ArticlePDF Available

Reassessing the Practical and Theoretical Influence of Entrepreneurship Through Acquisition

Authors:
The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance
Volume 16
Issue 1
Spring 2012
Article 2
December 2012
Reassessing the Practical and Theoretical In>uence of Reassessing the Practical and Theoretical In>uence of
Entrepreneurship Through Acquisition Entrepreneurship Through Acquisition
Richard A. Hunt
University of Colorado - Boulder
Bret Fund
University of Colorado - Boulder
Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.pepperdine.edu/jef
Recommended Citation Recommended Citation
Hunt, Richard A. and Fund, Bret (2012) "Reassessing the Practical and Theoretical In>uence of
Entrepreneurship Through Acquisition,"
The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance
: Vol. 16: Iss. 1, pp. 29-56.
DOI: https://doi.org/10.57229/2373-1761.1005
Available at: https://digitalcommons.pepperdine.edu/jef/vol16/iss1/2
This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Graziadio School of Business and Management at
Pepperdine Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance by an
authorized editor of Pepperdine Digital Commons. For more information, please contact
bailey.berry@pepperdine.edu.
The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance Volume 16, Number 1, Spring 2012 29-56
Copyright © 2012 Academy of Entrepreneurial Finance, Inc. All rights reserved.
ISSN: 1551-9570
29
Reassessing the Practical and Theoretical Influence of Entrepreneurship
Through Acquisition
Richard A. Hunt*
Bret Fund
University of Colorado Boulder
Abstract
This paper presents a long overdue reassessment of entrepreneurship through acquisition (ETA). Traditionally
considered simply a niche occurrence of small company leveraged buyouts (LBO), ETA is actually a meaningful
contributor to a nation’s entrepreneurial capacity and business revitalization. Scholarly understanding of ETA has
been severely limited by three factors: the paucity of data related to entrepreneurial acquisitions, the tendency to
equate entrepreneurship primarily with new venture creation, and the reliance upon explanatory models for buyouts
that are grounded in narrowly conceived notions of 1980s-era, large-scale, hyper-leveraged LBOs. Prior efforts to
conceptualize all buyouts based on the large LBO model and through the lens of agency theory have severely
restricted the ability of scholars to look past the buyout model motivated by financial reengineering gains to see
instead the entrepreneurial aims and outcomes often associated with buyouts, particularly ETA. In order to situate
ETA more fruitfully in the domain of entrepreneurship finance, we take issue with the conventional agency theory
framing and offer instead an explanatory model for ETA involving entrepreneurial intent and novel financing. To
overcome the data scarcity problems and to bring the characteristics of ETA into sharper relief, we present testable
propositions side-by-side with data from search funds, a specific ETA investment vehicle that substantively
replicates the entrepreneurial intents and outcomes of ETA. By examining the theoretical streams of LBO and
entrepreneurship finance in practical context of search funds, we build a more coherent conceptualization of ETA.
Key Words: Entrepreneurship through acquisition, entrepreneurial finance, search funds,
buyouts, buyins.
* Contact Information: Richard A. Hunt, Strategic, Organizational & Entrepreneurial Studies,
Leeds School of Business, University of Colorado at Boulder. richard.hunt@colorado.edu
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
30
Neither fish, nor fowl, nor good red herring.”
- German Proverb
Are leveraged acquisitions of small and medium-sized businesses best conceptualized
through the lens of entrepreneurship or the lens of finance? Either? Neither? Both?
Through questions like these, entrepreneurship through acquisition (ETA) poses unique
challenges and opportunities for the domain of entrepreneurial finance because ETA is a
boundary-spanning phenomenon and, in some respects, boundary-breaking. Few topics more
convincingly underscore the importance of gathering scholars and practitioners under the
entrepreneurial finance tent. Boundary-spanning topics typically experience one of two fates:
they either attract considerable attention by virtue of their numerous intersections with various
fields, or they are largely ignored, having been unceremoniously subsumed by explanations for
parallel phenomena. ETA has suffered the latter, more ignoble, fate. We assert in this paper that,
in isolation, the dominant conceptions from entrepreneurship and leveraged buyouts (LBO) have
a limited capacity to illuminate the ETA phenomenon. However, through the compound lens of
entrepreneurial finance, ETA can be better understood in its own right, and as an exemplar of the
entrepreneurship-finance nexus. As the first comprehensive theoretical and practical treatment
of entrepreneurial acquisitions, we will in this paper provide ample reason to propound that ETA
is indeed “fishand “fowl” and most certainly, “good red herring.”
I. Introduction
For more than 30 years, agency theory (Jensen & Meckling 1976; Jensen 1986) has
served as the dominant framework for explicating the antecedents and outcomes associated with
leveraged buyouts (LBO). Through the heyday of large-scale, multi-billion-dollar LBOs in the
1980s and 1990s, agency theory substantively captured the essence of those efforts to break the
tyranny of imprisoned assets (NYT, 1987) sitting dormant in a host of underachieving
companies locked morosely in declining industries (Jensen 1989a, 1989b). As Eisenhardt noted,
there has been broad use and misuse of agency theory (1989) but in all its various forms the
theory is best encapsulated by two principles: the costs for business owners to monitor business
managers and the divergent risk preferences among owners and managers (Eisenhardt, 1989).
Grounded in these key tenets, LBOs blossomed in the 1980s as a “revolutionary” (Jensen, 1989a)
vehicle to place the actions of management more squarely in the service of an owner’s best
interests (Friedman, 1962; Jensen & Ruback, 1983; Jensen, 1986). By Jensen’s own admission,
mega-LBOs were controversial, even while he argued for their indispensability (1989). The
controversy, he wrote, was understandable given the tectonic effect of LBOs on corporate
governance, owner-agent relations, equity ownership by management, and optimal utilization of
a company’s free cash flow, but these dislocations were temporary and necessary (Jensen 1986).
Other commentators were less sanguine. “LBOs are likely to be messy affairs,” Fox and Marcus
warned (1992). Lauded by some (Jensen 1989b; Kaplan, 1991), criticized by others (Lowenstein
1985; Andrews, 1987; Reich, 1989), LBOs were an undeniably fitting laboratory for testing the
basic premises of agency theory.
Time has allowed that LBOs and its explanatory bedfellow, agency theory, were neither
wholly successful nor abject failures (Kaplan & Stromberg 2003; Guo, Hotchkiss & Song, 2011).
In fact, within the specific context of mega-LBOs, an accumulating body of empirical work
supports the premise that agency theory has consistently described the conditions giving rise to
leveraged acquisitions and the resultant outcomes. (e.g. Jensen, 1989b; Kaplan, 1991; Kaplan &
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
31
Stromberg, 2003) However, the relative success in applying agency theory to large LBOs has
had the unintended collateral effect of obfuscating the significant heterogeneity in the various
forms buyouts can assume. From the very beginning, public company LBOs have constituted a
small fraction of the entire buyout market. In 1988, the peak year for LBOs, 410 LBOs were
consummated at terms totaling $188 billion (Olsen, 2003). Yet, these headline-gabbing
transactions constituted less than 1% of the total deal volume, once the full population of buyouts
is considered, including: management buyouts (MBO), management buyins (MBI), divisional
buyouts (DBO), hybrid buyin/management buyouts, miscellaneous investor-led buyouts (IBO)
and largest of all, the deals associated with ETA. We join Wright, Hoskisson, Busenitz, Dial
(2001a, 2001b) and others (e.g. Meuleman, Amess, Wright, & Scholes, 2009) in noting that there
is ample reason to believe that the motivations for these non-LBO buyouts are radically different
from the rationale underlying large-scale LBOs. Nowhere is this theoretical mismatch more
apparent than in the case of entrepreneurship through acquisition.
Though seldom mentioned in the scholarly literature, entrepreneurship through
acquisition is an important facet of any nation’s entrepreneurial ecosystem because it
fundamentally involves the revitalization of existing systems of wealth and contributes to the
well-documented interplay between entrepreneurship and economic growth (Wennekers &
Thurik, 1999; Audretsch, Keilbach & Lehman, 2006). Despite its scale, ETA has experienced the
dubious fate of being doubly eclipsed: first, in the entrepreneurship literature where the scholarly
focus is on new venture creation, and second, in the finance literature where conceptions of
leveraged transactions traditionally involve financial reengineering entailing billions of dollars
and thousands of employees. Challenging to categorize, entrepreneurial buyouts have “largely
been neglected in previous research” (Meuleman, et al., 2009:216). This relative neglect is at
odds with the fact that the ETA segment is actually much larger than venture capital in terms of
aggregate investment, employees affected and communities impacted (SBA Office of Advocacy).
The scholarly scotoma that has relegated ETA to a marginal presence in the literature is
unfortunate, underscoring the need for a comprehensive articulation of the ETA model.
For the purposes of this paper, we define ETA as the acquisition of an existing small or
medium-sized business (i.e. SMEs with annual revenues up to $50 million) by an entrepreneur
for the purpose of expanding and enhancing the business through transformational strategies
that fundamentally reshape market processes. There are three key components of this definition.
