google.com/view/mohammaddehghani.
2
1. Introduction
In contrast to the mainstream view in the business cycle literature, the plucking model proposed by
Milton Friedman (1964, 1993) suggests an asymmetric cyclical component, meaning that output does
not fluctuate around a long-run trend but instead is steeply plucked down below a ceiling, known as
potential output, during recessions and gradually returns toward this ceiling during recoveries. This
business cycle asymmetry is referred to as the plucking property or ceiling effect. In this regard, few
studies have empirically established the business cycle asymmetry in U.S. output (see, e.g., Kim and
Nelson, 1999a; Sinclair, 2010; Eo and Morley, 2022), which suggests that stabilization policies may
raise economic welfare by affecting the total average of output.
1
Likewise, the U.S. unemployment rate does not fluctuate around the trend, but it is characterized by
steep jumps above the natural rate of unemployment during recessions and gradual decrements to its
natural level during recoveries. Indeed, the unemployment rate distribution displays a remarkable
positive skewness, which is referred to as deepness asymmetry by Neftci (1984) and Sichel (1993).
Recently, Ferraro (2018), Dupraz et al. (2019), and Ferraro and Fiori (2023), by developing a number
of equilibrium models for the unemployment rate, have documented that the source of the plucking
property is search frictions and nominal wage rigidities in the U.S. labour market, yet their models
do not consider the potential transmission of such a plucking property from unemployment to output.
Okun’s law, first proposed by Arthur Okun (1962), is an empirical relation between U.S. output and
unemployment rate gaps. Although some studies state that Okun’s law has weakened over time or
cast doubt on its stability during recessions (Gordon, 2010; Owyang and Sekhposyan, 2012; Grant,
2018), many other researchers conclude in favour of the stability of Okun’s law (Galí et al., 2012;
Daly et al., 2014; Ball et al., 2017; Michail, 2019; among many others). Therefore, given the stability
of Okun’s law, fluctuations in output and unemployment must be synchronous and proportional; that
is what we call “co-fluctuations.
Considering Friedman’s plucking model and Okun’s law together, asymmetric fluctuations appear
to be a common feature of both U.S. output and the unemployment rate. We refer to this phenomenon
as “asymmetric co-fluctuationsof U.S. output and the unemployment rate. Since business cycle
asymmetries are more pronounced in unemployment (see, e.g., Falk, 1986; Sichel, 1993; McKay and
Reis, 2008), and the U.S. labour market is identified as the source of the plucking property, it seems
that the plucking property transmits from unemployment to output.
1
The asymmetric business cycle, instead of contraction and expansion, identifies recession and recovery as two
phases of business cycles. The term recession refers to the period in which output recedes from its potential, and
recovery conveys the period of returning to potential output. Therefore, stabilization policies, in this framework,
have the potential to increase the total average of output by reducing fluctuations.
3
In this study, we incorporate Friedman’s plucking model and Okun’s law into a bivariate Unobserved
Components (UC) model with Markov-switching to investigate the asymmetric co-fluctuations. This
model comprises four specification aspects, each of which entails choosing between two alternative
assumptions. The choices made on each of these aspects remarkably alter the features of the trend
and cyclical components estimated by different studies. We, therefore, discuss our choices on each
aspect by briefly reviewing the literature on trend-cycle decomposition.
2
The first aspect is whether the fluctuations in U.S. output and the unemployment rate are asymmetric
or symmetric. We select the asymmetric choice for this aspect since Kim and Nelson (1999a), Mills
and Wang (2002), De Simone and Clarke (2007), Sinclair (2010), Morley and Piger (2012), and Eo
and Morley (2022), by applying a univariate UC model with Markov-switching, confirm that output
fluctuations in the U.S. and other advanced economies are asymmetric. The second aspect concerns
whether unemployment must be included as an auxiliary within a bivariate model or not. Following
Clark (1989) and Morley and Wong (2020), we select to include the unemployment rate in our model.
As demonstrated by Gonzalez-Astudillo and Roberts (2022), this arrangement makes the features of
the estimated output components robust to changes in the specification of other aspects, in particular
the correlation between shocks.
The third aspect asks whether the trend growth of U.S. output is stochastic or deterministic. There is
a plethora of evidence supporting the presence of a time-varying drift (trend growth) in the output of
the U.S. and other advanced economies that reflects decline in productivity growth (Antolin-Diaz et
al., 2017; Fernald et al., 2017). Therefore, we utilize stochastic trend growth, namely a random walk
process, which is advocated by Clark (1987), Grant and Chan (2017a), and Kim and Chon (2020).
Alternatively, following Perron and Wada (2009), Luo and Startz (2014), Grant and Chan (2017b),
and Eo and Morley (2022), we adopt a specification for trend growth that accounts for a structural
break. Finally, the fourth aspect asks whether the correlation between shocks to the trend and cyclical
components matters or not. We exclude correlations in the main setup, yet we allow for correlations
to verify the robustness of our results.
3
We cast the proposed bivariate UC model with Markov-switching, which we name the asymmetric
bivariate model for ease of writing, and a number of alternative models into their state-space forms
to estimate parameters and log likelihood values.
4
For hypothesis testing, we use several pairwise
2
Table A1 in Appendix A lists the choice of each study in the literature for each of the four specification aspects.
3
There is a puzzle about the correlation between shocks to the trend and cyclical components, particularly in the
univariate UC model. In this regard, Basistha (2007), Wada (2012), and Iwata and Li (2015) show that the univariate
correlated UC model is subject to spurious correlation, meaning that the estimated correlation might pile-up towards
unity even though the true correlation parameter is zero.
4
Namely, we perform the symmetric bivariate UC model used by Clark (1989) and Gonzalez-Astudillo and Roberts
(2022), the univariate UC model proposed by Clark (1987), the univariate correlated UC model of Morley et al.
(2003), and the asymmetric univariate UC models of Kim and Nelson (1999a) and Sinclair (2010).
4
comparisons of log likelihoods estimated for the asymmetric bivariate model and those estimated for
nested models. Estimation results establish the asymmetric co-fluctuations; indeed, grounded on the
stable gap version of Okun’s law, we observe that output and unemployment are synchronously and
proportionally characterized by the plucking property. In particular, the estimated coefficients of the
plucking property and Okun’s law are 0.7 and -1.45, respectively, with small standard errors of 0.06
and 0.12. The likelihood ratio for testing the asymmetry is 91.2, which is substantially greater than
the 0.1% critical value of 10.8. Also, estimated gaps that are large in magnitude and often negative
for output and positive for unemployment verify the ceiling effect: output seldom ascends above the
ceiling (potential output), and correspondingly, the unemployment rate seldom descends below the
floor (natural rate). Further, the expected duration is about 3 quarters for recessions and 28 quarters
for recoveries, suggesting that recessions are short and recoveries are long. Overall, co-fluctuations
are asymmetric in amplitude, speed, and duration, which highlights that deep, steep, and transitory
recessions tend to be followed by commensurate, gradual, and permanent recoveries. This conclusion
is consistent with the empirical results of Neftci (1984), Sichel (1993), Friedman (1993), Kim and
Nelson (1999a), Sinclair (2010), Morley and Piger (2012), and Eo and Morley (2022), who test cycle
asymmetry for output and the unemployment rate separately.
Additionally, given that Ferraro (2018), Dupraz et al. (2019), and Ferraro and Fiori (2023) identify
the U.S. labour market as the source of the plucking property, we propose that the plucking property
transmits from the unemployment rate to output. To support this expression, we demonstrate that the
gap version of Okun’s law is indeed stable as long as asymmetric fluctuations of U.S. unemployment
and stochastic trend growth in U.S. output are accommodated.
Moreover, we document a gradual decline in U.S. output trend growth that began in the 1960s, which
is in accordance with Antolin-Diaz et al. (2017), Grant and Chan (2017a), Fernald et al. (2017), and
Kim and Chon (2020). We, however, observe that this decline has been exacerbated as a result of an
unprecedented deceleration in U.S. potential output in the aftermath of the 2007−09 financial crisis,
which is consistent with Luo and Startz (2014), Grant and Chan (2017b), and Eo and Morley (2022),
who find a structural break in trend growth around 2008. Concerning correlations between shocks,
an asymmetric bivariate model that accounts for both asymmetry and co-fluctuations yields robust
results with insignificant correlations. Finally, we apply a large number of bivariate and univariate
models to U.S. real GDP and U.S. unemployment to verify the robustness of our proposed model.
We also apply the proposed model to other time series, including U.S. real GDP per capita and U.K.
real GDP. In addition, we modify the proposed model to explore the COVID-19 recession.
Establishing asymmetric co-fluctuations of U.S. output and the unemployment rate suggests that
stabilization policies can raise the total average of output. Bearing this policy implication in mind,
5
this study contributes to the literature in several ways. To our knowledge, we are the first to explain
the asymmetric co-fluctuations by simultaneously characterizing the plucking property in U.S. output
and unemployment. We, thus, augment the univariate UC models with Markov switching presented
by Kim and Nelson (1999a), Sinclair (2010), and Eo and Morley (2022) by including unemployment
within the bivariate model, and augment the bivariate UC models presented by Clark (1989), Grant
(2018), and Gonzalez-Astudillo and Roberts (2022) by including a Markov-switching process in the
model. The model of this study provides two additional results: an unprecedented deceleration in
U.S. potential output and an insignificant correlation between shocks.
Last of all, jointly estimating the trends of output and unemployment while the plucking property is
accounted for offers a measure for the natural rate defined as a floor (lower limit) of unemployment,
which is linked to potential output as a ceiling (upper limit) of output. In light of the gap version of
Okun’s law, the natural rate in our model is the unemployment rate at which the output gap is zero,
and accordingly, it is named the Zero Output Gap Rate of Unemployment (ZOGRU). This measure
is a counterpart for the Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment (NAIRU), which applies
the Phillips curve to estimate the unemployment rate at which the inflationary pressure is zero.
The remainder of this paper reviews the literature on asymmetric business cycles and Okun’s law in
Section 2. Section 3 describes the data and methodology and also specifies the bivariate model as
well as univariate models applied to output and unemployment separately. In this section, we also
present alternatives to our choices regarding four specification aspects of trend-cycle decomposition.
Section 4 presents the results and discussion for the asymmetric bivariate model as well as several
alternative bivariate and univariate models. Finally, Section 5 provides the conclusion.
2. Literature review
This study relates to three branches of existing literature: the business cycle, Okun’s law, and trend-
cycle decomposition. In this section, we describe the controversy between two schools of thought in
the business cycle literature. We then review various attributes of business cycle asymmetries, and
then turn to the disagreement over the stability of Okun’s law. Regarding the literature on trend-cycle
decomposition, the four specification aspects are discussed in detail in the methodology section.
2.1.1 Business cycles: Friedman’s plucking model versus symmetric models
Typically, the business cycle literature supposes that output fluctuates symmetrically around a trend
known as the natural level. In this view, the peak of an expansion is above the trend meaning that the
economy can produce more than its natural level, and at the trough of a recession, output is below its
natural level. For example, the Real Business Cycle (RBC) model, proposed by Kydland and Prescott
(1982) and Long and Plosser (1983), regards technological shocks as the main drivers of symmetric
6
fluctuations. Although technological shocks play a role, the standard RBC tends to overlook the role
of adverse events such as wars, oil crises, financial crises, and the COVID-19 pandemic in shaping
recessions and the role of responsive policy in fostering recoveries. Most trend-cycle decompositions
also assume shocks to the cyclical component are symmetric (see, e.g., Beveridge and Nelson, 1981;
Nelson and Plosser, 1982; Harvey, 1985; Clark, 1987, 1989; Morley et al., 2003; Perron and Wada,
2009; Grant and Chan, 2017a, 2017b; Grant, 2018; Kim and Chon, 2020; Kim and Kim, 2022). On
the contrary, Friedman’s plucking model (1993) suggests business cycle asymmetry by considering
a ceiling of maximum feasible output referred to as the potential output determined by available
resources. Here, output cannot go above the ceiling and most of the time it is close to the potential
output except that occasionally it is plucked down by negative shocks during recessions. Then, during
the subsequent recoveries, output returns toward its potential through a series of self-equilibrating
forces known as the “bounce-back” effect.
The policy implications of these two perspectives are starkly conflicting. Under the symmetric cycle
assumption, stabilization policy does not raise the average level of output; hence, the welfare gain of
the stabilization policy is negligible (Lucas, 1987; 2003). For instance, RBC models see fluctuations
as Pareto optimal responses of households and firms to productivity shocks rather than as welfare-
reducing deviations from some ideal path. On the contrary, under the asymmetric cycle assumption,
stabilization policy aims to not only dampen the fluctuations but also raise the average level of output.
For instance, in the plucking model, fluctuations are negative deviations from the potential output
since recessions and recoveries refer to periods of time when output recedes from and returns to its
potential capacity. As a result, reducing fluctuations can increase the total average of output. This
conclusion is drawn from a few other studies. DeLong and Summers (1988), by viewing fluctuations
as gaps rather than cycles around the trend, support that stabilization policies in the U.S. can improve
the average level of output. Benigno and Ricci (2011) also report that a reduction in macroeconomic
volatility, as a result of better stabilization policies, can improve the long-run output gap, especially
when wage inflation is low.
2.1.2. Business cycle asymmetries
Business cycle asymmetry was initially observed by Mitchell (1927) and Keynes (1936), who note
that recessions take place briefly and violently, whereas there are no such sharp turning points during
expansions. Thereafter, Friedman (1964) proposes a plucking model in which output bumps along
the ceiling of maximum feasible production except that every now and then it is plucked down by
cyclical contractions, and it then returns to its ceiling potential. Friedman (1993) finally reaffirms the
idea of the plucking model by observing an asymmetrical correlation pattern in the U.S. and some
other advanced economies.
7
By reviewing the limited literature on business cycle asymmetry, we distinguish various attributes
of asymmetries, including correlation, deepness, steepness, and duration asymmetries. While these
asymmetries are explained separately in different studies to focus on one attributes of the general
concept, they are tightly related to each other such that they together describe the same phenomenon,
Friedman’s plucking property.
5
The correlation asymmetry, noted by Friedman (1964, 1993), states that the amplitude of recessions
is correlated with the amplitude of succeeding expansions, whereas the amplitude of expansions is
uncorrelated with the amplitude of succeeding recessions. This asymmetry accords with the ceiling
effect. When output is plucked down by negative shocks during a recession, the depth of the recession
varies depending on the severity of those negative shocks. Therefore, the amplitude of the previous
expansion is unrelated to the amplitude of the recession. Afterward, when the subsequent recovery
starts, output cannot go above a ceiling named “potential output,” so the amplitude of the subsequent
expansion tends to be correlated with the amplitude of the recession.
A similar expression of correlation asymmetry states that the deeper the recessions, the stronger the
subsequent recoveries, which is empirically supported by a few studies for U.S. output (Wynne and
Balke, 1992; Beaudry and Koop, 1993; Fatás and Mihov, 2013). Goodwin and Sweeney (1993) and
Fatás and Mihov (2013) also provide substantial support for the ceiling effect in the U.S. and other
advanced economies. In addition, by analysing 26 episodes of business cycles beginning in 1882 and
ending with the Great Recession, Bordo and Haubrich (2017) confirm that the recovery of output is
stronger following those recessions that are deep and coincide with financial crises. Recently, Dupraz
et al. (2019) present empirical evidence that the U.S. unemployment rate displays a striking plucking
property, which means that the amplitude of recessions forecasts the amplitude of the subsequent
recoveries but not vice versa.
Deepness asymmetry indicates that recession troughs are deep while expansion peaks are small in
amplitude, and steepness asymmetry signifies that recessions are steep (violent) whereas expansions
are gradual (mild). To test these two asymmetries in a time series, Sichel (1993) suggests measuring
the distributional asymmetry of the series and its difference. For instance, output exhibits deepness
if it displays negative skewness relative to the trend, and it exhibits steepness if its first difference
displays negative skewness. In this regard, Sichel (1993) and Goodwin and Sweeney (1993) report a
significant negative skewness in the distribution of the de-trended output. Jensen et al. (2020), by
comparing the skewness of real output growth before and after 1984, suggest a deepening asymmetry
since they detect a more negative skewness for the U.S. and other advanced economies after 1984.
Moreover, unemployment as a counter-cyclical variable exhibits deepness asymmetry if it displays
5
See Table A2 in Appendix A for a detailed explanation.
8
positive skewness, and it exhibits steepness if its first difference displays positive skewness. In this
regard, Neftci (1984), Sichel (1993), and Dupraz et al. (2019) report that unemployment distribution
displays a remarkable positive skewness. Ramsey and Rothman (1996) also document deepness and
steepness asymmetries in output and unemployment of the U.S. and other advanced economies by
relating the concept of time reversibility to deepness and steepness. Overall, the findings of the above
studies imply that, during recessions, output falls deeply and unemployment jumps sharply, whereas
during recoveries, they both gradually return to their trends.
Duration asymmetry states that recessions are short and recoveries are long. Given that recessions
are deep, it is clear that the duration asymmetry is analogous to the concept of steepness asymmetry.
In this regard, Neftci (1984) applies a Markov process to compare the transition probabilities between
contractionary and expansionary states. He concludes that unemployment is characterized by sudden
jumps during contraction and gradual decrements during expansion.
Empirically, excluding some basic statistical evidence provided by the abovementioned studies, there
are very few studies that examine the plucking model by developing a rigorous econometric model.
Kim and Nelson (1999a) develop a state-space model with Markov-switching to examine asymmetric
fluctuations in U.S. output and conclude in favour of Friedman's plucking model against symmetric
alternatives. Subsequently, Mills and Wang (2002) as well as De Simone and Clarke (2007) provide
international evidence for the Friedman's plucking model. In addition, Sinclair (2010), by developing
a correlated asymmetric model, demonstrates that ignoring business cycle asymmetry underestimates
the amplitude of the cyclical component.
Theoretically, Ferraro (2018), Dupraz et al. (2019), and Ferraro and Fiori (2023), using equilibrium
business cycle models, explain why the unemployment rate does not fluctuate around a trend but is
characterized by steep jumps above the natural rate of unemployment during recessions. They reach
the conclusion that search frictions and downward nominal wage rigidities in the U.S. labour market
are the main sources of the asymmetry in the unemployment rate. This result accords with DeLong
and Summers (1984), Falk (1986), Sichel (1993), and McKay and Reis (2008), who empirically show
that business cycle asymmetries are more pronounced in unemployment than in output, implying that
the primary source of the plucking property stems from the U.S. labour market. However, all the
above studies do not accommodate two plausible possibilities: (1) the potential transmission of the
plucking property from the unemployment rate to output, which is addressed by the model proposed
in this study; and (2) other potential sources of asymmetry, such as binding financial constraints, an
idea that is proposed by Jensen et al. (2020).
9
2.2. Okun’s law
Okun’s law is an empirical relationship between fluctuations in output and the unemployment rate
that was first proposed by Arthur Okun (1962) and is well-established for numerous countries (Ball
et al., 2017). The gap version of Okun’s law is the relationship between the output gap (the deviation
of output from potential output) and the unemployment gap (the deviation of unemployment from its
natural rate), whereas the difference version of Okun’s law explains the relationship between output
growth and change in the unemployment rate.
Although some studies cast doubt on the stability of Okun’s law during recessions, particularly the
Great Recession (see, e.g., Gordon, 2010; Owyang and Sekhposyan, 2012; Basu and Foley, 2013;
Valadkhani and Smyth, 2015; Berger et al., 2016; Grant, 2018), the bulk of the literature concludes
in favour of its stability in the U.S., the U.K. and other advanced economies (see, e.g., Sögner and
Stiassny, 2002; Daly et al., 2011; Galí et al., 2012; Daly et al., 2014; Economou and Psarianos, 2016;
Ball et al., 2017; Michail, 2019). Overall, the results suggesting the obsolescence of Okun’s law are
indeed greatly exaggerated, and the departures from Okun’s law are small and short-lived, such that
Okun’s law is alive (Daly et al., 2014; Ball et al., 2017).
In essence, the reason for the results suggesting instability of Okun’s law reported by a few studies
is perhaps caused by excluding two key features of U.S. output from their models: asymmetry in the
cyclical component and the decline in trend growth. If these two features are left unaccounted for,
their traces can be reflected in the form of an instability in Okun’s law. For instance, Berger et al.
(2016) report that the Okun’s coefficient drops and bounces back during recessions. However, given
the evidence provided for asymmetric fluctuations, this result can be caused by imposing a symmetric
cycle assumption. In addition, the gap or difference versions of Okun’s law applied by Owyang and
Sekhposyan (2012), Basu and Foley (2013), and Grant (2018) impose a constant trend growth (drift).
This assumption is not innocuous since there is evidence supporting a gradual decline in trend growth
in the U.S. and other advanced economies. Consequently, if the stochastic drift is the true model and
the deterministic drift is the false model, it is probable that the declining trend growth, which is not
accounted for, reflects itself in the form of an instability in the Okun’s coefficient. Additionally, the
instability of Okun’s law reported by Valadkhani and Smyth (2015) appears to be caused by imposing
a number of assumptions. For example, they impose a single Markov-switching process to explain
the regime-switching in both the Okun’s law coefficient and the output shock volatility, whereas no
theoretical or empirical evidence is presented to support this idea that Okun’s law and volatility have
the same regime-switching timing and dynamics.
10
3. Data and methodology
We use data on the seasonally adjusted real gross domestic product (GDPC1) and the unemployment
rate for people aged 16 and over (UNRATE) from FRED (Federal Reserve Economic Data). The
quarterly sample period runs from 1948Q1 to 2019Q4, though we extend the data until 2022Q4 to
explore the COVID-19 recession. We use the natural log of quarterly real GDP multiplied by 100
and the quarterly unemployment rate as two observed series in the model. We calculate the quarterly
unemployment rate as the average of rates of the three months within the corresponding quarter. For
example, the rate of unemployment for the first quarter is the average of the unemployment rates for
January, February, and March. Alternatively, to control for the lead-lag effect between output and
the unemployment rate, we calculate the leading quarterly unemployment rate by finding the average
of three months, two of which are within the same quarter and the other is in the subsequent quarter.
As an illustration, the leading unemployment rate for the first quarter is calculated as the average of
the unemployment rates for February, March, and April. We additionally apply the proposed model
to U.S. real GDP per capita and U.K. real GDP.
As specified in Section 3.1, we run the asymmetric bivariate model to examine the asymmetric co-
fluctuations. To model the asymmetry, we include a Markov-switching process in the unemployment
cyclical component with the aim of capturing the plucking property. To model co-fluctuations, we
apply a gap version of Okun’s law, where the unemployment rate is placed on the right-hand side,
with the intention of capturing the transmission of the plucking property from unemployment rate to
output in the U.S. economy. For the purpose of pairwise comparison, we estimate several models,
including the main asymmetric bivariate model and the symmetric bivariate model utilized by Clark
(1989) and Gonzalez-Astudillo and Roberts (2022), in which the plucking coefficient is imposed to
be zero.
Furthermore, as explained in Section 3.2, we run the asymmetric univariate model in the spirit of the
plucking model proposed by Kim and Nelson (1999a), Sinclair (2010), and Morley and Piger (2012),
where the asymmetry is modelled by using a Markov-switching process in the cyclical component.
We separately apply this model to U.S. output and unemployment to gain insight into the asymmetric
fluctuations of these two indicators and also verify that correlation is insignificant exclusively for the
asymmetric bivariate model. For pairwise comparison, we impose the plucking coefficient to be zero
in order to estimate several nested models, including the univariate uncorrelated UC model of Clark
(1987), the univariate correlated UC model proposed by Morley et al. (2003), the univariate UC
model with a break in trend growth proposed by Perron and Wada (2009), and also the univariate
correlated UC model with a break in trend growth designed by Grant and Chan (2017b).
11
In total, to account for the wide variety of specifications, we estimate twenty-two bivariate models,
fourteen univariate models for output, and five univariate models for unemployment. The detailed
specifications of each of the models are presented in Tables B1, B2, and B3 in Appendix B.
We cast each model in a state-space form to estimate models by using the Kalman’s (1960) filter. In
symmetric models, we simply use the maximum likelihood method. For asymmetric models in the
presence of the Markov-switching process of Hamilton (1989), we use Kim's (1994) approximate
maximum likelihood method to make the Kalman filter operable.
6
We evaluate the proposed model
against other alternatives by estimating the plucking coefficient, the Okun’s law coefficient, and their
standard errors, as well as deriving likelihood ratios based on pairwise comparisons of log likelihood
values.
3.1. The bivariate model: Friedman’s Plucking Model and Okun’s Law
In the bivariate model, to distinguish between the components of output and the unemployment rate,
we denote the observed series, unobserved trend component, and unobserved cyclical component for
output by , , and , and we respectively denote those variables for the unemployment rate by
, , and . In this setting, we decompose each of the output and the unemployment rate into a
trend and a cyclical component, as specified in Eq. (1) and Eq. (2):
(1)
(2)
where is the log of output and is the unemployment rate. and are unobserved trend and
cyclical components of output that play the roles of potential output and the output gap, respectively.
Similarly, and are unobserved trend and cyclical components of the unemployment rate, which
respectively play the roles of the natural rate of unemployment and the unemployment gap.
3.1.1. The trend components of output and the unemployment rate
We model the output trend as a random walk process with a drift term as follows:


