ArticlePDF Available

Abstract and Figures

Despite being one of the world's major internationally traded services, tourism remains neglected within debates on European integration and growth models. We highlight the rise of tourism-led growth in Southern Europe. We argue that the process of European integration has been a double-edged sword, simultaneously incentivizing and forcing Southern European economies to reap their comparative advantage in tourism. While European integration has created the preconditions for the expansion of intra-European tourism, monetary integration pre-empts macroeconomic management. Since the Eurozone crisis, internal devaluation and fiscal austerity have suppressed the domestic growth drivers, inducing these governments towards an export-led growth strategy. We document the emergence of unprecedented tourism-related current account surpluses in Southern Europe, driven strongly by tourism imports from the EMU-core countries and the UK. Thus, while different types of export-led growth strategies now coexist in the EMU, Southern Europe's excessive reliance on international tourism for growth comes with severe pitfalls.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Blessing or Curse? The Rise of Tourism-Led Growth in Europes
Southern Periphery
RETO BÜRGISSER
1
and DONATO DI CARLO
2
1
Department of Political Science, University of Zurich, Zurich, Switzerland
2
Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies, Cologne,
Germany
Abstract
Despite being one of the worlds major internationally traded services, tourism remains neglected
within debates on European integration and growth models. We highlight the rise of tourism-led
growth in southern Europe and argue that the process of European integration has been a
double-edged sword, simultaneously incentivizing and forcing southern European economies to
reap their comparative advantage in tourism. While European integration has created the precon-
ditions for the expansion of intra-European tourism, monetary integration pre-empts macroeco-
nomic management. Since the eurozone crisis, internal devaluation and scal austerity have sup-
pressed the domestic growth drivers, inducing these governments towards an export-led growth
strategy. We document the emergence of unprecedented tourism-related current account surpluses
in southern Europe, driven strongly by tourism imports from the EMU core countries and the UK.
Thus, while different export-led growth strategies now coexist in the EMU, southern Europes ex-
cessive reliance on international tourism for growth comes with severe pitfalls.
Keywords: European integration; growth models; varieties of capitalism; tourism; southern Europe
Introduction
Over the last half-century, tourism has grown from an elite pastime into the worlds larg-
est service sector industry in international trade (Lew, 2011). Today, tourism is the
third-largest economic sector in Europe (European Parliament, 2015) and a signicant
contributor to economic growth and employment to many national and local economies
worldwide (Scott and Gössling, 2015). Within this macro trend, southern Europe accounts
for more than 20 per cent of the global tourism market (UNWTO, 2020). Yet, while there
is awareness of the importance of the tourism industry among economists and
policy-makers (Du et al., 2016), one can rarely nd any mention of tourism in the com-
parative political economy (CPE) and European integration literature. This is remarkable
considering Europes leading role in the sector and, most importantly, tourisms potential
for socio-economic integration and political co-operation within Europe (Lijphart, 1963;
Russett, 1970).
While the varieties of capitalism (Hall and Soskice, 2001) and the growth models lit-
erature (Baccaro and Pontusson, 2016; Hassel and Palier, 2021) have identied different
models of capitalism, scholars of European integration continue to debate whether these
can co-exist within a hard-currency regime like the economic and monetary union
(EMU). The debate is polarized around two contrasting views. Some scholars argue that
countriesdiversity may be benecial in a monetary union, enabling mutual insurance
mechanisms among its members (Schelkle, 2017). Others, instead, argue that the EMU
JCMS 2023 Volume 61. Number 1. pp. 236258 DOI: 10.1111/jcms.13368
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial License, which permits use, distribution and reproduction in
any medium, provided the original work is properly cited and is not used for commercial purposes.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
destroys the governance capabilities (that is, exchange rate and countercyclical scal pol-
icies) on which the domestic demand-led countries of southern Europe have historically
relied. Thus, participation in the EMU rewards export-led growth strategies pursued by
the EMU core countries while it precludes domestic demand-led growth strategies
of the southern countries (Hall, 2014). This article contributes to the ongoing debate
(Johnston and Regan, 2016,2018) by highlighting the rise of tourism-led growth in south-
ern Europe since the eurozone crisis.
Despite its richness, this debate has overlooked the growing economic importance of
tourism in Europe. While EMU core countries have long relied on net exports from
manufacturing goods (for example, Germany) or high-end services (for example, the
Netherlands) as drivers of aggregate demand (Hassel and Palier, 2021), growth in south-
ern Europe was mainly consumption-led and fuelled by nancial integration and capital
ows from EMU core countries (Fuller, 2018; Jones, 2016; Stockhammer, 2016). Once
capital dried up during the eurozone crisis, scal austerity plus internal devaluations
forced southern European countries into export-led growth (Afonso, 2019; Perez and
Matsaganis, 2019; Scharpf, 2016). While this is well known, we complement this argu-
ment by documenting the emergence of a third variant of export-led growth strategy in
the EMU based on internationally traded tourism services, which today account for a sub-
stantial and growing part of southern Europes exports. By tracing the evolution of current
account (CA) balances, we argue that, from 2010 onwards, CA surpluses from interna-
tional tourism have grown to unprecedented levels, highlighting the increasing reliance
of Southern Europe on tourism-related surpluses to export their way to growth within
the EMU.
Moreover, through the analysis of bilateral CA balances, we also show that northern
and southern Europe have become increasingly integrated through international tourism
transactions. Since the crisis, southern Europe has substantially expanded its tourism
CA surpluses vis-à-vis EMU core countries and the UK. Although we cannot provide
conclusive evidence, we hypothesize that this process has likely been driven by a combi-
nation of internal devaluation and governmentsindustrial policies aimed at upgrading,
diversifying, and promoting their domestic tourism industries in the ever-expanding inter-
national tourism markets. We posit that the Single European Aviation Market (SEAM)
and travel and visa liberalizations have created the preconditions for an unprecedented ex-
pansion of intra-European travel. At the same time, EU state-aid prohibitions and a hard
currency regime cum legal constraints on national budgets pre-empt southern European
countriesprevious capacity to pursue growth strategies centred on expansionary scal
and wage policy-making as well as competitive devaluations. Thus, the process of Euro-
pean integration has created both incentives and constraints, forcing southern European
countries to capitalize on their comparative advantages in international tourism.
Tourism-led growth now provides these economies with an option for export-led growth
compatible with the requirements of the EMUs hard currency regime and Europes reg-
ulatory state.
This article contributes to European political economy scholarship both theoretically
and empirically. First, we contribute to burgeoning debates on growth models by urging
attention to international tourism as a full-edged growth strategy. For peripheral econo-
mies with suitable pre-conditions (for example, warm climate, coastlines, cultural heri-
tage), tourism represents a developmental strategy worth studying alongside other growth
The Rise of Tourism-Led Growth in Europes Southern Periphery 237
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
strategies based on foreign direct investment (FDI) and tax dumping (Ban and
Adascalitei, 2020; Bohle and Regan, 2021). Second, we contribute to political economy
debates on European integration by highlighting the growing international interdepen-
dence of southern Europes tourism-led growth strategies with northern Europes strate-
gies of export-led growth and privatized Keynesianism in the UK.
The article proceeds as follows. We rst locate tourism within key debates on growth
models and European integration. Then, we introduce international tourism as an
export-led strategy and briey discuss how European integration contributed to its expan-
sion. After that, we trace the evolution of southern Europes growth models and demon-
strate the rise of tourism-led growth. We conclude by discussing the perils of an excessive
reliance on tourism and sketching a future research agenda on the comparative political
economy of tourism.
