ArticlePDF Available

Degrowth is coming to town: What can it learn from critical perspectives on urban transport?

Authors:

Abstract

Degrowth offers a particularly trans-disciplinary and robust critique of growth-driven configurations of space, society and economy. However, its proponents are yet to seriously engage with urban environments by clearly outlining how, where, for whom and under what conditions the principles of degrowth could be applied in urban contexts. In this article, I focus on transport as a vehicle for understanding and addressing this challenge, thus contributing to the broader agenda of spatialising and urbanising degrowth. I turn to the specific case of ‘fare-free public transport’ (FFPT), a policy that exists in full form in nearly 300 localities worldwide. By referring to empirical material collected in FFPT programmes in Aubagne (France), Tallinn (Estonia) and Chengdu (China), I show that fare abolition can act as a policy that contradicts many principles of growth-driven capitalism by advancing an agenda of inter- and intra-municipal solidarity, working towards socio-spatial justice. Consequently, I demonstrate that when analysing and planning urban transport, degrowth may well build on diverse ‘critical’ perspectives on transport to engage head-on with explicitly political–economic questions underpinning urban agendas, thus avoiding joining the glossary of de-politicised and technocratic notions, and disregarding the socio-economic, political and spatial complexity of the urban. In this way, the article contributes to ongoing reflections about the role of urbanisation in the degrowth debate.
Degrowth is coming to town: What can it learn from
critical perspectives on urban transport?
Wojciech Kębłowski
Vrije Universiteit Brussel, COSMOPOLIS Centre for Urban Research, Brussels, Belgium
Université Libre de Bruxelles, Institut de Gestion de l'Environnement et d'Aménagement du
Territoire, Belgium
Kębłowski, W., (2023), Degrowth is coming to town. What can it learn from critical
perspectives on urban transport? Urban Studies, online first.
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1177/00420980221149825
CC BY-NC: This license allows reusers to distribute, remix, adapt, and build upon
the material in any medium or format for noncommercial purposes only, and only
so long as attribution is given to the creator.
1
Abstract: Degrowth oers a particularly trans-disciplinary and robust critique of growth-
driven congurations of space, society and economy. However, its proponents are yet to
seriously engage with urban environments by clearly outlining how, where, for whom and
under what conditions the principles of degrowth could be applied in urban contexts. In
this article, I focus on transport as a vehicle for understanding and addressing this
challenge, thus contributing to the broader agenda of spatialising and urbanising degrowth.
I turn to the specic case of ‘fare-free public transport’ (FFPT), a policy that exists in full
form in nearly 300 localities worldwide. By referring to empirical material collected in
FFPT programmes in Aubagne (France), Tallinn (Estonia) and Chengdu (China), I show
that fare abolition can act as a policy that contradicts many principles of growth-driven
capitalism by advancing an agenda of inter- and intra-municipal solidarity, working
towards socio-spatial justice. Consequently, I demonstrate that when analysing and
planning urban transport, degrowth may well build on diverse ‘critical’ perspectives on
transport to engage head-on with explicitly political–economic questions underpinning
urban agendas, thus avoiding joining the glossary of de-politicised and technocratic
notions, and disregarding the socio-economic, political and spatial complexity of the
urban. In this way, the article contributes to ongoing reections about the role of
urbanisation in the degrowth debate.
Keywords: degrowth, fare-free public transport, mobility, transport, urban policy
摘要 : 去增长对以增长为驱动的空间、社会和经济配置提出了跨学科的、有力的批评。然而,去
增长的倡导者尚未认真地参与城市环境治理,他们没有明确提出如何、在何处、为谁以及在什么
条件下将去增长原则应用于城市情境。在这篇论文中,我们重点关注交通,将其作为理解和应对
这一挑战的工具,从而为更广泛的空间化和城市化去增长议程做出贡献。我们将“免费公共交
通”(FFPT) 作为具体案例。全球有近 300 个地区发布了完整的免费公共交通政策。我们收集了欧
巴涅(法国)、塔林(爱沙尼亚)和成都(中国)的 FFPT 计划相关的实证材料,这些材料表明
取消交通费可推进各地区之间和地区内团结议程,是一项与许多以增长为驱动的资本主义原则相
矛盾的政策,有助于实现社会空间正义。因此,我们证明,在分析和规划城市交通时,去增长也
许要基于关于交通的不同批判性观点,直面构成城市议程基础的明确的政治经济问题,从而避免
成为去政治化和技术官僚主义的概念,忽视了城市的社会经济、政治和空间复杂性。通过这种方
式,本文有助于持续反思城市化在去增长争论中所处的角色。
关键词
去增长, 免费公共交通, 流动性, 交通, 城市政策
2
Introduction
The idea of degrowth articulates a radical critique of economic growth as the primary
organising principle of societies and economies (Demaria et al., 2013). It challenges the
ideology of growth and envisions a downscaling of production and consumption as a
means of achieving environmental sustainability, social justice and well-being (D’Alisa et
al., 2015). It therefore proposes a profound ecological, socio-economic and political
transformation that implies a fundamental change of institutions, norms, lifestyles and
values. This call for a broad transition has increasingly reverberated in academic, activist
and policy circles. However, as outlined in the introduction to this special issue (Kaika et
al., forthcoming), while the degrowth movement is gaining momentum, its proponents
have only recently begun to reect on questions related to urban development and urban
planning (e.g. Alexander and Gleeson, 2018; Savini et al., 2022). Meanwhile, only a handful
of urban scholars and planners have engaged with the degrowth debate (e.g. Lehtinen,
2018; von Schönfeld and Willems, 2021; Wächter, 2013; Xue, 2014, 2022; Xue and
Kębłowski, 2022).
To advance this dialogue, I focus on transport and mobility as a specic area of urban life.
Transport is central for criticising growth its infrastructure provides an essential
framework for dividing spaces of urban consumption and production, separating paid
workers from their households and enabling capitalist interests to extract maximum prot
from the workforce. Therefore, I examine what problems and policies the degrowth debate
has identied with regard to urban mobility. I reveal that the degrowth-inspired literature
focusing on transport is expanding, yet in its focus on the detrimental impact of
automobility and its call for stronger links between transport and urban planning,
degrowth largely reects the perspective of the sustainable mobility paradigm’ (SMP)
(Banister, 2008; Hickman et al., 2013) that remains hegemonic in academic and policy-
making circles alike (Kębłowski and Bassens, 2018). Therefore, despite some notable
exceptions (Chertkovskaya and Paulsson, 2022; Krähmer, 2021), while the questions of
social equity, justice and (re)politicisation of social and environmental challenges are
salient to degrowth, its proponents are yet to explore the political economic contradictions
and tensions that underpin the particular eld of urban transport and mobility.
3
To address this challenge, I argue that degrowth may benet from engaging with critical
perspectives on transport. To explain what this entails, I turn to the specic policy of
providing fare-free access to public transport (PT), known as ‘fare-free public
transport’ (FFPT). While it could be argued that FFPT contradicts degrowth on
environmental grounds, encouraging cost-free and unlimited mobility, diverse urban
movements (Dellheim and Prince, 2018; Santini, 2019) have advocated FFPT as a strategy
for contributing to social and spatial justice, addressing climate change and challenging the
pro-growth logic of urban development. Thus, below I employ it as an example of how
institutional transport planning can work towards spatialising degrowth.
FFPT exists in full form in no fewer than 250 nearly 300 localities worldwide. In this article,
I rely on material gathered during multiple eldwork stays in three FFPT sites (Aubagne,
France; Tallinn, Estonia; Chengdu, China) in 2016 and 2017. The eldwork entailed, rst,
conducting over 80 interviews with key local stakeholders: municipal ocials and
politicians, transport authorities and operators, NGO representatives and activists and
workers of local PT companies. Additionally, the interviews were accompanied by a scan of
local media and ocial documents provided by local political bodies. From this large
dataset, I extract specic observations and conclusions to demonstrate how and why to
explore transport critically, and what lessons this exercise might bring for degrowth.
Throughout the article I directly address the main goals of the special issue (Kaika et al.,
forthcoming) focused on the question of “spatialising degrowth”. First, I approach
transport as a vehicle for understanding the limits of the current conceptualisation of
degrowth on the urban scale, and by addressing them I hope to contribute to the broader
agenda of spatialising and urbanising degrowth (Xue and Kębłowski, 2022). Second, I add
to the ongoing documentation and critical assessment of urban practices that show
potential to align with degrowth, demonstrating how institutions and policymakers may
connect urban policies with degrowth agendas. I conclude by exploring how FFPT may
inspire a degrowth-driven urban agenda.