(3)
where 󰇛
󰇜 denotes the output trend shock and is assumed to be white noise and normally
distributed, just like all of the other shocks (also called innovations) in this study. Further, stands
for time-varying drift, which plays the role of trend growth and is specified in two alternative ways.
First, since a substantial time-variation in U.S. output trend growth is documented (see, e.g., Antolin-
6
For more explanation, especially the state-space representation of bivariate and univariate models, see Appendix
B. For estimation methods and initial values for parameters and state variables, see Appendix C, chapters 3-5 of
Kim and Nelson (1999b), and chapters 13 and 22 of Hamilton (1994).
12
Diaz et al., 2017; Fernald et al., 2017), we make use of a stochastic drift that evolves according to a
random walk process:

(4.a)
where 󰇛󰇜 represents the shock to output trend growth, and it is assumed to be white noise
and uncorrelated with all other shocks. The above setup accords with those of Clark (1987, 1989),
Grant and Chan (2017a), and Kim and Chon (2020). Second, similar to Perron and Wada (2009) and
Grant and Chan (2017b), we alternatively consider a non-stochastic drift with a structural break:
󰇛󰇜
(4.b)
where is an indicator function that takes the value of one after the break () and zero otherwise.
In this setup, is the trend growth of output before the break date, and is the trend growth after
the break date. Comparing two competing specifications for output trend growth in Eq. (4.a) and Eq.
(4.b), we advocate the former since the stochastic drift lets the data speak for itself and enables the
model to capture both the gradual decline and the potential break in U.S. output trend growth. This
choice is consistent with Antolin-Diaz et al. (2017), who suggest that the random walk process is
robust to misspecifications even if the actual process is characterized by discrete structural breaks.
The unemployment trend in our model is named ZOGRU since it measures the unemployment rate
at which the output gap is zero and is specified as a random walk with a drift that allows for a break:
󰇛󰇜

(5)
Under this equation, is an indicator that takes the value of one after the break date () and zero
otherwise. Thus, is the drift before the break date, and is the drift after the break date. Our
motivation for allowing for a break is the observed rise and decline in NAIRU, which measures the
U.S. natural rate of unemployment, before and after the 1980s by Ball and Mankiw (2002), Semmler
and Zhang (2006), and Basistha and Startz (2008). We include the shock to the unemployment trend,
󰇛
󰇜, to account for stochastic behaviour in the natural rate in the form of a random walk
by following Gordon (1997), Staiger et al. (1997), Laubach (2001), Watson (2014), among others.
7
3.1.2. The cyclical component of unemployment
To allow asymmetric fluctuations, we consider that shocks to the cyclical component are a mixture
of asymmetric and symmetric shocks. Since asymmetric fluctuations are more pronounced in the
unemployment rate (DeLong and Summers, 1984; Falk, 1986; Sichel, 1993; McKay and Reis, 2008),
and the U.S. labour market is identified as the source of the plucking property (Ferraro, 2018; Dupraz
7
If the variance of the unemployment trend shock () in Eq. (5) is estimated to be zero (
), one can argue
that the natural rate of unemployment does not exhibit stochastic behaviour, and its variation can be explained by a
drift term with a structural break.
13
et al., 2019; Ferraro and Fiori, 2023), we embed an unobservable, first-order, and two-state Markov-
switching variable into the cyclical component of unemployment rather than output, as follows:



(6)
where (the plucking coefficient) measures the amplitude of the asymmetric shock and is expected
to be positive since the unemployment rate is counter-cyclical. In Eq. (6), and are coefficients
of the AR(2) process. They allow for high persistence in unemployment, and their sum () is
expected to be less than one. Furthermore, 󰇛
󰇜 is a typical symmetric cyclical shock to
the unemployment rate.
In this model, identifies the state of the economy: during normal times and during
recessions. The state of the economy will be determined endogenously as it evolves according to the
Markov-switching process proposed by Hamilton (1989):
󰇟󰇠
(7)
󰇟󰇠
(8)
In this approach, and determine the transition probabilities. is the probability of staying in the
recession, and thus, is the probability of transitioning from the recession to the normal state.
Similarly, is the probability of staying in the normal state, and thus, is the probability of
transitioning from the normal to the recession state.
3.1.3. Okun’s law and the cyclical component of output
After characterizing the asymmetric fluctuations of unemployment, similar to Clark (1989), Berger
et al. (2016), Ball et al. (2017), Grant (2018), and Gonzalez-Astudillo and Roberts (2022), we utilize
the gap version of Okun’s law to capture the co-fluctuations of output and unemployment:

(9)
where is the Okun’s coefficient, and  is the Okun’s residual (also called the remaining cyclical
component in output), which is modelled as follows:

(10)
In Eq. (10), is the output-specific plucking coefficient that gauges the part of the plucking property
in output that is not explained by the plucking property in unemployment, and is an autoregressive
coefficient to control any persistency in the Okun’s residuals. If the leftover plucking property in
Okun’s residuals is negligible, we conclude that the plucking property in output is sourced from the
plucking property in unemployment. Overall, a significant and positive , a significant and negative
, and a trivial leftover plucking property confirm the asymmetric co-fluctuations of U.S. output and
unemployment, which indicates that output and unemployment are synchronously and proportionally
14
characterized by the plucking property. Furthermore, 󰇛
󰇜 is the shock to the remaining
cyclical component with a constant variance. For robustness tests, however, we allow this shock to
have different variances before and after the great moderation, as follows:

󰇛󰇜
󰇛󰇜
(11)
where is an indicator function so that the variance before the break date is equal to 
and after
the break date is
. In addition to exploring the above mentioned structural breaks, we test for a
potential break in Okun’s coefficient to address the concern about the stability of Okun’s law.
3.1.4. The variance-covariance matrix of shocks
Considering five shocks to the components presented in Eq. (1) to Eq. (11), the variance-covariance
matrix of shocks is:





󰇛
 



󰇜
(12)
where  stands for the correlation between shocks to the output trend and the symmetric cyclical
component,  is the correlation between shocks to the output trend and the remaining cyclical
component, and  is the correlation between shocks to the symmetric cyclical component and
the remaining cyclical component. In the main setup, we assume these three correlations are all zero;
yet, for robustness, we relax the zero-correlation assumptions.
8
Regarding other correlations, it is presumed that the shock to output trend growth () and the shock
to the unemployment trend () are uncorrelated with all other shocks. The former assumption is
common in the literature (see, e.g., Clark, 1987, 1989; Grant and Chan, 2017a; Antolin-Diaz et al.,
2017; Kim and Chon, 2020). The latter is also reasonable for three reasons. First, the natural rate of
unemployment is independent from temporary fluctuations since it is the structural unemployment
rate that would prevail in the absence of any cyclical variations (Phelps, 1967; Friedman, 1968).
Second, Gonzalez-Astudillo and Roberts (2022), using likelihood ratio tests, demonstrate that this
assumption is innocuous. Third, it is common in the empirical literature to specify the unemployment
trend as a random walk, with its shocks assumed to be uncorrelated with other shocks (see, e.g.,
Clark, 1989; Watson, 2014; Grant, 2018).
9
8
Favourably, our results show that these three correlations are all insignificant, confirming that our model handles
the pile-up issue related to spurious correlation.
9
Additionally, our results of both asymmetric and symmetric univariate UC models applied to unemployment show
that the correlation between shocks to the trend and the cyclical components of unemployment is insignificant.
15
3.2. The univariate model
In addition to the bivariate model, we run the univariate trend-cycle decomposition, in which a single
variable of interest, either output or the unemployment rate, is decomposed into a trend and a cyclical
component, as specified in Eq. (13):
(13)
where the observed series is denoted by . Accordingly, and are unobserved trend and cyclical
components. If we intend to decompose the log level of output, and play the roles of potential
output and the output gap; and likewise, if we decompose the unemployment rate, and play the
roles of the natural rate of unemployment and the unemployment gap, respectively.
3.2.1. The trend component
For U.S. output, we consider that the trend component is a random walk process with a drift:


where 󰇛
󰇜 denotes the output trend shock and is assumed to be white noise and normally
distributed like all other shocks. Similar to Section 3.1.1, is the drift term and is specified in two
alternative ways to capture the time-variation in U.S. output trend growth. Firstly, we can model the
output trend growth as a stochastic drift in the form of a random walk process, specified in Eq. (4.a),
and secondly, we model the trend growth as a non-stochastic drift with a structural break, specified
in Eq. (4.b).
For U.S. unemployment, it is observed that a measure of the natural rate of unemployment named
NAIRU, has gradually increased from 5% in the 1950s to 6% in the 1980s, and thereafter it has been
decreasing to the level of 4.5% until now. Therefore, we model the unemployment trend as a random
walk with a drift term, which accounts for the potential structural break in the following manner:
󰇛󰇜

where 󰇛
󰇜 stands for the shock to the unemployment trend and accounts for any potential
stochastic variation in the unemployment trend.
10
Under this equation, is an indicator function that
takes the value of one after the break date () and zero otherwise, and thus is the drift before and
is the drift after the break date. For references to studies that support the above specification
for the unemployment trend, see Section 3.1.1 in the bivariate model.
10
Our estimation results indicate that if the structural break in the unemployment trend is allowed for, the variance
of the shock to the unemployment trend is near zero. On this basis, one could remove the unemployment trend shock
by assuming that its variance is zero (
).
16
3.2.2. The cyclical component
To accommodate asymmetric shocks, we incorporate a Markov switching process into the cycle and
to allow for the possible high persistence of the cyclical component, we model it as an AR(2) process
as follows:



(16)
where and are coefficients of the AR(2) process, whose sum () is expected to be less
than one, and is the plucking coefficient measuring the amplitude of the asymmetric shocks. A
significant , which is expected to be negative for output and positive for the unemployment rate,
confirms Friedman’s plucking property for each of the above indicators separately. In this setup, the
state of the economy () is zero during normal times and one during recessions and follows a first-
order, and two-state Markov-switching process of Hamilton (1989) specified in Eq. (7) and Eq. (8).
For the usual symmetric shock to the cyclical component in Eq. (16), we assume that 󰇛
󰇜
has a constant variance. However, for robustness tests of the model applied to output, its variance
(
) is allowed to be different before and after the great moderation as follows:

󰇛󰇜
󰇛󰇜
(17)
where is an indicator function to capture the potential break in the variance of symmetric shocks
to the output cyclical component, which is equal to 
before and 
after the break date ().
3.2.3. The variance-covariance matrix of shocks
Finally, the variance-covariance matrix of shocks is represented in Eq. (18):


