ChapterPDF Available

The Impact of Corruption on Economic Growth: A Nonlinear Evidence

Authors:
  • Faculty of Economic Sciences and Management of Tunis, University of Tunis El Manar

Abstract

Several crosscountry studies have found that corruption slows growth, but these findings are not universally robust. Therefore, the questions to be addressed are to what extent corruption can be tolerated and at what threshold it has a detrimental effect on an economy. This article investigates the impact of corruption on economic growth by testing the hypothesis that the relationship between these two variables is nonlinear. In this article, a panel data analysis has been used to examine 65 countries over the 1987 to 2021 period. Our findings are that corruption can have a positive effect on growth. The results indicate that beyond an optimal threshold, both high and low corruption levels can decrease economic growth. Under this optimal threshold, a moderate level of corruption, defined by the point of reversal of the curve of the marginal corruption effect on growth, could have advantages for economic growth.
Selection of our books indexed in the Book Citation Index
in Web of Science™ Core Collection (BKCI)
Interested in publishing with us?
Contact book.department@intechopen.com
Numbers displayed above are based on latest data collected.
For more information visit www.intechopen.com
Open access books available
Countries delivered to Contributors from top 500 universities
International authors and editor s
Our authors are among the
most cited scientists
Downloads
We are IntechOpen,the world’s leading publisher ofOpen Access booksBuilt by scientists, for scientists
12.2%
169,000
185M
TOP 1%
154
6,200
Chapter
The Impact of Corruption on
Economic Growth: A Nonlinear
Evidence
Mohamed AliTrabelsi
Abstract
On basis of the lubricating effect hypothesis of corruption (grease-the-wheels
hypothesis), the impact of corruption on growth seems ambiguous. Therefore, the
question that arises is to what extent corruption can be tolerated and at what threshold
it has detrimental effect on an economy. This chapter investigates the impact of cor-
ruption on economic growth by testing the hypothesis that the relationship between
these two variables is nonlinear, and we assess whether the belief that corruption has
detrimental effects on the economy is always true. In this chapter, a panel data analy-
sis has been used to examine 65 countries over the 1987–2021 period. Our findings are
that corruption can have a positive effect on growth. The results indicate that beyond
an optimal threshold, both high and low corruption levels can decrease economic
growth. Under this optimal threshold, a moderate level of corruption, defined by the
point of reversal of the curve of the marginal corruption effect on growth, could have
advantages for economic growth.
Keywords: corruption, economic growth, panel data: PCSE estimator
. Introduction
Empirical literature in the field has consistently reported a negative correlation
between economic growth and corruption. These studies have shown that devel-
oped countries are known by low corruption levels and a relatively high growth
rate [1], and by contrast, most developing countries are known by high poverty and
corruption levels [2, 3].
The novelty of the empirical contribution is that we estimate a nonlinear growth
model that allows for threshold effects. To this end, we will use the method proposed
by Beck and Katz [4], who suggested estimating linear models of time-series cross-
section (TSCS) data by ordinary least squares (OLS). For this, they proposed the
panel-corrected standard errors model (PCSE).
The chapter is structured as follows: Section 1 presents a review of both the
theoretical and empirical literature; Section 2 presents the research methodology and
the main results followed by a discussion of the findings in the final section.
Corruption - New Insights
. Literature review
The theoretical and empirical literature on corruption has generated a rich debate
over the last 40years. This literature can be summarized in two opposing theories.
The first assumes that corruption “lubricates the economic cycle” orgreases the
economic wheel” and produces the most efficient economies [5–10]. In contrast, the
second theory blames corruption and sees it as a factor that slows down economic
activity [11–14].
Mauro [15] detects a weak statistical significance between corruption and
economic growth. However, this significance disappears once investment rate is
introduced in the model. Mo [13] finds that corruption negatively affects economic
growth. However, the additional introduction of variables such as investment to GDP
ratio, political stability, and human capital weakens or eliminates the significance of
this negative impact.