4
Degrowth and transport: The trap of sustainability
Degrowth and the city
While the degrowth scholars and activists represent heterogenous positions and elds, they
jointly identify growth as a hegemonic tenet of contemporary societies a foundation of a
profoundly unjust and unsustainable socio-economic paradigm (Flipo and Schneider,
2015). They propose to engage in a collective and deliberative process aimed at the
equitable downscaling of the overall capacity to produce and consume and of the role of
markets and commercial exchanges as a central organising principle of human
lives’ (Sekulova et al., 2013: 1). This vision involves ‘a radical critique of society’ (Flipo and
Schneider, 2015: xxv), recognising ecological planetary limits, emphasising the
environmental destruction spurred by economic growth and calling for consequent
reduction of consumption and production. It is imagined to guide a socio-political process
of profound reorganisation of the distribution of goods and knowledge, whilst ensuring
well-being, social justice and democracy, towards a society and economy built on sharing,
conviviality, care, frugality and simplicity.
This social, economic and political transformation has far-reaching consequences for
urban communities. Yet, the proponents of degrowth are still to provide a serious reection
on the role of urban development in the transformation they advance. As noted by Xue
(2022), the degrowth literature some times has expressed an anti-urban sentiment,
claiming that ‘cities are considered destined to be environmentally and socially
negative’ (p. 3), and an outcome of a growth-orientated paradigm (Nelson and Schneider,
2018). Degrowth communities are imagined to be located outside of existing urban cores
(Trainer, 2019), in suburban areas (Alexander and Gleeson, 2018) and eco-villages
(Trainer, 2012; Xue, 2014). Several degrowth scholars have explored small-scale practices
developed in the spirit of de-commodication and conviviality of urban space, such as
urban gardening (Anguelovski, 2015), squatting (Cattaneo and Gavaldà, 2010) and eco-
housing (Nelson, 2018). Although these studies have oered inspiring and critical insights
into urban ‘alternatives’ to growth-orientated society, they do not address the issue of the
scalability of particular practices, and their anchorage in local contexts. Some scholars
have reected on how to apply the idea of degrowth to urban development and planning
(Khmara and Kronenberg, 2022; Savini et al., 2022; von Schönfeld and Willems, 2021; Xue
5
and Kębłowski, 2022), focusing on urban compactness (Xue, 2022), critiquing ‘sustainable
urban development (Krähmer, 2021) and developing the notions of ‘polycentric
autonomism’, nity’ and ‘habitability’ (Savini, 2021). Research addressing potential socio-
spatial tensions, contradictions and inequalities generated by the degrowth transition has
focused primarily on housing (Cucca and Friesenecker, 2022; Martínez Alonso, 2022; Mete,
2022), without much consideration for other domains of the production of urban space and
society, including transport and mobility. As a result, even though degrowth scholars
recognise that ‘spatial planning plays a crucial role in imagining, promoting’ (Savini, 2021:
1077), a plethora of issues remains to be explored to articulate the relation between
degrowth and the urban.
Degrowth and transport: From radical foundations …
I attempt to strengthen the link between degrowth and urban studies by focusing on
transport and mobility, which I approach as a vehicle for, rst, understanding the political
economic dynamics in urban settings and, second, addressing the limitations of the current
conceptualisation of urban degrowth. While ‘urban mobility has not been addressed
extensively in the literature on degrowth’ (Chertkovskaya and Paulsson, 2022: 443), an
increasing number of degrowth scholars have nonetheless referred to urban transport
challenges. Although these observations might be scattered, oered as part of research
exploring diverse areas of urban life, they nonetheless provide a clear image of what
mobility problems and solutions are identied by the proponents of degrowth.
Early degrowth writing was remarkably radical in its vision of mobility. Both André Gorz
and Ivan Illich, two thinkers that laid the foundations for early conceptualisations of
degrowth, wrote about the centrality of mobility in challenging the growth paradigm. Gorz
(1980) identied automobility as a prime reason behind the dependence of contemporary
societies on fossil fuels, criticising the spatial imprint of car infrastructure. Illich (1973)
oered a critique of speed as of key social and economic value around which transport is
developed. He advocated a systemic slowing down of mobility not only as a way of limiting
the environmental impact of transport but also, even more importantly, as an element of a
broad challenge to ‘a worldwide class structure of speed capitalists [prioritising the]
exchange-value of time(Illich, 1973: 29), whose privilege hinges on ‘hours of compulsory
6
consumption of high doses of energy, packaged and unequally distributed by the
transportation industry’ (Illich, 1973: 19).
Gorz’s and Illich’s ideas reverberate in some of the contemporary discussions about the
role of transport in the anticipated degrowth transition. Notably, Sekulova and her
colleagues suggest ‘redirecting investment away from infrastructure in fast and car-based
modes of transport to slow-mode ones’ (Sekulova et al., 2013: 5), while Chertkovskaya and
Paulsson (2022: 4) propose an ‘overall presumption of reduced mobility, associated both
with a smaller material throughput’. Schneider (2008: 30) questions alleged rebound
eects related to the improvement of transport infrastructure, arguing that ‘rapid means of
transport create the potential to save time, but very often the time saved in faster
transportation is used to travel greater distances’. Relatedly, Moriarty and Honnery (2013:
20) discuss the limits of technical solutions to decreasing transport-related emissions,
claiming that ‘the time-savings benets are ambiguous, since faster modes of travel do not
necessarily lower total daily travel times’.
… to the trap of ‘sustainable’ mobility
However, when focusing on specic questions regarding urban mobility, the degrowth
literature appears somewhat less attached to the movement’s radical roots. Rather, it
proposes a general vision of urban development that is PT-orientated, compact and dense
(Moriarty and Honnery, 2013; Xue, 2022), identifying private motorised mobility as the key
problem threatening urban ‘liveability’, ‘happiness’ and a ‘good life’ (Sekulova et al., 2013) –
to the detriment of ‘health and wellbeing’ (Nørgård, 2013: 68). Degrowth envisions a
transition towards urban mobility systems characterised by scaled down car infrastucture,
which is to be achieved through a modal shift from private cars to PT and other low-carbon,
‘shared’ and convivial’ transport practices and systems (Cattaneo et al., 2022; Jackson,
2015; Khmara and Kronenberg, 2022; Schor, 2015), reducing overall dependence on
automobility. In this perspective, particular attention is paid to the importance of cycling
and walking (Khmara and Kronenberg, 2022; Samerski, 2018; Sekulova et al., 2013),
following Illich’s (1973) identication of the bicycle as an ultimately convivial and simple
mode of travel which is a vital element and potent symbol of degrowth. In sum, degrowth
imagines a shift towards a bicycle-based, ‘car-free city’ (Schneider, 2008) in which urban
space ‘liberated’ from cars is reclaimed by urban inhabitants.
7
At rst glance, this vision is highly desirable from both a social and an environmental
perspective. It would be unreasonable to argue against planning cities that are less car
orientated. However, I argue that this vision is underpinned by at least two problems. First,
its main tenets bear a striking resemblance to those of the SMP, conceptualised over a
decade ago (Banister, 2008; Hickman et al., 2013). Similarly to degrowth, the SMP
emphasises the need to reduce the environmental impact of mobility, notably through
curbing societal dependence on automobility and aviation, and reducing travel needs by
creating stronger links between land use and mobility policy. This is a striking parallel,
given how strongly the degrowth proponents criticise sustainable development, identifying
it as ‘a fallacious strategy’ (Krähmer, 2021: 6) that ‘depoliticizes genuine political
antagonisms about the kind of future one wants to inhabit [and] renders environmental
problems technical, promising win–win solutions and the (impossible) goal of perpetuating
development without harming the environment’ (Kallis et al., 2015: 9).
Reecting the SMP, degrowth shares its considerable limitations. Crucially, the SMP rarely
engages with the diverse social, spatial and political factors that shape how urban transport
is organised and practised (Kębłowski and Bassens, 2018; Kębłowski et al., 2022). Similarly,
degrowth fails to acknowledge the uneven socio-spatial distribution of anti-car measures
that often focus on ‘saving’ particular urban areas and population groups from
automobility (e.g. urban cores, which in many European cities are inhabited by more
mobile and wealthier residents), while sustaining its presence elsewhere (e.g. in suburban
areas, often populated by less mobile and poorer inhabitants who cannot aord living in
gentried urban cores). The seemingly enticing vision of creating ‘convivial urban
landscapes that are made for people and communities, not cars’ (Alexander and Gleeson,
2018: 80) is drawn without much discussion of the audience and opponents of this
imagined transformation. As little reference is made to how its benets and costs would be
distributed across the intersectional spectrum of class, sex, race and age, the revolutionary
transition envisioned by degrowth is allegedly consensual few social conicts or
contradictions are articulated. Recent degrowth-inspired writing on urban mobility is more
cognisant of these issues. For instance, inspired by the urban experience of Barcelona,
Cattaneo and his colleagues (2022) build on Illich’s work to assess diverse means of urban
transport against their autonomy and collective property, embracing a series of ‘shared’
means of transport as a way of ‘freeing’ urban space from motorised vehicles, and
considering the (in)justices related to the distribution of public space among dierent
8
transport modes – even if they pay very little attention to how shared mobilities have been
embraced by capitalist interests and actors across urban contexts, further exacerbating
socio-spatial inequalities. Chertkovskaya and Paulsson (2022) examine such tensions in
Moscow, where they observe how an urban regime composed of public and private actors
eectively dismantled the local trolleybus network, despite opposition from local social
movements. Krähmer (2021) oers a degrowth critique of Copenhagen’s mode of
‘sustainable’ urban development, which to a large extent hinges on transport policies. His
research demonstrates the contradiction between the popularity of ‘soft’ modes in inner-
city neighbourhoods and the plans for expanding the local airport, embedded in the
agenda of competition-driven urban entrepreneurialism geared towards boosting the city’s
‘global’ status.