First, the activity under examination is the acquisition of a “small or medium-sized business.”
Second, the acquisition is carried out by an entrepreneur (or small team of entrepreneurs) rather
than a large corporation. Third, the purpose of this acquisition is entrepreneurially motivated.
Being entrepreneurially motivated means that the purpose of the acquisition is to grow and
enhance the business, not carve it up or sit on it, as is sometimes the case with LBO firms (e.g.
Baumol, 1993; Covin & Miles, 1999).
As noted above, traditional conceptions of LBOs portray buyouts as a potent solution to
agency problems (Jensen & Meckling, 1976; Jensen 1989c), particularly agency-owner issues
involving the optimal deployment of free cash flow. While ETA is not utterly anathema to this
conception of buyouts, neither can it be said that the classic LBO model provides a strong
foundation for understanding the transformational strategies and entrepreneurial mechanisms that
are central to ETAs. These important similarities and marked differences between LBOs and
ETAs are captured in Table I. The differences are further highlighted in a comparison of the
candidate selection criteria commonly employed by LBO associations versus those employed by
entrepreneurs in identifying high-potential entrepreneurial acquisitions (see Table II).
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
32
Interestingly, both LBOs and ETA start with the goal of identifying underperforming,
undervalued assets in low-growth or even no-growth industries. From this common starting
point, however, the divergence is pronounced.
Given the common starting point of seeking to wrest value from stagnant business assets,
the fundamental divergence between the processes and outcomes of LBOs and ETAs draws forth
several basic questions of interest to entrepreneurial finance: How is this extreme divergence
possible? Why is ETA driven by the pursuit of innovation and growth rather than the value
capture and operational efficiency focus of traditional LBOs? How do entrepreneurs create
value through growth by acquiring businesses that others would target for a “milking strategy”?
(Porter, 1980) And finally, what are the prospective implications of ETA for the study of buyouts
in entrepreneurial finance?
The remainder of this paper addresses these questions while proceeding in four sections.
First, ETA is defined and situated in the context of entrepreneurship theory and practice
addressing how this extreme divergence is possible. Second, the paper addresses the ways in
which ETA challenges the accepted premises of traditional LBOs through the lens of agency
theory. Third, search funds are examined as an exemplar of ETA to demonstrate ex ante
entrepreneurial intent in the acquisition of existing businesses as well as showing how
entrepreneurs create value for the acquired business through growth. Applying the search fund
data as empirical grounding, propositions are developed to establish an agenda for follow-on
empirical studies of ETA. Finally, key contributions, research opportunities and potential
limitations are summarized, including potential refinements, extensions and implications for the
entrepreneurial finance literature.
II. Situating ETA in Theory and Practice
Conservatively estimated, ETA accounts for at least $25 billion of new entrepreneurial
activity each year in the U.S. alone, most of which is directed towards the transformation of
under-performing businesses. Despite the obvious scale of ETA and its direct role in fueling
entrepreneurial revitalization of dormant business assets, little empirical research has followed
largely as a consequence of three unsurprising realities: (a) the paucity of readily available data;
(b) the definitional and theoretical biases towards viewing new venture creation as the primary
entry mode for entrepreneurial activity; and, (c) the long legacy of viewing leveraged
acquisitions primarily as vehicles for financial engineering, rather than business rejuvenation.
1
1
There are no published data for annual ETA transactions in the U.S. However, by combining public and private sources,
estimates can be formulated for total deals and dollars. InfoUSA reports that there were, on average, 700,000 annual business
ownership transfers in the U.S. from 2000 2010. Approximately 10% of these transfers involved actual acquisitions of
companies with $500,000 to $50MM in annual revenue and up to 500 employees. Of these 70,000 acquisitions in the ETA range,
we estimate that 10,000 (14%) involved businesses acquiring other businesses, based on a random sample of ownership among
2,000 firms with revenues between $500,000 and $50MM in the Dun & Bradstreet database. Of the remaining 60,000 firms,
30,000 (50%) are estimated to be acquisitions with entrepreneurial intent, based on interviews with 15 mid-market business
brokers and 3 mid-market investment banks specializing in transactions up to $50 MM. In the opinion of this panel,
approximately half of acquirers undertook acquisitions for non-entrepreneurial reasons, such as lifestyle considerations,
investment diversification or the implementation of a milking strategy. Most of these acquirers did not plan to personally manage
the acquired business full-time. This leaves 30,000 instances of “true” ETA, where there exists an ex ante entrepreneurial
intention of implementing growth-oriented transformational strategies. As an added source of conservatism given the vagaries of
small business management, we estimate that some number of entrepreneurs may be forced to abandon their growth plans after
completing the purchase, suggesting that a conservative range of 20,000 to 30,000 ETAs come to fruition each year. Shifting to
dollars from this transaction volume, we have estimated that ETA-sourced firms constitute between $25 - 40 billion in total
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
33
We acknowledge the lack of appropriate data that is publicly available which would greatly
enhance the study of ETA and therefore make suggestions on how scholars might overcome this
later in the manuscript. The other two realities we address in the following paragraphs and
illustrate the divergence of ETA from the LBO literature in the process.
ETA is a notoriously elusive subject. For many scholars, there is no disputing the
“acquisition-ness” of ETA, but there is tremendous ambivalence regarding the “entrepreneur-
ness” of it. According to our definition above, a key condition that must be satisfied is that the
acquisition is entrepreneurially motivated. In the absence of an entrepreneurially motivated
acquisition, it is difficult to differentiate between an LBO and a one-off transaction in terms of
the overall expectations for the deal. By developing a more thorough understanding of what
entrepreneurial motivation involves, we lay the foundation for differentiating between the
various types of acquisition activity that occurs in the SME realm.
1. Underscoring the “E” in ETA
Wright, Hoskisson, Busenitz and Dial (2001a; 2001b) proposed that entrepreneurial
acquisitions (which they termed “management buy-ins”) constitute “an efficient means of
succession when the founding entrepreneur lacks good management and adaptation skills and
when incumbent management lacks entrepreneurial capabilities” (2001a: 253). In this sense,
ETA often involves the revitalization of under-managed, under-performing businesses. As
Tables I and II emphasized, this constitutes a radical departure from conventional agency theory-
driven conceptions of LBOs. The presence of ex ante entrepreneurial intent signals a growth-
based strategy in ETA, rather than a harvesting strategy built on tight management control and
efficiency improvements (Jensen & Meckling, 1976; Jensen, 1989b).
How is entrepreneurial intent identified? First off, a great deal of time can be saved and
intellectual distress can be quelled by acknowledging from the outset that not all acquisitions of
businesses between $500,000 and $50 million constitute entrepreneurship (See Figure 1). It is
patently incorrect to lump all small business purchases together with entrepreneurship because
most small business acquisitions are intended to do nothing more than perpetuate a proven cash
stream, capture the annuity value of the firm and secure a stable source of employment for the
new owners (Carland, Hoy, Boulton & Carland, 1984). It is widely agreed that simply buying a
small business or operating a small business does not constitute entrepreneurial activity (Carland
et al., 1984; Thurik & Wennekers, 2004). Neither is it specifically the presence of growth that
makes a business entrepreneurial (Davidsson, Delmar and Wiklund, 2008). Although firm
growth is often an excellent indicator of entrepreneurial mindset (Gartner, 1988), the presence or
intention of growth is a necessary but insufficient basis for entrepreneurship (Davidsson, 2004).
With respect to the entrepreneurial motivation condition of ETA, the defining
consideration is that risk capital is placed in support of an acquisition for which transformational
strategies will be implemented that expand and enhance the acquired business-system. In this
vein, Covin and Miles maintained that entrepreneurship involves risk and innovative behavior by
individuals who attempt to champion their ideas by exploiting new opportunities (1999).
Similarly applicable is Baumol’s conception of the entrepreneur as innovator, regardless of
whether or not the transformation occurs through the creation of a new venture (1993). This is
precisely the intent of ETA: acquisition of an existing business-system with a vital spark of
innovation. For instance, George Earl purchased a minimally profitable $2.5 million Colorado
acquisition consideration based on a median transaction size of $1.25MM as well as the R.W. Baird/Dealogic estimate that the
upper small firm ($1MM $5MM) and lower mid-market ($5MM - $50MM) transactions are a $125 billion annual segment.
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
34
Springs-based plastic injection molding company in 2010, sensing that increasing labor costs in
developing countries like China will re-open the door to U.S.-based manufacturers. Financed
with a combination of personal assets, a bank loan and a seller-carried note, Earl has invested in
new equipment to make products that will allow it to expand beyond its base of local customers.
As Earl’s acquisition demonstrates, although there are important differences between
ETA and new venture creation, the common threads are more important and more numerous,
particularly pertaining to opportunity identification and exploitation. According to Shane and
Venkataraman, “Entrepreneurship involves the study of sources of opportunities; the processes
of discovery, evaluation, and exploitation of opportunities; and the set of individuals who
discover, evaluate, and exploit them” (2000, p. 218). In this sense, entrepreneurship via either
ETA or new venture creation represents an approach grounded in many of the same processes
and desired outcomes. Davidsson sets one of the highest bars among current scholars for
defining entrepreneurship by further asserting that entrepreneurial activity must involve a
significant impact to the market processes (2004). As we shall see in examining the case of
search funds, ETA fulfills all these important criteria.