Aidt etal. [16] show that the impact of corruption on economic growth depends
on institutional quality. Moreover, they show that when political institutions are
of low quality, corruption has little impact on growth. On the other hand, Méndez
and Sepúlveda [17] find that high-quality political institutions result in corruption
being harmful to growth. In accord with Méndez and Sepúlveda [17], Heckelman
and Powell [8] find that at the lowest levels of democracy, corruption is harmful to
growth but becomes less harmful and eventually beneficial as the level of democracy
increases.
Méon and Weill [10] emphasize the hypothesis of the lubricating effect of cor-
ruption by studying the interaction between institutional quality, corruption, and
production efficiency, thereby validating the hypothesis that corruption may have a
positive effect on economic activities. In the same context, Kato and Sato [18] provide
evidence supporting the greasing the wheels” hypothesis and argue that corruption
enhances economic growth.
Mushfiq [14] tests corruption-growth relationship in a nonlinear framework. He
shows that corruption increases growth even at a higher level of corruption. In the
same context, Allan and Roland [19] use linear and nonlinear panel methods over the
period 1998–2009 for determining the causal relationship between economic growth
and corruption in 42 developing countries. Moreover, Aghion etal. [20] show that
corruption affects the marginal effect of taxation on growth.
Huang [21] examines the causal relationship between corruption and economic
development in 13 Asia-Pacific countries and finds that South Korea and China are
experiencing economic advancement despite high-corruption levels.
Trabelsi and Trabelsi [22] show that beyond an optimal threshold, both high
and low corruption levels can decrease economic growth. Under this optimal
threshold, a moderate level of corruption, defined by the point of reversal of the
curve of the marginal corruption effect on growth, could have advantages for
economic growth.
All these studies indicate that corruption may have either positive or negative
effects on economic growth, making the issue ambiguous and confirming the non-
linearity of the relationship between corruption and growth. However, one must ask
to what extent can corruption be tolerated and from what threshold would it become
destructive to the economy. The questioning is motivated by the fact that studies do
not test whether there is a growth-enhancing or growth-reducing level of corrup-
tion, and not one study thoroughly identified the corruption level that will allow an
optimal growth.
The Impact of Corruption on Economic Growth: A Nonlinear Evidence
DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.5772/intechopen.108876
. Research methodology
. Description of data
Corruption is not the only factor that affects economic growth [23–25]. Other
control variables are also relevant [26]. According to theory and on the basis of
arguments cited in the literature, we propose economic growth depends mainly on
investment, inflation, and trade openness.
The study is based on a panel data set over the period 1987–2021 for 65 countries
taken from the World Development Indicators (Growth rate, Foreign direct invest-
ment, Inflation & Trade). The ICRG index has been obtained from the Quality of
Government Institute, the Transparency International and International Country
Risk Guide published by Political Risk Services group. It measures the risk involved in
corruption rather than the perceived level of corruption.
The descriptive analysis for the full set of 65 countries appears in Table. It shows
that average economic growth is 3.63% with an average corruption index of 3.35.
Where:
Growth: Annual growth rate of GDP per capita.
Fdi: Percent of Foreign direct investment per GDP.
Inf: Consumer price index inflation (annual %).
Trad: Exports plus imports as share of GDP.
Icrg: International Country Risk Guide index of corruption, scaled 0–6. Higher
values indicate lower corruption.
These results do not specify the dependency relationship between growth and
corruption. To further probe this dependency relationship, an econometric study of
the relationship between growth and corruption is necessary.
. Empirical model
Empirical studies generally opt for the nonlinear approach to study the impact
of corruption on economic growth (Méon and Sekkat [11]; [14, 16, 17]; Allan and
Roland [19]; [27–29]). This is a quadratic function based on the hypothesis that the
impact of corruption on growth is not always negative and that a moderate corruption
level could have advantages for economic growth.
In order to verify this, a cross-sectional framework is used in which growth rate and
the ICRG index are observed only once for each country. The scatter plot (Figure ),
using the fitted Kernel curve, illustrates and confirms the hypothesis that the relation-
ship between corruption and economic growth (fitted values) is nonlinear.
Var i a b l e Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max
growth 2275 3.631514 3.694122 17.14604 21.82889
Fdi 2275 2.792351 4.098536 12.20843 33.56602
Inf 2275 5.787994 7.268143 11.68611 59.46156
Trade 2275 81.67821 51.23418 10.74832 439.6567
Icrg 2275 3.351098 1.462316 0 6
Table 1.