I. The Political Economy of European Economic and Monetary Integration
The process of European economic and monetary integration was premised on the idea
that free trade within a European single market would benet both producers and con-
sumers thanks to rmseconomies of scale and countriesgreater specialization based
on their respective comparative advantages (European Commission, 1985). A single cur-
rency was seen as complementary to enhance these gains from trade by reducing transac-
tion costs and guaranteeing macroeconomic stability (European Commission, 1990).
While the theory of optimal currency areas portrayed monetary integration as benecial
only for Member States with exible labour markets or synchronized business cycles,
1
in-
tegration proceeded under the assumption that greater competition and economic/nancial
integration would induce governments to generate the institutional and economic conver-
gence necessary for a common currency to work (Frankel and Rose, 1998).
Yet, three decades later, structural differences among European countries persist
(Höpner and Schäfer, 2012). Within the EMU, mounting economic divergence between
core countries and southern peripheral economies has instead ensued (Gambarotto and
Solari, 2015). Against this backdrop, scholars of the political economy of European inte-
gration debate whether European integration can successfully accommodate different va-
rieties of capitalism or growth models (Höpner and Schäfer, 2010; Johnston and
Regan, 2018; Scharpf, 1999; Stockhammer, 2016) without a political union capable of su-
pranational macroeconomic stabilization and social protection (McNamara et al., 2015;
Scharpf, 2014).
Some scholars argue that the diversity of European political economies within the
EMU allows for forms of monetary solidarity by providing diverse countries with mech-
anisms for mutual insurance for income and consumption smoothing (Schelkle, 2017).
Others oppose this view on three grounds: (1) the very crisis of the EMU was in the rst
place due to its membersincompatible growth models joined together within a system of
xed exchange rates which penalizes the previously soft-currency regimes of southern
Europe (Hancké, 2013; Höpner and Lutter, 2018; Johnston and Regan, 2016;
Scharpf, 2011); (2) the euro can now only be saved at the cost of suppressing democracy
1
As noted by some prominent US economists, these conditions were hardly achieved in Europe at the time (Feldstein, 1997).
For an extensive review on EMU and the theory of optimal currency areas, see Mongelli (2005).
Reto Bürgisser and Donato Di Carlo238
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
in southern Europe (Crum, 2013); (3) since the crisis, the EMUs strengthened economic
governance imposes a process of forced structural convergenceon southern economies
(Regan, 2017; Scharpf, 2016). Scholars have highlighted how northern European coun-
tries dispose of the institutional complementarities necessary for an export-led growth
strategy suitable for economic success within the EMU (Hall, 2014). On the contrary,
lacking these institutional prerequisites, southern Europes economies that have tradition-
ally relied on domestic demand-led growth strategies nd it hard to operate successfully
in the EMU without currency devaluations and tools for aggregate demand management
(Hassel, 2014; Iversen et al., 2016). Therefore, due to scal austerity, internal devalua-
tions and market-enhancing structural reforms, the EMU suppresses domestic growth
drivers and forces southern economies into export-led growth (Scharpf, 2016).
Despite their richness, current debates on the political economy of Europe have so far
overlooked the implications of European integration for the steep rise of the international
tourism industry and the consequences this development has had for the reconguration
of southern Europes growth models within the EMU. We contribute to these debates
by highlighting how European integration has put in place the preconditions for
expanding the international tourism industry. We demonstrate that southern European
economies have increasingly exploited their comparative advantage in the tourism indus-
try vis-à-vis northern Europes countries to rekindle their export-led growth strategies
within Europes post-crisis constrained governance environment.
II. International Tourism as an Export-Led Growth Strategy
The classic varieties of capitalism literature had identied four different models of capi-
talism: coordinated market economies (CMEs), liberal market economies (LMEs), mixed
market economies (MMEs) (Hall and Soskice, 2001; Molina and Rhodes, 2006) and
economies dependent on FDI (Nölke and Vliegenthart, 2009). Instead, the current growth
models literature categorizes countries based on an economys main drivers of aggregate
demand formation (Baccaro and Pontusson, 2016). Northern Europes CMEs consist of
export-led growth models with subdued domestic demand and a specialization in
manufacturing goodsexports (Austria, Belgium, Germany) and balanced growth
modelswith extensive exports of ICT-based services and high domestic demand (Nordic
countries, the Netherlands). The United Kingdom is an LME that relies on
consumption-led growth underpinned by deregulated access to credit and vibrant housing
markets also known as privatized Keynesianism(Crouch, 2009). Central and eastern
European economies and Ireland largely rely on lower labour costs and/or favourable tax
schemes and incentives to attract FDI by multinational corporations to generate growth
and jobs (Ban and Adascalitei, 2020; Bohle and Regan, 2021; Reurink and Garcia-
Bernardo, 2020). Lastly, before the eurozone crisis, the MMEs of southern Europe relied
on domestic private and public consumption underpinned by easy access to credit and/or
generous wage and scal policies (Hassel and Palier, 2021).
Along these ideal types identied by the literature, we conceptualize and add a hitherto
overlooked export-led growth strategy centred on exporting international tourism ser-
vices. According to standard classications, tourism consists of the activity of visitors
taking a trip to a main destination outside the usual environment, for less than a year,
for any main purpose, including business, leisure or other personal purposes, other than
The Rise of Tourism-Led Growth in Europes Southern Periphery 239
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
to be employed by a resident entity in the place visited(Eurostat, 2014). Three types of
tourism activities can be distinguished. Domestic tourism consists of within-country tour-
ism by residents. Travels by incoming foreign tourists are considered as inbound tourism,
and vice versa outbound tourism. Even though domestic tourism is a hefty economic sec-
tor in many countries and constitutes an essential component of private consumption, to
study the importance of tourism as an export-led growth strategy, we will focus only on
international tourism, that is, inbound/outbound tourism.
Today, international tourism is one of the worlds major internationally traded services.
Its transactions are recorded in the traveland passenger transportitems of the balance
of payments current account. To assess the economic contribution of tourism, we rely
mainly on data provided by the World Tourism Organization (UNWTO), which has de-
veloped a harmonized system of tourism satellite accounts together with the Organisation
for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) and Eurostat. Inbound tourism is
an export component (X) because foreign visitors travel to the country and acquire locally
produced tourism services spending their foreign currency earned in the country of resi-
dence. Vice versa, outbound tourism is an import component (M). Given the aggregate
demand (AD) equation, where:
AD ¼CþIþGþXMðÞ;
international tourisms net contribution to aggregate demand
2
is positive when receipts
from inbound tourism exceed those from outbound tourism, that is, when (X M) >0.
In multiple ways, international tourism surpluses contribute to economic growth, em-
ployment, foreign exchange earnings and tax income (Clancy, 1999; UNCTAD, 1998).
Historically, tourism in liaison with remittances has played a vital role in fostering
the industrialization of those developing countries that lacked the domestic factors of pro-
duction (De Kadt, 1984). This is because importing capital goods or raw materials from
abroad implies decits in the current account, which must be nanced through exports.
Inbound tourism has an essential developmental function because it mitigates the balance
of payment constraints by bringing foreign exchange into the country. Foreign currencys
availability, in turn, could be exploited to import the capital goods and raw materials
needed to kick-start industrialization (McKinnon, 1964). Furthermore, tourism can con-
tribute to development by stimulating governmentsinvestment in physical infrastructures
and human capital, thereby increasing productivity and generating positive externalities
(Blake et al., 2006). It is also an important driver of employment creation, providing in-
come to households that underpins domestic consumption (Lee and Chang, 2008).