Despite these notable exceptions, much remains to be done in terms of connecting
degrowth debates with research into political economic dynamics underpinning urban
mobility. At present, while degrowth oers a particularly trans-disciplinary and robust
critique of growth-driven congurations of contemporary societies, when discussing urban
mobility it draws too strong a parallel with the largely depoliticised paradigm of
‘sustainable’ mobility a limitation for both spatialising degrowth and degrowing’ urban
studies. I argue that the path ahead lies rst and foremost in connecting the degrowth
debate to critical approaches to urban transport (Kębłowski et al., 2022), which constitute
the analytical framework for the remainder of this article. Their ‘critical’ capacity lies in the
attempt to de-centre the transport debate by demonstrating that urban transport policies
and projects are part and parcel of growth-driven capitalism, hinging on capital
accumulation, elite entrepreneurial agendas and urban regimes (Enright, 2016). This
means analysing specic transport agendas, policies and practices not just in terms of their
impact on mobility patterns for instance on how they facilitate a modal shift away from
private cars and promote the use of collective and ‘soft’ modes of transport but rst and
foremost as a vehicle of urban governance, exploring the political institutions and
mechanisms that articulate and apply transport agendas and projects. This approach
contextualises individual mobility behaviour within broader social and political structures,
scrutinising how the organisation of mobility often (re)produces spatial and social
inequality, and the politics of class (Reigner et al., 2013), becoming an inherent element of
spatial revanchism (Soja, 2010).
9
The critical connection between degrowth and urban transport: Exploring the
case of fare-free public transport
Introducing fare-free public transport
To explore these questions while stimulating the degrowth debate, in the remainder of this
article I centre upon the policy of FFPT. Unsurprisingly, FFPT is often met with criticism,
usually voiced by transport economists and engineers, who deem it largely unsustainable
and uneconomical (Cats et al., 2017; Fearnley, 2013; Storchmann, 2003). Its advocates
belong to dierent academic elds, social movements and public institutions, located in
very diverse locales (Dellheim and Prince, 2018; Enright, 2019). They claim that oering
fare-free access to PT acts towards social and spatial justice, helps to mitigate the climate
crisis and challenges the pro-growth logic of urban development. Some of these actors
argue that FFPT questions the hegemonic role of technological eciency and nancial
protability achieved through economic growth, and at the same emphasises the public
role of PT by making it unconditionally open to all (Santini, 2019).
Below, I follow the perspective of comparative urbanism’ (McFarlane, 2010; Robinson,
2011), which emphasises the importance of contributing to urban theory by drawing from
diverse localities, especially those outside the global North. Accordingly, rather than
provide an in-depth analysis of a single case, I oer empirical observations across three
urban contexts: Aubagne (France), Tallinn (Estonia) and Chengdu (China). By juxtaposing
and emphasising the particularities of why and how FFPT has been applied, I aim to reach
a more complete understanding of FFPT as a policy, rather than universalising
observations from any of the three case studies.
The three cases dier, rst, in geography and scale. Aubagne is a small town (population of
45,128 in 2014) located in the periphery of Marseille, and a centre of an agglomeration of 12
peri-urban municipalities (further 58,890 inhabitants). Tallinn (443,932 inhabitants in
2020) is the economic and political centre of Estonia and the country’s largest city.
Chengdu (11.2 million inhabitants in 2020), the capital of the Sichuan province and one of
the fastest-growing metropolitan areas in China, is one of the largest cities in the world to
have experimented with partial fare abolition.
10
Second, in each case FFPT operates dierently. In Aubagne, the local PT network has been
unconditionally free of charge for all passengers since 15 May 2009, and no tickets apply. At
the time of this research, the network consisted of 20 regular bus routes, 10 school routes
and a single tram line. In Tallinn, FFPT was introduced on 1 January 2013 in a much larger
network of 74 bus routes, four tram routes and four trolleybus routes. Crucially, free rides
are available to ocially registered city residents, who have the right to purchase a ‘zero
ticket’ that has to be validated before each trip. Visitors and tourists continue to pay fares,
and therefore the ticketing system has been maintained. Passengers in Chengdu have fare-
free access to only a part of the local PT network. The fare-free regime embraces 116
‘community buses’ (社区巴士, shèqū bāshì) that operate on short routes of 1–3 km long. The
service can be used by validating an electronic ticket used in paid PT modes (other bus
routes and the metro). Otherwise, passengers must pay 0.24 per ride in cash. The
1
ticketing system continues to operate and bus drivers check the tickets upon front-door
boarding.
Exploring fare-free public transport: From transport sustainability …
As I argued above, most degrowth proponents that explore transport in urban settings
essentially mirror the perspective of the SMP, identifying automobility as the major
problem to be addressed by academics and policy-makers, and conceptualise PT rst and
foremost as part of a broader strategy for generating a modal shift away from private cars.
Curiously, it is precisely on these grounds that FFPT has been strongly criticised by the
SMP advocates. Although these arguments have not been explicitly raised by the degrowth
debate, I argue that they are largely in line with much of degrowth writing about transport
and mobility, as outlined in the previous section. First, the proponents of the SMP have
claimed that instead of improving the experience and overall quality of collective
transport, abolishing fares devalues the transport service while endangering local transport
operators and local governments by reducing or even eliminating income from PT tickets
(Fearnley, 2013; van Goeverden et al., 2006). Second, as car drivers are more responsive to
improvements in service frequency, speed and overall comfort rather than to a decrease
In the discussion about Chengdu’s FFPT, all gures have been converted from RMB (Chinese Yuan)
1
according to the rate that applied at the time of research: 1=7.5 RMB.
11
in price – zeroing fares has supposedly little to no impact in terms of attracting car users to
PT. Instead, FFPT is accused of creating ‘useless mobility’ (Duhamel, 2004: 6) by
generating additional inessential and excessive mobility, attracting predominantly PT
passengers, pedestrians and cyclists (Fearnley, 2013; Storchmann, 2003; van Goeverden et
al., 2006).
To address this critique, I turn to the evidence from Aubagne, Tallinn and Chengdu. In
Aubagne, the decision to abolish fares initiated a long-term strategy of redesigning the PT
system. In turn, the local authorities received a strong mandate for renewing the bus eet,
re-designing routes to cover the whole territory of the surrounding agglomeration,
signicantly increasing service frequency to satisfy the increased demand and – last but not
least building the network’s rst tram line. Similarly, Tallinn’s FFPT programme was
preceded and later accompanied by a long-term agenda of improving the quality of PT.
Back in the 1990s, following the collapse of the Soviet Union, the rolling stock was old,
unreliable, poorly heated and ventilated, and energy inecient. In the years preceding fare
abolition, the Tallinn municipality began to renew the PT eet, designate priority bus lanes
and introduce an electronic information system on vehicles and at key stations and stops.
Abolishing fares may therefore be understood as the nal stage in a sequence of steps
aimed at making PT in Tallinn more attractive and aordable’ (Cats et al., 2017: 1092).
Importantly, municipal ocials claim that many of these steps could not have been taken
without fare abolition, since the abolition of fares constituted a crucial event that rmly
positioned collective transport in the public debate. In this sense, as in Aubagne, FFPT can
be interpreted as a policy that enabled – rather than impeded – continuous development of
PT. It gave legitimacy to renewing vehicles, increasing their frequency and capacity, adding
new routes and facilitating and promoting new transport modes.