Descriptive statistics.
Corruption - New Insights
The curve is clearly increasing in the middle range of corruption and decreasing
where corruption is least and most.
Therefore, we propose the following quadratic model. Subscripts i (i=1,…,65) and
t (t=1987,…,2021) denote index country and time, respectively.
αβ γ µ δ λ ε
=++ ++ + +
2
it i it it it it it it
Growth Inf Trad Fdi Icrg Icrg (1)
Past studies have used a panel of 5-year averages and the system GMM estimator
because this choice reduces, in general, short run fluctuations and resolves the endo-
geneity due to time invariant effects; but this method will not address endogeneity
due to the possible interactions between higher growth rates and greater resources to
combat corruption or other time-varying effects. Levin and Satarov [30] and Paldam
[31] have presented evidence for the existence of both types of endogeneities.
Recently, the empirical studies characterized by having repeated observations over
time on some countries are resolved by others’ models. In this study, we will follow
the Beck and Katz [4] methodology, who suggested estimating linear models of time-
series cross-section (TSCS) data by ordinary least squares (OLS), and they proposed
the panel-corrected standard errors (PCSE) estimator.
The results for GDP growth using the PCSE estimator are reported in Table.
It can be seen that corruption negatively affects (1.0853466) economic growth
unlike the square coefficient of corruption, which positively affects (0.1982614)
economic growth. The significance of Icrg2 coefficient confirms the nonlinearity
of this model and shows the presence of a threshold above which there will be a
change of sign.
Figure 1.
Growth and corruption: countries distribution.
The Impact of Corruption on Economic Growth: A Nonlinear Evidence
DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.5772/intechopen.108876
. Determining the threshold
We will determine the governance level that allows for achieving maximum
growth. The resulting model is:
= + −+ +
2
Growth 2.153 0.0391 0.011Trad 1.08Icrg 0.198Icrg 0.062FdiInf
(2)
In deriving growth through governance, we get:
=−+ =
1.08 0.396Icrg 0
Grow
Icrg (3)
Relationship (3) shows that an optimum is achieved by Icrg=1.08/0.396=2.73.
This indicates that up to a corruption index of 2.73, the trend of the bell-shaped curve
(Figure ) increases showing that there is a positive relationship between corruption
and economic growth.
This bell-shaped curve (Figure ) is interpreted by the fact that corruption,
through tax evasion, has two types of effects in economics.
First, it offers households a tax that can be consumed or invested, and therefore, it
could improve growth up to a certain threshold. This optimal threshold represents the
reversal point of the curve otherwise the country can be found in an underdevelop-
ment trap like several countries that are immersed in corruption. This corruption, if
significant, will reduce state resources because of productive public spending, which
will lead to a loss in economic growth that sooner or later will lead to an uprising call-
ing for establishing democratic principles and good governance.
These results indicate that low of corruption (Icrg <2) negatively affects
economic growth. This result disappears in the presence of corruption (Icrg >3).
However, for an average corruption of (2Icrg 3), we will be at an optimum level
of growth (Figure ).
This result may surprise those who advocate lack corruption, but it can be
explained by the fact that administrative delays resulting from absence of “bribes”
paid in a corrupt economy may dampen economic growth and reduce economic
development.
Growth Coef. Std. Err. tP > | t | [ Conf. Interval]
Fdi 0.0618651 0.0238888 2.59* 0.008 0.0150430 0.1086871
Inf 0.0392218 0.0128872 3.04* 0.003 0.0644807 0.0139629
Trade 0.0112539 0.0022877 4.92* 0.000 0.0067700 0.0157378
Icrg 1.0853466 0.3167777 3.43* 0.001 1.7062309 0.4644623
Icrg 0.1982614 0.0464706 4.27* 0.000 0.1071790 0.2893438
Cons 2.153168 0.5132159 4.19* 0.000 1.1472648 3.1590712
*test statistic is significant at the  level.
Table 2.
Panels corrected standard errors (PCSE).
Corruption - New Insights
The results obtained are derived from static panel model, which has some
shortcomings. One of the reasons is not to take into account growths lag operator.