However, an excessive reliance on tourism-led growth comes with notable pitfalls.
First, critical scholars link tourism to dependency theory and denounce a new form of co-
lonialism whereby foreign multinationals invest in developing countriestouristic destina-
tions and deprive the local population of the prots generated through the intensive
2
Focusing only on the current account likely underestimates the actual contribution of tourism to domestic growth because it
does not consider foreign touristsconsumption of goods and services other than travel and transport. Moreover, tourism
does not sell just one product and decomposing each industry into tourism- and non-tourism-related components is chal-
lenging. Some scholars recommend the analysis of backward and forward linkages to fully assess the economic impact
of tourism (Cai et al., 2006), which, however, goes beyond the scope of this article.
Reto Bürgisser and Donato Di Carlo240
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
exploitation of local natural resources.
3
Second, as a growth strategy dependent on foreign
touristsinows, an excessive reliance on tourism makes the country highly vulnerable to
exogenous shocks such as the recent outbreak of the Covid-19 pandemic (Financial
Times, 2021) or terrorism (Fauzel and Seetanah, 2021; Pizam and Smith, 2000). Third,
excessive reliance on tourism leads to a restructuring of the economy around low produc-
tivity, low value-added sectors, characterized by seasonal jobs and precarious employ-
ment (Eurofound, 2012). Fourth, tourism can have severe adverse effects on the environ-
ment and on socio-cultural spaces; not only due to the expansion of the airline industry
but also the erosion of public infrastructures due to extensive use by foreign tourists,
the commodication and over-utilization of natural resources, vandalism and damage to
over-crowded cultural sites (Tisdell, 1987).
At any rate, for lack of better alternatives, international tourism can become a
full-edged strategy for governments to generate growth and employment, particularly
for less developed countries unable to compete with advanced economies in high-end
manufacturing or the knowledge economy. Yet, for such a growth strategy to be success-
ful, countries need a liberal travel visa regime to minimize transaction costs for foreign
tourists and a cheap and competitive passenger transportation system to facilitate travels.
By putting these conditions into place, European integration has been key to fostering the
rise of the European tourism industry.
III. How European Integration Has Underpinned the Expansion of Tourism
Tourism is not mentioned in the EU treaties until 1992 when the Maastricht Treaty intro-
duced the possibility for the EU to take measures in the spheres of energy, civil protec-
tion, and tourism. The European Commission has long aimed at expanding its competen-
cies in tourism policy, which it has used strategically to foster the completion of the EU
single market (Estol and Font, 2016). However, a full-edged EU tourism policy remains
limited due to the lack of direct competencies and unanimity requirements in the Euro-
pean Council (European Parliament, 2015). Member States have thus jealously protected
and advanced their national interests in tourism policy due to its strategic importance for
achieving balance of payment parity (Estol and Font, 2016, p. 231). With the Lisbon
Treaty, the EU eventually acquired competencies to encourage and promote
co-operation between Member States in tourism policy. However, EU competencies re-
main anchored to the principle of subsidiarity and the EU can only support, coordinate
or supplement(art. 6, TFEU) Member Statesactions. Any harmonization of Member
Stateslaws and regulations related to tourism is explicitly excluded (art. 195, TFEU).
Yet, tourism has indirectly beneted from the process of European integration in multiple
ways (see Table 1).
First, a liberal visa regime and the right to free movement have facilitated travels
within the EU. Thanks to the Schengen agreements (1985 and 1990), since the mid-
1990s, tourists have beneted from a common visa policy for short stays and the gradual
removal of internal barriers, enabling persons to cross borders freely irrespective of their
nationality. Visa obligations considerably impact tourism since potential travellers may be
deterred from traveling if visa procedures are too costly or burdensome. While European
3
For a review of the dependency literature, see Bianchi (2018, pp. 9091).
The Rise of Tourism-Led Growth in Europes Southern Periphery 241
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
residents travel freely across the EU, more than 70 per cent of the worlds population
needed a visa to travel to Europe in 2012, making it one of the most restrictive regions
regarding visa obligations for non-Europeans (Attström et al., 2013). The 1992 Maastricht
Treaty then introduced the concept of EU citizenship and institutionalized the individual
right for every EU citizen to move freely across the EU.
Second, tourism has beneted enormously from the deregulation and liberalization of
the European air transport markets. The creation of the Single European Aviation Market
(SEAM), the poster child of negative integration in Europe, was pushed forward by the
strategic actions of the Commission in alignment with the Dutch and British governments
(Dobson, 2010). National air transport markets have been liberalized through three legis-
lative packages by the European Council, which were inspired by the requirements of
market competition enshrined in the Treaty of Rome (1957) (Button, 2001). Before the
1990s, Europes aviation market was regulated by bilateral agreements. Strict national
regulations regulated routes, fares and market access.
Table 1: Dening Moments of European Integration for the Expansion of the Tourism Industry
Agreements and regulations Year Relevant institutional changes Effects on the tourism industry
Schengen Agreements 1985
&
1990
Common visa policy for short
stays and removal of internal
border controls
Personsfreedom to cross
internal borders without border
checks, irrespective of
nationality
1
st
legislative package on the
liberalization of air transport
markets (Council regulations,
directives & decisions)
1988 European Commission enabled
to apply antitrust regulation to
airlines; airlines granted greater
pricing freedom; partial
liberalization of market access
by airlines
First step in the creation of the
SEAM
2
nd
legislative package on the
liberalization of air transport
markets (Council regulations)
1990 Deregulation of air trafc
limitations; elimination of
governmentsdiscrimination
against airlines not
substantially owned by a
European state
Second step in the creation of
the SEAM
Maastricht Treaty 1992 Introduction of EU citizenship Institutionalization of
individual right for every EU
citizen to move and reside in
EU Member States
3
rd
legislative package on the
liberalization of air transport
markets (Council regulations)
1993 Removal of all signicant
barriers to market entry;
regulation of common safety
rules and nancial
requirements; removal of
national restrictions on ticket
prices; removal of restrictions
on routes; deregulation of fares;
permitted foreign ownership of
airlines
Third and nal step in the
gradual establishment of the
SEAM, leading to greater
competition in air transport
markets, lower ticket fares,
increased frequency of ights,
larger number of routes,
emergence of the low-cost
airlines
Reto Bürgisser and Donato Di Carlo
242
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Moreover, the market was monopolized by state-owned ag carriers, vigorously
protected by state aid (Button and Swann, 1988). This regime was misaligned with EU
principles of open markets and free competition. During the late 1980s and early
1990s, the European Council proceeded to deregulate and liberalize the European air mar-
kets, introducing the freedom for an EU carrier to operate any route within the EU, re-
moving restrictions on their capacity and operations and empowering airlines to set prices
by market principles rather than being dictated by government. The liberalization has led
to an enormous expansion of the European aviation industry to the benet of European
travellers who have enjoyed more ights, lower fares, a greater number of routes and des-
tinations, not least thanks to the mushrooming of low-cost airlines across Europe
(Burghouwt et al., 2015). Thus, by the 2000s, the preconditions had been put in place,
which would subsequently pave the way for southern European countriesgrowing reli-
ance on international tourism for growth.