󰇛


󰇜
(18)
Concerning the correlation in the proposed model, we maintain the assumption that all shocks are
uncorrelated. For the model applied to output, we allow for correlation between shocks to the output
trend and cyclical components () in robustness tests to investigate the possibility of non-zero
correlation, as suggested by Morley et al. (2003) and Sinclair (2010). For those models applied to
unemployment, since the natural rate represents structural unemployment that exists independently
of all temporary and seasonal fluctuations (Phelps, 1967; Friedman, 1968), the correlation between
shocks to the unemployment trend and cyclical components must be zero by definition. Nevertheless,
we allow for this correlation () in the robustness tests to verify that it is indeed insignificant.
17
4. Results and discussion
We estimate twenty-two bivariate models, fourteen univariate models for output, and five univariate
models for unemployment. We denote each model with an identifier and a descriptor. The descriptor
consists of five parts, four of which express specification aspects for output and one of which denotes
the specification for unemployment. For example, the identifier and descriptor of our proposed model
are 1a and A-Bi-RW-SB-UC, which means that this model is Asymmetric and Bivariate. The output
trend growth is a Random Walk, the natural rate of unemployment has a Structural Break, and finally,
the model is UnCorrelated as the correlation between shocks is presumed to be zero. The full list of
identifiers and descriptors of other models is presented in Tables B1, B2, and B3 in Appendix B.
In Section 4.1, we discuss the results of the bivariate models. To test for asymmetry, we compare the
results of the proposed model 1a with those of its symmetric counterpart reported in column 4a of
Table 1. Respecting time-variation in U.S. output trend growth, in addition to model 1a, which allows
for stochastic trend growth, we implement model 2a, which accounts for a structural break in output
trend growth, and model 3a, which imposes constant trend growth. Concerning the correlation, we
execute models 1b, 2b, and 3b that are correlated versions of models 1a, 2a, and 3a, respectively. We
also present the result of structural break tests and robustness tests for bivariate models in this section.
In Sections 4.2 and 4.3, we present the findings of univariate models for output and unemployment.
In Section 4.4, by extending the estimation period up to 2022Q4 and modifying the proposed model,
we explore the COVID-19 recession as an epitome of the plucking property. We finally report the
results for two additional series, U.S. output per capita and U.K. output in Section 4.5.
4.1. Results of the bivariate models
The results of the asymmetric bivariate model substantiate the asymmetric co-fluctuations of U.S.
output and unemployment. As presented in Table 1, the Okun’s law coefficient is  with a
standard error of 0.12, implying that a 1% gap in unemployment is accompanied by a 1.45% gap in
output. This supports their co-fluctuation, proving that fluctuations in U.S. output and unemployment
are indeed synchronous and proportional. Furthermore, these co-fluctuations are asymmetric because
the estimated plucking coefficient is  with a standard error of 0.06, and the product of two
coefficients () gauges the plucking property in output. Given that the labour market
is identified as the source of the plucking property (Ferraro, 2018; Dupraz et al., 2019; Ferraro and
Fiori, 2023), our findings advocate the transmission of the plucking property from the unemployment
rate to output. The top-left and bottom-left panels of Figure 1 depict potential output as a ceiling for
output and the natural rate implied by our model (ZOGRU) as a floor for unemployment, which are
estimated jointly. The top-right panel displays that estimated output gaps are deep, often negative,
18
and rarely positive; and likewise, the bottom-right panel shows that unemployment gaps are large in
amplitude, often positive, and rarely negative, which support the plucking property and the ceiling
effect, proposed by Friedman (1993), in both economic indicators.
Moreover, the estimated transition probability reported in column 1a of Table 1 is low for recessions
() and is high for recoveries (). Thus, the expected duration is around 3 quarters
for recessions and 28 quarters for recoveries. The sum of autoregressive coefficients estimated for
the cyclical component () is 0.93, suggesting a relatively persistent cyclical component and
gradual recoveries. Hence, altogether, we highlight that the co-fluctuations of U.S. output and the
unemployment rate are asymmetric in amplitude, speed, and duration, which implies that deep, steep,
and transitory recessions will be followed by commensurate, gradual, and permanent recoveries. We
now assess the four specification aspects in detail in the following subsections:
4.1.1. The first specification aspect (asymmetry vs. symmetry)
To substantiate asymmetric fluctuations, we compare the log likelihood of -11.9 for the asymmetric
bivariate model in column 1a of Table 1 with that of -57.5 for its symmetric counterpart in column
4a. This comparison yields a likelihood ratio of 91.2, which is greater than the critical value of 10.8
for a conservative 0.1% significance level.
11
We, therefore, document that the plucking coefficient
is significant and shocks to the cyclical component are asymmetric. This finding remains valid for
other asymmetric bivariate models, such as 2a and 3a,
12
and accords with the results of asymmetric
univariate models presented by Kim and Nelson (1999a), Sinclair (2010), and Eo and Morley (2022),
who note the presence of asymmetric fluctuations in U.S. output.
4.1.2. The second specification aspect (bivariate vs. univariate models)
The resemblance of the results obtained from the proposed model presented in Figure 1 to those of
its correlated counterpart shown in Figure D1 in Appendix D confirms that the asymmetric bivariate
model generates cyclical components with substantial amplitude no matter whether the correlation
is involved in the model or not. This casts doubt on the results of several symmetric univariate models
applied by Beveridge and Nelson (1981), Nelson and Plosser (1982), Morley et al. (2003), Grant and
11
In the presence of a Markov-switching process, testing hypotheses based on the likelihood ratio statistics is non-
standard as the nuisance parameter is not identified under the null hypothesis, and consequently the asymptotic
distribution of the likelihood ratio test is unknown and does not follow the standard distribution. Few papers
propose computationally burdensome simulation-based or bootstrap-based methods to test for Markov-switching
that are operable for simple models (see, e.g., Hansen, 1992; Garcia, 1998; Di Sanzo, 2009). Because of the large
dimension of our models and the forty-one different models estimated in this study, we maintain the use of the non-
standard likelihood ratio test. Also, exceptionally large likelihood ratios derived for testing asymmetry in this study
leave very little, if not no, doubt that co-fluctuations are asymmetric.
12
By comparing the log likelihoods of -7.4 and -19.9 for asymmetric models 2a and 3a shown in Table 1 with values
of -52.6 and -62.5 for their symmetric counterparts 5a and 6a, we favour the asymmetric models over symmetric
models because the corresponding likelihood ratios are 90.4 and 85.2.
19
Chan (2017b), Kim and Chon (2020), and Kim and Kim (2022), implying that the variation in output
is almost entirely driven by the supply-related trend and that the demand-related cyclical component
is tiny and noisy.
We also investigate the possibility of Okun’s law instability by comparing the log likelihood of model
8, which accounts for a potential break in Okun’s coefficient, with the log likelihood of our proposed
model 1a, where the Okun’s coefficient is presumed to be stable. The top-left panel of Figure 2 plots
the corresponding likelihood ratios for a sequence of breaks in the Okun’s coefficient rolling from
1960 to 2010. Likelihood ratios are less than any reasonable threshold, such as QLR critical values
of 8.9 and 7.2 for 5% and 10% significance levels. Therefore, we conclude that Okun’s law is stable
as long as the model heeds key specification aspects, such as the asymmetric cyclical component and
stochastic trend growth. This result is in line with the findings of Galí et al. (2012), Daly et al. (2014),
Ball et al. (2017) and Michail (2019), among others, while it is in opposition to Berger et al. (2016)
and Grant (2018), among a few others.
4.1.3. The third specification aspect (stochastic vs. deterministic trend growth)
The results of models 1a and 2a provide persuasive evidence for time-variation in output trend growth
in the U.S. in the form of both a gradual decline that began in the 1960s and a sharp structural break
following the 200709 financial crisis. The middle-left panel of Figure 1 plots the dynamics of the
trend growth over time: Annual trend growth gradually declined from about 4% in the 1960s to 2.6%
in the mid-2000s, and then it fell from 2.6% to an unprecedented rate of 1.2% in the aftermath of the
200709 financial crisis. This flags up an unusual annual shortfall of 1.3 percentage points following
the financial crisis by comparing the actual trend growth with long-run extrapolations from 1990 or
2009 as two counterfactuals.
Moreover, we explore an unknown break in U.S. output trend growth by rolling the break date in the
central 70% of the sample. The middle-left panel of Figure 2 plots the corresponding likelihood ratio
values for a sequence of structural breaks from 1960 to 2010 and exhibits two distinct episodes. First,
from the mid-1960s to the late-1990s, a lot of moderately significant breaks occurred repeatedly in
every period, which hints at the gradual decline in trend growth. Second, after the late-1990s, the
likelihood ratios are highly significant and peak markedly twice in a row in 2006 and 2010, hinting
at an unprecedented deceleration in U.S. potential output, which is displayed in the top-right panel
of Figure D2 in Appendix D.
Comparing two competing specifications for trend growth, the bottom-left panel of Figure 2 shows
that the random walk performs better than almost all models with a structural break date before 2000
and is also close to the best models with a selected break date near the 200709 financial crisis.
20
4.1.4. The fourth specification aspect (uncorrelated vs. correlated models)
Including both the plucking property (asymmetry) and Okun’s law (co-fluctuation) in the asymmetric
bivariate model makes the correlation irrelevant, which means that all correlations are insignificant,
and the features of the trend and cyclical components are robust to the assumption about correlations.
For instance, by comparing the log likelihood of -11.9 for the proposed model in column 1a with that
of -11.4 reported for its correlated counterpart in column 1b of Table 1, we accept the null hypothesis
that correlation between the trend and symmetric cyclical shocks () is zero, as the likelihood
ratio of 1.0 is less than the critical values of 3.84 and 2.71 for 5% and 10% significance levels. This
finding remains unchanged for the other asymmetric bivariate models 2a and 3a and for testing the
other two correlations ( and ).
13
By contrast, the correlation between shocks is significant
and affects the estimation of parameters and components in the symmetric bivariate model and the
asymmetric univariate model.
14
Combining these results, we state that insignificant correlation can
be achieved by accounting for both asymmetry and co-fluctuations, although including only one of
them helps to alleviate the sensitivity of the results to the correlation between shocks, which has
previously been reported by Gonzalez-Astudillo and Roberts (2022).
4.1.5. Structural breaks and robustness tests
We explore the robustness of our findings by estimating alternative models, each of which accounts
for a rolling structural break in one of the following parameters: the Okun’s coefficient, the volatility
of shocks to the output cyclical component, output trend growth, and the drift in the unemployment
trend. To find the unknown break date, we truncate the first and last ten years (15%) of the sample.
We then sequentially estimate the log likelihood values for the model with a potential break, whose
date rolls from 1960Q1 to 2010Q1 within the whole sample from 1950Q1 to 2019Q4. We compute
the likelihood ratios by comparing the estimated log likelihood values for the unrestricted model with
the value of the restricted model, where the break is unaccounted for. By comparing the supremum
of likelihood ratios with a reasonable threshold, such as the Quandt Likelihood Ratio (QLR) critical
values presented in Andrews (1993), we finally detect structural breaks.
15
Each panel in Figure 2 illustrates likelihood ratios for a sequence of breaks in one of the parameters
mentioned above. The top-left panel, as discussed before, dismisses the instability in the gap version
13
The likelihood ratios for testing any other correlations are all close to 0.0, which are reported in note 5 of Table
1 and notes 4 and 5 of Table D1 in Appendix D.
14
For the symmetric bivariate model, as stated in note 6 of Table D1 in Appendix D, we reject the null hypothesis
of zero-correlation. Similarly, for the asymmetric univariate model, as explained in Section 4.2 and note 5 of Table
2, we reject the null hypothesis of zero-correlation between shocks.
15
Since we take the supremum of log likelihood ratios the critical values to test for the unknown structural break
are considerably larger than those of the usual likelihood ratio test. In this sense, we use a conservative 1% QLR
critical value given that we apply the approximate, rather than exact, maximum likelihood method.
21
of Okun’s law since likelihood ratios are less than the 5% QLR critical value. The top-right panel
detects a break in the volatility of shocks to the remaining cyclical component in 1983, which is close
to the break date of 1982 reported by Eo and Morley (2022) and hints at the great moderationthe
decrease in the volatility of shocks to output that begun in the mid-1980s. In particular, the results of
model 7 presented in Table D1 in Appendix D show that the volatility is equal to 
 before
the break and 
 after the structural break. The middle-left panel identifies two sources of
instability in U.S. trend growth: a gradual decline started in the 1960s, and a structural break occurred
in 2009.
The middle-right panel reports a significant break in the drift of the natural rate of unemployment
(ZOGRU) in 1981, which is accounted for in our proposed model. Accordingly, the bottom-left panel
of Figure 1 depicts an increase in ZOGRU from 3% in the 1950s to 6% in the 1980s, followed by a
gradual decrease to levels around 4.5% until now. Our ZOGRU estimation is similar to the estimated
NAIRU, which measures the natural rate of unemployment, provided by Ball and Mankiw (2002),
Semmler and Zhang (2006), and Basistha and Startz (2008), who document its rise and decline before
and after the 1980s. Furthermore, since the estimated standard deviation of shocks to ZOGRU is not
significant ( with a standard error of 0.02), the unemployment trend does not involve
a stochastic element, and its variation could be explained by estimating a drift term with a structural
break.
Moreover, the middle-left panel of Figure D2 in Appendix D illustrates the small depth of the leftover
plucking property in the Okun’s residuals, which is attributable to the short lead-lag effect between
output and unemployment.
16
Finally, our results are robust to choices made on the third and fourth
specification aspects. For instance, the finding of asymmetry in business cycles stands up in models
1a, 2a, and 3a, no matter what the specification for U.S. trend growth is, and holds true for correlated
models 1b, 1c, 1d, 1e, 2b, 2c, 3b, and 3c independent from the assumption about correlation. Also,
regardless of the specifications for trend growth and correlation, the estimated Okun’s coefficient is
around -1.4 for most asymmetric models and is around -1.7 for most symmetric models.
4.2. Results of the univariate models for output
To confirm the asymmetric fluctuations of U.S. output, we compare the log likelihood of -336.9 for
the asymmetric univariate model 1a with the value of -354.4 for its symmetric counterpart reported
in column 4a of Table 2 and obtain a likelihood ratio of 35.0, which is greater than the 0.1% critical
value of 10.8. The estimated plucking coefficient is  with a standard error of 0.19. This
16
See the explanation in Appendix D for further discussion.
22
finding stands up in other asymmetric univariate models, restates the results of asymmetric bivariate
models in this study, and accords with the results of univariate models in earlier studies by Kim and
Nelson (1999a) and Sinclair (2010). The transition probabilities are  and , and
the expected duration is about 3 quarters for recessions and about 23 quarters for recoveries, which
are close to those estimated in the asymmetric bivariate model. As shown in the top-right panel of
Figure 3 output gaps are deep, often negative, and rarely positive. In addition, the estimated sum of
autoregressive coefficients for the cyclical component () is 0.76 for model 1a, implying a
moderate cyclical persistency in output.
4.3. Results of the univariate models for unemployment
The results in Figure 3 and Table 3 are derived from the asymmetric univariate model applied to the
unemployment rate. The estimated plucking coefficient () is close to  estimated
in the asymmetric bivariate model. To confirm the asymmetry in fluctuations of U.S. unemployment,
we compare the log likelihood of -4.9 for the asymmetric univariate model 1a with the value of -36.7
for its symmetric counterpart 2a and report a likelihood ratio of 63.6. The transition probabilities are
 for recessions and  for recoveries, which are almost equal to those estimated by
the asymmetric univariate and asymmetric bivariate models. The sum of autoregressive coefficients
for the unemployment cyclical component () is 0.94, which is greater than the 0.76 estimated
for the output cyclical component and implies a higher persistency in unemployment. Comparing the
middle-left and middle-right panels of Figure 3 suggests a remarkable resemblance between the
plucking probabilities in U.S. output and the unemployment rate estimated by univariate models
applied separately to these two indicators.
Both asymmetric and symmetric univariate models applied to the unemployment rate are robust to
the assumption about the correlation between shocks to the trend and cyclical components simply
because this correlation is estimated to be near zero. Comparing the log likelihoods of -4.9 and -36.7
for uncorrelated models 1a and 2a with those of -4.9 and -36.4 for their correlated counterparts 1b
and 2b accepts the null hypothesis of zero-correlation because the corresponding likelihood ratios of
0.0 and 0.8 are negligible. This is consistent with the definition of the natural rate of unemployment,
as it represents the structural unemployment rate that exists independently of all cyclical fluctuations
(Phelps, 1967; Friedman, 1968). In fact, U.S. unemployment inherently encompasses cyclicality in
the form of plucking property. This desirable feature introduces this indicator as a reliable proxy for
measuring business cycles and a straightforward auxiliary to be included within a bivariate model to
facilitate the trend-cycle decomposition of U.S. output.
23
4.4. Exploring the COVID-19 recession
In this section, we modify the main proposed model to account for the COVID-19 recession, which
exemplifies the plucking property because it severely constrained output, led to spare capacity, and
created a deep output gap in the U.S. and other economies. A sharp jump in the unemployment rate
from 3.8% in 2020Q1 to 13% in 2020Q2 and a proportional steep pluck-down in output identify the
COVID-19 recession as the deepest and shortest recession among post-World War II recessions in
the U.S. As a result, Eq. (6) that applies a single plucking coefficient () for all recessions is unable
to account for the unprecedented depth and duration of the COVID-19 recession. To deal with this
issue, we follow a simple approach by adding a dummy variable for the COVID-19 pandemic and
estimating the COVID-specific plucking coefficient () as follows:
󰇛󰇜