Indeed, economic growth is attributed to the results obtained a year earlier, and
therefore, it is desirable to include this variable in the model. Therefore, a dynamic
panel is needed.
. The dynamic model
The dynamic panel model we propose is defined as follows:
αρ β γ µ δ λ ε
=+ ++ + + + +
2
1
it i it it it it it it it
Growth Growth Inf Trad Fdi Icrg Icrg (4)
Where Growthit-1 represents per capita lagged GDP growth rate.
The results of the estimation are reported in Table, which shows that H0
hypothesis of the validity of the instruments is not rejected (the probability of Sargan
statistics exceeds 5%, which means that instruments are in all exogenous). Similarly,
there is no order 2 serial autocorrelation (probability of Arellano & Bond AR test (2)
is greater than 5%). This allows us to assert that the GMM system model is appropri-
ate and specifies well the instruments, with no heteroscedasticity or autocorrelation
problems.
This method is more robust than the previous one. Table  confirms our hypoth-
esis that corruption negatively affects growth (1.86). However, square corruption
positively affects growth (0.33). The results obtained by the two methods (static and
dynamic) confirm the positive impact of investment on growth.
The estimated model is written as follows:
=+ + −+
++
2
1
Growth 2.885 0.0505 0.0419Trad 1.865Icrg 0.332Icrg
0.0213 0.098Growth
Inf
Fdi (5)
Figure 2.
Bell-shaped curve of growth through governance.
The Impact of Corruption on Economic Growth: A Nonlinear Evidence
DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.5772/intechopen.108876
By analogy to Section 2.3, determining the threshold effect shows that an optimum
is achieved by Icrg=1.865/0.664=2.81. This value confirms our hypothesis on the
relevance of moderate corruption to achieve an optimal growth value.
. Results and discussion
The concave function (Figures  and ) may be interpreted in the following way.
Corruption, which facilitates tax evasion, has two types of effects in economics. It
offers households an opportunity of tax savings that can be consumed or invested,
as tax evasion leads to a transfer of public resources to private agents [32, 33]. This
could improve growth up to a certain threshold. The optimal threshold represents the
reversal point of the curve; otherwise, the country may suffer underdevelopment like
several countries immersed in corruption.
This corruption, if significant, will reduce state resources because of produc-
tive public spending, which will lead to a loss in economic growth, which sooner or
later will lead to an uprising calling for establishing democratic principles and good
governance.
This result may surprise those who advocate the negative effects of corruption,
but it can be explained by the fact that administrative delays resulting from absence
of “bribes” paid in a corrupt economy may dampen economic growth and reduce
economic development.
. Conclusion
The aim of this paper is to examine the impact of corruption on economic growth.
The empirical literature that reported a linear relationship between corruption
Coef. Std. Error zP > z [ Conf. Interval]
Growth L 0.0987477 0.0229037 4.31* 0.000 0.0538573 0.143638
Inf 0.0505543 0.0260105 1.94** 0.052 0.0004253 0.1015339
Fdi 0.0212885 0.0311189 0.68** 0.049 0.0397035 0.0822805
Trade 0.041935 0.0092438 4.54* 0.000 0.0238175 0.0600525
Icrg 1.864927 0.5426194 3.44* 0.001 2.928442 0.8014126
Icrg0.3316179 0.0813414 3.20* 0.001 0.1011917 0.4200442
_Co n s 2.885563 1.041519 2.77* 0.006 0.844223 4.926903
AR(2) Sargan Test
(1.0000)*** (0.1428)***
AR (): Arellano and Bond test of null of zero second-order serial correlation, distributed N (, ) under null. Sargan
test: is a statistical test used to check for over-identifying restrictions in a statistical model. t-statistics are displayed in
parentheses under the coefficient estimates.*test statistic is significant at the  level.
**test statistic is significant at the  level and.
***the numbers in parentheses are p-values.
Table 3.
Estimation of the model by GMM.
Corruption - New Insights
Author details
Mohamed AliTrabelsi
Faculty of Economic Sciences and Management ofTunis, University of Tunis El
Manar, Tunisia
*Address all correspondence to: daly1704@yahoo.fr
and economic development failed to differentiate between growth-enhancing and
growth-reducing levels of corruption.