IV. The Rise of Tourism-Led Growth in Southern Europe after the Crisis
Southern Europes Growing Peripheralization
Despite their national differences, Greece, Italy, Portugal and Spain share some key fea-
tures that have induced scholars to speak of a distinct model of southern European capi-
talism. These countries had large agricultural sectors and developed into industrialized
economies with a substantial lag. Late and disorganized industrialization led to idiosyn-
cratic models of capitalism characterized by inconsistencies between the productive sys-
tem and the institutional and regulatory setting (Fuà, 1980). These structural weaknesses
pushed the state into adopting a direct role in the economic governance of markets to
compensate for market failures, promote coordination among market actors and give co-
herence to the system of capitalist accumulation (Molina and Rhodes, 2006;
Schmidt, 2002). Thus, in the aftermath of World War II, the interventionist state played
a central role in shaping and directing markets through regulation and active forms of in-
dustrial policy such as direct ownership in strategic sectors (Vernon and Aharoni, 2014),
active credit policy and various forms of scal subsidies (Shoneld, 1965;
Thatcher, 2014).
In brief, by the 1980s, southern European economies developed into a model of capi-
talism featuring the following characteristics (Amable, 2003): dualized welfare states or-
ganized around the central role played by the family and the protection of labour market
insiders (Ferrera, 1996); dual labour markets with a divide between highly protected in-
siders and unprotected outsiders; adversarial industrial relations and a fragmented system
of interest representation conducive to inationary wage-setting; the dominance of small
and medium enterprises, often family-owned; a bank-based system of corporate gover-
nance, often under political control; rooted forms of political clientelism (Hopkin and
Mastropaolo, 2001); little investment in research and development, low public expendi-
tures in education, low enrolment rates in tertiary education and weak vocational training
systems. Unsurprisingly, these countries pursued production strategies based on price
rather than quality competition and were apt to currency devaluations to compensate
for systematic expansionary scal and wage policies and structural deciencies
(Hancké, 2013; Scharpf, 2016).
The Rise of Tourism-Led Growth in Europes Southern Periphery 243
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Due to these characteristics, the deepening of European economic and monetary inte-
gration and economic globalization have hit southern European economies
disproportionally hard. First, the rise of the European regulatory state has imposed a shift
in national economic governance for which southern Europes statist models were unt.
European competition policy and state aid regulations have severely reduced the capacity
for statist forms of economic governance and have tilted the balance of power in favour of
markets and regulatory governance (Majone, 1994). By privatizing state-owned assets
and liberalizing core strategic sectors, southern European states have lost their grip on
the economy and their pivotal role in domestic markets.
Second, the Maastricht Treaty and the adoption of the single currency have removed
further governance capabilities that had historically been crucial for southern Europes
states. On the one hand, the loss of exchange rate policy prevents the pursuit of compet-
itive currency devaluations to mitigate structural deciencies. Conversely, the Stability
and Growth Pact constrains countercyclical scal policy to pursue aggregate demand
management. Finally, a one-size-ts-none supranational monetary policy fostered eco-
nomic divergence between the high-ination southern periphery and the northern
low-ination core (Enderlein, 2006; Scharpf, 2011).
Taken together, the EMU has forced a hard-currency regime into previously
soft-currency countries, while the European regulatory state prevents governments from
steering domestic markets. Having lost the crucial governance capabilities necessary to
run a statist model, southern Europes economies found themselves between a rock and
a hard place by the turn of the century. On the one hand, their political economies were
simultaneously too regulated and expensive to compete on price with the low-cost newly
industrialized economies in the developing world and eastern Europe. On the other hand,
their persisting structural weaknesses prevented them from competing upmarket with the
high-skilled, high value-added production systems of northern Europe (Burroni et
al., 2022; Simoni, 2020). In fact, Chinas entry into the World Trade Organization
(WTO) in 2001 generated an asymmetric shock in the eurozone. Northern Europes econ-
omies based on the export of high value-added production were well positioned to reap
the benets of the growing Chinese demand for capital and industrial goods. At the same
time, however, southern European economies were hit hard by low-cost competition in
key sectors of their economies by countries with low labour costs and weak labour rights
(De Ville and Vermeiren, 2016). All these factors, some scholars have argued, contributed
to the peripheralizationof southern European economies within the EMU (Celi
et al., 2017; Rhodes et al., 2019) and their deindustrialization (Gambarotto et al., 2019).
Before the crisis, southern European economies within the EMU pursued a growth
strategy based on domestic demand expansion and centred in their large, sheltered sectors.
Conversely, EMU core countries relied on export-led growth strategies based on
manufacturing goods (Austria, Belgium, and Germany) or high-end services (the
Netherlands) (Hassel and Palier, 2021). These two complementary models were kept to-
gether in the EMU thanks to nancial integration and capital ows from Germany, France
and the UK to peripheral economies (Blyth, 2013; Jones, 2015; Stockhammer, 2016).
However, this toxic complementarity(Fuller, 2018) came to a halt when the global -
nancial crisis disrupted nancial markets and inter-bank lending froze. Panic and uncer-
tainty generated a sudden stop crisis and the reversal of nancial ows towards northern
Europe (Merler and Pisani-Ferry, 2012).
Reto Bürgisser and Donato Di Carlo244
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
In the adjustment process, southern European countries were forced into scal auster-
ity, internal devaluations and structural reforms through formal and informal conditional-
ity imposed by European institutions (Braun et al., 2021; Bulfone and Tassinari, 2020;
Hodson and Puetter, 2013). These measures have killed the domestic drivers of aggregate
demand, imposing a ight to exports(Scharpf, 2016). Since the nancial crisis, southern
European countries have been forced to export their way to economic growth or perish
(Perez and Matsaganis, 2019).
However, as we document below, southern European economies have increasingly
capitalized on their comparative advantage in the tourism industry in their quest for
export-led growth. In fact, these countries enjoy a comparative advantage in tourism
exports thanks to their climate, geographical location, natural resources and historical/
cultural heritage, as indicated by their high scores in the Travel and Tourism Competi-
tiveness Indexof the World Economic Forum (Calderwood and Soshkin, 2019).
Export or Perish? Southern Europes Shift towards Tourism-Led Growth in the Aftermath
of the Euro Crisis
As shown in Figure 1,scal austerity and internal devaluation during the last decade de-
pressed domestic demand and forced southern European countries into a ight to ex-
ports(Scharpf, 2016). The slow growth of the post-crisis period has been driven almost
Figure 1: Average Yearly Contribution to the Change of GDP by Aggregate Demand Component.
Source: AMECO.
The Rise of Tourism-Led Growth in Europes Southern Periphery 245
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
exclusively by net exports in Greece, Italy and Spain. In Portugal, next to net exports, pri-
vate consumption has also been an important driver of GDP growth.
The contribution of net exports to GDP growth has diminished in northern Europe
after the crisis most notably in Germany but also in Austria, Belgium and Finland.
Conversely, since the aftermath of the nancial crisis, net exports have become the
main drivers of GDP growth in southern Europe, reversing the pre-crisis trend (see
Figure 2).
However, export-led growth in southern Europe was driven mainly by exporting tour-
ism services. Figure 3shows that receipts from international tourism account for around
one-fourth of total exports in Greece and Portugal. Here, one should highlight an apparent
country-size effectregarding the incidence of tourism exports in total exports. Smaller
countries with less diversied industrial systems like Portugal and Greece depend heavily
on tourism receipts for their export-led growth. Spain is located somewhere between the
smaller southern countries and Italy. Italy, instead, does not differ much from the other
countries of the EMU core, with tourism exports accounting for only around 8 per cent
of total exports. While surprising, Italys low share of tourism exports can be explained
partly due to Italys incapacity to devise coherent developmental policies to keep up with
the international competition in tourism markets (OECD, 2011) and due to Italys larger,
more sophisticated, and resilient industrial sector.