(19)
where is an indicator that takes one during the COVID-19 pandemic and zero otherwise. We set
the start of the COVID-19 pandemic () at 2020Q1 and the end () at 2021Q1,
with unemployment remaining above 6%. By extending the estimation period up to 2022Q4, the
model gauges 8.5% and 11% gaps in unemployment and output during the COVID-19 pandemic.
The estimated components and parameters, presented in Figure 4 and Table D4 in Appendix D, are
similar to those of the main model. However, the common plucking coefficient () is larger
than that of the proposed model to explain a portion of the greater depth of the COVID-19 recession
compared to the depth of previous recessions. The COVID-specific plucking coefficient (
 with a standard error of 0.32) is also remarkable because it helps the model explain the rest of
the extra depth of the COVID-19 recession. In total, the additional plucking property during the
COVID-19 recession is captured by both a larger common and a sizeable.
17
4.5. Results for U.S. output per capita and U.K. output
In addition to U.S. real output, we apply the asymmetric bivariate model to two other macroeconomic
time series: U.S. output per capita to demonstrate that its annual trend growth in the aftermath of the
financial crisis is lower than 1%, and U.K. output to provide international evidence for asymmetric
co-fluctuations, with the results shown in Table D5 in Appendix D. For U.S. output per capita, we
report the same plucking coefficient, Okun’s coefficient, and transition probabilities as reported for
output. Based on Figure D3 in Appendix D, the components have very similar features as derived
for output, and the annual trend growth of 0.7% for U.S. output per capita is incredibly low. For U.K.
17
In our approach presented in Eq. (19),  captures the additional plucking property during the COVID-19
pandemic. Another approach to modelling the plucking property during the COVID-19 pandemic is to incorporate
two independent Markov-switching processes, one for previous recessions and another for the COVID-19 recession,
whose depth is around double the average of previous recessions.
24
output, the estimated plucking coefficient and Okun’s law coefficient are  and 
with standard errors of 0.35 and 0.05, respectively. The estimated transition probabilities for U.K.
output are  and , which indicate that although the amplitude of the U.K. plucking
property is milder than that of the U.S., its recession duration is longer.
5. Concluding remarks
By embedding output and unemployment in a bivariate state-space model with a Markov-switching
process, we integrate Friedman’s plucking model and Okun’s law. Estimating substantial plucking
and Okun’s law coefficients ( and ) establishes the asymmetric co-fluctuations,
stating that fluctuations in output and the unemployment rate are synchronously and proportionally
characterized by the plucking property. Given that recent studies identified the labour market as the
source of the plucking property, this study highlights the transmission of the plucking property from
unemployment to output.
Our model also sheds light on four specification aspects of trend-cycle decomposition. The plucking
property and ceiling effect are remarkable in both indicators because gaps are large in magnitude and
often negative for output and positive for unemployment. By capturing business cycle asymmetries,
our empirical findings indicate that recessions are deep, steep, and transitory and will be followed by
commensurate, gradual, and permanent recoveries. Additionally, we demonstrate that the gap version
of Okun’s law is stable provided that asymmetric fluctuations and stochastic trend growth are both
accommodated. We also document a gradual decline in trend growth that started in the 1960s as well
as an unprecedented deceleration in U.S. potential output in the aftermath of the 2007−09 financial
crisis. Furthermore, the asymmetric bivariate model that includes both Friedman’s plucking property
(asymmetry) and Okun’s law (co-fluctuation) yields robust results with an insignificant correlation.
Moreover, by jointly estimating the trends of output and the unemployment rate and accounting for
the plucking property in both indicators, our model provides a counterpart for the Non-Accelerating
Inflation Rate of Unemployment (NAIRU) to measure the natural rate of unemployment. We call
this new measure the Zero Output Gap Rate of Unemployment (ZOGRU), the unemployment rate at
which the output gap is zero.
Concerning limitations, we impose a constant plucking coefficient for all recessions, while the depth
of each recession differs from the others. The effect of this assumption, however, is moderate since
the model has enough flexibility to adjust the duration of the state of the economy for an individual
recession to capture its special depth. Further, other potential sources of asymmetry that are not taken
into account, such as binding borrowing constraints, liquidity shortages, and credit crunches, open
avenues for future research.
25
References
Acemoglu, D., & Scott, A. (1997). Asymmetric business cycles: Theory and time-series evidence. Journal of
Monetary Economics, 40(3), 501-533.
Andrews, D. W. K. (1993). Tests for parameter instability and structural change with unknown change point.
Econometrica, 61(4), 821-856.
Antolin-Diaz, J., Drechsel, T., & Petrella, I. (2017). Tracking the slowdown in long-run GDP growth. Review
of Economics and Statistics, 99(2), 343-356.
Ball, L., Leigh, D., & Loungani, P. (2017). Okun's law: Fit at 50? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,
49(7), 1413-1441.
Ball, L., & Mankiw, N. G. (2002). The NAIRU in theory and practice. Journal of Economic Perspectives,
16(4), 115-136.
Barnichon, R., & Matthes, C. (2017). The natural rate of unemployment over the past 100 years. FRBSF
Economic Letter, 23, 219-231.
Basistha, A. (2007). Trend‐cycle correlation, drift break and the estimation of trend and cycle in Canadian
GDP. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique, 40(2), 584-606.
Basistha, A., & Startz, R. (2008). Measuring the NAIRU with reduced uncertainty: a multiple-indicator
common-cycle approach. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(4), 805-811.
Basu, D., & Foley, D. K. (2013). Dynamics of output and employment in the US economy. Cambridge Journal
of Economics, 37(5), 1077-1106.
Beaudry, P., & Koop, G. (1993). Do recessions permanently change output? Journal of Monetary Economics,
31(2), 149-163.
Benigno, P., & Antonio Ricci, L. (2011). The inflation-output trade-off with downward wage rigidities.
American Economic Review, 101(4), 1436-1466.
Berger, T., Everaert, G., & Vierke, H. (2016). Testing for time variation in an unobserved components model
for the US economy. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 69, 179-208.
Beveridge, S., & Nelson, C. R. (1981). A new approach to decomposition of economic time series into
permanent and transitory components with particular attention to measurement of the business cycle.” Journal
of Monetary Economics, 7(2), 151174.
Bordo, M. D., & Haubrich, J. G. (2017). Deep recessions, fast recoveries, and financial crises: Evidence from
the American record. Economic Inquiry, 55(1), 527-541.
Clark, P. K. (1987). The cyclical component of US economic activity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102(4),
797814.
Clark, P. K. (1989). Trend reversion in real output and unemployment. Journal of Econometrics, 40(1), 15-32.
26
Daly, M. C., Fernald, J., Jordà, Ò., & Nechio, F. (2014). Interpreting deviations from Okun’s law. FRBSF
Economic Letter, 12.
Daly, M., Hobijn, B., Sahin, A., & Valletta, R. (2011). A Rising Natural Rate of Unemployment: Transitory
or Permanent? (No. 11-160/3). Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper.
DeLong, J. B., & Summers, L. H. (1984). Are business cycles symmetric? NBER working papers 1444.
National Bureau of Economic Research.
DeLong, J. B., Summers, L. H. (1988). How does macroeconomic policy affect output? Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, 1988(2), 433-494.
De Simone, F. N., & Clarke, S. (2007). Asymmetry in business fluctuations: International evidence on
Friedman's plucking model. Journal of International Money and Finance, 26(1), 64-85.
Diebold, F. X., & Rudebusch, G. D. (1990). A nonparametric investigation of duration dependence in the
American business cycle. Journal of Political Economy, 98(3), 596-616.
Di Sanzo, S. (2009). Testing for linearity in Markov switching models: a bootstrap approach. Statistical
Methods and Applications, 18(2), 153-168.
Dupraz, S., Nakamura, E., & Steinsson, J. (2019). A plucking model of business cycles. NBER working papers
26351. National Bureau of Economic Research.
Economou, A., & Psarianos, I. N. (2016). Revisiting Okun’s law in European Union countries. Journal of
Economic Studies, 43(2), 275-287.
Eo, Y., & Morley, J. (2022). Why has the US economy stagnated since the Great Recession? Review of
Economics and Statistics, 104(2), 246-258.
Falk, B. (1986). Further evidence on the asymmetric behaviour of economic time series over the business
cycle. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 1096-1109.
Fatás, A., & Mihov, I. (2013). Recoveries. CEPR Discussion Papers 9551.
Fernald, J., Hall, R., Stock, J., & Watson, M. (2017). The disappointing recovery of output after 2009.
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2017(1), 1-81.
Ferraro, D. (2018). The asymmetric cyclical behaviour of the US labour market. Review of Economic
Dynamics, 30, 145-162.
Ferraro, D., & Fiori, G. (2023). Search frictions, labour supply and the asymmetric business cycle. Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking, 55(1), 5-42.
Friedman, M. (1964). Monetary Studies of the National Bureau, the National Bureau Enters its 45th Year, 44th
Annual Report. 7-25.
Friedman, M. (1968). The role of monetary policy. The American Economic Review. 58 (1), 1-17.
Friedman, M. (1993). The “plucking model” of business fluctuations revisited. Economic Inquiry, 31(2), 171-
177.
27
Galí, J., Smets, F., & Wouters, R. (2012). Slow recoveries: A structural interpretation. Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking, 44, 9-30.
Garcia, R. (1998). Asymptotic null distribution of the likelihood ratio test in Markov switching models.
International Economic Review, 763-788.
Gonzalez-Astudillo, M., & Roberts, J. M. (2022). When are trend-cycle decompositions reliable? Empirical
Economics, 62(5), 2417-2460.
Goodwin, T. H., & Sweeney, R. J. (1993). International evidence on Friedman's theory of the business cycle.
Economic Inquiry, 31(2), 178-193.
Gordon, R. J. (1997). The time-varying NAIRU and its implications for economic policy. Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 11(1), 11-32.
Gordon, R. J. (2010). Okun's law and productivity innovations. American Economic Review, 100(2), 11-15.
Grant, A. L. (2018). The great recession and Okun's law. Economic Modelling, 69, 291-300.
Grant, A. L., & Chan, J. C. (2017a). Reconciling output gaps: Unobserved components model and Hodrick
Prescott filter. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 75, 114-121.
Grant, A. L., & Chan, J. C. (2017b). A Bayesian model comparison for trend‐cycle decompositions of output.
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 49(2-3), 525-552.
Hamilton, J. D. (1989). A new approach to the economic analysis of nonstationary time series and the business
cycle. Econometrica, 357-384.
Hamilton, J. D. (1994). Time series analysis. Princeton University Press.
Hansen, B. E. (1992). The likelihood ratio test under nonstandard conditions: testing the Markov switching
model of GNP. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 7(S1), S61-S82.
Harvey, A. C. (1985). Trends and cycles in macroeconomic time series. Journal of Business and Economic
Statistics, 3(3), 216227.
Iwata, S., & Li, H. (2015). What are the differences in trend cycle decompositions by Beveridge and Nelson
and by unobserved component models? Econometric Reviews, 34(1-2), 146-173.
Jensen, H., Petrella, I., Ravn, S. H., & Santoro, E. (2020). Leverage and deepening business-cycle skewness.
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 12(1), 245-81.
Kalman, R. E. (1960). A new approach to linear filtering and prediction problems. Transactions of the ASME
Journal of Basic Engineering, 35-45.
Keynes, John Maynard. The general theory of employment, interest and money. London: Macmillan, 1936.
Kim, C. J. (1994). Dynamic linear models with Markov-switching. Journal of Econometrics, 60(1-2), 1-22.
Kim, J., & Chon, S. (2020). Why are Bayesian trend-cycle decompositions of US real GDP so different?
Empirical Economics, 58(3), 1339-1354.
28
Kim, C. J., & Kim, J. (2022). Trend-cycle decompositions of real GDP revisited: classical and Bayesian
perspectives on an unsolved puzzle. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 26(2), 394-418.
Kim, C. J., & Nelson, C. R. (1999a). Friedman's plucking model of business fluctuations: tests and estimates
of permanent and transitory components. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 317-334.
Kim, C. J., & Nelson, C. R. (1999b). State-space models with regime switching: classical and Gibbs-sampling
approaches with applications. MIT Press Books.
Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1982). Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica, 50(6), 1345.
Laubach, T. (2001). Measuring the NAIRU: evidence from seven economies. Review of economics and
statistics, 83(2), 218-231.
Long Jr, J. B., & Plosser, C. I. (1983). Real business cycles. Journal of Political Economy, 91(1), 3969.
Lucas, R. E., & Lucas. (1987). Models of business cycles (Vol. 26). Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Lucas Jr, R. E. (2003). Macroeconomic priorities. American Economic Review, 93(1), 1-14.
Luo, S., & Startz, R. (2014). Is it one break or ongoing permanent shocks that explains US real GDP? Journal
of Monetary Economics, 66, 155-163.
Michail, N. A. (2019). Examining the stability of Okun's coefficient. Bulletin of Economic Research, 71(3),
240-256.
Mills, T. C., & Wang, P. (2002). Plucking models of business cycle fluctuations: Evidence from the G-7
countries. Advances in Markov-Switching Models, 113-134.
Mitchell, W. C. (1927). Business cycles: The problem and its setting. NBER Books.
McKay, A., & Reis, R. (2008). The brevity and violence of contractions and expansions. Journal of Monetary
Economics, 55(4), 738-751.
Morley, J. C., Nelson, C. R., & Zivot, E. (2003). Why are the Beveridge-Nelson and unobserved-components
decompositions of GDP so different? Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(2), 235243.
Morley, J., & Piger, J. (2012). The asymmetric business cycle. Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(1),
208-221.
Morley, J., & Wong, B. (2020). Estimating and accounting for the output gap with large Bayesian vector auto
regressions. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 35(1), 1-18.
Neftçi, S. N. (1984). Are economic time series asymmetric over the business cycle? Journal of Political
Economy, 92(2), 307328.
Nelson, C. R., & Plosser, C. R. (1982). Trends and random walks in macroeconmic time series: Some evidence
and implications. Journal of Monetary Economics, 10(2), 139-162.
Okun, A. M. (1962). Potential GNP: Its measurement and significance, Cowles Foundation Paper 190. Cowles
Foundation, Yale University: New Haven, CT, USA.
29
Owyang, M. T., & Sekhposyan, T. (2012). Okun’s law over the business cycle: was the great recession all that
different? Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 94(5), 399-418.
Perron, P., & Wada, T. (2009). Let's take a break: Trends and cycles in US real GDP. Journal of Monetary
Economics, 56(6), 749-765.
Phelps, E. S. (1967). Phillips curves, expectations of inflation and optimal unemployment over time.
Economica, 254-281.
Ramsey, J. B., & Rothman, P. (1996). Time irreversibility and business cycle asymmetry. Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking, 28(1), 1-21.
Semmler, W., & Zhang, W. (2006). Nonlinear Phillips curves, endogenous NAIRU and monetary policy.
Contributions to Economic Analysis, 277, 483-515.
Sichel, D. E. (1993). Business cycle asymmetry: a deeper look. Economic Inquiry, 31(2), 224-236.
Sinclair, T. (2010): Asymmetry in the business cycle: Friedman’s plucking model with correlated innovations,
Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, 14 (1), 131.
Sögner, L., & Stiassny, A. (2002). An analysis on the structural stability of Okun's law--a cross-country study.
Applied Economics, 34(14), 1775-1787.
Staiger, D., Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (1997). The NAIRU, unemployment and monetary policy. Journal
of economic perspectives, 11(1), 33-49.
Valadkhani, A., & Smyth, R. (2015). Switching and asymmetric behaviour of the Okun coefficient in the US:
Evidence for the 19482015 period. Economic Modelling, 50, 281-290.
Wada, T. (2012). On the correlations of trendcycle errors. Economics Letters, 116(3), 396-400.
Watson, M. W. (2014). Inflation persistence, the NAIRU, and the great recession. American Economic
Review, 104(5), 31-36.
Wynne, M. A., & Balke, N. S. (1992). Are deep recessions followed by strong recoveries? Economics Letters,
39(2), 183-189.
30
Figures
(a) Potential output (trend) and output gap (cyclical component)
(b) Trend growth of output and the plucking probabilities for bivariate model
(c) Natural rate of unemployment (trend) and unemployment gap (cyclical component)
Figure 1: Results of the asymmetric bivariate model
Notes:
(1) All panels plot the results of our proposed model (Asymmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB-UC).
(2) The top panels plot potential output and the output gap, and the middle-left panel plots the trend growth of output.
(3) The middle-right panel plots the plucking probabilities, which are estimated for both output and unemployment jointly.
(4) The bottom panels plot the trend and gap for unemployment.
(5) The shaded areas are the NBER recession dates. See Table E1 in Appendix E for details.
31
(a) Likelihood ratios at different break dates for Okun’s law coefficient (left) and volatility (right)
(b) Likelihood ratios at different break dates for output trend growth (left) and unemployment trend drift (right)
(c) Log likelihood values of models 1a and 2a
Figure 2: Exploring structural breaks in the parameters for asymmetric bivariate model
Notes:
(1) All panels plot the log likelihood values for the model with a break whose date rolls from 1960 to 2010.
(2) The top-left panel plots the likelihood ratios for breaks in Okun’s law, given the setup of the proposed model 1a. Since likelihood ratios are
less than 5% QLR critical values, we rule out instability of Okun’s law. In addition, likelihood ratios are even less than a 1% LR critical value
of 6.63, which itself is less than the suitable critical value for the supremum of likelihood ratio among a sequence of breaks. The top-right panel
plots the likelihood ratios for breaks in volatility of shocks to the remaining cyclical component on different dates.
(3) The middle panels plot likelihood ratio test statistics. In the middle-left panel, likelihood ratio compares the log likelihood value of model 2a
with a break in trend growth with that of its counterpart model 3a with constant trend growth. The middle-right panel plots the likelihood ratios
testing for structural breaks in the drift of the unemployment trend (ZOGRU) on different dates against a constant trend. The bottom-left panel
shows the log likelihood values to detect a break in trend growth, conditioned on the setup of the model 2a. The bottom-right panel shows the
log likelihoods to detect the break in the drift of the unemployment trend (ZOGRU), conditioned on a break in output trend growth in 2009. In
both panels, the black dashed line represents the log likelihood of our proposed model, which specifies the trend growth as a random walk.
(4) The shaded areas are the NBER recession dates.
32
(a) Potential output (trend) and output gap (cyclical component)
(b) Plucking probabilities for output (left) and unemployment (right)
(c) Natural rate of unemployment (trend) and unemployment gap (cyclical components)
Figure 3: Comparing the results of the asymmetric univariate models for output and unemployment
Notes:
(1) The top panels plot the results of the asymmetric univariate model for output with a stochastic (random walk) trend growth
where shocks to the trend and cyclical components are uncorrelated (Asymmetric-Univariate-RW-UC). This model replicates
the work of Kim and Nelson (1999a), and its correlated version is presented in Figure D4 in Appendix D.
(2) The middle panels plot the plucking probabilities for output and unemployment estimated separately.
(3) The bottom panels plot the results of the asymmetric univariate model for unemployment with a break in the drift of the
unemployment trend where shocks to the trend and cyclical components are uncorrelated (Asymmetric-Univariate-SB-UC).
(4) The shaded areas are the NBER recession dates.
33
(a) Potential output (trend) and output gap (cyclical component)
(b) Trend growth of output and the plucking probabilities for bivariate model
(c) Natural rate of unemployment (trend) and unemployment gap (cyclical component)
Figure 4: Results of the asymmetric bivariate model, including the COVID-19 recession
Notes:
(1) All panels plot the results of the modified model (Asymmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB-UC-Mod), which is estimated based
on Eq. (19) for the period of 1948Q1 to 2022Q4 to include the COVID-19 recession.
(2) The top panels plot potential output and the output gap, and the middle-left panel plots the trend growth of output.
(3) The middle-right panel plots the plucking probabilities, which are estimated for both output and unemployment jointly.
(4) The bottom panels plot the trend and gap for unemployment.
(5) The shaded areas are the NBER recession dates.
34
Tables
Table 1: Estimated parameters of the bivariate models
Models
1a
1b
2a
2b
3a
4a
5a
6a
Parameters
A-Bi-RW-SB-UC
A-Bi-RW-SB-C1
A-Bi-SB-SB-UC
A-Bi-SB-SB-C1
A-Bi-Con-SB-UC
S-Bi-RW-SB-UC
S-Bi-SB-SB-UC
S-Bi-Con-SB-UC
0.44 (0.09)
0.39 (0.10)
0.51 (0.06)
0.51 (0.06)
0.62 (0.02)
0.56 (0.11)
0.54 (0.21)
0.65 (0.03)
0.21 (0.01)
0.19 (0.02)
0.21 (0.01)
0.21 (0.01)
0.21 (0.01)
0.27 (0.01)
0.27 (0.01)
0.27 (0.01)

0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.02 (0.01)
0.00 (0.02)
0.07 (0.07)
0.00 (0.03)
0.00 (0.02)
0.00 (0.01)
0.02 (0.04)
0.02 (0.05)
0.02 (0.05)
0.34 (0.08)
0.37 (0.08)
0.25 (0.08)
0.26 (0.09)
0.00 (0.11)
0.25 (0.18)
0.31 (0.35)
0.05 (0.05)
T-V
T-V
0.83 (0.03)
0.82 (0.03)
0.75 (0.03)
T-V
0.82 (0.04)
0.75 (0.04)
T-V
T-V
-0.49 (0.08)
-0.48 (0.08)
T-V
-0.49 (0.09)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.03 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.03 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
1.38 (0.04)
1.39 (0.06)
1.36 (0.04)
1.36 (0.04)
1.36 (0.04)
1.60 (0.04)
1.60 (0.04)
1.60 (0.04)
-0.45 (0.04)
-0.45 (0.06)
-0.43 (0.04)
-0.42 (0.04)
-0.43 (0.04)
-0.65 (0.04)
-0.65 (0.04)
-0.65 (0.04)
0.70 (0.06)
0.70 (0.06)
0.69 (0.05)
0.70 (0.05)
0.69 (0.05)
0.66 (0.09)
0.66 (0.09)
0.67 (0.09)
0.67 (0.09)
0.66 (0.09)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
-1.45 (0.12)
-1.33 (0.17)
-1.44 (0.13)
-1.36 (0.19)
-1.34 (0.14)
-1.73 (0.10)
-1.78 (0.11)
-1.72 (0.11)
-1.01 (0.15)
-1.04 (0.18)
-1.05 (0.15)
-1.09 (0.17)
-1.04 (0.17)
0.49 (0.10)
0.54 (0.12)
0.50 (0.11)
0.53 (0.12)
0.54 (0.10)
0.56 (0.24)
0.73 (0.33)
0.77 (0.16)

-0.26 (0.27)
-0.06 (0.11)