In our study, we have presented evidence that suggests the existence of hump-
shaped relationship between corruption and growth, which shows the existence of a
nonlinear relationship between these two variables. This nonlinear result shows that
growth increases at middle-corruption and decreases as nations achieve higher level
of governance (low corruption). In other words, the results indicate that higher or
lower levels of corruption negatively affect growth. Minimum corruption can be ben-
eficial to economic growth. This confirms some theories that assume that corruption
“lubricates the economic cycle” and produces the most efficient economies. However,
this lubricating effect has a threshold beyond which it becomes a threat to economic
growth. Conversely, lack of corruption may be a mechanism that slows down growth.
Statements and declarations
On behalf of myself as the alone author, I state that there is no conflict of interest
and I declare that no funds, grants, or other support was received during the prepara-
tion of manuscript. Data are available from the author on reasonable request.
Additional information
Unreviewed version of the chapter published on Research Square preprint server.
JEL: B23, C51, D73, O47
© 2022 The Author(s). Licensee IntechOpen. This chapter is distributed under the terms of
the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0),
which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided
the original work is properly cited.
The Impact of Corruption on Economic Growth: A Nonlinear Evidence
DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.5772/intechopen.108876
References
[1] Cooper DA, Krieckhaus J, Lusztig M.
Corruption, democracy and economic
growth. International Political Science
Review. 2006;(2):121-136
[2] Chetwynd E, Chetwynd F, Spector B.
Corruption and poverty: A review of
recent literature, management systems
international, Final Report, Washington.
2003
[3] Umbreen J, Saadat F. Corruption
pervades poverty: In perspective of
developing countries. Research Journal of
South Asian Studies. 2015;(1):175-187
[4] Beck N, Katz J. What to do (and not
to do) with time-serie cross-section
data. American Political Science Review.
1995;(3):634-647
[5] Acemoglu D, Verdier T. The choice
between market failures and corruption.
The American Economic Review.
2000;(1):194-211
[6] Barreto RA. Endogenous corruption
in a neoclassical growth model. European
Economic Review. 2000;(1):35-60
[7] Egger P, Winner H. Evidence on
corruption as an incentive for foreign
direct investment. European Journal of
Political Economy. 2005;(4):932-952
[8] Heckelman JC, Powell B. Corruption
and the institutional environment for
growth. Comparative Economic Studies.
2010;:351-378
[9] Johnson ND, Ruger W, Sorens J,
Yamarik S. Corruption, regulation and
growth: An empirical study of the
United States. Economics of Governance.
2014;(1):51-69
[10] Méon PG, Weill L. Is corruption an
efficient grease? World Development.
2010;(3):244-259
[11] Méon PG, Sekkat K. Does corruption
grease or sand the wheels of growth?
Public Choice. 2005;(1):69-97
[12] Mironov M. Bad Corruption, Good
Corruption and Growth. Chicago:
University of Chicago; 2005
[13] Mo PH. Corruption and economic
growth. Journal of Comparative
Economics. 2001;:66-79
[14] Mushfiq S. Economic growth with
endogenous corruption: An empirical
study. Public Choice. 2011;:23-41
[15] Mauro P. Corruption and growth.
Quarterly Journal of Economics.
1995;(3):681-712
[16] Aidt T, Dutta J, Sena V. Governance
regimes, corruption and growth: Theory
and evidence. Journal of Comparative
Economics. 2008;:195-220
[17] Méndez F, Sepúlveda F. Corruption,
growth and political regimes: Cross
country evidence. European Journal of
Political Economy. 2006;:82-98
[18] Kato A, Sato T. Greasing the
wheels? The effect of corruption in
regulated manufacturing sectors of
India. Canadian Journal of Development
Studies. 2015;:459-483
[19] Allan SW, Roland C. Economic
growth and corruption in developing
economies: Evidence from linear and
non-linear panel causality tests. Business,
Finance and Economics in Emerging
Economies. 2013;(2):21-43
[20] Aghion P, Akcigit J, Kerr WR.
Taxation, corruption, and growth,
National Bureau of Economic Research,
NBER Working Papers: 21928. 2016
Corruption - New Insights

[21] Huang CJ. Is corruption bad for
economic growth? Evidence from Asia-
Pacific countries. The North American
Journal of Economics and Finance.