Southern Europes increased dependence on international tourism for growth can be
gauged through a balance of payment analysis. Figure 4shows current account balances
Figure 2: Average Yearly Contribution of Net Exports to the Change of GDP.
Source: AMECO.
Reto Bürgisser and Donato Di Carlo246
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Figure 3: Incidence of Tourism Exports in Total Exports.
Notes: EMU core includes Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Netherlands and Finland. Tourism
includes the travel and passenger transport items.
Source: UNWTO
Figure 4: Current Account Balance for International Tourism Services, % of GDP.
Notes: EMU core includes Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Netherlands and Finland. Tourism
balance includes the travel and passenger transport items.
Source: UNWTO
The Rise of Tourism-Led Growth in Europes Southern Periphery 247
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
for international tourism services. While EMU core countries and the UK record stable
decits, southern European surpluses have skyrocketed between 2010 and 2019. Italy
the outlier displays a small and constant surplus of around 1 per cent of GDP while
Spains tourism surplus has increased from 3 to 4 per cent. However, it is in the small
southern European economies that the most spectacular tourism-led growth can be ob-
served. As of 2019, Greece runs a 9 per cent of GDP tourism surplus a threefold in-
crease compared with 2010. Over the same period, Portugals tourism surplus has more
than doubled, standing at more than 7 per cent of GDP. Thus, while EMU core countries
continue to run current account surpluses driven by exports of manufactured goods (for
example, Germany) or high-end services (for example, Netherlands) (Hassel and
Palier, 2021), these imbalances have now been mirrored by southern Europes mounting
surpluses from international tourism.
Figure 5further indicates that rising tourism surpluses are not the result of declining
outbound tourism. Outbound tourism (imports) in southern Europe has remained at over
the last three decades and has even increased slightly since 2015. On the contrary, except
for Italy, inbound tourism (exports) in southern Europe has skyrocketed after 2010. More-
over, the steep rise in inbound tourism in southern Europe is not mirrored by an equal in-
crease in outbound tourism in EMU core countries and the UK. However, this does not
imply that tourism-led growth in southern Europe relies increasingly on non-European
Figure 5: Inbound and Outbound Tourism Expenditure, % of GDP.
Notes: EMU core includes Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Netherlands and Finland. Tourism
balance includes the travel and passenger transport items.
Source: UNWTO
Reto Bürgisser and Donato Di Carlo248
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
tourists, but instead that northern Europeans are more often travelling to southern Europe
than other world regions, pointing to a regional recomposition of tourism patterns.
This regional recomposition is evident in Figure 6, which shows countriesbilateral
balances of the travel item of the servicescurrent account. It unequivocally indicates that
northern European and British citizens have substantially expanded their imports of tour-
ism services from southern Europe after the eurozone crisis. Thus, southern Europe has
become increasingly economically integrated with northern Europe and the UK thanks
to international tourism. Greece runs surpluses of around 1.4 per cent of GDP vis-à-vis
both Germany and the UK. These surpluses have more than doubled over the last decade.
Greece also runs substantial and increasing surpluses vis-à-vis France, Austria and the
Netherlands. Similarly, Portugal runs a 1.4 per cent of GDP travel surplus vis-à-vis the
UK, surpluses of around 1 per cent of GDP vis-à-vis both Germany and France, and sub-
stantial and increasing surpluses vis-à-vis other EMU core countries. Data on Spain are
scant and bilateral balances are unavailable. Yet, travel receipts as a per cent of GDP show
inows of 1.2 per cent of GDP from the UK and of 0.8 per cent of GDP from both
Germany and France. Again, Italy is the outlier with 0.3 per cent of GDP travel surpluses
from Germany.
In a nutshell, the analysis of tourisms contribution to economic growth yields unique
insights. As highlighted in the literature, the engine of growth in southern Europe after the
crisis has been net exports engineered via scal and wage devaluations (Perez and
Matsaganis, 2019; Scharpf, 2016). However, what has been neglected is the central role
Figure 6: Bilateral Travel Balances or Inbound Receipts, as a percentage of GDP.
Notes: Data on bilateral balances for the travel item of the current account is not available in Spain
and travel receipts only from 2016
Sources: Bank of Greece, Bank of Italy, Bank of Portugal, Bank of Spain
The Rise of Tourism-Led Growth in Europes Southern Periphery 249
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
of international tourism in this adjustment process. Tourism is a substantial component of
these countriesexports and a major engine of growth and employment creation. When
considering the direct and indirect impact of tourism on national economies, tourism ac-
counts for roughly 20 per cent of GDP in Greece, 17 per cent in Portugal, 15 per cent in
Spain, and 13 per cent in Italy (Figure 7left panel). In terms of employment, one-fourth in
Greece and one-fth in Portugal are employed in a business that directly or indirectly de-
rives its income from tourism activities. In Spain and Italy, around 15 per cent work in a
tourism-related undertaking (Figure 7right panel). On the contrary, tourism servicescon-
tribution to GDP and employment in EMU core countries and the UK is low and declin-
ing steadily over time.
While we do not have the space to provide conclusive evidence, we hypothesize that
the rise of tourism-led growth in the south has likely been driven by the combination of
amarket-based and an agency-based mechanism.
4
On the one hand, the expansion of tourism exports has likely been boosted by internal
devaluation in southern Europe after the crisis. Our calculations indicate that tourism ex-
ports are signicantly price-sensitive in Italy, Greece and Spain, while Portugals tourism
Figure 7: Total Contribution of Tourism to National GDP (Left Panel) and Employment (Right
Panel)
Source: World Travel and Tourism Council (WTTC).
4
This is only partially related to political turmoil in the Middle East and Northern Africa (MENA). Despite a fall in tourist
arrivals in 2011, they returned to previous levels and experienced steady tourism growth above the worlds average before
the COVID-19 pandemic (Hopnger and Scharfenort, 2020; UNWTO, 2019). However, it played a role in the restructuring
of tourism ows, that is, northern Europeans travelling more often to southern Europe, while the MENA countries increas-
ingly rely on non-European tourists.
Reto Bürgisser and Donato Di Carlo250
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
competitiveness appears less price-sensitive (Tables A1A4 and Figure A1 in the Online
Appendix). This may be due to Portugal already being a much cheaper travel destination
than Italy, Spain and Greece.
5
Since 2008/09, Spain, Greece and Italy have experienced
lower ination of tourism servicesprices relative to the EU average. Thus, southern
Europes tourism exports have seemingly beneted from the decline in the relative price
of tourism-related services vis-à-vis the rest of the EU.
On the other hand, however, southern European governments have also developed co-
herent industrial policies to capitalize on their comparative advantage in tourism. Avail-
able assessments of industrial policies for tourism development suggest that governments
succeed (i) when generous public budgets support comprehensive developmental strate-
gies; (ii) when the governance of tourism policy is centralized or tightly coordinated at
the national level to activate synergies and co-operation among the plethora of actors
and economic sectors involved in the travel and tourism industry; and (iii) when govern-
ments support domestic markets by creating institutional complementarities on which
tourism thrives such as physical (for example, airports, highways) and digital (for ex-
ample, marketing/advertising platforms) infrastructures, vocational training schools to up-
grade tourism-specic skills, and the integration of small and medium-sized enterprises
(SMEs) in the tourism value chains (Haxton, 2015).