Log likelihood
-11.9
-11.4
-7.4
-7.2
-19.9
-57.5
-52.6
-62.5
(a) T-V means that the model considers a time-varying state variable for the corresponding parameter.
(b) Standard errors of the estimated parameters are reported in parenthesis.
(c) Numerical values for parameters denoted by 0.00 are respectively 0.0004 for model 1a, 0.00001 for model 2a, 0.0002 for
model 2b, and 0.0001 and 0.001 for model 3a.
Notes:
(1) The estimation period runs from 1948Q1 to 2019Q4. We estimate twenty-two bivariate models on the basis of choices
on the four specification aspects. We denote each model with a term consisting of five parts, four of which is related to
one of the specification aspects of output and the other denotes the specification of the unemployment trend. For example,
A-Bi-RW-SB-UC represents an Asymmetric-Bivariate-Random Walk-Structural Break-Uncorrelated model. For this
model, the shocks are asymmetric, there are two variables (output and the unemployment rate), the trend growth is
presumed to be a random walk (stochastic), the drift in unemployment trend has a structural break, and the correlation
between shocks to the trend and cyclical components is presumed to be zero. For the list of models and their specifications,
see Table B1 in Appendix B. The results of the other fourteen models are presented in Table D1 in Appendix D.
35
Table 1: The notes Continue
(2) For all models, the structural break in the drift of the unemployment trend (natural rate of unemployment) in 1981Q1
is accounted for. The break date is identified based on likelihood ratio statistics estimated for a sequence of breaks from
1960 to 2010, which spiked around 1981, as shown in the middle-right panel of Figure 2. For models 2a, 2b, and 5a, the
structural break in trend growth in 2009Q3 is accounted for. The break date is determined based on likelihood ratio
statistics estimated for a sequence of breaks from 1960 to 2010, which spiked around the 2007−09 financial crisis, as
shown in the middle-left panel of Figure 2.
(3) By pairwise comparison of the log likelihood values of -11.9, -7.4, and -19.9 reported for asymmetric models 1a, 2a,
and 3a with values of -57.5, -52.6, and -62.5 for their symmetric counterpart models 4a, 5a, and 6a, respectively, we favour
the asymmetric models over symmetric models. The corresponding likelihood ratios of 91.2, 90.4, and 85.2 are all
exceedingly greater than the critical values of 10.8 for a 0.1% significance level. The comparison between likelihood
ratios of -11.4 for the asymmetric correlated model 1b and -49.1 for the symmetric correlated model 4b, which is presented
in Table D1 in Appendix D, bears a likelihood ratio of 75.4, indicating that including the correlation in the model does
not change the result.
(4) We compare the log likelihood values of -7.4 and -52.6 reported for models 2a and 5a with values of -19.9 and -62.5
for their counterpart models 3a and 6a, where the trend growth is assumed to be constant. We reject the null hypothesis
of constant drift in the asymmetric and symmetric bivariate models because the likelihood ratios of 25.0 for the asymmetric
and 19.8 for the symmetric models are greater than the critical value of 10.8 for 0.1% significance level. Regarding the
models with stochastic trend growth, the log likelihood values of -11.9 and -57.5 for models 1a and 4a are respectively
near to values of -7.4 and -52.6 for their counterpart models with a structural break in trend growth in 2009, which
maximizes the approximate log likelihood with respect to the break date. In addition, by comparing the log likelihood
values of -11.9 and -57.5 for models 1a and 3a with values of -19.9 and -62.5 for models 3a and 6a with constant trend
growth, we observe a considerable improvement in the log likelihood value. We also report the log likelihood of -22.1 for
a model named 3a′, which is presented in Table D1 in Appendix D and is fully nested in model 1a. We therefore favour
the model with stochastic drift over the model with constant drift. Thus, the random walk is capable of accommodating
unknown breaks in trend growth and competing with the best model selected among models with structural breaks.
(5) We relax the assumption of zero correlation between shocks to the output trend and the symmetric cyclical component
() by estimating models 1b and 2b. By comparing the log likelihood values of -11.9 and -7.4 for uncorrelated models
1a and 2a with values of -11.4 and -7.2 for their correlated counterpart models 1b and 2b, respectively, we accept the null
hypothesis of zero-correlation in the asymmetric bivariate model. Indeed, the likelihood ratio values of 1.0 for model 1
and 0.4 for model 2 are less than critical values of 3.84 and 2.71 for 5% and even 10% significance levels. Further, as
shown in Table D1 in Appendix D, we find the other correlations between shocks to the output trend and the remaining
cyclical component () in model 1c, and between shocks to the symmetric cyclical component and the remaining
cyclical component () placed in the model 1d. are negligible, with log likelihood ratios of 0.0. Finally, by running
model 1e, we show that all three correlations are jointly insignificant. Overall, relaxing the zero-correlation assumption
does not change the estimated parameters, confirming that the correlation is irrelevant in the asymmetric bivariate model.
36
Table 2: Estimated parameters of the univariate models for output
Models
1a
1b
2a
2b
3a
4a
5a
6a
Parameters
A-Uni-RW-UC
A-Uni-RW-C
A-Uni-SB-UC
A-Uni-SB-C
A-Uni-Con-UC
S-Uni-RW-UC
S-Uni-SB-UC
S-Uni-Con-UC
0.63 (0.03)
1.06 (0.13)
0.68 (0.03)
1.04 (0.11)
0.70 (0.03)
0.60 (0.07)
0.62 (0.07)
0.67 (0.06)
0.00 (0.15)
0.64 (0.16)
0.002 (0.17)
0.62 (0.16)
0.001 (0.08)
0.50 (0.09)
0.50 (0.08)
0.45 (0.07)

0.06 (0.02)
0.01 (0.01)
0.02 (0.01)
T-V
T-V
0.82 (0.04)
0.85 (0.06)
0.77 (0.04)
T-V
0.82 (0.04)
0.77 (0.04)
T-V
T-V
-0.38 (0.11)
-0.40 (0.17)
T-V
-0.35 (0.13)
1.11 (0.08)
1.14 (0.07)
1.10 (0.07)
1.09 (0.07)
1.05 (0.09)
1.58 (0.10)
1.57 (0.08)
1.61 (0.11)
-0.35 (0.08)
-0.40 (0.07)
-0.28 (0.07)
-0.35 (0.07)
-0.39 (0.09)
-0.67 (0.09)
-0.65 (0.08)
-0.69 (0.07)
-1.67 (0.19)
-1.88 (0.27)
-1.71 (0.20)
-1.82 (0.20)
-1.70 (0.26)
0.64 (0.06)
0.60 (0.09)
0.64 (0.08)
0.62 (0.09)
0.91 (0.02)
0.95 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.97 (0.01)

-0.88 (0.05)
-0.85 (0.06)
Log likelihood
-336.9
-332.6
-334.7
-329.3
-341.0
-354.4
-352.6
-357.1
(a) T-V means that the model considers a time-varying state variable for the corresponding parameter.
(b) Standard errors of the estimated parameters are reported in parenthesis.
Notes:
(1) The estimation period runs from 1948Q1 to 2019Q4. We estimate fourteen univariate models on the basis of choices on the
four specification aspects. We denote each model with a term consisting of four parts, each of which is related to one of the
specification aspects. For example, A-Uni-RW-UC means Asymmetric-Univariate-Random Walk-Uncorrelated. Indeed, in this
model, shocks are asymmetric, there is only one variable, the trend growth is presumed to be a random walk (stochastic), and
the correlation between shocks to the trend and cyclical components is presumed to be zero. For the list of models and
specifications, see Table B2 in Appendix B. The results of the other six models are presented in Table D2 in Appendix D.
(2) In models 2a, 2b, and 5a, a break in trend growth in 2009Q3 is accounted for. The break date is determined based on likelihood
ratio statistics estimated for a sequence of break dates from 1960 to 2010, which spiked around the 2007−09 financial crisis, as
shown in the middle-left panel of Figure 2 and in the left panel of Figure D10 in Appendix D.
(3) By pairwise comparison of the log likelihood values of -336.9, -334.7, and -341.0 reported for asymmetric models 1a, 2a,
and 3a with values of -354.4, -352.6, and -357.1 for their symmetric counterparts 4a, 5a, and 6a, respectively, we favour the
asymmetric models over symmetric models. The corresponding likelihood ratios of 35.0, 35.8, and 32.2 are all considerably
greater than the critical value of 10.8 for a 0.1% significance level.
(4) We compare the log likelihood values of -334.7 and -352.6 reported for models 2a and 5a with values of -341.0 and -357.1
for their counterpart models 3a and 6a, where the trend growth is assumed to be constant. We reject the null hypothesis of
constant drift in the symmetric and asymmetric univariate models because the likelihood ratios of 12.6 for the asymmetric and
9.0 for the symmetric models are greater than the critical value of 6.63 for a 1% significance level. Regarding the models with
stochastic trend growth, the log likelihoods of -336.9 and -354.4 for models 1a and 4a are close to those of their counterpart
models with a break in trend growth in 2009, which relatively maximizes the log likelihood with respect to the break date. In
addition, by comparing the log likelihoods of -336.9 and -354.4 for models 1a and 4a with those of -341.0 and -357.1 for models
3a and 6a with constant trend growth, we observe a considerable improvement in log likelihood. We additionally report the log
likelihood of -344.1 for a model named 3a′, which is presented in Table D2 in Appendix D and is fully nested in model 1a. We
therefore favour the model with stochastic drift over the model with constant drift. As a result, the random walk is indeed capable
of accommodating unknown breaks in trend growth and competing with a good model among models with structural breaks.
(5) By comparing the log likelihood values of the uncorrelated and correlated versions of each of the models 1 and 2, we reject
the null hypothesis of zero-correlation in the asymmetric univariate model because the likelihood ratio values of 8.6 for model 1
and 10.8 for model 2 are greater than the 1% critical value of 6.63. Although the correlation is significant, the change in the
estimation of other parameters and features of the trend and cyclical components is mild when the business cycle asymmetry is
accounted for. For example, the trend and cyclical components shown in Figure 3 for the uncorrelated asymmetric model are
similar to those in Figure D4 in Appendix D for the correlated asymmetric model. Likewise, the trend and cyclical components
of the uncorrelated and correlated models in the left and right panels of Figure D5 in Appendix D are very similar.
37
Table 3: Estimated parameters of the univariate models for unemployment
Models
1a
1b
2a
2b
3
Parameters
A-Uni-SB-UC
A-Uni-SB-C
S-Uni-SB-UC
S-Uni-SB-C
A-Uni-SB0-UC
0.0001 (0.02)
0.001 (0.03)
0.0001 (0.03)
0.03 (0.05)
0.21 (0.009)
0.21 (0.02)
0.27 (0.01)
0.28 (0.04)
0.21 (0.009)
0.03 (0.006)
0.03 (0.006)
0.02 (0.008)
0.02 (0.009)
0.03 (0.006)
-0.04 (0.009)
-0.04 (0.009)
-0.03 (0.01)
-0.03 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.009)
1.38 (0.04)
1.38 (0.04)
1.60 (0.04)
1.58 (0.06)
1.38 (0.04)
-0.44 (0.04)
-0.44 (0.04)
-0.65 (0.04)
-0.64 (0.07)
-0.44 (0.04)
0.75 (0.06)
0.75 (0.06)
0.75 (0.06)
0.63 (0.11)
0.63 (0.11)
0.63 (0.11)
0.97 (0.01)
0.97 (0.01)
0.97 (0.01)

0.58 (10.75)
-0.60 (0.80)
Log likelihood
-4.9
-4.9
-36.7
-36.4
-4.9
(a) T-V means that the model considers a time-varying state variable for the corresponding parameter.
(b) Standard errors of the estimated parameters are reported in parenthesis.
Notes:
(1) The estimation period is from 1948Q1 to 2019Q4. We estimate five univariate models for unemployment. We denote
each model with a term consisting of four parts, each of which is related to each specification aspect. For example, A-
Uni-SB-UC means Asymmetric-Univariate-Structural Break-Uncorrelated. Indeed, in this model, shocks are asymmetric,
there is one variable, the drift in unemployment trend has a break, and the correlation between shocks to the trend and
cyclical components is presumed to be zero. For the list of models and specifications, see Table B3 in Appendix B.
(2) For all models, the structural break in the drift of the unemployment trend (natural rate of unemployment) in 1981Q1
is accounted for. The break date is identified based on likelihood ratio statistics estimated for a sequence of breaks from
1960 to 2020, which spiked around 1981, as shown in the middle-right panel of Figure 2 and in the right panel of Figure
D10 in Appendix D.
(3) By pairwise comparison of log likelihood values of -4.9 and -4.9 reported for two asymmetric models 1a and 1b with
values of -36.7 and -36.4 reported for their symmetric counterpart models 2a and 2b, we favour the asymmetric models
over symmetric models. The corresponding likelihood ratios of 63.6 and 63.0 are exceedingly greater than the critical
value of 10.8 for a 0.1% significance level.
(4) By comparing the log likelihood of -4.9 reported for the asymmetric uncorrelated model 1a with the value of -4.9 for
its correlated counterpart 1b, we accept the null hypothesis of zero-correlation because the likelihood ratio is 0.0.
(5) By comparing the log likelihood of -36.7 reported for the symmetric uncorrelated model 2a with the value of -36.4 for
its correlated counterpart 2b, we accept the null hypothesis of zero-correlation because the negligible likelihood ratio of
0.8 is less than the critical values of 3.84 and even 2.71 for 5% and 10% significance levels.
(6) Model 3, which is nested in model 1a, assumes that the variance of shocks to the unemployment trend must be zero
(
), yet its estimated parameters are identical to those of model 1a.
38
Supplementary Appendices to
Asymmetric Co-fluctuations of U.S. Output and Unemployment:
Friedman’s Plucking Model and Okun’s Law
Mohammad Dehghani†,* Sungjun Cho Stuart Hyde
Appendix A: Summary of empirical literature
Table A1: Four specification aspects in existing trend-cycle decompositions
Choices on four specification aspects
Models and Authors
Asymmetric Bivariate Model
1. Asymmetric
2. Bivariate
3. Stochastic trend growth
4. Insignificant Correlation
This study
Symmetric Bivariate Model
1. Symmetric
2. Bivariate
3. Stochastic trend growth
4. Correlated shocks
Clark (1989), Gonzalez-Astudillo and Roberts (2022)
1. Symmetric
2. Bivariate
3. Stochastic trend growth
4. Uncorrelated shocks
Berger et al. (2016), Fernald et al. (2017),
1. Symmetric
2. Bivariate
3. Constant trend growth
4. Uncorrelated shocks
Owyang and Sekhposyan (2012), Grant (2018)
Asymmetric Univariate Model
1. Asymmetric
2. Univariate
3. Stochastic trend growth
4. Uncorrelated shocks
Kim and Nelson (1999a), Mills and Wang (2002), De Simone
and Clarke (2007), Morley and Piger (2012)
1. Asymmetric
2. Univariate
3. Structural break in trend growth
4. Uncorrelated shocks
Eo and Morley (2022)
1. Asymmetric
2. Univariate
3. Constant trend growth
4. Correlated shocks
Sinclair (2010)
Symmetric Univariate Model
1. Symmetric
2. Univariate
3. Stochastic trend growth
4. Correlated shocks
Kim and Chon (2020), Kim and Kim (2022)
1. Symmetric
2. Univariate
3. Stochastic trend growth
4. Uncorrelated shocks
Harvey (1985), Clark (1987), Grant and Chan (2017a)
1. Symmetric
2. Univariate
3. Structural break in trend growth
4. Correlated shocks
Luo and Startz (2014)
1. Symmetric
2. Univariate
3. Structural break in trend growth
4. Uncorrelated shocks
Perron and Wada (2009), Grant and Chan (2017b)
1. Symmetric
2. Univariate
3. Constant trend growth
4. Correlated shocks
Beveridge and Nelson (1981), Nelson and Plosser (1982),
Morley et al. (2003)
Notes:
(1) This table categorizes the literature on trend-cycle decomposition by determining the decision made by each study regarding
each of the four specification aspects. These four aspects are: whether the cyclical component is asymmetric or symmetric;
whether unemployment must be included within a bivariate model; whether the trend growth is stochastic or deterministic; and
whether the correlation between shocks to the trend and cyclical components is relevant or not.
(2) If a study performs different setups for one or two of the specification aspects, the above table refers to the main model it
uses.
† Alliance Manchester Business School. Email: mohammad.dehghani@manchester.ac.uk.
* Corresponding author. See the website https://sites.google.com/view/mohammaddehghani for data and code. For
details about the method and parameter constraints, see the comments in the MATLAB code.
39
Table A2: Four attributes of business cycle asymmetries
Definition
Related literature
Correlation asymmetry (ceiling effect)
The amplitude of recessions is strongly correlated with the
amplitude of succeeding expansions, but the amplitude of
expansions is uncorrelated with the amplitude of
succeeding recessions.
Friedman (1964, 1993), Wynne and Balke (1992),
Beaudry and Koop (1993), Goodwin and Sweeney
(1993), Fatás and Mihov (2013), Bordo and
Haubrich (2017), Dupraz et al. (2019).
Deepness asymmetry
Recession troughs are deep and expansion peaks are
small in amplitude.
Output displays a negative skewness relative to the trend.
The unemployment rate displays a positive skewness.
Neftci (1984), DeLong and Summers (1984),
Sichel (1993), Goodwin and Sweeney (1993).
Steepness asymmetry
Recessions are steep (violent) and expansions are gradual
(mild).
Output growth (first difference) displays a negative
skewness.
Unemployment growth (first difference) displays a
positive skewness.
DeLong and Summers (1984), Falk (1986), Sichel
(1993), McKay and Reis (2008), Jensen et al.
(2020).
Duration asymmetry
Recessions are short and recoveries are long.
Neftci (1984)
Notes:
(1) This table reviews four attributes of business cycle asymmetries considered in different studies.
(2) The output gap skewness of -0.93 and -0.4 as well as unemployment gap skewness of +0.75 and +0.94 reported in
Figure D11 in Appendix D, provides preliminary evidence for asymmetries in output and unemployment.
(3) The Markov-switching process has the potential to capture all types of asymmetries: A significant plucking coefficient
with the addition of estimating output gaps that are often negative and rarely positive confirms the ceiling effect
(correlation asymmetry). Estimating deep output gaps with a short expected duration for recessions and a long expected
duration for recoveries implies deepness, steepness, and duration asymmetries.
(4) Besides the asymmetries explained in the above table, other studies have defined alternative asymmetries. For example,
McQueen and Thorley (1993) explore the sharpness symmetry, which means that peaks are sharp and troughs are round
for the unemployment rate. Another classification suggests two asymmetries: asymmetry around the vertical line, and
asymmetry around the horizontal line. In this sense, correlation and deepness are asymmetries around the horizontal line
and steepness and duration are asymmetries around the vertical line.
40
Appendix B: State-space representations
B.1: Bivariate state-space model with Markov-switching
We cast the bivariate model explained in Eq. (1) to Eq. (12) in a state-space form. The observation
equation, the transition equation, and variance covariance matrix of error terms are as follows:
󰇣
󰇤󰇣 
󰇤


󰇣
󰇤
(B.1.1)


󰇛󰇜











(B.1.2)





󰇛
 


(B.1.3)
In the above model, we consider natural log GDP multiplied by 100 and the unemployment rate as
the observed series ( and ). To test for asymmetry, we derive the restricted symmetric model by
imposing on the unrestricted asymmetric model.
There are multiple state-space representations for the bivariate model. In addition to the above one,
for example, we could consider a measurement error for Okun’s law and cast the bivariate model in
the state-space form explained below, which estimates very similar parameters as the first form.
󰇣
󰇤󰇣 
󰇤

󰇣
󰇤
(B.1.4)

󰇛󰇜









(B.1.5)
󰇣
󰇤󰇛
(B.1.6)
41




󰇛


(B.1.7)
Table B1: Specification of 22 bivariate models
Model name
Tables and Figures
Related model in the
literature
Model 1a: Asymmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB-UC
Model 1b: Asymmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB-C1 ()
Model 1c: Asymmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB-C2 ( )
Model 1d: Asymmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB-C3 ()
Model 1e: Asymmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB-C123 (, )
Table 1, Figures 1, 2
Table 1, Figure D1
Table D1
Table D1
Table D1
--
--
--
--
--
Model 2a: Asymmetric-Bivariate-SB-SB-UC
Model 2b: Asymmetric-Bivariate-SB-SB-C1 ()
Model 2c: Asymmetric-Bivariate-SB-SB-C2 ( )
Table 1
Table 1
Table D1
--
--
--
Model 3a: Asymmetric-Bivariate-Con-SB-UC (5 state variable)
Model 3a′: Asymmetric-Bivariate-Con-SB-UC (6 state variables)
Model 3b: Asymmetric-Bivariate-Con-SB-C1 ()
Model 3c: Asymmetric-Bivariate-Con-SB-C2 ( )
Table 1
Table D1
Table D1
Table D1
--
--
--
--
Model 4a: Symmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB-UC
Model 4b: Symmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB-C1 ()
Model 4c: Symmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB-C2 ( )
Table 1
Table D1
Table D1
(Clark, 1989)
--
--
Model 5a: Symmetric-Bivariate-SB-SB-UC
Model 5b: Symmetric-Bivariate-SB-SB-C1 ()
Table 1
Table D1
--
--
Model 6a: Symmetric-Bivariate-Con-SB-UC
Model 6b: Symmetric-Bivariate-Con-SB-C1 ()
Table 1
Table D1
--
(Gonzalez-Astudillo and Roberts, 2022)
Model 7: Asymmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB-UC-SB
Figure 2
--
Model 8: Asymmetric-Bivariate-SB-RW-SB-UC
Figure 2
--
Model 9: Asymmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB0-UC
Table D1
--
Notes:
(1) We estimate twenty-two different bivariate models on the basis of different choices on the four specification aspects.
Accordingly, we denote each model with an identifier and a descriptor. The descriptor consists of five parts, four of which
are related to each specification aspect. The first part determines whether the model is asymmetric or symmetric, and the
second part shows whether the model is univariate or bivariate. The third part hints at the specification of output trend
growth (stochastic, structural break, or constant). The fourth part shows that we take a structural break in drift of the
natural rate of unemployment into account. The last part indicates whether the model is uncorrelated or correlated. For
example, model 1a, which is the main model and is denoted by Asymmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB-UC, means the model is
asymmetric and bivariate. The trend growth is presumed to be a random walk (stochastic) process, and the natural rate
has a structural break. The correlation between shocks to the trend and cyclical components is also assumed to be zero.
(2) The second SB, as an additional part of model 7, expresses a structural break in the volatility of shocks to the remaining
cyclical component. This model is used to find a break in the variance of the Okun’s law residual to explain the change in
variances before and after the great moderation.
(3) The first SB, as an additional part of model 8, expresses a structural break in Okun’s coefficient. This model is used
to investigate instability in Okun’s law, particularly following the global financial crisis.
(4) The term SB0 shown in model 9 indicates that model 9 is nested in model 1a by assuming that the variance of shocks
to the unemployment trend is zero (
). See footnote 7 for more information.
(5) We present the results of the bolded models in Table 1, and the rest are presented in Table D1 in Appendix D.
42
B.2: Univariate state-space model with Markov-switching
To estimate the output trend and cyclical components, we cast the univariate model explained in Eq.
(13) to Eq. (18) in a state-space form. The observation equation, the transition equation, and variance
covariance matrix of error terms are as follows:
󰇟󰇠󰇟󰇠