In Chengdu, too, a transition to partial FFPT ran in parallel with an overall increase in PT
quality. As discussed by Jing and Van de Ven (2014), in the years preceding fare abolition,
the bus network had been transformed from a conglomerate of competing bus operators,
both private and public, into a unied system run by one public company. This allowed the
urban authorities to optimise and integrate bus routes and fares, upgrade the bus eet,
increase its punctuality and frequency, and improve the drivers’ working conditions,
thereby reducing the number of road accidents. Furthermore, electronic tickets were
introduced to improve data collection and enable passengers to transfer for free (up to two
12
times) on a single fare. Thus, the policy of partial fare abolition in Chengdu both originated
from and contributed to the municipality’s long-term commitment to developing PT.
Second, evidence from FFPT programmes conrms a fundamental observation that fare
abolition is ‘virtually certain to result in signicant ridership increases no matter where it is
implemented’ (Volinski, 2012: 2). In Aubagne, prior to fare abolition, the local PT network
‘was hardly used’ (semi-structured interview with a representative of the local PT operator
(TransDev), March 2016). Introducing FFPT triggered a stunning increase in ridership.
From 1.9 million passengers transported in 2008, passenger volumes increased to 4.48
million in 2011 (+135.8%) and stayed at this level throughout 2012 and 2013. The
construction of the city’s rst tram line led to a further increase from 4.8 million trips in
2014 to 5.5 million in 2015. Consequently, the ridership nearly tripled (+189.5%) between
2008 and 2015 and remained stable in the following years (6.27 million passengers in 2018
and 6.57 million in 2019) (Façonéo, n.d.), which suggests that the impact of FFPT is long-
lasting. In Tallinn, ocials at the municipal transport department also attribute to FFPT a
strong increase in passenger volumes (+6.5%, from 133.923 million in 2012 to 142.675
million in 2013), while Cats and his colleagues (2017) refer to a 14% increase in the number
of trips on PT in the same time period. Here, too, the passenger volumes remained stable
until the COVID-19 pandemic, reaching 142.4 million in 2019 (Aktsiaselts Tallinna
Linnatransport, 2020). An even higher growth of passengers was observed on trains that
enter the city’s administrative limits. After they were incorporated into Tallinn’s FFPT
system in October 2013, the number of travellers who began and ended their journey
within the city borders, eectively using local trains as their means of urban transport,
increased by 944.9% from 160,000 in 2012 (averaging 438 trips per day) to 1,671,834 in
2014 (averaging 4580 trips per day). As a result, FFPT boosted the popularity of an
underused travel mode.
Third, the evidence partly responds to the critique that new passengers do not shift to PT
from private cars. In Aubagne, before the abolition of fares, the modal split was dominated
by private vehicles (71% of trips) and walking (22%), with only a minor share of PT (5%)
and cycling (2%) (ATT – CAREX, 2006). It is dicult to determine how the introduction of
FFPT aected this situation, as the local authorities only conducted occasional surveys that
never reached more than 1000 respondents. Even though this data is limited, it shows that
among passengers who began to use PT only after the introduction of the fare-free system,
13
50% previously used private cars or motorcycles, 20% walked and 10% cycled (CAPAE,
2012), which partly refutes the accusations that FFPT primarily attracts cyclists and
pedestrians (Fearnley, 2013; Storchmann, 2003; van Goeverden et al., 2006). Among car
drivers who did not use collective transport prior to fare abolition, 20% became its
passengers precisely due to FFPT. Nonetheless, as 61% of them continued to use cars,
automobility ‘remains a privileged mode of transport’ (Mark&Ter’ and Transdev, 2013: 11),
and only a small shift from cars to PT has been observed. In Tallinn, one year before fare
abolition the share of PT usage amounted to 55%, followed by cars (31%), walking (12%)
and cycling (1%). One year after the fares were abolished, the modal share of PT increased
by 8%. Free access to PT attracted some car users (+3% increase of modal share), yet the
modal shift from walking was somewhat larger (+5%).
In Chengdu, ocials claim that the provision of free community buses ‘has achieved only
limited results’ with regard to attracting car users (semi-structured interview with a
member of the board of Chengdu’s public bus operator (Chengdu Bus Group), November
2016). PT is considered one of the key instruments that can help facilitate urban growth,
yet partial abolition of fares was never expected to curb automobility. Characteristically for
large-scale urban areas across China, car ownership is rising sharply. According to ocial
estimates between 2015 and 2018, the number of motor vehicles registered in Chengdu
increased by nearly half, from 3.29 million to 4.88 million (Sichuan Provincial Bureau of
Statistics, 2016, 2019), with almost 1500 new vehicles registered in the city every day,
although the actual gure is likely to be much higher.
Overall, this data shows that even though the overall eect of fare abolition in terms of
attracting car drivers to PT is small, its impact on the increase in PT usage is unequivocal.
Moreover, FFPT contributes to existing eorts towards increasing the quality of PT service,
instead of impeding its quality. Put simply, the supposed contradiction between quality of
service and its fare-free character has not materialised in any of the three cases analysed.
… to urban tensions and contradictions
Even though the evidence explored above may suggest that FFPT has a somewhat limited
capacity to alter urban transport systems, as alone it cannot curb the detrimental
environmental and social impact of automobility in a short time scale, I argue that this
14
reection should be placed in the context of broader political economic dynamics observed
in specic urban settings. Below, I refer to FFPT to demonstrate that critical analysis of a
transport policy – which can hopefully inspire the degrowth debate – entails examining not
only its impact on mobility patterns but also its spatial and social embeddedness in
mechanisms and agendas of urban governance.
This means, rst, exploring the spatial dimension of transport governance – an aspect that
is not explicitly articulated by most voices in the degrowth debate. Aubagne’s FFPT
programme was clearly framed as a strategy for inter-municipal solidarity and spatial
inclusion. Until 2014, the town formed part of the Communauté d’agglomération du pays
d’Aubagne et de l’ Étoile (Agglomeration community of Pays d’Aubagne et de l’Etoile,
CAPAE) composed of 12 municipalities that are largely unequal in terms of their size and
political inuence, as nearly half of CAPAE’s population resides in Aubagne. Instead of
reecting this inequality, CAPAE’s transport policy directly addressed it. Already in the
years preceding fare abolition, the local PT network was redesigned to provide an on-
demand PT service to the most remote areas of the agglomeration, while several of its
municipalities became connected with Aubagne by express bus services (Claux, 2014: 230–
237). One of the key objectives of fare abolition was to strengthen this approach by oering
spatially inclusive PT services. Importantly, the policy embraced both urban cores and
suburban settlements: ‘it was not only about Aubagne, it was about the whole territory of
CAPAE (semi-structured interview with a mayor of one of the CAPAE municipalities,
March 2016). As expressed by one of the authors of the local FFPT programme, it ‘acts as a
glue that keeps our society and our territory together’, facilitating links between its
municipalities, building links across the territory and preventing ‘the emergence of
enclaves (semi-structured interview with a mayor of one of the CAPAE municipalities,
March 2016). The FFPT-led integration thereby acquired an inherently social dimension
as opposed to the situation in Marseille, where many of the youth are isolated in their
neighbourhoods, and cannot aord high PT fares, ‘here, a lot of young people discovered
dierent villages within the agglomeration’ (semi-structured interview with an ex-member
of the CAPAE council, March 2016).
Seen through the same spatial lens, the FFPT programme in Tallinn reveals a strikingly
dierent image: inter-territorial competition is more apparent than solidarity. Fare-free
tickets are oered by Tallinn authorities only to formally registered residents. This
15
limitation is fundamental to the political economy of FFPT, as the national authorities
transfer to the municipality part of each resident’s annual income tax, amounting to
approximately 1600 per resident (data for 2017, Tallinn City Government, 2017). As
changing one’s ocial address in Estonia is a simple online procedure that is not followed
by strict administrative or police verication, within three years following the abolition of
fares Tallinn gained as many as 25,000 registered inhabitants, which translates to an
additional annual income of 40 million. As a result, as explained by a local ocial,
‘[thanks to FFPT,] Tallinn has earned […] a substantial addition of funds to invest in [PT].
Otherwise [it would] denitely not be at the same level’ (semi-structured interview with an
ocial at Tallinn City Oce, May 2016). To respond to this policy, suburban municipalities
located in the county surrounding Tallinn, where in the same time period approximately
14,000 residents disappeared from the books (author’s communication with Estonian
Statistical Oce), have begun oering resident-only public services such as kindergartens
and sports facilities, eectively competing with the capital city. However, peri-urban and
rural municipalities located at a greater distance from Tallinn, especially those located on
major PT corridors to Tallinn, could not engage in a similar strategy. Suering from limited
nancial resources, they observed a loss of registered population, enticed by Tallinn’s
FFPT programme.
A further contradiction revealed by a critical analysis of FFPT regards its social dimension.