In this respect, Greece (2007), Spain (2009) and Portugal (2007) have all successfully
implemented National Strategic Plansto rebrand, upgrade, diversify and promote their
domestic tourism industries internationally. While Greece and Portugal feature a highly
centralized governance of tourism, Spain tightly co-ordinates the autonomous regionsac-
tivities at the national level under the aegis of the Ministry of Industry, Tourism and Trade
(OECD, 2012,2014). By the early 2010s, all three countries devoted large budgets to the
promotion of tourism; earmarking between 6 and 8 per cent of their total budgets to tour-
ism policy (Blanke and Chiesa, 2013, p. 405). Italy the outlier in our account has so
far not implemented a national developmental plan, let alone formed a coherent institu-
tional setting for tourism governance. This is largely due to the regionally fragmented
and unco-ordinated governance of tourism policy, which resulted from the broader disor-
ganized decentralization to regional governments in the late 1990s (OECD, 2011). As a
result, Italysrst strategic tourism plan developed by the government in 2013 has never
been implemented. Initially developed to counteract Italys loss of tourism market share,
the plan failed because the government did not include the regional stakeholders, which
continue to promote their regional destinations individually (Banca DItalia, 2018,p.
102). Moreover, Italy spent approximately half (3.6 per cent of total budgets) compared
to its southern European peers on tourism development and promotion (Blanke and
Chiesa, 2013, p. 405).
Conclusion: Tourism-Led Growth in the European Political Economy
This article speaks to burgeoning European political economy debates by directing
scholarsattention towards a novel and hitherto neglected strategy for export-led growth
based on internationally traded tourism services. We aimed to analyse how the process of
5
For instance, measured in terms of average hotel room rates, prices in Portugal were much lower than those in Spain,
Greece, and Italy in the early 2010s (Blanke and Chiesa, 2013, p. 440).
The Rise of Tourism-Led Growth in Europes Southern Periphery 251
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
European economic and monetary integration has provided both opportunities and con-
straints underpinning southern Europes increasing reliance on tourism-centred growth.
Through a balance of payment analysis, we have shown that southern European econo-
mies have substantially expanded their current account surpluses in the tourism services
and that the main export markets reside in the EMU core countries and the UK. Especially
after the nancial crisis, tourism exports have thus been major drivers of growth and em-
ployment creation in southern Europe.
We argue that the process of European economic and monetary integration has been a
double-edged sword, simultaneously incentivizing and forcing southern European
governments to reap their comparative advantages in the tourism industry. On the one
hand, European integration processes have created the preconditions for a boom of
intra-European travel, paving the way for southern Europes growing specialization
as Europes tourism destinations. On the other, EU state-aid prohibitions and a
hard-currency regime cum legal constraints on national budgets pre-empt southern
European countriesprevious capacity to pursue growth strategies centred on expansion-
ary scal and wage policy as well as competitive devaluations. International tourism now
provides these economies with an option for export-led growth compatible with the re-
quirements of the EMUs hard-currency regime and Europes regulatory state. Although
the EMU as a whole has moved towards a sizeable export-oriented bloc (Scharpf, 2016),
different types of export-oriented growth strategies now co-exist in Europe. Over the last
decade, the persistent surpluses of northern economies in manufacturing or high-end
services have become the mirror image of structural tourism surpluses in southern
Europe.
However, while growing tourism surpluses have partially compensated for the collapse
of domestic demand in southern Europe after the eurozone crisis, an over-reliance on in-
ternational tourism is highly problematic. First, tourism fosters a restructuring of eco-
nomic activity centred on low-skilled, low-productivity activities. It leaves southern
Europe structurally dependent on northern European tourists for growth and likely
trapped in a bad equilibrium, while northern core countries increasingly move towards
high-skilled, high value-added manufacturing and high-end services. Second, the unstop-
pable growth of global tourism comes with erce competition from developing countries,
which are easily reachable through affordable ights. These countries enjoy comparable
natural and cultural resources but have lower prices and labour standards. Unless southern
Europe upgrades its tourism offer, low-cost price competition for tourist destinations is
likely to worsen even further employment and wage conditions in its tourism industry.
Third, high CO
2
emissions of the aviation industry and the damage to local natural re-
sources are orthogonal to climate change mitigation and environmental protection.
Fourth, a tourism-led growth strategy is highly vulnerable to exogenous shocks. As the
world has faced an unprecedented global pandemic, tourism activities have been among
the most affected sectors and southern Europe has been hit disproportionally hard.
Therefore, it is crucial to gain a better understanding of the role of international tourism
within todays globalized economies. The recent literature on the political economy of
growth focused mainly on the (shrinking) manufacturing sector, high-end services, or
FDI attraction. While this focus remains legitimate, neglecting the tourism industry is
no longer possible. For better or worse, tourism has emerged as one of the worlds
fastest-growing industries and internationally traded services. Too little, if anything, is
Reto Bürgisser and Donato Di Carlo252
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
known in comparative political economy about the determinants of these secular
socio-economic transformations and their social, economic, environmental and political
consequences.
We aimed to provide a macro-level analysis of longitudinal and cross-country develop-
ments of tourism-led growth in Europe. Building on our ndings, future research should
investigate the comparative political economy of tourism and uncover the characteristics
and the socio-economic drivers of different varieties of tourism-led growth strategies in
Europe. In fact, the tourism industry has become highly diversied over time with coun-
tries specializing in different types of tourism activities (for example, educational, medi-
cal, cultural or business tourism). Such specializations differ substantially in terms of the
sophistication and the value added of the services provided as well as the institutional
complementarities and physical infrastructures required to sustain such growth strategies.
Hence, future research should analyse the different policy pillars of various
tourism-centred strategies: investment in transport infrastructure, systems of skills forma-
tion, attraction of tourism FDI, destination management organizations, and professional
services in support of the tourism industry (for example, insurance, marketing, advertise-
ment). Lastly, future research should investigate the politics of tourism-led growth in dif-
ferent countries to uncover the social coalitions underpinning governmentsdevelopmen-
tal strategies.
Acknowledgements
We would like to thank Odysseas Konstantinakos for excellent research assistance. Previous versions
of this article were presented at the Annual Conference of the Council of European Studies 2021,
the Workshop on the Political Economy of Growth in Peripheral Economies, and at seminars at
the European University Institute, University of Zurich, and the Max Planck Institute for the Study
of Societies. We are very grateful for insightful comments and feedback from Björn Bremer, Fabio
Bulfone, Loriana Crâsnic, Lukas Haffert, Anke Hassel, Martin Höpner, Philipp Kerler, Maximilian
Kiecker, Camilla Locatelli, Giorgio Malet, Valentina Petrović, Vera Šćepanović, Marco Simoni,
Wolfgang Streeck, Arianna Tassinari, Elisa Volpi, Visnja Vukov and the anonymous reviewers of
the JCMS. Open access funding provided by Universitat Zurich.
Correspondence:
Reto Bürgisser, Department of Political Science, University of Zurich, Affolternstrasse 56,
CH-8050 Zurich, Switzerland.
email: buergisser@ipz.uzh.ch
References
Afonso, A. (2019) State-led Wage Devaluation in Southern Europe in the Wake of the Eurozone
Crisis.European Journal of Political Research, Vol. 58, No. 3, pp. 93859.
Amable, B. (2003) The Diversity of Modern Capitalism (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Attström, K., Bausager, M., Nielsen, I., Leonardsen, J., Hansen, T. and Mercer, A. (2013) Study on
the Economic Impact of Short Stay Visa Facilitation on the Tourism Industry and on the Over-
all Economies of EU Member States Being Part of the Schengen Area (Luxembourg:
Publications Ofce of the European Union).