2. The Issue of Size: ETA Means Small, But Not Too Small
Obviously, not all acquisitions involve small companies, and most acquisitions of small
companies do not involve entrepreneurship. So, how is ETA situated in this slurry of
transactions? The answer is to define a sensible range, the boundaries of which capture the great
preponderance of owner-managers who acquire a business for entrepreneurial intentions and who
possess the abilities and resources to engage in transformative strategic activity. Given this, ETA
does not pertain to the smallest acquisitions, which predominate in sheer number of completed
transactions, or the largest acquisitions, which predominate in sheer dollar amounts. The range
propounded here extends from $500,000 to $50 million in annual revenues. It is projected that
there are at least 20,000 to 30,000 ETAs within this range (see Footnote 1 above). To provide
some context for the significance of this pool, one should consider that at the peak of venture
capital investment in 2000, only 2,200 U.S.-based start-ups received initial capital from VC
firms (Gompers & Lerner, 2001). In 2009, 728 firms received first-time funding (NVCA, 2010).
Below this $500,000 to $50MM range, the businesses are very small and the transaction
flow is very high. 78% of all American businesses gross less than $100,000 per year (SBA
Office of Advocacy). This category comprises more than 80% of all the businesses sold each
year, but this category cannot be considered ETA. While it is certainly true that entrepreneurship
can be manifested in a countless array of sizes and innovative pursuits, businesses below
$100,000 in revenue rarely allow the acquirer to generate a living wage, much less allowing him
or her to engage in strategic transformation of the business. Even acquired businesses grossing
less than $500,000 per year rarely possess the financial capacity to simultaneously compensate
the entrepreneur, cover the debt maintenance associated with the business acquisition, and still
allow for substantive investment in a market-transforming strategic reorientation of the business.
Of the acquired businesses with revenues exceeding $50MM, several hundred annually
involve large firms with transactions extending up to billions of dollars. These high-profile
acquisitions are financially and strategically material, but we would not consider them ETA.
Large buyouts can certainly have entrepreneurial motivations, but these transactions involve a
complex array of financial and organizational considerations that make it far more difficult to
identify and isolate entrepreneurial activity subsequent to the acquisition, much less
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
35
entrepreneurial intent prior to the acquisition. Another reason to exclude buyouts larger than
$50MM from ETA is due to the fact that this threshold approaches the upper limit for which
entrepreneurship can generally be pursued by owner-operators. Above this threshold, private
equity (PE) firms begin to have competing interests since profitable firms over $50 million have
the capacity to support a large professional management team at top salaries and still have free
cash flow sufficient enough to make the financial reengineering worth incurring the associated
transaction costs (Metrick & Yasuda, 2010). To be sure, there exists a large population of small
private equity firms that buy businesses under $50 million (Fenn, Liang & Prowse, 1995);
however, most PE firms are interested in keeping the pre-acquisition management in place long-
term. In sharp contrast, ETA involves the acquisition of businesses by owner-investors who
actively manage the acquired business.
III. Challenging the Legacy of Mega-LBOs
With the exception of a small cadre of scholars such as Wright and colleagues (1991,
2001a, 2001b), Malone (1989) and Kelly (Kelly, Pitts & Shin, 1986), ETA has been simply
lumped in with the broad swath of transactions known collectively as leveraged buyouts (LBO).
While this would technically be true ETA usually involves the purchase of a business with
borrowed funds the LBO heritage and its scholarly literature have little of substance to
contribute to a discussion of ETA. This is especially important when seeking to understand why
ETA is driven by the pursuit of innovation and growth rather than the value capture and
operational efficiency focus of traditional LBOs. Efforts to address this mismatch extend as far
back as the 1980s (Kelly, et al. 1986; Malone, 1989), when the term “entrepreneurial leveraged
buyout” (E-LBO) was coined to distance small company LBOs from the dominant scholarly and
popular conceptions of multi-billion-dollar LBOs that were fueled principally by the goals of
financial manipulation (Malone, 1989).
The attempt to differentiate LBOs from E-LBOs is understandable, but Malone’s
conceptual pathway is strained and somewhat incomplete because the most important facet of an
E-LBO is not its leveraged structure, but its entrepreneurial intent. By constructing a limited
sample from existing small firms (n = 56), the Malone study suffers from a sample selection bias
(Cameron & Trivedi 2005) that cannot capture intent. As a one-time, cross-sectional survey, the
study can only retrospectively presume the presence of ex ante entrepreneurial intent. In some
cases, the acquisitions in Malone’s study occurred more than six years prior to the survey.
Because of these factors, Malone’s categorization of the 56 firms as E-LBOs involves a
tautology since the firms were classified as E-LBOs on the basis that they each displayed certain
characteristics that Malone judged to be consistent with his definition of E-LBO (Malone, 1989).
Malone’s findings and his conception of E-LBOs thus fail to differentiate entrepreneurial
buyouts from traditional LBOs on the basis of ex ante entrepreneurial intent. More broadly,
since most LBOs, including small company LBOs, are not undertaken for entrepreneurial
purposes (Wright, et al., 2001a; 2001b), the inability to identify clear, ex ante entrepreneurial
intent leaves Malone’s E-LBOs chained to the convoluted heritage of the classic LBO model.
The differentiating substance of an entrepreneurially motivated LBO is that “the
purchaser expects that he can substantially improve the firm’s prospects” (Malone, 1989) and
therefore acquires the business with the intention of implementing innovative means to expand
and enhance the acquired business. The difference between LBO and ETA is not one of mere
semantics. There are a number of important reasons for the differentiation. The first reason is a
matter of effective set-building: not all LBOs are entrepreneurial. As Wright et al. noted, there
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
36
are different categories of buyouts (2001a), most of which are not entrepreneurial. Second, the
popular and scholarly conception of LBOs is utterly unrepresentative of the intentions and
outcomes associated with entrepreneurially motivated small business acquisitions (Meuleman et
al., 2009; Wright et al., 2001a). Every facet of the famed mega-LBOs runs contrary to ETA: the
sheer size, the hyper-leveraged financing vehicles, and the oft-resultant carnage. Third, the long-
standing bias against including small firm LBOs in discussions of entrepreneurship has
marginalized even those acquisitions that are patently entrepreneurial. The bias is not without
foundation since there was a period in which small business management and entrepreneurship
suffered from a troubling level of conflation, as noted by Carland et al. (1984). However, the bias
makes little sense now that the definitions for entrepreneurship have matured in the ensuing
decades, making differentiation straight-forward (Thurik & Wennekers, 2004). The most famous
example of ETA, underscores this differentiation. In 1995, Jim Ellis and Kevin Taweel
purchased Road Rescue, a dilapidated $6 million roadside assistance company. Fifteen years
later, the company has become Asurion, a $2.5 billion provider of cell phone insurance. Rather
than approaching Road Rescue as an annuity-driven, small business management opportunity,
Ellis and Taweel leveraged the company into an innovative growth engine (NYT, 2009).
The Wright et al. buyout model (2001a; 2001b) advances a perspective that does much to
support these sources of differentiation between traditional LBOs and growth-oriented buyouts.
Unfortunately, the framework suffers from two notable shortcomings. First, is the recurrent
confound of sample selection bias. The Wright et al. study suffers from the same deficiency as
the Malone (1989) study in that their retrospective analysis of management buyouts cannot
demonstrate the presence ex ante entrepreneurial intent. A second deficiency is that the model
only offers limited explanatory power and practical applicability, specifically to the ETA
phenomenon. For example, the focus on larger company management buyouts leads Wright et al.
to model relationships and circumstances that draw distinctions between the entrepreneurial
mindset” and the “managerial mindset(2001b). This distinction has decidedly less application
in the context of ETA, where the acquirers fully intend to be active owner-managers from the
outset, long before even consummating the acquisition. Therefore, the types of agency issues
(Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Jensen, 1986) and managerial intention issues (Carland et. al.,
1984) that might arise in management buy-outs are rarely, if ever, evidenced in the case of ETA.
Indeed, principal-agent and manager-entrepreneur roles are intentionally conflated through ETA
in order to maximize the entrepreneurial effects of the acquisition. For instance, Paul Vardley
and Trevor Buschlein acquired a $5 million hard copy printing company in Los Angeles, that had
loyal customers but declining revenues due to technological changes in the printing industry. It
took four years to convert the business to a fully electronic platform, but by aggressively
reinvesting profits rather than distributing gains, Vardley and Buschlein retained their customer
base and have positioned the business to become a $10 million company by the end of 2011.
Examples like this underscore the importance of clearly distinguishing ETAs from LBOs,
management buy-outs and even management buy-ins and E-LBOs. ETA must be conceptualized
as a separate value-generation vehicle in and of itself, as we shall see in examining an illustration
of ETA: Search Funds.