2016;:247-256
[22] Trabelsi MA, Trabelsi H. At what
level of corruption does economic
growth decrease? Journal of Financial
Crime. 2021;(4):1317-1324
[23] Barro RJ. Economic growth in a cross
section of countries. Quarterly Journal of
Economics. 1991;:407-443
[24] Brunetti A. Political variables in
cross-country growth analysis. Journal of
Economic Survey. 1997;:163-190
[25] Lambsdorf f JG. Corruption
in empirical research - A review.
Transparency International Working
Paper, Berlin. 1999
[26] Fernando D, Carlos D, MarÃa
angeles CP. Growth, inequality and
corruption: Evidence from developing
countries. Economics Bulletin.
2016;(3):1811-1820
[27] Eatzaz A, Muhammad AU,
Muhammad IA. Does corruption
affect economic growth? Latin
American Journal of Economics.
2012;(2):277-305
[28] Kolstad I, Wiig A. Digging in the
dirt? Extractive industry FDI and
corruption. Economics of Governance.
2013;(4):369-383
[29] Saha S, Gounder R. Corruption and
economic development nexus: Variations
across income levels in a non-linear
framework. Economic Modelling.
2013;:70-79
[30] Levin M, Satarov GA. Corruption and
institutions in Russia. European Journal of
Political Economy. 2000;:113-132
[31] Paldam M. The cross-country pattern
of corruption: economics, culture and
the seesaw dynamics. European Journal
of Political Economy. 2002;:215-240
[32] Cerqueti R, Coppier R. Economic
growth, corruption, tax evasion.
Economic Modelling. 2011;:489-500
[33] Tanzi V, Davoodi HR. Corruption,
growth and public finances. International
Monetary Fund Working Paper. 2000
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
This article empirically investigates the effects of corruption and privatisation on economic growth in the post-communist countries of Central and Eastern Europe and the former USSR. We use a corruption and privatisation augmented open-economy leader–follower endogenous growth model to derive our research hypotheses. In this setting, corruption, privatisation and external openness jointly determine the per capita income in the follower economy. This model predicts that economies with higher shares of private ownership, lower corruption, and higher external openness enjoy higher rates of growth. Our empirical verification of these predictions is based on a panel of 29 post-communist countries during the period 1996–2014. Our estimation results confirm the negative effects of corruption, while the positive effects of privatisation are limited to small-scale privatisation.
Article
Full-text available
Corruption is beyond an evil, it is violation of regulations of the country, abrogation of rule of law and devastation of rights of those who are living depressed. It saps the energies, abilities and capabilities of the population in general and those of who are honest, sincere in particular. The causes and factors of it lay in political, social and economic mechanism of that particular society in general and in present scenario it provokes behind the process of globalization. It is an after effect of universalization of globe and globalization of population of the universe. The spread of corruption is easy but to control and root it out from the social network is difficult and somehow impossible. Once a social disease is caused to affect its paraphernalia cannot easily be removed from values of society easily. It will take time to make available benefits of justice to all the segments of society with equilibrium and realize its impact on those segments of society. Causes of corruption can be tackled one by one to make the society pure. However, it is noteworthy that one hundred percent eradication of corruption and poverty from society in not possible. By using all means it should be reduced to minimum possible level, so that society does not get affected from it at large. The corruption may not block the benefits of socio-political and economic progress to reach the poor, downtrodden, feeble and special segment of society. In democratic setup a strong independent system of accountability is a necessity, with the people, in-charge, who have viable integrity and honesty. Their loyalty to the nation should be beyond the limits of forces that stratify society on the basis of class, creed, and religions or sects etc. They may have clear, objectives based on logic and sound reasoning with the spirit of religiosity working as a dynamic forcein perspective. Society can survive for long without corruption, a corrupt society end at its own and fall in the hands of powerful, free of corruption societies. It is the first most responsibility of government to avoid cancer of corruption, politician can do it but they need it to an extent. Individuals with the help of administration and with political will can, also, do this job in a better way; only and only if political forces do not snub and discourage them. As weak politician take it as a check on their polity. Eradication of corruption and poverty requires a joint struggle and strong national will with honesty to achieve the target.