Baccaro, L. and Pontusson, H.J. (2016) Rethinking Comparative Political Economy: The Growth
Model Perspective.Politics and Society, Vol. 44, No. 2, pp. 175207.
The Rise of Tourism-Led Growth in Europes Southern Periphery 253
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Ban, C. and Adascalitei, D. (2020). The FDI-Led Growth Regimes of the East-Central and the
South-East European Periphery. CBDS Working Paper No. 2020/2.
Banca DItalia. (2018). Turismo in Italia. Numeri e potenziale di sviluppo. Bank of Italy Occa-
sional Paper No. 505.
Bianchi, R. (2018) The Political Economy of Tourism Development: A Critical Review.Annals
of Tourism Research, Vol. 70, pp. 88102.
Blake, A., Sinclair, M.T. and Soria, J.A.C. (2006) Tourism Productivity: Evidence from the
United Kingdom.Annals of Tourism Research, Vol. 33, No. 4, pp. 1099120.
Blanke, J. and Chiesa, T. (2013). The Travel and Tourism Competitiveness Report 2013. Available
at: https://reports.weforum.org/travel-and-tourism-competitiveness-report-2013
Blyth, M. (2013) Austerity: The History of a Dangerous Idea (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Bohle, D. and Regan, A. (2021) The Comparative Political Economy of Growth Models:
Explaining the Continuity of FDI-Led Growth in Ireland and Hungary.Politics and Society,
Vol. 49, No. 1, pp. 75106.
Braun, B., Di Carlo, D., Diessner, S. and Düsterhöft, M. (2021) Between Governability and
Legitimacy: The ECB and Structural Reforms.SocArXiv..https://doi.org/10.31235/osf.io/
dp3nv
Bulfone, F. and Tassinari, A. (2020) Under Pressure. Economic Constraints, Electoral Politics and
Labour Market Reforms in Southern Europe in the Decade of the Great Recession.European
Journal of Political Research, Vol. 60, No. 3, pp. 50938.
Burghouwt, G., De Leon, P.M. and De Wit, J. (2015) EU Air Transport Liberalisation Process,
Impacts and Future Considerations.International Transport Forum Discussion Paper No.
2015-04.
Burroni, L., Pavolini, E. and Regini, M. (2022) Mediterranean Capitalism Revisited (Ithaca, NY:
Cornell University Press).
Button, K. (2001) Deregulation and Liberalization of European Air Transport Markets.Innova-
tion: The European Journal of Social Science Research, Vol. 14, No. 3, pp. 25575.
Button, K. and Swann, D. (1988) European Community Airlines Deregulation and its Prob-
lems.JCMS, Vol. 27, No. 4, pp. 25982.
Cai, J., Leung, P. and Mak, J. (2006) Tourisms Forward and Backward Linkages.Journal of
Travel Research, Vol. 45, No. 1, pp. 3652.
Calderwood, L. and Soshkin, M. (2019) The Travel & Tourism Competitiveness Report 2019.
Available at: https://reports.weforum.org/travel-and-tourism-competitiveness-report-2019/
Celi, G., Ginzburg, A., Guarascio, D. and Simonazzi, A. (2017) Crisis in the European Monetary
Union: A Core-Periphery Perspective (London: Routledge).
Clancy, M.J. (1999) Tourism and Development. Evidence from Mexico.Annals of Tourism Re-
search, Vol. 26, No. 1, pp. 120.
Crouch, C. (2009) Privatised Keynesianism: An Unacknowledged Policy Regime.The British
Journal of Politics & International Relations, Vol. 11, No. 3, pp. 38299.
Crum, B. (2013) Saving the Euro at the Cost of Democracy?JCMS, Vol. 51, No. 4,
pp. 614630.
De Kadt, E.J. (1984) Tourism: Passport to Development? Perspectives on the Social and Cultural
Effects of Tourism in Developing Countries (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
De Ville, F. and Vermeiren, M. (2016) The Eurozone Crisis and the Rise of China in the Global
Monetary and Trading System: The Political Economy of an Asymmetric Shock.Comparative
European Politics, Vol. 14, No. 5, pp. 572603.
Dobson, A. (2010) Civil Aviation and European Integration: Creating the Seemingly Impossible
SEAM.JCMS, Vol. 48, No. 4, pp. 112747.
Du, D., Lew, A.A. and Ng, P.T. (2016) Tourism and Economic Growth.Journal of Travel Re-
search, Vol. 55, No. 4, pp. 45464.
Reto Bürgisser and Donato Di Carlo254
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Enderlein, H. (2006) Adjusting to EMU: The Impact of Supranational Monetary Policy on Do-
mestic Fiscal and Wage-Setting Institutions.European Union Politics, Vol. 7, No. 1,
pp. 11340.
Estol, J. and Font, X. (2016) European Tourism Policy: Its Evolution and Structure.Tourism
Management, Vol. 52, pp. 23041.
Eurofound. (2012) Employment and Industrial Relations in the Hotels and Restaurants Sector.
Available at: https://www.eurofound.europa.eu/sites/default/les/ef_les/docs/eiro/
tn1109011s/tn1109011s.pdf. Accessed 9 June 2022.
European Commission. (1985) Completing the Internal Market. White Paper from the
Commission to the European Council. Available at: https://op.europa.eu/s/whdI. Accessed 9
June 2022.
European Commission (1990) One market, one money.European Economy, Vol. 44.
European Parliament. (2015) Tourism and the European Union. Available at: https://www.
europarl.europa.eu/thinktank/en/document/EPRS_IDA(2015)568343. Accessed 9 June 2022.
Eurostat. (2014). Methodological Manual for Tourism Statistics. Available at: https://ec.europa.
eu/eurostat/documents/3859598/6454997/KS-GQ-14-013-EN-N.pdf/166605aa-c990-40c4-
b9f7-59c297154277. Accessed 9 June 2022.
Fauzel, S. and Seetanah, B. (2021) Assessing the Impact of Terrorism on African Tourism De-
mand.Tourism Analysis, Online First.
Feldstein, M. (1997) The Political Economy of the European Economic and Monetary Union.
Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 11, No. 4, pp. 2342.
Ferrera, M. (1996) The Southern modelof Welfare in Social Europe.Journal of European So-
cial Policy, Vol. 6, No. 1, pp. 1737.
Financial Times. (2021). European Tourism: With Another Lost Summer, Many Businesses Will
Disappear”’. Available at: https://www.ft.com/content/8b0f0347-d715-4bab-bc55-
a07ad4bcac49. Accessed 9 June 2022.
Frankel, J.A. and Rose, A.K. (1998) The Endogenity of the Optimum Currency Area Criteria.
The Economic Journal, Vol. 108, No. 449, pp. 100925.
Fuà, G. (1980) Problems of Lagged Development in OECD Europe: A Study of Six Countries
(Paris: OECD).
Fuller, G.W. (2018) Exporting Assets: EMU and the Financial Drivers of European Macroeco-
nomic Imbalances.New Political Economy, Vol. 23, No. 2, pp. 17491.
Gambarotto, F., Rangone, M. and Solari, S. (2019) Financialization and Deindustrialization in the
Southern European Periphery.Athens Journal of Mediterranean Studies, Vol. 5, No. 3,
pp. 15172.
Gambarotto, F. and Solari, S. (2015) The Peripheralization of Southern European
Capitalism within the EMU.Review of International Political Economy, Vol. 22, No. 4,
pp. 788812.
Hall, P. (2014) Varieties of Capitalism and the Euro Crisis.West European Politics, Vol. 37, No.
6, pp. 122343.