IV. Search Funds: A Window to Entrepreneurially Motivated Acquisitions
Without the existence of a population of ETA-sourced companies that constitute a
defined pool of entrepreneurially motivated acquisitions, it would be impossible to properly
frame the defining characteristics of ETA. Fortunately, there is just such a population of firms
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
37
that can serve as an effective exemplar of ETA: Search Funds. Started in 1984 by Stanford
Business School Professor Irv Grousbeck, search funds constitute a small, but rapidly growing
niche of ETA whereby entrepreneur-searchers raise capital for the sole intent of identifying and
acquiring undermanaged businesses that grow in value through an infusion of entrepreneurial
strategic intent (Grousbeck, 2010). Analysis of search funds provides a meaningful basis to
confirm empirically that buyouts occur for the purpose of implementing entrepreneurially
motivated strategies, allowing us to develop an understanding of how ETA meaningfully
contributes to small business growth and entrepreneurial capacity.
The relative neglect of search funds is somewhat at odds with the extent to which ETA
generally has attracted interest among business school students (evidenced by the increasing
number of classes and student organizations devoted to the subject) and investors (evidenced by
press references and vehicle-specific funds). Although more a manifestation of systemic search
processes (Fiet & Patel, 2007, 2009) than entrepreneurial alertness (Kirzner, 1997), search funds
elude simplistic categorization, except this: search funds are a pure example of entrepreneurship
through acquisition. And for that, they are of great value. The search fund model involves four
stages (see Figure 2). In stage one, entrepreneur-searchers raise a relatively small pool of capital
(averaging $450,000) from ten to twenty investors to cover the expenses during their search for
an attractive business to buy. If a promising opportunity is identified, then stage two financing is
invoked, involving an additional round of funding to purchase the identified company, which is
subsequently operated by the entrepreneur-searcher (Stage 3), who maintains an ownership stake
in the acquired company. Stage four involves exit from the acquired business.
Aggregate pre-tax IRR for the known universe of search funds is 37% (Grousbeck, 2010
See Table III), exceeding the long-term range experienced by upper-tier angel and VC
investors (Table IV), and with somewhat less variance. Aside from the similar returns, sharp
differences separate search funds from other entrepreneurial investments. Far from competing
for nascent-stage opportunities, search funds actually fill a notable gap between angel investors,
venture capital and private equity because they offer the prospect of initiating entrepreneurial
activity within the parameters of a pre-existing business platform. In this sense, search funds
provide an interesting model of entrepreneurship financing because the survival risk that
typically accompanies early-stage investment is significantly mitigated when an entrepreneur
assumes control of an existing business. This mitigation of survival risk, however, comes with
the price tag of heightened liquidity risk. Since search funds primarily seek to acquire under-
managed business assets in reliable, well-worn, highly fragmented industries (Table V), it is rare
for novel, innovative assets to transfer with the acquisition, thereby impacting the downstream
marketability of the business.
Five specific areas of inquiry will be examined through the lens of the search fund model in
order to provide develop empirically verifiable propositions regarding ETA:
1. Entrepreneurially motivated acquisitions can be empirically demonstrated.
2. ETA constitutes a dynamic, large-scale entrepreneurial pathway.
3. ETA exhibits less survival risk than new venture creation, but with at least
comparable returns and substantially less variance.
4. ETA exhibits key investment trade-offs involving liquidity risk versus capital
structure flexibility.
5. ETA’s system wealth generation equals or exceeds that of VC-backed ventures.
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
38
1. Comparative Data
This review of search funds compares a variety of publicly accessible data sources for
search funds, angel-backed firms and start-up-stage venture capital-backed firms. Except for
data pertaining to IPOs and M&A, all of the data is self-reported by individual firms to third-
party data-aggregation entities. The search fund data analyzed here was gathered largely from
the 129-firm database collected by the Center for Entrepreneurial Studies (CES) at Stanford
University’s Graduate School of Business. The CES database represents the only comprehensive
and systematic collection of data pertaining to search funds. The data includes all the U.S.-based
search funds known to exist as of December 31, 2009. Search funds in Canada and Europe,
which are still few in number, are not included in the CES data. Since much of the search fund
data is gathered through self-report surveys, there are material gaps in some of the data.
Therefore, the CES report was supplemented by 52 telephone interviews: 17 investors, 12
current owners, 8 current searchers, and 15 search fund alumni to confirm major trends and
better understand the underlying data. Also, since the CES data only includes search fund
foundings through 2009, the data for 30 known funds initiated in 2010 was gathered
independently and added to the CES data.
Angel data was gathered from a combination of sources: The Kauffmann Foundation
Annual Angel Report and the SBA Office of Advocacy (Shane, 2008) and Thomson Reuters
(SDC). All the data sources that are used in this study have been used previously in analyses of
angel investment returns and descriptive demographics. Venture capital data is also gathered
from a combination of sources comprised of databases maintained by Thomson Reuters (SDC),
Cambridge Associates, and the National Venture Capital Association (NVCA). All the data
sources that are used in this study have been used previously in analyses of venture capital
investment returns and descriptive demographics.
2. Search Funds as Evidence of Ex Ante Entrepreneurial Intent
By definition, search fund owners possess entrepreneurial intent. Initiating a search fund
definitionally entails ex ante signaling of entrepreneurial intent in a fashion that no other form of
buyout can readily replicate. For this reason, search funds provide empirical confirmation that
LBOs occur for reasons other than financial engineering, thereby demonstrating explicitly that
Wright et al. (1991; 2001a; 2001b) were correct in contending that ex ante conditions often exist
regarding entrepreneurial intentions in buyouts, but did not go far enough in demonstrating how
ETA constitutes its own class of entrepreneurially motivated activity.
Searchers have entrepreneurial ambition equal to that of new venture creators, but the
entrepreneurship is grounded in an existing business-system (Lumpkin & Dess, 1996), utilizing
an approach that is more focused on implementing the benefits of evidence-based management
(EBM), which “seeks to apply the best currently available data and theory to management
decision making” (Pfeffer, 2010: 7). In this sense, ETA is the creation of value through applied
business innovation” (Chaflin, 2010:1). Search fund-sourced companies are traditionally selected
from fragmented industries with few dominant players (Table V). Entrepreneur-owners of these
businesses necessarily seek to implement EBM because it is indispensible to business-system
expansion and enhancement. This receptivity to more effective decision-making processes
underlies the significantly lower survival risk in search fund-sourced businesses (Table IV).
The post-acquisition entrepreneurial commitment of search fund owners is similarly
evidenced. Findings from the Stanford Report (Grousbeck, 2010) reveal that 97% of search
funds successfully consummating an acquisition identified increased revenue as a primary value
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
39
creation lever in the newly acquired business. Differentiating themselves from private equityled
small company buyouts, search fund owner-managers serve in key operating roles in the
acquired companies, and remain with the company for a median period of nine years after
forming the search fund (Grousbeck, 2010). Although owner-managers earn salaries, the primary
motivators are the opportunity to run a business and to share in its equity ownership.
3. Search Funds as Evidence of ETA Sector Vitality
Consistent with its roots, most search funds continue to be initiated by recent graduates of
top MBA programs. There is evidence, however, that search funds are being created by a
widening circle of MBA graduates (Grousbeck, 2010). Previously the primary domain of
Stanford and Harvard graduates, recent fund launches have come from graduates of Wharton,
Chicago, Babson, Duke, and others. This trend has had interesting collateral impact. Classes in
ETA are now offered by several business schools, including: Wharton (MGMT811:
Entrepreneurship Through Acquisition), Stanford (STRAMGT543: Entrepreneurship Through
Acquisition). Ross (ES516 Entrepreneurship via Acquisitions), and Kenan-Flagler (MBA843:
Entrepreneurship Through Acquisitions: Structuring Your Buyout). Several dozen student
organizations devoted to ETA have been initiated, reflecting the growing interest in pursuing
entrepreneurship by applying alternatives to new venture creation. The most surprising and
impactful development of all may be that there is evidence of the model extending outside MBA
networks to include mid-career professionals (Grousbeck, 2009).
As with most business sectors reliant upon leverage, search funds felt the pinch of
tightened credit during the 2008 2010 period. It is all the more impressive then that the number
of new search funds grew dramatically over that time period (Tables VI). Only ten years ago new
search funds appeared at the rate of 2 or 3 per year (Grousbeck, 2010). Significantly, 2010 saw
the commencement of at least thirty new funds. Near-term, the competition for good companies
is unlikely to be a factor. The target pool of U.S. companies with revenues between $5MM to
$15MM and EBITDA greater than $1 million is approximately 300,000, providing searchers
with a plethora of targets, especially as aging baby boomer-owners seek to exit their businesses.