Despite its competition-driven logic in Tallinn, FFPT forms part of the municipal social
agenda developed in opposition to the neoliberal and pro-austerity strategy of the Estonian
state. Rather than approach PT as a product that should compete with private cars and
conceptualise passengers as individual customers whom PT should entice, a fully
subsidised and universal PT service is oered to all Tallinn residents. As a result, the
zeroing of fares has generated more frequent usage of PT among a number of under-
privileged social groups. As shown by data from the annual municipal survey (analysed by
Cats and his colleagues, 2017), within one year after the introduction of free fares, PT
usage had increased among the unemployed (+32%), pensioners (+17%) and inhabitants on
a parental or home leave (+21%). A similar increase has been observed for inhabitants on
low incomes: +26% among residents living on less than 300/month, and +14% among
those with a 300–400/month income. Abolishing fares has made PT more popular among
the youth (+21% among 15–19-year-olds) and the elderly (+19% among residents between
60 and 74years old). Therefore, FFPT could be argued to introduce a mobility paradigm
16
that is more inclusive of inhabitants across the spectrum of age and income, albeit more
research is needed to understand whether the opening up of PT possibly leads to access to
the city and the diverse spaces and functions it oers.
Chengdu’s FFPT programme – albeit applied only partially, and on a limited scale – reveals
another set of urban dynamics and demonstrates the importance of studying mobility as
part and parcel of urban development. The provision of free access to ‘community buses’
implicitly challenges several principles of urbanisation in China. As observed by
Campanella (2008), ever since the country’s opening up to global capitalism in the 1970s,
its urban development has proceeded at a record-breaking scale and extraordinary pace. As
‘perhaps no other regime has equated national social and political development with
urbanization so explicitly and determinedly as China’s’ (Abramson, 2016: 156), until the
COVID-19 pandemic the urban expansion and sprawl continued nationwide at an
unprecedented scale, strongly relying on the construction of spectacular transport
infrastructure and generating acute intra-urban segregation. For, similarly to other Chinese
metropolises, Chengdu’s fast-paced development hinges on massive migration from rural
to urban areas, controlled by the State by means of the strict segregation and exploitation
of rural migrants. Their disenfranchisement derives from a distinction between rural and
urban citizens dened by the household registration system called hùkǒu (户⼝).
Introduced in 1958, it limits access to urban welfare. As the majority of rural migrants have
very little chance of obtaining an urban hùkǒu, the system is blamed for maintaining an
‘urban–rural apartheid’ (Miller, 2012: 176), identied as ‘a major source of injustice and
inequality, perhaps the most crucial foundation of China’s social and spatial
stratication’ (Wing Chan and Buckingham, 2008: 583). In the particular case of Chengdu,
at the time of research approximately a quarter of the city’s inhabitants did not have the
urban hùkǒu.
The policy of enabling free rides on Chengdu’s community buses stands out as a measure
that does not follow the growth-driven paradigm outlined above. Even though FFPT can be
accessed throughout the city’s extensive urban core, it functions on the scale of particular
neighbourhoods, as community buses are intended to support short-distance trips and are
operated using relatively small vehicles. The fare-free buses have a very mundane
character and lack any spectacular or large-scale elements. FFPT is also a very inexpensive
17
policy that does not entail signicant infrastructural investment. Furthermore, providing
free access to a part of the bus network is not motivated by an ambition to contribute to the
city’s land valorisation strategies. Rather than expand the network of collective transport to
open new opportunities for real estate speculation, the goal of partial FFPT is to ‘improve
connectivity within neighbourhoods […], ll gaps in the overall [PT] system, and make it
more operational and exible at its fringes (semi-structured interview with a member of
the board of Chengdu’s public bus operator (Chengdu Bus Group), November 2016). Most
importantly, free rides are available to all users, including inhabitants who do not hold the
urban hùkǒu. While these people continue to be excluded from municipal healthcare,
education and housing services, their personal status does not aect access to FFPT.
Community buses work against existing social inequalities and injustices, ‘providing
welfare to the public’ (Tallinn City Government, 2017) regardless of its formal status. In
this way, FFPT challenges the fundamental principles of Chengdu’s growth-driven urban
development, acting as a policy developed on a small scale, in a largely unspectacular
manner, without contributing to urban sprawl, and tackling social segregation instead of
exacerbating it.
Critical analysis of transport and mobility: What lessons for degrowth?
In this article, I have argued that despite its radical roots, the contemporary degrowth
debate oers a rather limited view on mobility, echoing the currently dominant framing of
transport as a contributor to sustainable’ development by advocating dense and car-free
urbanities (Khmara and Kronenberg, 2022; Nørgård, 2013; Sekulova et al., 2013). While this
viewpoint emphasises important environmental aspects of mobility, it fails to explore
fundamental political economic questions regarding the embeddedness of transport in
urban governance even if important exceptions to this rule have begun to emerge
(Cattaneo et al., 2022; Chertkovskaya and Paulsson, 2022; Krähmer, 2021).
To expand this outlook, I referred to the recently conceptualised ‘critical’ perspectives on
urban transport, which thus far have only rarely resounded in the degrowth literature. This
approach explicitly engages with political economic dynamics observed in urban settings,
perceiving mobility as a backbone of the capitalist mode of producing urban society and
space. I examined FFPT as a particular case of a transport policy and an example of how
18
I would like to thank an anonymous reviewer for raising this point.
2
19
neither the continued development of transport mega-infrastructure nor economic and
pandemic crises have led local actors to question free fares on community buses. Finally, in
each of these localities, FFPT proved to be strongly resilient to the COVID-19 pandemic,
whether in terms of responding to the drastic reduction of passengers (which in ‘classic’
paid PT systems meant a signicant decrease of revenue) or ensuring physical distance
between PT sta and passengers.
These ndings are relevant for conceptualising a future urban agenda inspired by
degrowth. The vision of urban mobility currently advanced by the degrowth movement
builds on the idea of creating ‘car-freecities that are more ‘green’, ‘healthy’ and ‘convivial’
than the currently dominant growth-driven urbanities. It emphasises the need to generate
a shift from private motorised means of transport to more ‘shared’ transport modes such as
PT, cycling and walking. However, I argue that examining transport policies against their
potential to contribute to a fundamental socio-economic transition away from the growth
paradigm requires analysing much more than their impact on travel behaviour. Rather, as
the particular case of FFPT demonstrates, transport policies should be approached as
complex agendas, contextualised in the social and spatial landscapes of specic urban
settings, and analysed through the lens of political economic and governance dynamics.
Put simply, incorporating a critical perspective on transport means analysing mobility
policies that could potentially embrace the degrowth ideology of which FFPT is but one
example as multi-faceted urban strategies. Even more importantly, following this
approach means resisting the temptation to remove the urban from transport, to echo the
popular tune of ‘sustainable’ development or, worse yet, to join the glossary of de-
politicised and technocratic notions such as ‘resilience’ and smartness’, which share a
disregard for socio-economic, political and spatial complexity of the urban.
Critical analysis of transport and mobility: What lessons for degrowth?
I would like to thank my hosts and colleagues in dierent FFPT sites. Without the
assistance and trust of Hélène Reigner (Institut d’Urbanisme et d’Aménagement Régional,
Aix-Marseille Université), Allan Alaküla (Tallinn municipality), Tauri Tuvikene, Tarmo
Pikner (Centre for Landscape and Culture, Tallinn University), She Chen and Ming Zhuang
(Chinese Academy of Social Sciences, Chengdu), studying fare-free public transport
programmes in contexts as diverse as Aubagne, Tallinn and Chengdu would have not been
20
possible. I would also like to thank the participants of the 2017 Summer School on
Degrowth and Environmental Justice in Barcelona and Cerbère. Needless to say, none of
the above bear any responsibility for the arguments developed in the article.
Funding
The author disclosed receipt of the following nancial support for the research, authorship,
and/or publication of this article: Fonds Wetenschappelijk Onderzoek, grant numbers
G079720N and 1262821N.
References
Abramson DB (2016) Periurbanization and the politics of development-as-city-building in China.
Cities 53: 156–162.
Aktsiaselts Talinna Linnatransport (2020) The number of passengers in Tallinn public trans- port
increased by 7.7 percent during the year. Available at: https://www.tlt.ee/en/the-num ber-of-
passengers-in-tallinn-public-transport- increased-by-7-7-percent-during-the-year/ (accessed
7 December 2022).
Alexander S and Gleeson B (2018) Degrowth in the Suburbs: A Radical Urban Imaginary. Sin-
gapore: Springer.
Anguelovski I (2015) Urban gardening. In: D’Alisa G, Demaria F and Kallis G (eds) Degrowth: A
Vocabulary for a New Era. New York, NY: Routledge, pp. 33–36.
ATT – CAREX (2006) SITCA. Plan de de " place- ments urbains. Le projet, 4 July.