󰇟󰇠
(B.2.1)







(B.2.2)


󰇛


(B.2.3)
In the above model, we consider natural log GDP multiplied by 100 as the observed series (). To
test for asymmetry, we derive the restricted symmetric model by imposing on the unrestricted
asymmetric model. We then estimate this nested model by using Kalman’s (1960) filter. In the above
setup, we consider a stochastic trend growth that moves according to a random walk. Alternatively,
if we model the trend growth as a non-stochastic drift with a structural break, the corresponding state-
space representation would be:
󰇟󰇠󰇟 󰇠󰇯

󰇰󰇟󰇠
(B.2.4)
󰇯

󰇰󰇛󰇜
󰇯


󰇰

(B.2.5)


󰇛󰇯


󰇰
(B.2.6)
For the trend and cyclical components for unemployment, we use the following state-space form:
󰇟󰇠󰇟 󰇠󰇯

󰇰󰇟󰇠
(B.2.7)
󰇯

󰇰󰇛󰇜󰇜
󰇯


󰇰

(B.2.8)
43


󰇛󰇯


󰇰
(B.2.9)
Where the unemployment rate is considered as the observed series () and the structural break for
the natural rate of unemployment is accounted for. In above models, we could find the break date by
exploring the supremum of the log likelihood ratios calculated for a sequence of structural breaks
rolling from 1960 to 2010.
Table B2: Specification of 14 univariate models for output
Model name
Tables and Figures
Related model in the
literature
Model 1a: Asymmetric-Univariate-RW-UC
Model 1b: Asymmetric-Univariate-RW-C ()
Table 2, Figure 3
Table 2, Figure D4
(Kim and Nelson, 1999a)
--
Model 2a: Asymmetric-Univariate-SB-UC
Model 2b: Asymmetric-Univariate-SB-C ()
Table 2, Figure D5
Table 2, Figure D5
--
--
Model 3a: Asymmetric-Univariate-Con-UC (3 state variables)
Model 3a′: Asymmetric-Univariate-Con-UC (4 state variables)
Model 3b: Asymmetric-Univariate-Con-C ()
Table 2, Figure D6
Table D2
Table D2, Figure D6
--
--
(Sinclair, 2010)
Model 4a: Symmetric-Univariate-RW-UC
Model 4b: Symmetric-Univariate-RW-C ()
Table 2, Figure D7
Table D2, Figure D7
(Clark, 1987)
--
Model 5a: Symmetric-Univariate-SB-UC
Model 5b: Symmetric-Univariate-SB-C ()
Table 2, Figure D7
Table D2, Figure D7
(Perron and Wada, 2009)
--
Model 6a: Symmetric-Univariate-Con-UC
Model 6b: Symmetric-Univariate-Con-C ()
Table 2, Figure D8
Table D2, Figure D8
--
(Morley, 2003)
Model 7: Asymmetric-Univariate-RW-UC-SB
Figure D10
--
Table B3: Specification of 5 univariate models for unemployment
Model name
Tables and Figures
Related model in the
literature
Model 1a: Asymmetric-Univariate-SB-UC
Model 1b: Asymmetric-Univariate-SB-C ()
Table 3, Figure 3
Table 3, Figure D4
--
--
Model 2a: Symmetric-Univariate-SB-UC
Model 2b: Symmetric-Univariate-SB-C ()
Table 3, Figure D9
Table 3, Figure D9
--
--
Model 3: Asymmetric-Univariate-SB0-UC
Table 3
--
Notes:
(1) We estimate fourteen univariate models for output and five univariate models for unemployment. We show each model
with an identifier and a descriptor. The descriptor consists of four parts, each of which is related to each specification
aspect. The first part determines whether the model is asymmetric or symmetric, and the second part re-emphasises that
the model is univariate. The third part hints at the specification of output trend growth (stochastic, structural break, or
constant). Regarding the unemployment rate, the third part shows that we take a structural break in drift term of the natural
rate of unemployment into account. The last part indicates whether the model is uncorrelated or correlated. For example,
model 1a, which is denoted by Asymmetric-Univariate-RW-UC, means the model is asymmetric, univariate, the trend
growth is random walk, and the correlation between shocks to the trend and cyclical components is presumed to be zero.
(2) The term SB, as an additional part of model 7 that is applied to output, expresses a structural break in the variance of
the cyclical component to explain the change in variances before and after the great moderation. This model is used to
find the break in residual volatility.
(3) The term SB0 shown in model 3 that is applied to unemployment indicates that model 3 is nested in model 1a by
assuming that the variance of shocks to the unemployment trend is zero (
). See footnote 7 for more information.
(4) We present the results of the bold models in Tables 2 and 3, and the rest are presented in Table D2 in Appendix D.
44
Appendix C: Approximate maximum likelihood method
For asymmetric models in the presence of the Markov-switching process of Hamilton (1989), we use
Kim's (1994) approximate maximum likelihood method to make the Kalman’s (1960) filter operable.
For more explanation, see chapters 4 and 5 of Kim and Nelson’s (1999b) and chapters 13 and 22 of
Hamilton (1994). For symmetric models, we use the maximum likelihood method, performed by the
Kalman’s (1960) filter as explained in chapters 2 and 3 of Kim and Nelson (1999b) and chapter 5 of
Hamilton (1994).
We need to impose a set of constraints on parameters, which are explained carefully in the first part
of Appendix C. We also consider a set of initial values for parameters as well as state variables. For
the former, all initial values for parameters are presented in Tables C1, C2, and C3 in the second part
of Appendix C. For the latter, we use the first observation for trend components, zero for cyclical
components, and 3.2% for annual trend growth to determine the prior values for state variables. The
prior variances of state variables are set to be 10. The results are robust to changes in prior values of
state variables and their variances. For example, we can use a wilder guess by setting the variances
of state variables equal to 1000, which bears the same estimation for parameters.
45
C.1: Parameters constraints
We employ a numerical optimization procedure to maximize the approximate log likelihood function
subject to a set of constraints. We need to impose these constraints on some of the parameters, namely
coefficients, probabilities, and standard deviations of shocks. To this end, we account for constraints
by using a transformation function, 󰇛󰇜, which transforms a vector of unconstrained parameters
󰇟󰇠 to a vector of constrained parameters 󰇟󰇠 presented below:
󰇟󰇠
(C.1.1)
where 󰇛󰇜 is the vector of parameters of interest that we want to estimate and 󰇛󰇜 is a vector
function, whose elements are continuous transformation functions 󰇛󰇜 for . We know
that performing unconstrained optimization with respect to is equivalent to performing constrained
optimization with respect to . We therefore adopt an unconstrained optimization with respect to the
vector , where the objective (approximate log likelihood) function is considered as a function of
the transformation function. We define each element of the transformation function as follows:
First, for coefficients and standard deviations of shocks that should be positive, we use an exponential
transformation suggested by Kim and Nelson (1999b). For example,
󰇛󰇜
(C.1.2)
where is the standard deviation (square root of variance) of shocks to the trend component of
output and is assumed to be positive. Similarly, for other standard deviations, including , , ,
and and for coefficients , , and that are expected to be positive and for other coefficients
, , , and that are expected to be negative, we use an exponential transformation. For example,
󰇛󰇜 ensures a positive plucking coefficient for unemployment, and 󰇛󰇜
ensures a negative Okun’s law coefficient.
Second, to have transition probabilities in the 󰇟󰇠 interval, we exert the following transformations:
󰇛󰇜
󰇛󰇜 󰇛󰇜
󰇛󰇜
(C.1.3)
Third, for the coefficient of the autoregressive process of order one, we use Eq. (C1..4):


(C.1.4)
Clearly, lies in the stationary region since . For coefficients of the autoregressive
process of order two, we need to set the values of and within the stationary region that means
the roots of the lag polynomial () must lie outside the unit circle. In this sense,
we use the following transformations proposed by Morley et al. (2003):
46
󰇛󰇜
(C.1.5.a)
where and are determined below:

󰇛󰇜

(C.1.6.a)
For these two coefficients of the autoregressive process, we can take an alternative transformation
proposed by Kim and Nelson (1999b):

(C.1.5.b)
where and are determined below:



(C.1.6.b)
However, transformations in Eq. (C.1.5) and Eq. (C.1.6) impose a further restriction that the roots of
the autoregressive polynomial are real numbers.
Fourth, for correlation coefficients, we consider Eq. (C.1.7):


(C.1.7)
where  is the correlation between shocks and clearly satisfies the condition .
Finally, for correlated models, we can use alternative constraints for standard deviations of shocks
to components and their correlation. In this setting, we use a Cholesky factorization like Hamilton
(1994) and Morley et al. (2003), which is presented as follows:
󰇟󰆒󰇠󰇟󰆒󰇠󰇟󰆒󰇠
󰇟󰆒󰇠󰇟󰆒󰇠
(C.1.8)
In Eq. (C.1.8), 󰇟󰆒󰇠 is the element on the row and column of the symmetric positive definite
matrix denoted by 󰇟󰆒󰇠, which is known as the Cholesky factorization. To derive the elements
of 󰇟󰆒󰇠, we first need to construct the Cholesky factor (), a lower triangular matrix with
positive diagonal elements 󰇛󰇜 and 󰇛󰇜 and an off-diagonal element of
.
It is worth noting that the results of this study are robust to the choice of the transformation functions
when there are two alternatives. In addition, the plucking property (asymmetry) and Okun’s law (co-
fluctuations) are two pronounced features of U.S. macroeconomics so that excluding each or both of
their corresponding constraints ( and ) does not change the estimated parameters.
47
C.2: Tables of initial values for parameters
Table C1: Initial values (after-transformation) for the parameters of the bivariate model
1a
1b
2a
2b
3a
4a
5a
6a
Parameters
A-Bi-RW-SB-UC
A-Bi-RW-SB-C1
A-Bi-SB-SB-UC
A-Bi-SB-SB-C1
A-Bi-Con-SB-UC
S-Bi-RW-SB-UC
S-Bi-SB-SB-UC
S-Bi-Con-SB-UC
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50

0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
T-V
T-V
0.80
0.80
0.80
T-V
0.80
0.80
T-V
T-V
-0.30
-0.30
T-V
-0.30
0.03
0.03
0.03
0.03
0.03
0.03
0.03
0.03
-0.03
-0.03
-0.03
-0.03
-0.03
-0.03
-0.03
-0.03
1.2
1.2
1.2
1.2
1.2
1.2
1.2
1.2
-0.4
-0.4
-0.4
-0.4
-0.4
-0.4
-0.4
-0.4
1.8
1.8
1.8
1.8
1.8
0.70
0.70
0.70
0.70
0.70
0.90
0.90
0.90
0.90
0.90
-1.50
-1.50
-1.50
-1.50
-1.50
-1.50
-1.50
-1.50
-1.8
-1.8
-1.8
-1.8
-1.8
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.70*
0.75*

0.50
0.50


Notes:
(1) The results of the main proposed model as well as other models are unbelievably robust to the choice of the initial
values for each parameter. Therefore, we use the same initial values for almost all models. Alternatively, one can follow
a hierarchical method to find initial values, meaning that the researcher estimates the simplest model (symmetric univariate
model) first and keeps the estimated parameters to use as a best guess for the initial values for less restricted models.
(2) We set a few initial values for a few models different from those in other models to avoid deriving imaginary standard
errors in one or two parameters. These initial values are denoted by asterisks.
48
Table C2: Initial values (after-transformation) for the parameters of the univariate model for output
Models
1a
1b
2a
2b
3a
4a
5a
6a
Parameters
A-Uni-RW-UC
A-Uni-RW-C
A-Uni-SB-UC
A-Uni-SB-C
A-Uni-Con-UC
S-Uni-RW-UC
S-Uni-SB-UC
S-Uni-Con-UC
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50

0.50
0.50
0.50
T-V
T-V
0.75
0.75
0.75
T-V
0.75
0.75
T-V
T-V
-0.30
-0.30
T-V
-0.30
1.2
1.2
1.2
1.2
1.2
1.2
1.2
1.2
−0.4
−0.4
−0.4
−0.4
−0.4
−0.4
−0.4
−0.4
-1.80
-1.80
-1.80
-1.80
-1.80
0.70
0.70
0.70
0.70
0.70
0.90
0.90
0.90
0.90
0.90

0.50
0.50
Table C3: Initial values (after-transformation) for the parameters of the univariate model for unemployment
Models
1a
1b
2a
2b
3
Parameters
A-Uni-SB-UC
A-Uni-SB-C
S-Uni-SB-UC
S-Uni-SB-C
A-Uni-SB-UC
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.50
0.03
0.03
0.03
0.03
0.03
-0.03
-0.03
-0.03
-0.03
-0.03
1.2
1.2
1.2
1.2
1.2
-0.4
-0.4
-0.4
-0.4
-0.4
1.8
1.8
1.8
0.70
0.70
0.70
0.90
0.90
0.90