Mirroring this heightened interest among entrepreneurs, and partially fueling it, there is
an increasing number of investment funds devoted to financing search funds. Primarily initiated
by search fund “alumni,” they are set up to fund increasingly large portfolios of search funds
(Grousbeck, 2010). From a handful only five years ago, there are now several dozen funds
devoted partially or exclusively to investment in search funds. Though small when compared to
typical venture capital or private equity funds, search fund-focused investors have raised well
over $150 million for new investments, including $35 million raised by fund manager and
search fund alum, Jim Southern of Pacific Lake Partners (NYT, 2009).
4. Propositions
The special case of search funds provides a window to entrepreneurship through
acquisition that is instrumental to the formulation of several propositions that chart a course for
future empirical inquiry and put to the test the prevailing conceptions of entrepreneurial risk-
return, firm failure rates, and value generation.
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
40
4a. Entrepreneurship with Less Survival Risk than New Venture Creation
As we have seen, search funds involve the purchase of existing businesses, typically in
highly fragmented industries marked by relative stability and slow growth. (Table III) As Jim
Southern, a search fund investor and the founder of PacificLake Partners, noted: For aspiring
entrepreneurs who embrace the search fund model, the likelihood of a quality return is much
greater for a search fund than “the gamble of trying to do a start-up” (NYT, 2009). In sharp
contrast, angel-financed and early-stage venture capital investments are geared towards new
business creation. Survival risk for seed-stage and early-stage firms is legendary (Mason &
Harrison, 2002; Cochrane, 2005; Kaplan & Schoar, 2005; Shane, 2008). And, for the most part,
the portfolio investment approach to early stage investment by angel and venture capital firms
underscores the extent to which the presence of this risk is well understood (Van Osnabrugge
1998). However, while the presence of risk may be well understood in the case of new ventures,
there is evidence that start-up and survival risks are notoriously mispriced (Kaplan & Schoar,
2005). ETA meanwhile, certainly entails some degree of survival risk, but it side-steps start-up
risk entirely while largely mitigating the mispricing of survival risk. This is driven by the fact
that many of the firms acquired by search funds have operated for nearly a generation, well past
the time frame for which company survival hangs in the balance. In this regard, it is therefore
proposed that the ETA will generally display the survival advantages found among search fund-
sourced firms.
Proposition 1: On average, ETA-sourced companies will display less survival
risk than seed/early stage companies when comparing ETA-sourced companies
from inception with angel and VC-backed firms from inception.
Table IV reveals the enormous difference between the survival rates for search fund-
sourced firms (90%) versus angel and VC-backed firms (35% each). Without question, most of
this difference arises simply due to the fact that starting a business as a new venture is inherently
more risky than acquiring and operating a business with a pre-existing cash flow. It could be
reasonably argued that comparing search fund survival rates to angel and VC-backed start-ups is
comparing apples to oranges. But this is only a compelling assertion if the long-term angel and
VC investment returns are meaningfully better than ETA, thereby indicating that angel and VC
investors are compensated for the higher risk of business failure. Table IV shows, however, that
angel and VC funds hold no performance edge over search funds.
4b. Liquidity Risk Versus Capital Structure Flexibility
Although search fund-sourced businesses display less survival risk than angel and VC-
backed firms, it is possible that the mitigation of operational variability comes at the cost of
increased barriers to liquidity opportunities. Since the great preponderance of companies
acquired by search funds are in service-related industries or light manufacturing (Table III), there
is relatively little intellectual capital transferred in the acquisition. Innovations developed by the
new management team will often transform the company-specific prospects, but these
transformations are less likely to involve novel technologies. Alternatively, new ventures are
likely to face a steep climb to achieve ongoing viability, but those that do survive will have built
their valuations through novel processes or technologies, potentially providing them a wider
array of exit alternatives. However, this is only expected to be true for those companies that
have survived to the point of achieving a “steady state” of operations. When measured from firm
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
41
inception, it would be expected that search funds would have no worse, and potentially
somewhat better liquidity event prospects than the average angel and VC-funded firm. This is
true for two reasons: (a) the effects of higher attrition for angel/VC-backed firms; and, (b)
search funds typically will be more heavily debt-financed than angel/VC firms, which will be
primarily equity-financed. Accordingly:
Proposition 2a: On average, ETA-sourced companies will display less
exit/liquidity risk than angel or venture-backed companies when comparing ETA-
sourced companies from inception with Angel and VC-backed firms from
inception.
Measured from inception, the low start-up risk and survival risk will, by extension, create
a liquidity event advantage for search funds over VC-sourced ventures. However, when VC-
sourced ventures are measured from the point of adolescence rather than infancy, it is not
expected that search funds will maintain the liquidity advantage. After allowing for the culling
out effects of early attrition, liquidity events for the pool of surviving VC-backed ventures are
expected to be more frequent than liquidity events for search fund-sourced firms (Table IV). On
this basis, it is asserted that:
Proposition 2b: On average, ETA-sourced companies will display more
exit/liquidity risk than angel or venture-backed companies that have achieved
profitability or have survived at least five years.
Since the principal preoccupation of ETA is the growth of a business-system, the looming
specter of liquidity that plays a substantial role in the venture capital arena has a markedly
different character in ETA. The ability to finance a ETA-sourced business through debt rather
than equity inherently de-emphasizes the focus that is often associated with the drive towards a
liquidity event in those entrepreneurial ventures that are principally structured with equity
financing. Given the relative abundance of debt-issuance alternatives available to ETAs, it
would be expected that owner-manager tenures at ETA-sourced firms would be significantly
longer than tenures at angel and venture-backed firms. Since entrepreneurs acquiring existing
businesses often intend to run the businesses for many years, even decades, it is highly apropos
that the ETA structure afford owners the financial flexibility to consummate a recapitalization
enabling investors to exit while still allowing the entrepreneur to retain ownership control of the
company.
The ETA owner-operator rarely faces investor-driven expectations that a well-defined
exit plan be in place from the outset, as is the VC-sourced milieu of limited partner agreements
and investor pools (Kaplan & Stromberg, 2003). For VC-backed companies, the absence of a
liquidity event is often tantamount to a failure to attain any investment returns on that portfolio
component. Not so, in the case of ETA. The operations-intensive orientation of the ETA
entrepreneur-owner frames the issue of investor liquidity as just one part of a wealth-generation
context rather than a precondition of the wealth-generation context. Since ETA owner-managers
acquire businesses as both long-term investments and the principal source of their occupational
livelihood, it is expected that ETA owners will capitalize on their ability to issue debt when
cashing out equity investors. In this fashion, the entrepreneurs can continue to operate the
company while allowing their investors to exit.
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
42
Proposition 3a: Debt restructurings will be more prevalent in ETA-sourced
companies than in angel or venture-backed companies.
Proposition 3b: On average, owner-managers of ETA-sourced companies will
display longer tenures and will exit less frequently than angel or venture-backed
companies.
Proposition 3c: On average, exit proceeds will constitute a smaller proportion of
financial returns to owner-managers of ETA-sourced companies than for angel or
venture-backed companies.
On the whole, liquidity exits are far more prevalent for angel and venture-backed
companies than for ETA companies, as is evident in the search fund data (see Table IV). Search
funds specifically, and ETA-sourced companies generally, have experienced less frequent and
less lucrative exits than have companies comprising the universe of angel and VC-backed firms.
This phenomenon is partially due to the debt issuance power of ETA discussed above, but also
the more limited market for ETA company assets. The annuity value of ETAs provides owner-
operators access to a wider array of strategic financing options, including the option to cash out
financial investors while retaining ownership of a privately held company. However, the price
tag for this lower risk is manifested in lower exit potential and a concomitantly higher exit-
related liquidity risk.
While IPOs and even strategic sales are clearly less common among ETAs, the relative
de-emphasis of exit strategies and liquidity events for ETA-sourced companies, versus angel and
VC-backed firms, is far from absolute. There are instances of ETAs having highly lucrative
liquidity events (primarily through strategic sales) and there are instances of VC-backed firms
maturing into independent, well-capitalized, closely held corporations. Clearly though, neither
of these scenarios represent the norm. There are numerous reasons for this. First, venture capital
investments are managed as a portfolio of firms. Overall portfolio returns require extraordinarily
high gains on a handful of stars to offset the numerous failures, thereby necessitating lucrative
exits wherever they can be attained (Pfeffer, 2010). Second, ETAs can be financed with a
smaller percentage of equity than start-ups and nascent-stage industries. Without having to cash
out investors’ equity holdings, there exists a wider range of financial options, including debt-
driven recapitalization to allow original investors to see a return on their investment. Third,
ETA-sourced companies are often in low-tech, low-growth industries. IPOs are a more difficult
route for these kinds of businesses, though strategic sales to larger aggregators could be very
attractive. Finally, the relationship that the ETA manager-owners have with their investors and
their businesses is different from angel and venture-backed firms. Unlike nascent-stage firms,
entrepreneurial acquisitions immediately place the entrepreneur in the position of managing
customers and delivering products or services. The daily preoccupation of an owner-manager (of
an ETA-sourced firm) is in servicing the system that has been purchased, expanding and
enhancing it through innovation and dynamism. In this context, the issue of investor liquidity is
less prominent because a lucrative exit is not a precondition to a successful investment.