Banister D (2008) The sustainable mobility para- digm. Transport Policy 15(2): 73–80.
Campanella TJ (2008) The Concrete Dragon: Chi- na’s Urban Revolution and What It Means for the
World. New York, NY: Princeton Archi- tectural Press.
CAPAE (2012) Agenda 21 – Plan Climat E "nergie Territorial. Aubagne: CAPAE.
Cats O, Susilo YO and Reimal T (2017) The prospects of fare-free public transport: Evi- dence from
Tallinn. Transportation 44(5): 1083–1104.
Cattaneo C and Gavalda` M (2010) The experi- ence of rurban squats in Collserola, Barcelona:
What kind of degrowth? Journal of Cleaner Production 18(6): 581– 589.
Cattaneo C, Kallis G, Demaria F, et al. (2022) A degrowth approach to urban mobility options: Just,
desirable and practical options. Local Environment 27(4): 459–486.
Chertkovskaya E and Paulsson A (2022) The end of the line: Envisioning degrowth and ecoso- cial
justice in the resistance to the trolleybus dismantlement in Moscow. Local Environment
27(4): 440–458.
21
Claux M (2014) La ville mobile gouverne "e: Inter- communalite "s, politiques de de "placements et
trajectoires de de "veloppement dans la Re "gion Urbaine Marseillaise. PhD thesis, Aix-Mar-
seille Universite " , France.
Cucca R and Friesenecker M (2022) Potential and limitations of innovative housing solutions in
planning for degrowth: The case of Vienna. Local Environment 27(4): 502–516.
D’Alisa G, Demaria F and Kallis G (2015) Pre- face. In: D’Alisa G, Demaria F and Kallis G (eds)
Degrowth: A Vocabulary for a New Era. New York, NY: Routledge, pp. xx–xxii.
Dellheim J and Prince J (eds) (2018) Free Public Transit and Why We Don’t Pay to Ride Eleva- tors.
Montreal: Black Rose Books.
Demaria F, Schneider F, Sekulova F, et al. (2013) What is degrowth? From an activist slogan to a
social movement. Environmental Values 22(2): 191–215.
Duhamel Y (2004) Gratuite " des transports publics urbains et repartition modale retour sur rapport
nal. Ivry: Axiales.
Enright T (2016) The Making of Grand Paris: Metropolitan Urbanism in the Twenty-First Century.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Enright T (2019) Transit justice as spatial justice: learning from activists. Mobilities 14(5): 665–680.
Façonéo (n.d.) Façonéo gestionnaire des Lignes de l’agglo. Available at: https://www.faconeo. com/
faconeo-mobilite/le-transport-public/ (ac cessed 7 December 2022).
Fearnley N (2013) Free fares policies: Impact on public transport mode share and other trans- port
policy goals. International Journal of Transportation 1(1): 75–90.
Flipo F and Schneider F (2015) Foreword. In: D’Alisa G, Demaria F and Kallis G (eds) Degrowth: A
Vocabulary for a New Era. New York, NY: Routledge, pp. xxiii–xxvi.
Gorz A (1980) The social ideology of the motor- car. In: Gorz A (ed.) Ecology as Politics. New York,
NY: Black Rose Books, pp. 69–77.
Hickman R, Hall P and Banister D (2013) Plan- ning more for sustainable mobility. Journal of
Transport Geography 33: 210–219.
Illich I (1973) Energy and Equity. New York, NY: Harper & Row.
Jackson T (2015) New economy. In: D’Alisa G, Demaria F and Kallis G (eds) Degrowth: A
Vocabulary for a New Era. New York, NY: Routledge, pp. 178–181.
Jing R and Van de Ven AH (2014) A yin-yang model of organizational change: The case of Chengdu
bus group. Management and Organi- zation Review 10(1): 29–54.
Kaika M, Varvarousis A, Demaria F, et al. (forthcoming) Spatializing degrowth: Five steps towards a
radical urban degrowth agenda in the face of climate emergency. Urban Studies.
Kallis G (2020) The Case for Degrowth. Cam- bridge; Medford, MA: Polity Press.
Kallis G, Demaria F and D’Alisa G (2015) Intro- duction. In: D’Alisa G, Demaria F and Kallis G (eds)
Degrowth: A Vocabulary for a New Era. New York, NY: Routledge, pp. 1–18.
22
Kębłowski W (2022) The making(s) of an alterna- tive urban policy: What happens when free fares
come to town? Antipode. Epub ahead of print 12 August 2022. DOI: 10.1111/ anti.12865.
Kębłowski W and Bassens D (2018) ‘‘All transport problems are essentially mathematical’’: The
uneven resonance of academic transport and mobility knowledge in Brussels. Urban
Geography 39(3): 413–437.
Kębłowski W, Dobruszkes F and Boussauw K (2022) Moving past sustainable transport studies:
Towards a critical perspective on urban trans- port. Transportation Research Part A 159: 74–
83.
Khmara Y and Kronenberg J (2022) Urban degrowth economics: Making cities better places for
living, working, and playing. Local Environment. Epub ahead of print 31 October 2022. DOI:
10.1080/13549839.2022.2136638
KrähmerK(2021)Aregreencitiessustainable?A degrowth critique of sustainable urban devel- opment
in Copenhagen. European Planning Studies 29(7): 1272–1289.
Lehtinen AA (2018) Degrowth in city planning. Fennia – International Journal of Geography 196(1):
43–57.
McFarlane C (2010) The comparative city: Knowledge, learning, urbanism. International Journal of
Urban and Regional Research 34(4): 725–742.
Mark&Ter’ and Transdev (2013) Aubagne. Obser- vatoire Transdev des mobilite "s. Synthe`se.
Printed report, August.
Martinez Alonso L (2022) Barcelona’s housing policy under austerity urbanism: A contribu- tion to
the debate on degrowth and urban planning. Local Environment 27(4): 487–501.
Mete S (2022) Towards degrowth housing devel- opment? Lessons from a scenario-based gam- ing
session in the Oslo region. Local Environment 27(4): 517–536.
Miller T (2012) China’s Urban Billion. London: Zed Books.
Moriarty P and Honnery D (2013) Greening pas- senger transport: AA review. Journal of Clea- ner
Production 54: 14–22.
Nelson A (2018) Small Is Necessary: Shared Liv- ing on a Shared Planet. London: Pluto Press.
Nelson A and Schneider F (eds) (2018) Housing for Degrowth. Abingdon: Routledge.
Nørgård JS (2013) Happy degrowth through more amateur economy. Journal of Cleaner Production
38: 61–70.
Reigner H, Brenac T and Hernandez F (2013) Nouvelles Idéologies Urbaines. Dictionnaire Critique
de La Ville Mobile, Verte et Suˆre. Rennes: Presses Universitaires de Rennes.
Robinson J (2011) Cities in a world of cities: The comparative gesture. International Journal of
Urban and Regional Research 35(1): 1–23.
Samerski S (2018) Tools for degrowth? Ivan Illich’s critique of technology revisited. Journal of
Cleaner Production 197: 1637–1646.
Santini D (2019) Passe Livre – As Possibilidades Da Tarifa Zero Contra a Distopia Da Uberizaxca #o.
Aracaju: Autonomia Litera " ria.
23
Savini F (2021) Towards an urban degrowth: Habitability, nity and polycentric autono- mism.
Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space 53(5): 1076–1095.
Savini F, Ferreira, A, and von Schönfeld K(2022) Post-Growth Planning: Cities Beyond the Market
Economy. New York, NY: Routledge. Schneider F (2008) Macroscopic rebound eects as
argument for economic degrowth. In: Pro- ceedings of the rst international conference on
economic de-growth for ecological sustain- ability and social equity, Paris, France, 18–19 April
2008, pp. 29–36. Paris: Degrowth Conference.
Schor JB (2015) Work sharing. In: D’Alisa G, Demaria F and Kallis G (eds) Degrowth: A Vocabulary
for a New Era. New York, NY: Routledge, pp. 195–197.
Sekulova F, Kallis G, Rodrı "guez-Labajos B, et al. (2013) Degrowth: From theory to practice. Journal
of Cleaner Production 38: 1–6.
Sichuan Provincial Bureau of Statistics (2016) Statistical Yearbook 2016. Available at: http://
tjj.sc.gov.cn/scstjj/c105855/nj.shtml (accessed 7 December 2022).
Sichuan Provincial Bureau of Statistics (2019) Statistical Yearbook 2019. Available at: http://
tjj.sc.gov.cn/scstjj/c105855/nj.shtml (accessed 17 December 2022).
Soja EW (2010) Seeking Spatial Justice. Minnea- polis, MN: University of Minnesota Press.
Storchmann K (2003) Externalities by automo- biles and fare-free transit in Germany: A para- digm
shift? Journal of Public Transportation 6(4): 89–105.