0.65*
0.20*
Notes:
(1) The results of all models for both indicators are robust to the choice of the initial values for each parameter.
(2) We use the same initial values for all models for both indicators that are almost the same as the initial values for the
bivariate model. For correlations between shocks to the unemployment trend and cyclical components in models 1b and
2b, we use different initial values to avoid deriving imaginary standard errors in one or two parameters. These initial
values are denoted by asterisks.
49
Appendix D: Additional empirical results
Some additional figures and tables are presented and explained here in Appendix D. Figure D1 shows
the results of model 1b, the correlated version of the asymmetric bivariate model. The insignificant
correlation between shocks says that the features of our proposed model are robust no matter whether
the correlation is involved in the model or not. Panels of Figure D2 present supplementary results of
the asymmetric bivariate model to establish its results. The top panels display trend growth and trend
acceleration to call attention to an unprecedented deceleration in U.S. potential output. The middle-
left panel shows that the depth of the leftover plucking property in the Okun’s residuals is small. This
implies that the plucking property in output is sourced from the plucking property in unemployment.
To be substantiated, we provide additional evidence confirming that the leftover plucking property
in the main proposed model is attributable to the lead-lag effect between output and unemployment.
The middle-right panel, in this regard, indicates that controlling the 1-month lead-lag effect between
output and unemployment entirely removes the leftover plucking property in the Okun’s residuals.
In addition, as reported in Table D3, while the output-specific plucking coefficient is notable in the
main model (), it is negligible in the model with the 1-month lead-lag effect controlled
(), and is finally zero in models with the 2-month or 3-month lead-lag effect controlled
(). As a result, considering that the unemployment rate lags behind output for only one
month, we infer that their co-fluctuations are sufficiently synchronous. The bottom panels of Figure
D2 also present routine diagnostic tests on error terms by showing that shocks to the Okun’s residuals
are zero-mean noise and their autocorrelation functions are fast decaying.
Additionally, Figure D3 and Table D5 present the results of applying the asymmetric bivariate model
to the U.S. GDP per capita and the U.K. GDP. Tables D1 and D2 are extensions of Tables 1 and 2,
each of which presents the results of several alternative bivariate and univariate models, respectively.
Table D3 lists the estimated parameters of the proposed model with the lead-lag effect controlled,
and Table D4 lists the results for the modified model that accommodates the COVID-19 recession.
We also uncover the consequences of misspecifications in the asymmetric univariate model. Figure
3, left panels of Figure D4, and Figure D5 highlight that because a time-varying trend growth is
accommodated in models 1a or 2a, the features of the estimated cyclical component are sensible and
similar to those of asymmetric bivariate models. Conversely, the middle-left panel of Figure D6
reveals that an unaccounted for break in trend growth in model 3a compels the plucking probability
to stay at one, which brings a paradoxical result: a permanent output gap in the transitory component.
Concerning the correlation between shocks, we derive the likelihood ratio values of 8.6, 10.8, and
19.0 by comparing pairwise the log likelihoods of -336.9, -334.7, and -341.0 for the uncorrelated
asymmetric models 1a, 2a, and 3a with those values of -332.6, -329.3, and -331.5 for their correlated
50
counterpart models 1b, 2b, and 3b. The correlation is therefore relevant in the asymmetric univariate
model, yet similarities of the features of trend and cyclical components of the uncorrelated and
correlated models in the left and right panels of Figure D5 in Appendix D shows that embedding the
asymmetry reduces the univariate model sensitivity to the assumption about the correlation.
We finally show that the counter-intuitive and sensitive features of the estimated components in the
symmetric univariate models are consequences of two misspecifications related to trend growth and
correlation. Figure D8 in Appendix D displays the trend and cyclical components estimated by model
6a on the left panel and its correlated counterpart 6b that replicates the results derived by Morley et
al. (2003) on the right panel, where in both models the trend growth is assumed to be deterministic.
Such an assumption leads to a cyclical component that clearly exhibits a downward leftover trend in
the bottom-left panel and an unusually small amplitude in the bottom-right panel.
18
As a result, the
features of components in a model with constant trend growth are dubious since they are sensitive to
the assumption about the correlation. Figure D7 shows that relaxing the assumption of constant trend
growth yields more intuitive and less sensitive results. The cyclical components of model 4a with
stochastic trend growth and model 5a with a break in trend growth in the left panels do not contain a
noticeable leftover trend. Further, although the cyclical components of correlated models 4b and 5b
in the right panels have clearly smaller amplitudes compared to their uncorrelated counterparts, they
are not diminutive and noisy like those in model 6a.
Figure D9 in Appendix D presents results of the univariate model applied to the unemployment rate,
indicating that there is a very mild increase in the natural rate of unemployment from the 1950s to
the 1980s, and then a mild reduction until now. Figure D10 provides evidence for the occurrence of
breaks in output trend growth and unemployment trend drift. The left panel shows two clusters of
repeatedly highly significant breaks, one in the 1970s and another in the 2000s, with multiple local
peaks in 1973, 1978, 2000, and 2006, which supports the use of stochastic rather than deterministic
drift to characterize the dynamics of trend growth in the U.S. The right panel reaffirms a significant
break in the drift term of natural rate of unemployment occurred in 1981Q1. Finally, Figure D11
reports the output gap skewness of -0.93 and -0.4 and the unemployment gap skewness of +0.75 and
+0.94 as initial evidence for asymmetries in output and unemployment.
18
Constant trend growth is improper because comparing the log likelihoods of -354.4 and -352.6 for models 4a and
5a with the value of -357.1 for model 6a, reaffirms the presence of stochastic trend growth and a break in 2009, as
the likelihood ratios of 5.4 and 9.0 are greater than the critical value of 3.84 for a 5% significance level.
51
Appendix D: Additional figures
(a) Potential output (trend) and output gap (cyclical component)
(b) Trend growth of output and the plucking probabilities for bivariate model
(c) Natural rate of unemployment (trend) and unemployment gap (cyclical component)
Figure D1: Results of the correlated version of the asymmetric bivariate model
Notes:
(1) All panels plot the results of the correlated version of our proposed model (Asymmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB-C1).
(2) The top panels plot potential output and the output gap, and the middle-left panel plots the trend growth of output.
(3) The middle-right panel plots the plucking probabilities, which are estimated for both output and unemployment jointly.
(4) The bottom panels plot the trend and gap for unemployment.
(5) The shaded areas are the NBER recession dates.
52
(a) Trend growth and trend acceleration of U.S. output
(b) Okun’s law residuals without (left) and with (right) the 1-month lead-lag effect controlled
(c) Diagnostic of shocks to the Okun’s residuals for model without (left) and with (right) the 1-month lead-lag effect controlled
Figure D2: Supplementary results of the asymmetric bivariate model
Notes:
(1) The top panels plot trend growth and trend acceleration (growth of trend growth) of U.S. output.
(2) The middle panel plots the Okun’s law residuals. In the left panel, although some part of the plucking property remains in
the residuals because it is not explained by Okun’s law, the depth of the residuals is small in amplitude. The right panel shows
controlling the 1-month lead-lag effect between output and unemployment entirely removes the leftover plucking property. This
supports that the plucking property in output is mainly sourced from the plucking property in the unemployment rate.
(3) The shocks to the Okuns law residuals are zero-mean noise and its autocorrelation function decays very fast.
(4) The shaded areas are the NBER recession dates.
53
(a) Potential and gap for GDP per capita
(b) Trend growth of output per capita and the plucking probabilities for bivariate model
(c) Natural rate of unemployment (trend) and unemployment gap (cyclical component)
Figure D3: Results of the asymmetric bivariate model for GDP per capita
Notes:
(1) All panels plot the results of our proposed model (Asymmetric-Bivariate-RW-SB-UC), applied to the U.S. GDP per capita.
(2) The top panels plot the potential and gap for GDP per capita, and the middle-left panel plots the trend growth of output per
capita.
(3) The middle-right panel plots the plucking probabilities, which are estimated for both output and unemployment jointly.
(4) The bottom panels plot the trend and gap for unemployment.
(5) The shaded areas are the NBER recession dates.
54
(a) Potential output (trend) and output gap (cyclical component)
(b) Plucking probabilities for output (left) and unemployment (right)
(c) Natural rate of unemployment (trend) and the unemployment gap (cyclical components)
Figure D4: Comparing results of the asymmetric univariate models for output and unemployment (correlated models)
Notes:
(1) The top panels plot the results of the asymmetric univariate model for output with a stochastic (random walk) trend growth,
where shocks to the trend and cyclical components are correlated (Asymmetric-Univariate-RW-C).
(2) The middle panels plot the plucking probabilities for output and unemployment estimated in two separate models.
(3) The bottom panels plot the results of the asymmetric univariate model for unemployment with a break in the drift of the
unemployment trend, where shocks to the trend and cyclical components are correlated (Asymmetric-Univariate-SB-C).
(4) The shaded areas are the NBER recession dates.
55
(a) The trend component
(b) Output gap (cyclical component)
(c) Plucking probabilities
Figure D5: Results of the asymmetric univariate models with a break in trend growth
Notes:
(1) The left panels plot the results of the asymmetric univariate model with uncorrelated shocks.
(2) The right panels plot the results of the asymmetric univariate model with correlated shocks.
(3) The shaded areas are the NBER recession dates.
56
(a) The trend component
(b) Output gap (cyclical component)
(c) Plucking probabilities
Figure D6: Results of the asymmetric univariate models with constant trend growth
Notes:
(1) The left panels plot the results of the asymmetric univariate model with uncorrelated shocks.
(2) The right panels plot the results of the asymmetric univariate model with correlated shocks, which replicates the work
of Sinclair (2010).
(3) The shaded areas are the NBER recession dates.
57
(a) The cyclical component of uncorrelated (left) and correlated (right) models, with stochastic trend growth
(b) The cyclical component of uncorrelated (left) and correlated (right) models, with a break in trend growth
Figure D7. Results of the symmetric univariate models with inconstant trend growth for U.S. output
Notes:
(1) The top panels are the results of the model with stochastic (random walk) trend growth where shocks to the trend and
cyclical components are uncorrelated (Symmetric-Univariate-RW-UC) in the left panel and correlated (Symmetric-
Univariate-RW-C) in the right panel. The former replicates the work of Clark (1987).
(2) The bottom panels are the results of the model with a structural break in trend growth in 2009, where shocks to the
trend and cyclical components are uncorrelated (Symmetric-Univariate-SB-UC) in the left and correlated in the right
panels (Symmetric-Univariate-SB-C). They are similar to those of Perron and Wada (2009) and Grant and Chan (2017b)
with a break in 2009.
(3) The shaded areas are the NBER recession dates.
58
(a) The trend component of uncorrelated (left) and correlated (right) models
(b) The cyclical component of uncorrelated (left) and correlated (right) models
Figure D8: Results of the symmetric univariate models with constant trend growth for U.S. output
Notes:
(1) The left panels plot the results of the symmetric univariate model with constant trend growth, where shocks to the
trend and cyclical components are uncorrelated (Symmetric-Univariate-Con-UC).
(2) The right panels plot the results of the symmetric univariate model with constant trend growth, where shocks to the
trend and cyclical components are correlated (Symmetric-Univariate-Con-C), and replicates those of Morley et al. (2003).
(3) The shaded areas are the NBER recession dates.
59
(a) The trend component of uncorrelated (left) and correlated (right) models
(b) The cyclical component of uncorrelated (left) and correlated (right) models
Figure D9: Results of the symmetric univariate model for U.S. unemployment
Notes:
(1) The left panels plot the results of the model with a structural break in the drift of the unemployment trend (natural rate)
and uncorrelated shocks to the trend and cyclical components (Symmetric-Univariate-SB-UC). Similar setting is applied
to the asymmetric bivariate model.
(2) The right panels plot the results of the model with a structural break in drift in unemployment rate trend (natural rate)
and correlated shocks to the trend and cyclical components (Symmetric-Univariate-SB-C).
(3) The resemblance of the components of uncorrelated and correlated models indicates an insignificant correlation (-0.60
with a standard error of 0.80) for the unemployment rate.
(4) The shaded areas are the NBER recession dates.
60
Likelihood ratios at different break dates for trend growth (left) and the unemployment trend (right)
Figure D10: Exploring structural breaks in the parameters for asymmetric univariate model
Notes:
(1) Both panels plot likelihood ratio values for a sequence of breaks rolling from 1960 to 2010. The left panel plots the likelihood
ratios testing for breaks in trend growth on different dates against a constant trend growth. The right panel plots the likelihood
ratios testing for breaks in the drift of the unemployment trend on different dates against a constant trend.
(2) The shaded areas are the NBER recession dates.
(a) The histogram of U.S. output gap estimated by Tukey’s bi-weight filter (left) and UC model (right)
(b) The histogram of U.S. unemployment gap by Tukey’s bi-weight filter (left) and UC model (right)
Figure D11: Histogram of output gap and unemployment gap.
Notes:
(1) The output gap skewness is -0.93 for the left and -0.41 for the right panel.
(2) The unemployment gap skewness is +0.75 for the left and +0.94 for the right panel.
61
Appendix D: Additional tables
Table D1 (Continue of Table 1): Estimated parameters of the bivariate models
Models
1c
1d
1e
2c
3a′
3b
3c
Parameters
A-Bi-RW-SB-C2
A-Bi-RW-SB-C3
A-Bi-RW-SB-C123
A-Bi-SB-SB-C2
A-Bi-Con-SB-UC
A-Bi-Con-SB-C1
A-Bi-Con-SB-C2
0.44 (0.09)
0.43 (0.10)
0.44 (0.10)
0.52 (0.06)
0.62 (0.03)
0.63 (0.03)
0.70 (0.09)
0.21 (0.01)
0.21 (0.01)
0.21 (0.01)
0.21 (0.01)
0.21 (0.01)
0.21 (0.01)
0.21 (0.01)

0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.00 (0.02)
0.00 (0.03)
0.00 (0.03)
0.00 (0.02)
0.00 (0.01)
0.00 (0.03)
0.00 (0.02)
0.18 (2.50)
0.35 (0.09)
0.20 (1.25)
0.28 (1.57)
0.00 (0.10)
0.00 (0.14)
0.13 (0.51)
T-V
T-V
T-V
0.83 (0.03)
0.76 (0.03)
0.76 (0.04)
T-V
T-V
T-V
-0.50 (0.08)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.04 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.04 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
1.38 (0.04)
1.38 (0.04)
1.37 (0.04)
1.36 (0.04)
1.38 (0.04)
1.35 (0.04)
1.37 (0.04)
-0.44 (0.04)
-0.44 (0.04)
-0.44 (0.04)
-0.43 (0.04)
-0.44 (0.04)
-0.42 (0.04)
-0.44 (0.04)
0.70 (0.06)
0.70 (0.06)
0.70 (0.06)
0.70 (0.06)
0.70 (0.06)
0.71 (0.06)
0.70 (0.05)
0.66 (0.09)
0.66 (0.09)
0.66 (0.09)
0.67 (0.09)
0.66 (0.09)
0.66 (0.09)
0.66 (0.09)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
-1.44 (0.12)
-1.42 (0.14)
-1.30 (0.17)
-1.44 (0.13)
-1.39 (0.14)
-1.04 (0.29)
-1.29 (0.15)
-1.01 (0.15)
-1.01 (0.16)
-1.07 (0.17)
-1.05 (0.16)
-1.00 (0.17)
-1.20 (0.25)
-1.05 (0.17)
0.49 (0.10)
0.51 (0.12)
0.52 (0.12)
0.51 (0.11)
0.53 (0.11)
0.66 (0.12)
0.61 (0.11)

-0.24 (0.18)
-0.16 (0.12)

0.66 (16.6)
-0.65 (7.97)
-0.08 (3.59)
-0.69 (1.69)

-0.04 (0.12)
-0.25 (1.67)
Log likelihood
-11.9
-11.9
-10.9
-7.4
-22.1
-18.8
-19.2
(a) T-V means that the model considers a time-varying state variable for the corresponding parameter.
(b) Standard errors of the estimated parameters are reported in parenthesis.
(c) Numerical values for parameters denoted by 0.00 are 0.0001 for model 1c, 0.0002 for model 1d 0.0005 for model 1e, 0.001
for model 2c, .0000003 and 0.0006 for model 3a′, 0.0002 and 0.001 for model 3b, and 0.0006 for model 3c.
Notes:
(1) The estimation period runs from 1948Q1 to 2019Q4. See Table 1 for the main results and explanations.
(2) For all models, the structural break in the drift of the unemployment trend in 1981Q1 is accounted for. For models 2b and
5c, the structural break in trend growth in 2009Q3 is accounted for.
(3) Model 3a′ is another version of model 3a with almost identical estimation of parameters. Since in the former, we treat the
drift term (constant trend growth) as a state variable and in the latter, the drift term is estimated as a parameter; model 3a′ is fully
nested in model 1a, but model 3a is not.
(4) Models 1c, 2c, and 3c are correlated counterparts of asymmetric bivariate models 1a, 2a, and 3a, respectively, which are
presented in Table 1. By comparing the log likelihoods of -11.9, -7.4, and -19.9 for the uncorrelated models with values of -11.9,
-7.4, and -19.2 for correlated models, we accept the null hypothesis suggesting that the correlation between shocks to the output
trend and remaining cyclical component () is negligible, as likelihood ratios of 0.0, 0.0, and 1.4 are zero or near zero.
62
Table D1 continued: Estimated parameters of the bivariate models
Models
4b
4c
5b
6b
7
8
9
Parameters
S-Bi-RW-SB-C1
S-Bi-RW-SB-C2
S-Bi-SB-SB-C1
S-Bi-Con-SB-C1
A-Bi-RW-SB-UC-SB
A-Bi-SB-RW-SB-UC
A-Bi-RW-SB0-UC
0.55 (0.07)
0.57 (0.13)
0.56 (0.06)
0.64 (0.04)
0.42 (0.20)
0.44 (0.09)
0.44 (0.09)
0.23 (0.02)
0.27 (0.01)
0.23 (0.02)
0.22 (0.01)
0.21 (0.01)
0.21 (0.01)
0.21 (0.01)

0.02 (0.01)
0.02 (0.01)
0.03 (0.02)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.14 (0.02)
0.03 (0.04)
0.14 (0.02)
0.14 (0.02)
0.00 (0.03)
0.00 (0.02)
0.21 (0.14)
0.27 (0.01)
0.18 (0.13)
0.06 (0.18)
0.550 (0.13)
0.039 (1.50)
0.34 (0.08)
0.34 (0.08)
T-V
T-V
0.83 (0.04)
0.78 (0.04)
T-V
T-V
T-V
T-V
T-V
-0.43 (0.10)
T-V
T-V
T-V
0.02 (0.02)
0.02 (0.01)
0.02 (0.02)
0.02 (0.02)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
-0.03 (0.02)
-0.03 (0.01)
-0.03 (0.02)
-0.05 (0.02)
-0.03 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
1.71 (0.04)
1.61 (0.04)
1.71 (0.04)
1.70 (0.04)
1.40 (0.06)
1.38 (0.04)
1.38 (0.04)
-0.74 (0.04)
-0.67 (0.05)
-0.74 (0.04)
-0.73 (0.04)
-0.47 (0.05)
-0.44 (0.04)
-0.45 (0.04)
0.70 (0.06)
0.70 (0.06)
0.70 (0.06)
0.64 (0.11)
0.66 (0.09)
0.66 (0.09)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
-1.38 (0.15)
-1.74 (0.10)
-1.42 (0.16)
-1.27 (0.17)
-1.33 (0.13)
-1.45 (0.12)
0.03 (0.15)
-1.45 (0.12)
-1.07 (0.20)
-1.00 (0.16)
-1.01 (0.15)
0.12 (0.67)
0.55 (0.48)
0.06 (0.80)
0.51 (0.74)
0.58 (0.13)
0.49 (0.11)
0.49 (0.10)

-0.65 (0.14)
-0.63 (0.15)
-0.65 (0.13)

-0.07 (0.52)

Log likelihood
-49.1
-57.5
-46.2
-54.4
8.7
-11.9
-11.9
(a) T-V means that the model considers a time-varying state variable for the corresponding parameter.
(b) Standard errors of the estimated parameters are reported in parenthesis.
(c) Numerical values for parameters denoted by 0.00 are 0.0006 for model 7, and 0.0002 for model 8.
Notes continued:
(5) Model 1d is the correlated counterpart of asymmetric bivariate model 1a, which is presented in Table 1. By comparing the
log likelihood of -11.9 for the uncorrelated model with the value of -11.9 for the correlated model, we ensure that the correlation
between shocks to the symmetric cyclical component and the remaining cyclical component () is negligible as its likelihood
ratio is 0.0. Further, model 1e allows for all correlations to test if three correlations are jointly significant or not. Comparing the
log likelihood of -11.9 for model 1a with the value of -10.9 for model 1e indicates a negligible correlation as the likelihood ratio
of 2.0 is smaller than the critical values of 7.81 and 6.25 for 5% and even 10% significance levels with three restrictions.
(6) Models 4b, 5b, and 6b are the correlated counterparts of symmetric bivariate models 4a, 5a, and 6a, respectively. By
comparing the log likelihood values of -57.5, -52.6, and -62.5 for the uncorrelated models 4a, 5a, and 6a with values of -49.1, -
46.2, and -54.4 for the correlated models 4b, 5b, and 6b, we reject the null hypothesis of zero-correlation between shocks to the
trend and symmetric cyclical components (), because likelihood ratios of 17.0, 12.8, and 16.2 are greater than the 0.1%
critical value of 10.8.
(7) In model 7, the estimated volatility of shocks to the cyclical component before and after 1983 is allowed to be different. In
model 8, a break in Okun’s coefficient in 2009 is allowed, although it is insignificant. Model 9 assumes that the variance of
shocks to the unemployment trend is zero (
), yet its estimated parameters are identical to those of model 1a.
63
Table D2 (Continue of Table 2): Estimated parameters of the univariate models for output
Models
3a′
3b
4b
5b
6b
7
Parameters
A-Uni-Con-UC
A-Uni-Con-C
S-Uni-RW-C
S-Uni-SB-C
S-Uni-Con-C
A-Uni-Con-C-SB
0.69 (0.03)
1.13 (0.12)
0.93 (0.19)
0.99 (0.19)
1.18 (0.15)
0.40 (0.03)
0.00 (0.12)
0.70 (0.16)
0.80 (0.20)
0.86 (0.22)
0.79 (0.25)
0.950 (0.08)
0.003 (0.29)

0.02 (0.01)
0.05 (0.02)
0.78 (0.06)
T-V
0.83 (0.06)
0.78 (0.07)
T-V
-0.31 (0.17)
1.12 (0.09)
1.09 (0.07)
1.44 (0.10)
1.44 (0.10)
1.24 (0.20)
1.36 (0.10)
-0.29 (0.08)
-0.36 (0.07)
-0.57 (0.07)
-0.56 (0.09)
-0.63 (0.17)
-0.45 (0.08)
-1.62 (0.22)
-1.88 (0.23)
-1.21 (0.24)
0.60 (0.07)
0.61 (0.09)
0.40 (0.26)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.97 (0.02)

-0.88 (0.04)
-0.71 (0.18)
-0.76 (0.14)
-0.92 (0.08)
Log likelihood
-344.1
-331.5
-353.2
-350.5
-349.4
-305.4
(a) T-V means that the model considers a time-varying state variable for the corresponding parameter.
(b) Standard errors of the estimated parameters are reported in parenthesis.
(c) Numerical values for the parameter denoted by 0.00 is 0.001 for model 3a′.
Notes:
(1) The estimation period runs from 1948Q1 to 2019Q4. See Table 2 for the main results and explanations.
(2) For model 5b, the structural break in trend growth in 2009Q3 is accounted for.
(3) Model 3a′ is another version of model 3a. It is clear that their estimations for parameters are very similar. The former
treats the drift term (constant trend growth) as a state variable, and the latter estimates the drift as a parameter. Hence,
model 3a′ is fully nested in model 1a, but model 3a is not.
(4) Models 4b and 5b are correlated counterparts of univariate models 4a and 5a, respectively, which are presented in
Table 2. By comparing the log likelihoods of the uncorrelated models (-354.4 and -352.6) with those of the correlated
models (-353.2 and -350.5), we accept the null hypothesis of zero-correlation because the likelihood ratios of 2.4 and 4.2
are less than the 1% critical value of 6.63.
(5) Model 6b is the correlated counterpart of the univariate model 6a presented in Table 2. By comparing the log likelihood
of the uncorrelated model (-357.1) with that of the correlated model (-349.4), we reject the null hypothesis of zero-
correlation because the likelihood ratio of 15.4 is greater than the 1% critical value of 6.63.
(6) In model 7, the estimated volatility of shocks to the cyclical component before and after 1983 is allowed to be different.
64
Table D3: Estimated parameters of the asymmetric bivariate model, with controlled lead-lag effect
Models
1a
1-month
2-month
3-month
Parameters
A-Bi-RW-SB-UC
A-Bi-RW-SB-UC
A-Bi-RW-SB-UC
A-Bi-RW-SB-UC
0.44 (0.09)
0.34 (0.11)
0.36 (0.09)
0.33 (0.14)
0.21 (0.01)
0.17 (0.01)
0.16 (0.01)
0.15 (0.01)