Of course, the paucity of IPOs among ETA-sourced firms cannot be solely attributed to
long owner-manager tenures and higher debt carrying capacities. While it is certainly true that
many ETA-sourced firms are never intended for resale (Malone 1989), it is also true that
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
43
potentially attractive liquidity event options, such as IPOs, are not realistically viable for the vast
majority of ETA-sourced companies. Therefore:
Proposition 4: ETA-sourced companies will have IPOs at a lower rate than angel
or venture-sourced companies.
4c. A System Wealth Approach to ETA Value Creation
By its very nature, ETA involves acquiring an existing business-system and making it
larger and more vibrant. In this sense, the only way to substantively capture the relevant wealth
creation (and preservation) is to formulate the conception of ETA as a system. Otherwise, the
tendency is to focus primarily on the liquidity exit, which is only one facet of wealth creation,
and one which is heavily ensconced within the new venture portfolio approach to risk
identification and exploitation. As we have seen, ETA often possesses elements that are
analogous to VC/Angel-backed firms: outside investors/stakeholders, growth orientation,
entrepreneurial purpose and intent. But, ETA also possesses elements that are analogous to
family firms: value creation and promulgation of an existing system of wealth, for which the
primacy of liquidity/exit outcomes is rendered to subordinate to the preservation and growth of
the wealth system. These hybrid characteristics are the key to understanding the wider
circumference of ETA value creation.
Notably, even Jensen and Meckling (1994) argue, “there does not have to be a loss of
economic efficiency when ownermanagers pursue the maximization of a utility function that
includes non-economic goals.” Chrisman and Carroll (1984) went even farther by demonstrating
that firm pursuits of noneconomic goals can actually “enhance their economic performance and
produce a systemic, synergistic effect upon wealth creation” (Chrisman et al., 2003: 468).
System value creation captures multiple goals and a purpose that transcends profitability.
Therefore, it is proposed that:
Proposition 5: On average, ETA-sourced companies will display overall system
wealth creation at least comparable to angel and venture-backed investments,
and with less variance.
V. Conclusion
In a sense, this treatment of entrepreneurship through acquisition signals the end of a
Ulyssesian voyage back home. And so it is fitting that the rebranded ETA concept be launched
under the auspices of entrepreneurial finance. Among all the various entrepreneurial finance
vehicles, ETA stands the most resolutely as equal parts entrepreneurship and finance.
We have asserted from the outset that traditional conceptions of large-scale LBOs are ill-
equipped to address the antecedents and outcomes of entrepreneurial acquisitions. Agency
theory, which is well-suited to the description and prescription of mega-LBOs, is of limited use
in the context of the “owner as agent” governance found in ETA. Though traditional LBOs and
ETA share a common starting point in identifying underperforming businesses, they swiftly
embark upon radically different paths, ultimately bearing little material resemblance to one
another. Though ETA literally involves the financial machinations of an LBO, there is little in
the LBO literature that forcefully addresses the antecedents and outcomes of ETA.
Prior efforts to identify and explicate the phenomenon of entrepreneurial buyouts (Kelly
et al. 1986; Malone 1989; Wright et al. 2001) have succeeded in demonstrating the presence of
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
44
entrepreneurial buyouts, but not their importance. Even the terminology they have employed
misses the point. Wright et al.’s management buy-ins and buy-outs (2001a, 2001b) fail to
apprehend the entrepreneurial component, while Malone’s E-LBO (1989) identifies
entrepreneurship, but mistakenly links ETA to the heritage of classic large-scale leveraged
buyouts. Only “entrepreneurship through acquisition” conveys the fact that entrepreneurial
intent results in the engagement of entrepreneurial finance towards the instigation of
entrepreneurial action. In ETA, the acquisition of an existing business system is the vehicle
through which entrepreneurial intent is operationalized. This is the dynamic that differentiates
ETA from all other forms of entrepreneurial finance because the owners are creating new value
from existing value, and new innovations from dormant assets.
In addition to proffering a coherent conceptualization of ETA, this paper has also brought
important closure to long-standing inadequacies in the LBO literature. For the first time, an
empirical case has been presented to definitively conclude that buyouts are not solely confined to
realm of financial engineering and milking strategies. Rather, we find compelling evidence that
in the form of ETA, buyouts are motivated by ex ante entrepreneurial intent.
Limitations. A current limitation related to the study of ETA is finding appropriate data.
While it is certainly true that data collection challenges accompany analyses involving virtually
any facet of entrepreneurial finance, the effort required to access ETA data is particularly
burdensome. Efforts to formalize the reporting of venture capital data has opened frontiers in that
sphere, now spanning 25-years worth of generally reliable data. Even the collection of angel
investment data from highly diffuse sources has improved dramatically in last decade. While
organizational networks comprised of mutually interested parties have helped to formalize the
collection and dissemination of angel and venture data, the process of building a similar data
collection mechanism for ETA from the tens of thousands of business brokers, commercial real
estate brokers, merchant bankers and mid-market investment bankers is comparatively daunting.
Of course, our stipulation that ETA necessarily involves ex ante entrepreneurial intent only
exacerbates the data acquisition challenge.
Recognizing that there is little value in simple identifying the data availability challenges,
we have sought to build our propositions on a relatively small but highly reliable source of ETA
data in the form of search funds, supplemented by extensive interviews with scores of
prospective acquirers and owner-managers from ETA-sourced firms. Although the search fund
data is a starting point not an ending point in the process of researching ETA, it constitutes a
significant advance over retrospective data that failed to capture ex ante entrepreneurial intent.
Generalizability. Given the heavy reliance on the search fund model in this discussion of ETF,
the generalizability of search fund results requires careful consideration. First and foremost, it
was our aim in this article to contribute a coherent description of what ETA is and how it
operates. We are fascinated by ETA’s scale, its importance, its distinctive characteristics and,
ironically, its virtual anonymity. Without equivocation, each of these key facets is readily
generalizable from the search fund data. In fact, search funds are uniquely helpful in
illuminating the distinctive nature of ETA because of the inherent process of signaling ex ante
intent through the birth of each new search fund.
There are, however, reasons to expect that there is a difference between search funds and
the general pool of ETAs. For instance, it is prudent to expect that most ETA-sourced firms will
not look exactly like search funds because most ETAs are likely to involve smaller targets than
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
45
the $5 million to $15 million range favored by search funds. While search funds gravitate
towards companies with sufficient EBITDA to support a larger management team typically $1
million or more most ETA-sourced firms are expected to originate from the pool of 25,000 U.S.
businesses that are sold annually with 20 to 50 full-time employees and with revenues ranging
from $2 million to $5 million.
Smaller ETAs should not be mistaken for less-successful ETAs. While the average ETA
transaction size is expected to be smaller than the average search fund acquisition, the
similarities between search funds and the general pool of ETAs are likely to be more numerous
and more consequential than the differences because all ETAs including all search funds
embody the same central assumptions about firm governance and strategic intent. Unlike
traditional LBOs, ETAs are governed by “owner-agents” and unlike angel and venture-backed
firms, ETAs acquire underperforming assets in out-of-favor industries. These distinctive
characteristics define the operational focus, risk profile and financial potential of all ETAs. By
supplanting the prior owners, the acquiring entrepreneurs have maximum latitude to embark new
growth through market-transforming strategies. For these reasons, the success rate for search
funds should be indifferentiable from the complete population of ETAs even while size may vary
considerably as a function of acquisition mode.
Perhaps most importantly, search funds are a categorical exemplar representing the ex
ante entrepreneurial impetus that distinguishes ETA from traditional LBOs and even the buyout
modes included in the Malone (1989) and Wright et al. (2001a) studies. Search funds
demonstrate the entrepreneurial dynamic in a fashion that ultimately eludes earlier efforts to
study buyouts. This shared dynamic simultaneously differentiates ETA from other buyouts and
binds them as a subject of interest to entrepreneurial finance. LBOs are rooted in the discovery
and exploitation of existing value. Angel and venture-backed firms are rooted in value creation.
Meanwhile, ETA is rooted in existing value and value creation.
Future Opportunities. The agenda for ongoing studies of ETA is broad and deep, and it
directly engages entrepreneurial finance scholars and practitioners. First and foremost, there is a
need to build more and better data sources. In the absence of existing data, researchers will find
it fruitful to conduct detailed case studies to further refine the portrait of ETA. Armed with an
improved understanding of the antecedent conditions of ETA from these detailed studies, it is
likely that the targeted use of retrospective data sets will bear more and better fruit. Specifically,
the private sector data in Securities Data Company (SDC) and the new business longitudinal
panel data comprising the Kauffman Firm Study (KFS) are typical of sources that may become
more applicable to the study of ETA when used in conjunction with qualitative research data.
Access to new and better data will open avenues to a broader analysis of the conditions
impacting variation in ETA’s risk-adjusted returns and its ability to contribute to socio-economic
rejuvenation. The dual effects of value-creation and value-preservation situate ETA as a
phenomenon of interest to numerous fields. Cross-disciplinary research will find in ETA an
intriguing playground for testing notions of innovation, development and emergent finance.