Tallinn City Government (2017) Tallinn in g- ures. Available at: http://www.tallinn.ee/est/ Tallinn-
arvudes (accessed 1 January 2022).
Trainer T (2012) De-growth: Do you realise what it means? Futures 44: 590–599.
Trainer T (2019) Remaking settlements for sus- tainability: The simpler way. Journal of Politi- cal
Ecology 26(1): 202–223.
van Goeverden C, Rietveld P, Koelemeijer J, et al. (2006) Subsidies in public transport. European
Transport 32: 5–25.
Volinski J (2012) Implementation and Outcomes of Fare-Free Transit Systems: A Synthesis of
Transit Practice. Washington, DC: Transport Research Board of the National Academies.
von Schönfeld KC and Willems J (2021) Los van groei: Diepgewortelde duurzaamheid voor de
planologie? Rooilijn, 24 August. Available at: https://www.rooilijn.nl/artikelen/los-van-groei/
(accessed 7 December 2022).
Wächter P(2013) The impacts of spatial planning on degrowth. Sustainability 5(3): 1067–1079. Wing
Chan K and Buckingham W (2008) Is China abolishing the hukou system? The China
Quarterly 195: 582–606.
Wood A, Kębłowski W and Tuvikene T (2020) Decolonial approaches to urban transport
geographies: Introduction to the special issue. Journal of Transport Geography 88: 102811.
Xue J (2014) Is eco-village/urban village the future of a degrowth society? An urban plan- ner’s
perspective. Ecological Economics 105: 130–138.
24
Xue J (2022) Urban planning and degrowth: A miss- ing dialogue. Local Environment 27(4): 404–
422.
Xue J and Kębłowski W (2022) Spatialising degrowth, degrowing urban planning. Local
Environment 27(4): 397–403.
25
... While FFPT is often anticipated to be backed by progressive and environmental concerns, existing research suggests that stakeholders who decide to abolish fares may be guided by very different motives, more anchored in urban development agendas and electoral politics than in transport and mobility plans (e.g. Kębłowski, 2023aKębłowski, , 2023b. However, this does not necessarily suggest that FFPT is a post-political measure, or even that post-politics is an accurate framework for capturing the raison d'être of FFPT. ...
... Put simply, how FFPT has been conceived seems to affect how and for whom it works. For instance, it is sometimes entangled in electoral strategies that are at least partially geared toward co-opting the political opposition (Kębłowski et al., 2019), PT passengers, or workers (Kębłowski, 2023a(Kębłowski, , 2023b. ...
... Albeit the literature on FFPT is growing, it tends to focus on individual cases, whether to explore their context and functioning (Baum, 1973;Scheiner and Starling, 1974;Brand, 2008;Kȩ błowski et al., 2019;Š traub and Jaroš, 2019), or study their impact (Busch-Geertsema et al., 2021;Š traub, 2020;Inturri et al., 2020;Cats et al., 2017;Cools et al., 2016). While some contributions compare several FFPT cases (Studenmund and Connor, 1982;Fearnley, 2013;Hess, 2017;Kębłowski, 2022Kębłowski, , 2023, few studies identify broad dynamics observed across large groups of localities engaging in fare abolition, for instance offering a global overview of motivations behind the policy (Kębłowski, 2020) or an in-depth view into its nationwide development in France (Delevoye et al., 2022) and the United States (Volinski, 2012). ...
Article
This article explores the recent and rapid development of fare-free public transport (FFPT) in local public transport networks across Poland. The question of pricing public transport, in particular the idea of abolishing fares, is gathering increased attention among academics, policy-makers and activists. Albeit the literature on FFPT is growing, it usually examines individual cases instead of offering a comparative analysis across large samples. Therefore, we explore the FFPT landscape of Poland, a country that since 2007 has witnessed a remarkable increase in FFPT cases, with no less than 93 municipalities engaged in fare-free programmes. Our study provides a first inquiry into the temporal and spatial dynamics of FFPT in Poland, identify main characteristics of fare-free localities, and the modus operandi of fare-free schemes. We observe several geographical clusters and distinguish various categories of FFPT municipalities. We further reveal that that fare-free programmes are more likely to emerge in localities with stable or increasing population, relatively high level of public expenditure, and high electoral support for liberal-right and left-wing political parties. Our work concludes with a framework for other large-scale explorations of FFPT, advancing knowledge on this controversial yet increasingly popular policy.
Article
Film representations of transport networks’ closure events are valuable materials in a critical, comparative urban studies. Here, 1953 and 1962 films commemorating the last nights of the London and Glasgow tramways exemplify such use. The present study examines them as part of work towards an understanding of public transport as a type of contested public space, since publics can have them removed. On the one hand, both films manufacture consent for the removal of on-street electric public transport on rails at a time when internal combustion engine vehicles, both private and public, were becoming more and more widespread in the UK. On the other, the film-makers provide affectionate views of urban transport modes which in the late twentieth century were largely considered obsolete, thus paving the way for heritage discourses of transport and even anticipating sustainability-led positions on the city that would only gain traction decades after these networks closed.
Article
Based on the critical debates in urban theory, political ecology and urban political ecology literature, this article interrogates the potentialities and limitations of degrowth/post-growth planning, regarding relational, non-dualistic and multi-scalar spatialization of nature conservation. It firstly reveals that pragmatic, technoscientific and “sustainable/ecological urbanism” and market-based nature conservation it incorporates exacerbate socio-ecological crises and socio-spatial inequalities in and beyond cities under the conditions of planetary urbanisation. Second, it interrogates how new market-based nature conservation turned into 'green-grabbing' and primitive accumulation. Having explored the degrowth or post-growth approach in relation to other radical nature conservation approaches (e.g., convivial conservation and global safety network), it interrogates the ways in which post-growth planning deals with socio-spatial aspects of nature conservation. It takes the “degrowth/ post-growth planning” both as an instrument to spatialize radical nature conservation and as an approach addressing socio-ecological injustices and inequalities intersecting at multiple scales. It concludes that the degrowth/ post-growth planning can overcome its limitations and advance its potentialities, drawing from already existing radical conservation and critical approaches in neighbouring disciplines as well as the discipline itself.
Article
Degrowth is gaining traction as a viable alternative to mainstream approaches to sustainability. However, translating degrowth insights into concrete strategies of collective action remains a challenge. To address this challenge, this paper develops a degrowth perspective for strategic spatial planning as well as a strategic approach for degrowth. I argue that a degrowth transition needs to address three strategic issues: depth, agency, and trajectory. Degrowth strategies aim for satiation, the satisfaction of all essential needs in a particular society. To do so, they rely on diffused societal power, raising from existing practices of reduction. Strategies also follow a nonlinear trajectory that seeks to prefigure satiation, popularize it among the masses, and then pressure existing institutions. Strategic spatial planning offers important insights for dealing with these challenges but needs to embrace satiation as a strategic goal. It can do so by creating complementarities between prefigurative practices that perform satiation. The article defines and illustrates these processes by looking at the making of Amsterdam’s ‘doughnut’ strategy.
Article
Full-text available
We call for coupling degrowth with urban studies and planning agendas as an academically salient and politically urgent endeavour. Our aim is threefold: to explore ways for 'operationalising' degrowth concepts into urban and regional everyday spatial practices; to sketch pathways for taking degrowth conceptually and methodologically beyond localised experiments and inform larger scale planning practices and international agendas; and to critically assess the multiple ways in which such a radical urban degrowth agenda will have to differ in the Global North and in the Global South. We outline five steps for such a programmatic, yet paradigmatic, urban degrowth agenda. These are: (1) grounding current degrowth debates within their historical-geographical context; (2) engaging (planning) institutions in linking degrowth practices to urbanisation policies; (3) examining how urban insurgent degrowth alliances can be scaled up without co-optation; (4) focusing on the role of experts and professionals in bringing degrowth principles into everyday urban practice; and (5) prefiguring how degrowth agendas can confront the diverse and unequal urban social relations and uneven outcomes in the Global North and South.
Article
Full-text available
We call for coupling degrowth with urban studies and planning agendas as an academically salient and politically urgent endeavour. Our aim is threefold: to explore ways for 'operationalising' degrowth concepts into urban and regional everyday spatial practices; to sketch pathways for taking degrowth conceptually and methodologically beyond localised experiments and inform larger scale planning practices and international agendas; and to critically assess the multiple ways in which such a radical urban degrowth agenda will have to differ in the Global North and in the Global South. We outline five steps for such a programmatic, yet paradigmatic, urban degrowth agenda. These are: (1) grounding current degrowth debates within their historical-geographical context; (2) engaging (planning) institutions in linking degrowth practices to urbanisation policies; (3) examining how urban insurgent degrowth alliances can be scaled up without co-optation; (4) focusing on the role of experts and professionals in bringing degrowth principles into everyday urban practice; and (5) prefiguring how degrowth agendas can confront the diverse and unequal urban social relations and uneven outcomes in the Global North and South.