Article
Full-text available
This paper presents eclectic evidence on the corruption-growth relationship in a wide sample of developing countries. Direct effects of corruption on growth are positive, while the indirect effects, through investment and human capital channels, are negative. Finally, inequality is not significant.
Article
Purpose The purpose of this study is to examine the impact of corruption on economic growth by testing the hypothesis that the relationship between these two variables is nonlinear and by assessing the veracity of the assumption that corruption is always detrimental to economic growth. Several cross-country studies have treated this question but the findings are not universally robust. Design/methodology/approach In this paper, a panel data analysis has been used to examine 88 countries over the 1984-2011 period. A cross-sectional framework is used in which growth rate and the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) index are observed only once for each country. Findings The findings indicate that beyond an optimal threshold, both high and low corruption levels can decrease economic growth. Under this optimal threshold, a moderate level of corruption, defined by the point of reversal of the curve of the marginal corruption effect on growth, could have advantages for economic growth. Originality/value This paper shows that the threshold would be a corruption level between 2.5 and 3, which represents the “acceptable corruption level”. This result is conforming to one of the ten principles of economics: “Rational people think at the marginal change”. This threshold represents the point where the marginal benefits of corruption are equal to marginal costs incurred by corruption. Conversely, lack of corruption may be a mechanism that slows down growth.
Article
In this paper we study the effects of corruption using an open economy version of the endogenous growth model with international capital mobility. In particular, the model predicts that corruption negatively affects the stock of international investment in the host country. In addition, the model predicts that growth should be impaired by the uncertainty caused by corruption. Bribes, unlike taxes, involve unpredictable distortion in the discretionary and uncertain use of the government power. This results in additional costs to businesses and alongside with resources allocated to unproductive activities impose an extra burden on the economy. We test empirically the predictions of the theory using a sample of 142 countries for the period 1994–2014 and GMM methods. Using indicators of control of corruption from the World Bank, the lack of corruption is found to have a positive and statistically significant effect on the growth rate of real per capital GDP and increased the investment ratio. Hence, the empirical results suggest that corruption directly hinders economic growth by hampering investment. The estimated effects are robust to changes in specifications and estimation methods. Thus, it can be concluded that richer countries with better access to international financing should be growing faster and be less prone to the adverse effects of corruption than the emerging economies.
Article
This paper investigates whether the costs of corruption are conditional on the extent of government intervention in the economy. We use data on corruption convictions and economic growth between 1975 and 2007 across the US states to test this hypothesis. Although no state approaches the level of government intervention found in many developing countries, we still find evidence for the “weak” form of the grease-the-wheels hypothesis. While corruption is never good for growth, its harmful effects are smaller in states with more regulation.
Article
Because government intervention transfers resources from one party to another, it creates room for corruption. As corruption often undermines the purpose of the intervention, governments will try to prevent it. They may create rents for bureaucrats, induce a misallocation of resources, and increase the size of the bureaucracy. Since preventing all corruption is excessively costly, second-best intervention may involve a certain fraction of bureaucrats accepting bribes. When corruption is harder to prevent, there may be both more bureaucrats and higher public-sector wages. Also, the optimal degree of government intervention may be nonmonotonic in the level of income
Article
This study investigates the relationship between environmental performance, corruption and economic growth using panel data of 87 countries covering the period from 2002 to 2012. The Environmental Performance Index is used for the first time to evaluate the environmental quality on economic growth. By employing both ‘static’ and ‘dynamic’ panel models, we find that environmental performance is positively related to economic growth and is more significant in non-Organization for Economic Cooperation Development (OECD) countries. Moreover, when corruption is incorporated, the empirical estimation results indicate that although lower corruption helps economic growth in non-OECD countries, the negative coefficients of the three interactive terms show that the positive effect of environment performance on economic growth will drop, while greater environmental performance combined with natural resource abundance inevitably leads to inefficient bureaucracies and hence disadvantageous economic growth. As a result, policymakers in non-OECD countries should carefully ensure better government quality when they exhibit strong environmental performance so as to avoid any disadvantageous impact upon economic growth.