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
46
Figure I
ETA within the U.S. Acquisition Landscape
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
47
Figure II
Four Stages of the Search Fund Process
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
48
TABLE I
LBO and ETA - Key Similarities and Differences
Dimension
Defining Characteristics
LBO
ETA
Over-Arching Purpose
Identification and capitalization
of undervalued assets
Identification and
capitalization of undervalued
assets
Theoretical Heritage
Agency Theory (Jensen &
Meckling 1976; Eisenhardt
1989)
Entrepreneurship Theory
(Knight 1921; Schumpeter
1942; Kirzner 1978, 1999;
Shane & Venkataraman 2000)
Ownership Trajectory
Public firm taken private and
then taken public again
Private firm remains private.
Typical Owner-Investors
Financial sponsor usually
private equity firms or LBO
associations.
One or more individual
entrepreneurs.
Governance
Classical Owner-Agent structure
“Owner as Agent”
Defining Strategy
Short-term financial engineering
Long-term growth/expansion
into new products, services and
markets
Approach to Free Cash
Flow
Cash flow to service debt.
Cash flow deployed to growth
initiatives
Holding Period
Up to several years
Up to several decades or
generations
Exit Strategy
Key element of purchase
decision. Typically taken public
3 to 5 years after the LBO.
Rarely instrumental to
purchase decision.
Ideal Candidate
Underperformance.
Financially undermanaged
Underperformance.
Operationally or strategically
undermanaged
Size
Up to $100 Billion and 10,000s
of employees
Up to $50 Million or 500
employees
Expense Rationalization
Expense reduction for profit
enhancement
Expense reduction for strategic
redeployment
Leverage
Leverage is the key to producing
high returns. Focus on the
“discipline of debt” to influence
management behaviors
Leverage holds no special
importance because of long-
term horizon and “owner as
agent” governance.
Management Approach to
Risk
Short-term focus due to
expectations of return. Potential
danger of incoherent long-term
commitment.
Long-term focus. “Owner as
Agent” governance creates
potential for insufficient short-
term risk-taking.
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
49
Management Continuity
Strong existing management to
implement new owner goals
Existing management
entrepreneurially limited.
Displaced by the acquirers.
Impact on Capital
Structure
Replacing equity with debt.
Cash deployed to dividends.
Replacing equity with debt.
But, cash is used for growth.
TABLE II
LBO and ETA Candidate Selection Criteria
Target-Firm Features
Selection Criteria
LBO
Prior Results
Historical underperformance
Assets / Holdings
Large asset base
Investment Requirements
Low future capital
requirements
Cost Structure
Potential for process
improvements towards cost
reductions.
Market Position
Strong, even leading, market
position.
Company Management
Strong team in place to
implement profit goals.
Value Multiples
Relatively low enterprise
value.
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
50
TABLE III
Search Fund Returns (Through 2009)
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
Distribution of Search Fund IRR
Total Loss of Capital No Acquisition
N/A
N/A
11%
12%
17%
Total Loss of Capital - Acquisition
N/A
N/A
9%
10%
15%
Partial Loss of Capital
N/A
N/A
33%
27%
28%
0% to 25%
N/A
N/A
22%
25%
19%
26% to 50%
N/A
N/A
14%
18%
14%
50% to 75%
N/A
N/A
4%
2%
3%
76% to 100%
N/A
N/A
2%
2%
2%
Greater than 100%
N/A
N/A
4%
5%
2%
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
Aggregate Blended IRR
38%
32%
37%
52%
37%
Source: Center for Entrepreneurial Studies (CES) at Stanford University and phone surveys.
TABLE IV
Comparison of Investment Returns
Search Funds
Angel Investments
VC Start-Up Stage
Investments
Aggregate Blended IRR
37%
27%
24%
Companies Exiting with
Negative Returns
44%
52%
65%
IRR of 50% or more
7%
23%
22%
Median Multiple of
Returns for Exits
1x
Negative Returns
at Median
Negative Returns
at Median
% of Firms Surviving
as Going Concerns
90%
35%
35%
M&A Strategic Exits
2005 - 2010
20
(12% of Search
Fund Universe)
1,427
(3% of Angel-
Backed Universe)
2,132
(8% of Venture-
Backed Universe)
Initial Public Offerings
2005 - 2010
0
177
293
Sources: Search Fund Data from CES and phone surveys. Angel Data from Kauffmann
Foundation Report. Venture data from National Venture Capital Association.
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
51
TABLE V
Favored Industries Recent Trends by Funding Source
Search Funds
Angel Investments
Seed and Startup VC
Misc. Services (60%)
Software/Internet (19%)
Software (24%)
Manufacturing (20%)
Health/Biotech (18%)
Biotech (15%)
Distribution (5%)
Bus. Products & Services (16%)
Med Devices & Equip (10%)
Manufacturing/Service (5%)
Consumer Prods & Srvcs (15%)
Media & Entertainment (9%)
All Other (10%)
Hardware (12%)
Industrial & Energy (8%)
Sources: Search Fund Data from CES. Angel Data from Kauffmann Foundation Report. Venture
data from National Venture Capital Association.
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
52
TABLE VI
Search Fund Pipeline Through 2010
Stage
Number of Search Funds
Funds Launched in 2010
30
Funded Searches In Process (Prior to 2010)
41
Operating Acquired Company
33
Closed Fund without Acquiring Company
19
Exited Acquired Company with a Loss
16
Exited Acquired Company with a Gain
20
TOTAL Search Fund Universe
159
Source: CES. 2010 data gathered through phone interviews.
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
53
REFERENCES
Andrews, K., 1987, The concept of corporate strategy, Homewood, IL: Irwin
Audretsch D., M. Keilbach and E. Lehman, 2006, Entrepreneurship and economic growth, New
York: Oxford University Press.
Baumol, W. 1993, Formal entrepreneurship theory in economics: Existence and bounds”,
Journal of Business Venturing, 8, 197-210.
Busenitz, L.W., D. Mossel, J. Fiet, and J. Barney, 1997, The framing or perceptions of fairness
in relationships between venture capitalists and new venture teams, Entrepreneurship
Theory and Practice, 21(3), 5 21.
Cameron, A. and P. Trivedi, 2005, Microeconometrics - Methods and Application. Cambridge
University Press.
Carland, J., F. Hoy, W. Boulton and J. Carland, 1984, Differentiating entrepreneurs from small
business owners,” Academy of Management Review, 9(2), 354-359.
Chaflin, R.J., 2010, Entrepreneurship Through Acquisition, Management Coursework Notes.
Wharton School of Business.
Cochrane, J., 2005, “The risk and return of venture capital, Journal of Financial Economics, 75,
3 52”.
Covin, J., and M. Miles, 1999, Corporate entrepreneurship and the pursuit of competitive
advantage, Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 23(3), 47 - 63.
Davidsson, P., 2004, Researching Entrepreneurship, New York: Springer.
Davidsson, P, F. Delmar, and J. Wiklund, 2008, Entrepreneurship and Growth.
Northampton, MA: Elgar.
The Economist, May 10, 2010.
Eisenhardt, K. M., 1989, Agency theory: An assessment and review”, Academy of
Management Review, 14, 57-74.
Fenn, G., N. Liang, and S. Prowse, 1995, The Economics of the Private Equity, Market Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve. Number 168.
Fiet, J., and P. Patel, 2008, Entrepreneurial discovery as constrained, systematic search, Small
Business Economics, 30(3), 215229.
Fox, I., and A. Marcus, 1992, “The causes and consequences of leveraged management buyouts”,
Academy of Management Review, 17, 6285.
Friedman, M., 1962, Capitalism and freedom, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
54
Gartner, W. B., 1988, “Who is an entrepreneur? is the wrong question, American Small
Business Journal, Spring, 11 - 31.
Gompers, P., and J. Lerner, 2001, The money of invention: How venture capital creates new
wealth, Cambridge, MA: HBS Press.
Grousbeck, H. I., 2010, Search Funds 2009 : Selected Observations, Stanford Graduate School
of Business Center for Entrepreneurial Studies, E-386.
Guo, S., E. Hotchkiss, and W. Song, 2011, Do buyouts (still) create value?”, The Journal of
Finance, 66, 2, 479-517.
Jensen, M.C., 1986, “Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers”,
American Economic Review, 76, 323-329.
Jensen, M.C., 1989a, “Is leverage an invitation to bankruptcy”, The Wall Street Journal,
February 1, 1989, pp. 29.
Jensen, M. C., 1989b, “Eclipse of the public corporation”, Harvard Business Review 67, 60-70.
Jensen, M. C., 1989c, “Active investors, LBOs and the privatization of bankruptcy”, Journal of
Applied Corporate Finance 2, 35-44.
Jensen, M. C., 1993, “The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control
systems”, Journal of Finance 48, 831-880.
Jensen, M.C. and W.H. Meckling, 1976, Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs,
and ownership structure, Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305360.