Article
Full-text available
The aim of this paper is to find ways to operationalise degrowth in an urban context by connecting to urban economics. Based on eleven textbooks, we identify five main themes analysed in urban economics: (1) urban growth and city size; (2) urban land rent and land-use patterns; (3) industrial location, agglomeration and clustering; (4) housing and housing policy; and (5) transport. We address these from the normative perspective of degrowth, simultaneously highlighting the existing economic policies and instruments that could be used for degrowth operationalisation. In essence, urban economics focuses on the efficient use of scarce resources to make cities better "places for living, working and playing". We propose taking what is relevant from economics, ensuring the transition to the desired future, instead of radically changing everything from scratch. Our premise is that applying many of the already proposed policies and mechanisms may facilitate the transition towards degrowth and contribute to creating a comprehensive urban degrowth narrative. ARTICLE HISTORY
Article
Full-text available
This article focuses on the potentials and barriers to the realisation of a degrowth scenario in housing development in the Oslo region. The point of departure is a previously designed radical degrowth scenario, which depicts a future housing development that is both environmentally sustainable and socially just. Through a gaming session with housing stakeholders in the Oslo region, I investigated the elements hindering or facilitating the degrowth scenario. This paper analyses the results of the gaming session using morphogenetic theory, theory of political economy of environmental sustainability and critical urban theory. The results of the gaming session reveal important structural hindrances to the scenario within the current housing model, which directly depends on the socio-economic structures of capitalism. The article promotes a debate concerning housing for degrowth and a reflection on the deep socio-economic conditions for degrowth transformation.
Article
Full-text available
While many urban policies and practices claim to offer an “alternative” to the “mainstream” of urban entrepreneurialism, they remain under‐theorised and prone to alignment with entrepreneurial agendas. In this paper I examine fare‐free public transport (FFPT) as a salient example of an alternative urban policy. Looking at Aubagne (France) and Tallinn (Estonia), I explore what happens when an alternative policy “comes to town”. I detect how FFPT enters local urban regimes, and study the (non‐)participation of public transport passengers and workers in the decision‐making process about whether and how to abolish public transport fares. My analysis reveals that albeit alternative policies such as FFPT seem to oppose entrepreneurialism, they may hinge on urban regimes that span across institutions, leave the local configurations of power unchallenged, and strenghten local elites. The adaptability of alternatives to diverse political and intellectual positions explains their resilience. Consequently, their radical character cannot be taken for granted and remains an object of political struggle.
Article
Full-text available
In this introduction to the Special Issue titled Degrowth, Cities and Planning, we explore the urban dimension of a radical socio-ecological transformation inspired by the idea of degrowth, geared towards achieving humanity’s long-term wellbeing and sustainability. Although cities and urban planning should arguably play a central role in such a transition, the urban dimension of degrowth has remained largely unexplored. Bringing together the contributions to the Special Issue, we hope to strengthen degrowth by reflecting how its vision applies in urban contexts, and what insights and values from urban planning it might incorporate. At the same time, we explore the relevance of degrowth for urban planning itself, scrutinising urban development and planning from the degrowth perspective. Put simply, we work towards spatialising degrowth and degrowing urban planning.
Article
Full-text available
This article introduces a virtual special issue that carries the same title. We open our editorial by observing that the contemporary transport debate continues to find strong inspiration in the notion of “sustainable” development, which strongly resonates among academics and practitioners alike. While placing important environmental issues on the agenda, sustainable approaches to urban transport exhibit a number of serious limitations, as, as it has insufficiently engaged with diverse social, political and economic dynamics that shape how transport is planned, regulated, organised, practiced and contested in urban contexts. To respond to this gap, we propose to develop an emerging “critical” perspective on urban transport, which considers it it to be socially constructed and contested, underpinned by structural power dynamics, class relations, gender and patriarchy, ethnicity and race. Building on critical urban theory, we argue that being critical about urban transport involves approaching it as a phenomenon that reproduces complex social and spatial processes, and acts as a crucial component of capitalism. On the one hand, this means analysing transport policy, practice and infrastructure through the lens of capitalist dynamics observed in particular urban contexts. On the other, it entails exploring the complexity of processes, institutions and interests that make up a city through its transport. While critical research on transport and mobility may be on the rise, it still constitutes a rather marginal research area. Therefore, the objective of the virtual special issue is to advance the critical agenda of transport research. The diverse contributions to this virtual special issue offer a number of avenues for thinking critically with and through urban transport as part and parcel of capitalism. Our authors discuss theoretical and methodological frameworks for studying transport, and offer empirical analyses of specific policies and practices, inquiring into their socio-spatial impact, political-economic embeddedness and the power relations and regulatory frameworks by which they are shaped. What emerges from this anthology is that there is no singular or universal way of being critical about urban transport. Unravelling and analysing power and ideology underpinned and reproduced by transport in urban settings is by no means an exercise that hinges on a particular theoretical lens or focuses on a specific social group or factor. As this endavour is far from complete, we outline several directions for further critical research. Notably, we suggest to diversify spaces and scales of analysis by exploring long-distance travel, to diversify research objects by analysing freight and logistics. We also note that future research could consider diversifying social theories and epistemologies through which transport is perceived, to contribute to a decolonial turn in transport studies.
Article
Full-text available
Following Illich’s (1974) notion of convivial tools and the distinction he makes between “self-propelled transit” and “motorized transport” of mobility, we apply the emerging paradigm of degrowth to urban mobility. Based on the degrowth literature and Illich’s work, we derive principles and criteria for the mobility of a degrowth society that include institutional, energy and material use, infrastructure, local environmental impacts, social impacts and justice, proximity and speed, and autonomy. To ground our analysis in real-world conditions, we consider the practical perspective of mobility and add another set of criteria: comfort and safety, travel time, monetary cost, and health. We then compare urban mobility options, including recently developed hybrid mobility and sharing schemes. Our results show that, although private means have an advantage in terms of personal practicality, they are not desirable from a degrowth perspective, due to their high social and environmental costs and as constituting a source of urban injustice. Public, hybrid, and self-propelled mobility options would become more practical if such injustices were recognised, and if effective public policies challenged the radical monopoly of cars. Further, hybrid options and sharing/pooling schemes have the potential to reduce the use of private means for metropolitan mobility. The adoption of this degrowth framework can enrich debates on sustainable urban mobility and moves beyond the common proposition of promoting public transport as the solution.
Book
In 1996, the Los Angeles Bus Riders Union, a grassroots advocacy organization, won a historic legal victory against the city’s Metropolitan Transit Authority. The resulting consent decree forced the MTA for a period of ten years to essentially reorient the mass transit system to better serve the city’s poorest residents. A stunning reversal of conventional governance and planning in urban America, which almost always favors wealthier residents, this decision is also a concrete example of spatial justice in action. This book argues that justice has a geography and that the equitable distribution of resources, services, and access is a basic human right. Building on current concerns in critical geography and the new spatial consciousness, the book interweaves theory and practice, offering new ways of understanding and changing the unjust geographies in which we live. After tracing the evolution of spatial justice and the closely related notion of the right to the city in the influential work of Henri Lefebvre, David Harvey, and others, it demonstrates how these ideas are now being applied through a series of case studies in Los Angeles, the city at the forefront of this movement. The book focuses on such innovative labor-community coalitions as Justice for Janitors, the Los Angeles Alliance for a New Economy, and the Right to the City Alliance; on struggles for rent control and environmental justice; and on the role that faculty and students in the UCLA Department of Urban Planning have played in both developing the theory of spatial justice and putting it into practice.
Book
This book draws on a wide range of conceptual and empirical materials to identify and examine planning and policy approaches that move beyond the imperative of perpetual economic growth. It sketches out a path towards planning theories and practices that can break the cyclical process of urban expansion, crises, and recovery that negatively affect ecosystems and human lives. To reduce the dramatic social and environmental impact of urbanization, this book offers both a critique of growth-led urban development and a prefiguration of ecologically regenerative and socially just ways of organizing cities and regions. It uncovers emerging possibilities for post-growth planning in the fields of collective housing, mobility, urban commoning, ecological land-use, urban–rural symbiosis, and alternative planning worldviews. It provides a toolkit of concepts and real-life examples for urban scholars, urbanists, activists, architects, and designers seeking to make cities prosper within planetary boundaries. This book speaks to both experts and beginners in post-growth thinking. It concludes with a manifesto and glossary of key terms for urban scholars, students, and practitioners.