0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.00 (0.02)
0.11 (0.01)
0.12 (0.01)
0.13 (0.01)
0.34 (0.08)
0.38 (0.08)
0.35 (0.07)
0.44 (0.09)
T-V
T-V
T-V
T-V
T-V
T-V
T-V
T-V
0.03 (0.01)
0.02 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.03 (0.01)
-0.03 (0.01)
-0.03 (0.01)
1.38 (0.04)
1.47 (0.04)
1.48 (0.04)
1.47 (0.04)
-0.45 (0.04)
-0.53 (0.04)
-0.55 (0.04)
-0.54 (0.04)
0.70 (0.06)
0.66 (0.06)
0.62 (0.05)
0.65 (0.06)
0.66 (0.09)
0.57 (0.13)
0.61 (0.11)
0.61 (0.11)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
-1.45 (0.12)
-1.86 (0.13)
-1.96 (0.10)
-1.91 (0.10)
-1.01 (0.15)
-0.46 (0.18)
-0.000 (0.001)
-0.000 (0.001)
0.49 (0.10)
0.39 (0.20)
0.12 (0.21)
0.28 (0.20)
Log likelihood
-11.9
-22.3
-23.3
-38.0
(a) T-V means that the model considers a time-varying state variable for the corresponding parameter.
(b) Standard errors of the estimated parameters are reported in parenthesis.
Notes:
(1) The estimation period runs from 1948Q1 to 2019Q4.
(2) All columns present the results of the proposed model 1a with different observed series for unemployment. The first
column is the model without controlling the lead-lag effect between output and the unemployment rate. In this model, we
simply calculate the quarterly unemployment rate as the average of the rates of the three months within the corresponding
quarter. On the other hand, columns two, three, and four present the estimation results when the 1-month, 2-month, and
3-month lead-lag effect is accounted for. For example, we use 1-month leading unemployment as the data for the observed
series to estimate the 1-month model. We calculate the 1-month leading unemployment rate for each quarter by taking an
average of three months, two of which are within the same quarter, and the other one is in the subsequent quarter.
(3) The output-specific plucking coefficient () is significant. This suggests that some minor part of the plucking property
is not explained by Okun’s law. However, it is clear that this leftover plucking property is related to the lead-lag effect
between output and the unemployment rate because by controlling the 1-month lead-lag effect, the coefficient will be less
significant, and finally, by controlling the 2-month lead-lag effect, the output-specific plucking coefficient will be zero.
(4) Log likelihood values in this table are not comparable since the data inputs for unemployment are different.
65
Table D4: Estimated parameters of the bivariate model, including the COVID-19 recession
Models
1a1
1a2
Parameters
A-Bi-RW-SB-UC
A-Bi-RW-SB-UC
0.60 (0.03)
0.60 (0.03)
0.58 (0.02)
0.56 (0.02)

0.02 (0.01)
0.02 (0.01)
0.00 (0.01)
0.00 (0.02)
0.00 (1.52)
0.00 (0.12)
T-V
T-V
T-V
T-V
0.03 (0.01)
0.03 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
0.75 (0.05)
0.69 (0.05)
0.09 (0.05)
0.06 (0.05)
1.33 (0.17)
1.26 (0.14)
0.65 (0.09)
0.76 (0.07)
0.96 (0.01)
0.96 (0.01)
-1.18 (0.06)
-1.18 (0.06)
-1.38 (0.16)
-1.35 (0.16)
-0.12 (0.17)
-0.17 (0.15)

0.46 (0.28)
1.38 (0.32)



Log likelihood
-310.3
-305.8
(a) T-V means that the model considers a time-varying state variable for the corresponding parameter.
(b) Standard errors of the estimated parameters are reported in parenthesis.
(c) Numerical values for parameters denoted by 0.00 are 0.0004, 0.003, 0.00017 and 0.000 42 , respectively.
Notes:
(1) The estimation period is from 1948Q1 to 2022Q4. The table reports the results of the modified model (Asymmetric-
Bivariate-RW-SB-UC-Mod), which accounts for the COVID-19 recession by using Eq. (19) that includes a dummy for
the COVID-19 recession. The start of the COVID-19 pandemic () is assumed to be 2020Q1 for model 1a1
and 2020Q2 for model 1a2. The end of the COVID-19 pandemic () is 2021Q1 for both models.
(2) The COVID-specific plucking coefficient () is sizeable as the depth of the Covid-19 recession is greater than
those of previous recessions. The estimated common plucking coefficient () is also larger than that of the main proposed
model to explain a portion of the greater depth of the COVID-19 recession compared to that of previous recessions.
(3) The log likelihood value of these modified models are not comparable with that of the main model because the data
inputs for output and the unemployment rate are different from those of the main model.
(4) We set initial values for plucking parameters and one of the standard deviations () different from those presented
in Table C1 for the proposed model 1a to avoid deriving imaginary standard errors for . The selected initial values are
1.1, -1.1, 1.1, and 0.45 for , , , and , respectively.
66
Table D5: Estimated parameters of the bivariate model, for U.S. output per capita and U.K. output
Models
1a for U.S. GDP per capita
1a for U.K. GDP
Parameters
A-Bi-RW-SB-UC
A-Bi-RW-SB-UC
0.50 (0.09)
0.75 (0.13)
0.21 (0.01)
0.10 (0.01)

0.02 (0.01)
0.02 (0.01)
0.00 (0.02)
0.08 (0.01)
0.29 (0.10)
0.35 (0.22)
T-V
T-V
T-V
T-V
0.03 (0.01)
0.04 (0.01)
-0.04 (0.01)
-0.05 (0.02)
1.38 (0.05)
1.62 (0.07)
-0.44 (0.04)
-0.65 (0.06)
0.70 (0.05)
0.23 (0.05)
0.66 (0.09)
0.88 (0.07)
0.96 (0.01)
0.97 (0.02)
-1.45 (0.12)
-1.53 (0.35)
-1.02 (0.16)
-0.77 (0.52)
0.48 (0.11)
0.60 (0.28)



Log likelihood
-13.4
28.2
(a) T-V means that the model considers a time-varying state variable for the corresponding parameter.
(b) Standard errors of the estimated parameters are reported in parenthesis.
Note:
The estimation period runs from 1948Q1 to 2019Q4 for U.S. GDP per capita and spans from 1955Q1 to 2019Q4 for the
U.K. GDP.
67
Appendix E: Business cycle dates
Table E1: Dates of the U.S. Business Cycles (Peak and Trough)
N
ECRIa
NBERb
Description
1
1957M8-1958M4
1957M8-1958M4
--
2
1960M4-1961M2
1960M4-1961M2
--
3
1969M12-1970M11
1969M12-1970M11
--
4
1973M11-1975M3
1973M11-1975M3
First Oil Crisis
5
1980M1-1980M7
1980M1-1980M7
Second Oil Crisis
6
1981M7-1982M11
1981M7-1982M11
Early 1980s recession
7
1990M7-1991M3
1990M7-1991M3
Early 1990s recession
8
2001M3-2001M11
2001M3-2001M11
Early 2000s recession
9
2007M12-2009M6
2007M12-2009M6
Global crisis and recession
10
2020M2-2020M4
2020M2-2020M4
COVID-19 recession
(a) Economic Cycle Research Institute
(b) National Bureau of Economic Research
Table E2: Dates of the U.K. Business Cycles (Peak and Trough)
N
ECRIa
NIESRb
Description
1
-
1951M3-1952M8
--
2
-
1955M12-1958M11
--
3
-
1961M3-1963M1
--
4
1974M9-1975M8
1973M1-1975M3
First Oil Crisis
5
1979M6-1981M5
1979M2-1982M4
Second Oil Crisis
6
-
1984M1-1984M3
--
7
-
1988M4-1992M2
Early 1990s recession
8
1990M5-1992M3
-
Early 1990s recession
9
2008M5-2010M1
-
Global crisis and recession
10
2019M10-2020M4
-
COVID-19 recession
(a) Economic Cycle Research Institute
(b) National Institute of Economic and Social Research
68
References for Appendices
Basu, D., & Foley, D. K. (2013). Dynamics of output and employment in the US economy. Cambridge Journal
of Economics, 37(5), 1077-1106.
Beaudry, P., & Koop, G. (1993). Do recessions permanently change output? Journal of Monetary Economics,
31(2), 149-163.
Berger, T., Everaert, G., & Vierke, H. (2016). Testing for time variation in an unobserved components model
for the US economy. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 69, 179-208.
Beveridge, S., & Nelson, C. R. (1981). A new approach to decomposition of economic time series into
permanent and transitory components with particular attention to measurement of the business cycle.” Journal
of Monetary Economics, 7(2), 151174.
Bordo, M. D., & Haubrich, J. G. (2017). Deep recessions, fast recoveries, and financial crises: Evidence from
the American record. Economic Inquiry, 55(1), 527-541.
Clark, P. K. (1987). The cyclical component of US economic activity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102(4),
797814.
Clark, P. K. (1989). Trend reversion in real output and unemployment. Journal of Econometrics, 40(1), 15-32.
DeLong, J. B., & Summers, L. H. (1984). Are business cycles symmetric? NBER working papers 1444.
National Bureau of Economic Research.
De Simone, F. N., & Clarke, S. (2007). Asymmetry in business fluctuations: International evidence on
Friedman's plucking model. Journal of International Money and Finance, 26(1), 64-85.
Dupraz, S., Nakamura, E., & Steinsson, J. (2019). A plucking model of business cycles. NBER working papers
26351. National Bureau of Economic Research.
Eo, Y., & Morley, J. (2022). Why has the US economy stagnated since the Great Recession? Review of
Economics and Statistics, 104(2), 246-258.
Falk, B. (1986). Further evidence on the asymmetric behaviour of economic time series over the business
cycle. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 1096-1109.
Fatás, A., & Mihov, I. (2013). Recoveries. CEPR Discussion Papers 9551.
Fernald, J., Hall, R., Stock, J., & Watson, M. (2017). The disappointing recovery of output after 2009.
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2017(1), 1-81.
Friedman, M. (1964). Monetary Studies of the National Bureau, the National Bureau Enters its 45th Year, 44th
Annual Report. 7-25.
Friedman, M. (1993). The “plucking model” of business fluctuations revisited. Economic Inquiry, 31(2), 171-
177.
Gonzalez-Astudillo, M., & Roberts, J. M. (2022). When are trend-cycle decompositions reliable? Empirical
Economics, 62(5), 2417-2460.
69
Goodwin, T. H., & Sweeney, R. J. (1993). International evidence on Friedman's theory of the business cycle.
Economic Inquiry, 31(2), 178-193.
Grant, A. L. (2018). The great recession and Okun's law. Economic Modelling, 69, 291-300.
Grant, A. L., & Chan, J. C. (2017a). Reconciling output gaps: Unobserved components model and Hodrick
Prescott filter. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 75, 114-121.
Grant, A. L., & Chan, J. C. (2017b). A Bayesian model comparison for trend‐cycle decompositions of output.
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 49(2-3), 525-552.
Hamilton, J. D. (1989). A new approach to the economic analysis of nonstationary time series and the business
cycle. Econometrica, 357-384.
Hamilton, J. D. (1994). Time series analysis. Princeton University Press.
Harvey, A. C. (1985). Trends and cycles in macroeconomic time series. Journal of Business and Economic
Statistics, 3(3), 216227.
Hodrick, R. J., & Prescott, E. C. (1997). Postwar US business cycles: an empirical investigation. Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking, 1-16.
Jensen, H., Petrella, I., Ravn, S. H., & Santoro, E. (2020). Leverage and deepening business-cycle skewness.
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 12(1), 245-81.
Kalman, R. E. (1960). A new approach to linear filtering and prediction problems. Transactions of the ASME
Journal of Basic Engineering, 35-45.
Kim, C. J. (1994). Dynamic linear models with Markov-switching. Journal of Econometrics, 60(1-2), 1-22.
Kim, J., & Chon, S. (2020). Why are Bayesian trend-cycle decompositions of US real GDP so different?
Empirical Economics, 58(3), 1339-1354.
Kim, C. J., & Kim, J. (2022). Trend-cycle decompositions of real GDP revisited: classical and Bayesian
perspectives on an unsolved puzzle. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 26(2), 394-418.
Kim, C. J., & Nelson, C. R. (1999a). Friedman's plucking model of business fluctuations: tests and estimates
of permanent and transitory components. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 317-334.
Kim, C. J., & Nelson, C. R. (1999b). State-space models with regime switching: classical and Gibbs-sampling
approaches with applications. MIT Press Books.
Luo, S., & Startz, R. (2014). Is it one break or ongoing permanent shocks that explains US real GDP? Journal
of Monetary Economics, 66, 155-163.
Mills, T. C., & Wang, P. (2002). Plucking models of business cycle fluctuations: Evidence from the G-7
countries. Advances in Markov-Switching Models, 113-134.
McKay, A., & Reis, R. (2008). The brevity and violence of contractions and expansions. Journal of Monetary
Economics, 55(4), 738-751.
McQueen, G., & Thorley, S. (1993). Asymmetric business cycle turning points. Journal of Monetary
Economics, 31(3), 341-362.
70
Morley, J. C., Nelson, C. R., & Zivot, E. (2003). Why are the Beveridge-Nelson and unobserved-components
decompositions of GDP so different? Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(2), 235243.
Morley, J., & Piger, J. (2012). The asymmetric business cycle. Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(1),
208-221.
Neftçi, S. N. (1984). Are economic time series asymmetric over the business cycle? Journal of Political
Economy, 92(2), 307328.
Nelson, C. R., & Plosser, C. R. (1982). Trends and random walks in macroeconmic time series: Some evidence
and implications. Journal of Monetary Economics, 10(2), 139-162.
Owyang, M. T., & Sekhposyan, T. (2012). Okun’s law over the business cycle: was the great recession all that
different? Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 94(5), 399-418.
Perron, P., & Wada, T. (2009). Let's take a break: Trends and cycles in US real GDP. Journal of Monetary
Economics, 56(6), 749-765.
Sichel, D. E. (1993). Business cycle asymmetry: a deeper look. Economic Inquiry, 31(2), 224-236.
Sinclair, T. (2010): Asymmetry in the business cycle: Friedman’s plucking model with correlated innovations,
Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, 14 (1), 131.
Wynne, M. A., & Balke, N. S. (1992). Are deep recessions followed by strong recoveries? Economics Letters,
39(2), 183-189.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
We consider how to estimate the trend and cycle of a time series, such as real GDP, given a large information set. Our approach makes use of the Beveridge‐Nelson decomposition based on a vector autoregression, but with two practical considerations. First, we show how to determine which conditioning variables span the relevant information by directly accounting for the Beveridge‐Nelson trend and cycle in terms of contributions from different forecast errors. Second, we employ Bayesian shrinkage to avoid overfitting in finite samples when estimating models that are large enough to include many possible sources of information. An empirical application with up to 138 variables covering various aspects of the U.S. economy reveals that the unemployment rate, inflation, and, to a lesser extent, housing starts, aggregate consumption, stock prices, real money balances, and the federal funds rate contain relevant information beyond that in output growth for estimating the output gap, with estimates largely robust to substituting some of these variables or incorporating additional variables.
Article
Full-text available
The stability of Okun's law coefficient in the United States from 1949 to 2015 is examined using a regression with GARCH errors in order to capture the volatility of the series. Rolling estimations suggest that taking the volatility of the series into account yields more stable results compared to the simple OLS estimation, irrespective of the specification (gap or growth model), the data frequency (monthly or quarterly), or the length of the rolling window. The results also suggest that the persistence of shocks became much more important in explaining contemporaneous volatility when data from the recent global financial crisis were incorporated. In contrast, the feedthrough of output shocks in next period's output volatility was more important in the past, and especially during the 1970s stagflation period, but has been declining since.
Article
We develop a business cycle model that generates asymmetry between peaks and troughs of the unemployment rate and symmetric fluctuations of the participation rate as in the U.S. data. We calibrate the model and find that search frictions are solely responsible for the peak–trough asymmetry. Participation decisions do not generate asymmetry but contribute to the fluctuations in search frictions by changing the size and composition of the pool of job seekers, which in turn affects the tightness ratio and thereby slack in the labor market. The participation rate would be counterfactually asymmetric absent labor supply responses to shocks.
Article
The employment rate in the United States fluctuates asymmetrically over the business cycle: it contracts deeply and sharply during recessions, but it recovers slowly and gradually during expansions. By contrast, aggregate output exhibits nearly symmetric fluctuations about trend. I explain these facts using an equilibrium business cycle model with search frictions in the labor market and worker heterogeneity in productivity, featuring endogenous job destruction and fluctuations in labor composition. The model predicts that the response of the employment rate to shocks greatly varies over the business cycle; notably, it raises in recessions and declines in expansions.
Book
This book was originally published by Macmillan in 1936. It was voted the top Academic Book that Shaped Modern Britain by Academic Book Week (UK) in 2017, and in 2011 was placed on Time Magazine's top 100 non-fiction books written in English since 1923. Reissued with a fresh Introduction by the Nobel-prize winner Paul Krugman and a new Afterword by Keynes’ biographer Robert Skidelsky, this important work is made available to a new generation. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money transformed economics and changed the face of modern macroeconomics. Keynes’ argument is based on the idea that the level of employment is not determined by the price of labour, but by the spending of money. It gave way to an entirely new approach where employment, inflation and the market economy are concerned. Highly provocative at its time of publication, this book and Keynes’ theories continue to remain the subject of much support and praise, criticism and debate. Economists at any stage in their career will enjoy revisiting this treatise and observing the relevance of Keynes’ work in today’s contemporary climate.
Article
Using a dynamic factor model that allows for changes in both the long-run growth rate of output and the volatility of business cycles, we document a significant decline in long-run output growth in the United States. Our evidence supports the view that most of this slowdown occurred prior to the Great Recession. We show how to use the model to decompose changes in long-run growth into its underlying drivers. At low frequencies, a decline in the growth rate of labor productivity appears to be behind the recent slowdown in GDP growth for both the United States and other advanced economies. When applied to real-time data, the proposed model is capable of detecting shifts in long-run growth in a timely and reliable manner. © 2017 The President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Article
Purpose – The purpose of this paper is to examine Okun’s Law in European countries by distinguishing between the transitory and the permanent effects of output changes upon unemployment and by examining the effect of labor market protection policies upon Okun’s coefficients. Design/methodology/approach – Quarterly data for 13 European Union countries, from the second quarter of 1993 until the first quarter of 2014, are used. Panel data techniques and Mundlak decomposition models are estimated. Findings – Okun’s Law is robust to alternative specifications. The effect of output changes to unemployment rates is weaker for countries with increased labor market protection expenditures and it is more persistent for countries with low labor market protection. Originality/value – The paper provides evidence that the permanent effect of output changes upon unemployment rates is quantitatively larger than the transitory impact. In addition, it provides evidence that increased labor market protection mitigates the adverse effects of a decrease in output growth rate upon unemployment.