Jensen, M.C., & W.H. Meckling, 1994, The nature of man”, Journal of Applied Corporate
Finance, 7(2), 4 - 19.
Jensen, M.C., & R. Ruback, 1983, The market for corporate control: The scientific evidence”,
Journal of Financial Economics, 11, 5 - 50.
Kaplan, S. N., 1991, The staying power of leveraged buy-outs, Journal of Financial Economics,
29, 287- 313.
Kaplan, S., and A. Schoar, 2005, “Private equity performance: Returns, persistence and capital
flows”, Journal of Finance, 60, 1791-1823.
Kaplan, S. and P. Stromberg, 2003, Financial contracting theory meets the real world: An
mpirical analysis of venture capital contracts”, Review of Financial Studies, 70, 281
315.
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
55
Kelly, J., R. Pitts, and B. Shin, 1986, Entrepreneurship by leveraged buyout: Some preliminary
hypotheses, Frontiers of Entrepreneurial Research. Babson College.
Kirzner, I.M., 1997, Entrepreneurial discovery and the competitive market process: An Austrian
approach, Journal of Economic Literature, 35, 6085.
Lowenstein, L., 1985, “Management buyouts”, Columbia Law Review, 85, 730-784.
Lumpkin, G. T. and G. G. Dess, 1996, “Clarifying the entrepreneurial orientation construct and
linking it to performance, Academy of Management Review 21, 135172.
Malone, S., 1989, Characteristics of smaller company leveraged buyouts, Journal of Business
Venturing, 4, 349-359.
Mason, C., and R. Harrison, 2002, Is it worth it? The rates of return from informal venture
capital investments, Journal of Business Venturing, 17, 211-236.
Metrick, A., and A. Yasuda, 2007, The economics of private equity funds, Review of Financial
Studies. 23 (6), 2303-2341.
Meuleman, M., K. Amess, M. Wright, and L. Scholes, 2009, “Agency, strategic entrepreneurship
and the performance of private equity backed buyouts”, Entrepreneurship Theory and
Practice, 33, 21340.
National Venture Capital Association, Quarterly Reports, 1990 - 2010.
New York Times, May 6, 1987.
New York Times, March 11, 2009.
Olsen, J., 2003, “Note on leveraged buyouts”, Foster Center for Private Equity.
http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pecenter/research/pdfs/LBO_Note.pdf
Pfeffer, J., 2010, Evidence-based management for entrepreneurial environments: Faster and
better decisions with less risk,” Stanford GSB Research Paper No. 2051.
Porter, M. E., 1980, Competitive Strategy. Free Press, New York.
Reich, R., 1989, “America pays the price”, New York Times Magazine, January 29, 32-40.
Shane, S., and S. Venkataraman, 2000, “The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research,
The Academy of Management Review, 25 (1), 217-226.
Shane, S., 2008, The importance of angel investing in financing the growth of entrepreneurial
ventures, SBA Office of Advocacy Working Paper.
Richard A. Hunt /The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16 (2012)
56
Thurik, R., and S. Wennekers, 2004, Entrepreneurship, small business and economic growth,”
Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development, 11: 140 - 149.
U.S. Small Business Administration Office of Advocacy, Monthly Notes 2008 - 2010.
Van Osnabrugge, M., 1998, Comparison of business angels and venture capitalists,
Oxford Venture Capital Report, Ltd.
Wennekers, S., and R. Thurik, 1999, Linking entrepreneurship and economic growth, Small
Business Economics, 13:1, 27-56.
Wiltbank, R., and W. Boeker, 2007, “Returns to angel investors in group”, A Report for the
Ewing Marion Kauffmann Foundation.
Wright, M., S. Thompson, B. Chiplin, and K. Robbie, 1991, “Buy-ins and buy-outs: New
strategies in corporate management, London: Graham and Trotman.
Wright, M., R. Hoskisson, and L. Busenitz, 2000, “Entrepreneurial growth through privatization:
The upside of management buy-outs”, Academy of Management Review, 25(3), 591-601.
Wright, M., E. Hoskisson, L. Busenitz and J. Dial, 2001a, Finance and management buyouts:
agency versus entrepreneurship perspectives, Venture Capital. 3(3), 239 261.
Wright, M., E. Hoskisson, and L. Busenitz, 2001b, “Firm rebirth: Buyouts as facilitators of
strategic growth and entrepreneurship, Academy of Management Executive, 1, 111-125.
Zahra, S., 1995, “Corporate entrepreneurship and financial performance: The case of
management leveraged buy-outs”, Journal of Business Venturing, 10(3), 225-247.
Article
Full-text available
In order to obtain a better understanding why some entrepreneurs retain more control over their venture than others, this article analyzes the relationship between the social identity of the entrepreneur and her/his desire for control. In fact, entrepreneurs face an important tradeoff between attracting resources required to build company value and retaining decision-making control. Yet, we currently lack insight into whether and how entrepreneurs’ social motivations shape this trade-off. This study draws on social identity theory and a unique sample of 148 buyout entrepreneurs, as this setting confronts aspiring entrepreneurs directly with the value–control tradeoff. In our logistic regression, we find that entrepreneurs with a strong missionary identity, where venture creation revolves around advancing a cause, hold a higher desire for control. We do not observe a significant relationship between entrepreneurs having a Darwinian (driven by economic self-interest) or communitarian (driven by the concern for the community) identity and the desire to control their venture. When adding the moderating role of the portion of personal wealth the entrepreneur is willing to invest in her/his venture, the relationships between having a Darwinian or missionary social identity and the desire for control become significantly positive when the entrepreneur is looking to invest a larger portion of her/his wealth.
Article
Full-text available
This paper presents a theoretical exploration of the construct of corporate entrepreneur-ship. Of the various dimensions of firm-level entrepreneurial orientation identified in the literature, it is argued that innovation, broadly defined, is the single common theme underlying all forms of corporate entrepreneurship. However, the presence of innovation per se is insufficient to label a firm entrepreneurial. Rather, it is suggested that this label be reserved for firms that use innovation as a mechanism to redefine or rejuvenate themselves, their positions within markets and industries, or the competitive arenas in which they compete. A typology is presented of the forms in which corporate entrepreneurship is often manifested , and the robustness of this typology is assessed using criteria that have been proposed for evaluating classificational schemata. Theoretical linkages are then drawn demonstrating how each of the generic forms of corporate entrepreneurship may be a path to competitive advantage. V-'orporate entrepreneurship has long been recognized as a potentially viable means for promoting and sustaining corporate competitiveness.
Article
Full-text available
Agency theory, the predominant theoretical lens employed to examine leveraged buyouts, focuses on buyouts principally as a governance and control device. This view is especially useful in evaluating mature firms where discipline, incentives and limits to managerial discretion serve to mitigate the destruction or the downside of firm value. In contrast, an entrepreneurial view of buyouts is introduced, which incorporates upside incentives for growth and improvements not associated with pure efficiency gains or more effective monitoring to curtail opportunism. Investors such as venture capitalists in the UK and LBO associations in the US are increasingly investing in buyouts to realize entrepreneurial opportunities. Understanding how entrepreneurs make decisions with greater reliance on cognitive biases and heuristics provides an insightful lens for understanding why different types of buyouts occur. These perspectives provide a view of buyouts as a vehicle for strategic innovation and renewal that fosters upside growth opportunities in a variety of buyout types which heretofore have not been incorporated into buyout theory. Finally, research issues are discussed to facilitate future conceptual development and empirical testing of the upside as well as the downside of buyouts.
Article
This paper investigates how a variety of conditions in place at the time of first-round funding can frame a new venture team's (NVT) perception of the fairness of its relations with its venture capitalists (VC). It assumes that a team's perception of whether its treatment by its VC is procedurally just will affect a team's receptivity to VC advice. An analysis of data from 116 firms funded by venture capitalists indicated that some governance mechanisms and the background of the venture team significantly framed perceptions of fairness in their relationship. A major finding of this research is that the indiscriminant use of contractual covenants can adversely frame a NVT's perception of how fairly it is treated by its VC, which ultimately could inhibit the former's receptivity to advice. Directions for future research are indicated.
Article
The primary purpose of this article is to clarify the nature of the entrepreneurial orientation (EO) construct and to propose a contingency framework for investigating the relationship between EO and firm performance. We first explore and refine the dimensions of EO and discuss the usefulness of viewing a firm's EO as a multidimensional construct. Then, drawing on examples from the EO-related contingencies literature, we suggest alternative models (moderating effects, mediating effects, independent effects, interaction effects) for testing the EO-performance relationship.
Article
In this paper we draw on recent progress in the theory of (1) property rights, (2) agency, and (3) finance to develop a theory of ownership structure for the firm.1 In addition to tying together elements of the theory of each of these three areas, our analysis casts new light on and has implications for a variety of issues in the professional and popular literature, such as the definition of the firm, the “separation of ownership and control,” the “social responsibility” of business, the definition of a “corporate objective function,” the determination of an optimal capital structure, the specification of the content of credit agreements, the theory of organizations, and the supply side of the completeness-of-markets problem.