Hall, P. and Soskice, D. (2001) Varieties of Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Hancké, B. (2013) Unions, Central Banks, and EMU: Labour Market Institutions and Monetary
Integration in Europe (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Hassel, A. (2014). Adjustments in the Eurozone: Varieties of Capitalism and the Crisis in
Southern Europe. LEQS Paper 76.
Hassel, A. and Palier, B. (2021) Growth and Welfare in Advanced Capitalist Economies: How
Have Growth Regimes Evolved? (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Haxton, P. (2015) A Review of Effective Policies for Tourism Growth. OECD Tourism Papers,
2015/01.
The Rise of Tourism-Led Growth in Europes Southern Periphery 255
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Hodson, D. and Puetter, U. (2013) The European Union and the Economic Crisis.In
Cini, M. and Perez-Solorzano, N. (eds) European Union Politics (Oxford: Oxford Univer-
sity Press).
Hopnger, H. and Scharfenort, N. (2020) Tourism Geography of the MENA Region: Potential,
Challenges and Risks: Editorial.Zeitschrift für Tourismuswissenschaft, Vol. 12, No. 2,
pp. 13157.
Hopkin, J. and Mastropaolo, A. (2001) From Patronage to Clientelism: Comparing the Italian and
Spanish Experiences. In Piattoni, S. (ed.) Clientelism, Interests, and Democratic Representa-
tion (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), pp. 15271.
Höpner, M. and Lutter, M. (2018) The Diversity of Wage Regimes: Why the Eurozone is
too Heterogeneous for the Euro.European Political Science Review, Vol. 10, No. 1,
pp. 7196.
Höpner, M. and Schäfer, A. (2010) A New Phase of European Integration: Organized Capitalisms
in post-Ricardian Europe.West European Politics, Vol. 33, No. 2, pp. 34468.
Höpner, M., & Schäfer, A. (2012). Integration among Unequals: How the Heterogeneity of
European Varieties of Capitalism Shapes the Social and Democratic Potential of the EU.
MPIfG Discussion Paper No. 12/5.
Iversen, T., Soskice, D. and Hope, D. (2016) The Eurozone and Political Economic Institutions.
Annual Review of Political Science, Vol. 19, pp. 16385.
Johnston, A. and Regan, A. (2016) European Integration and the Incompatibility of National
Varieties of Capitalism.JCMS, Vol. 54, No. 2, pp. 31836.
Johnston, A. and Regan, A. (2018) Introduction: Is the European Union Capable of Integrating
Diverse Models of Capitalism?New Political Economy, Vol. 23, No. 2, pp. 14559.
Jones, E. (2015) Getting the Story Right: How You Should Choose between Different Interpreta-
tions of the European Crisis (and Why You Should Care).Journal of European Integration,
Vol. 37, No. 7, pp. 81732.
Jones, E. (2016) Competitiveness and the European Financial Crisis. In Caporaso, J.A. and
Rhodes, M. (eds) The Political and Economic Dynamics of the Eurozone Crisis (Oxford:
Oxford University Press), pp. 7999.
Lee, C.C. and Chang, C.P. (2008) Tourism Development and Economic Growth: A Closer Look
at Panels.Tourism Management, Vol. 29, pp. 18092.
Lew, A.A. (2011) Tourisms Role in the Global Economy.Tourism Geographies, Vol. 13, No. 1,
pp. 14851.
Lijphart, A. (1963) Tourist Trafc and Integration Potential.JCMS, Vol. 2, No. 3, pp. 25162.
Majone, G. (1994) The Rise of the Regulatory State in Europe.West European Politics, Vol. 17,
No. 3, pp. 77101.
McKinnon, R.I. (1964) Foreign Exchange Constraints in Economic Development and Efcient
Aid Allocation.The Economic Journal, Vol. 74, No. 294, pp. 388409.
McNamara, K.R., Matthijs, M. and Blyth, M. (2015) The Forgotten Problem of Embeddedness.
In Matthijs, M. and Blyth, M. (eds) The Future of the Euro (Oxford: Oxford University Press),
pp. 2143.
Merler, S. and Pisani-Ferry, J. (2012) Sudden Stops in the Euro Area.Bruegel Policy Contribu-
tion, Vol. 6, No. 12, pp. 113.
Molina, O. and Rhodes, M. (2006) Mixed Market Economies.Newsletter of the European Poli-
tics & Society Section of the American Political Science Association, Vol. 5, No. 1.
Mongelli, F.P. (2005) What is European Economic and Monetary Union Telling Us about the
Properties of Optimum Currency Areas?JCMS, Vol. 43, No. 3, pp. 60735.
Reto Bürgisser and Donato Di Carlo256
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
Nölke, A. and Vliegenthart, A. (2009) Enlarging the Varieties of Capitalism.World Politics, Vol.
61, No. 4, pp. 670702.
OECD (2011) OECD Studies on Tourism: Italy: Review of Issues and Policies (Paris: OECD).
OECD (2012) OECD Tourism Trends and Policies (Paris: OECD).
OECD (2014) OECD Tourism Trends and Policies (Paris: OECD).
Perez, S. and Matsaganis, M. (2019) Export or Perish: Can Internal Devaluation Create Enough
Good Jobs in Southern Europe?South European Society and Politics, Vol. 24, No. 2,
pp. 25985.
Pizam, A. and Smith, G. (2000) Tourism and Terrorism.Tourism Economics, Vol. 6, No. 2,
pp. 12338.
Regan, A. (2017) The Imbalance of Capitalisms in the Eurozone: Can the North and South of
Europe Converge?Comparative European Politics, Vol. 15, No. 6, pp. 96990.
Reurink, A. and Garcia-Bernardo, J. (2020) Competing for Capitals: The Great Fragmentation of
the Firm and Varieties of FDI Attraction Proles in the European Union.Review of Interna-
tional Political Economy, Vol. 28, No. 5, pp. 1274307.
Rhodes, M.J., Epstein, R. and Börzel, T.A. (2019) Introduction: Peripheries in Competition? Po-
litical and Economic Development in the EU.West European Politics, Vol. 42, No. 5,
pp. 92740.
Russett, B.M. (1970) Interdependence and Capabilities for European Cooperation.JCMS, Vol. 9,
No. 2, pp. 14350.
Scharpf, F.W. (1999) Governing in Europe (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Scharpf, F.W. (2011) Monetary Union, Fiscal Crisis and the Pre-emption of Democracy.Journal
for Comparative Government and European Policy, Vol. 9, No. 2, pp. 16398.
Scharpf, F.W. (2014) Political Legitimacy in a Non-optimal Currency Area. In Cramme, O. and
Hobolt, S.B. (eds) Democratic Politics in a European Union under Stress (Oxford: Oxford
University Press), pp. 1947.
Scharpf, F.W. (2016). Forced Structural Convergence in the Eurozone Or a Differentiated Eu-
ropean Monetary Community. MPIfG Discussion Paper No. 16/15.
Schelkle, W. (2017) The Political Economy of Monetary Solidarity: Understanding the Euro Ex-
periment (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Schmidt, V.A. (2002) The Futures of European Capitalism (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Scott, D. and Gössling, S. (2015) What Could the Next 40 Years Hold for Global Tourism?Tour-
ism Recreation Research, Vol. 40, No. 3, pp. 26985.
Shoneld, A. (1965) Modern Capitalism: The Changing Balance of Public and Private Power
(Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Simoni, M. (2020) Institutional Roots of Economic Decline: Lessons from Italy.Italian Political
Science Review/Rivista Italiana di Scienza Politica, Vol. 50, No. 3, pp. 38297.
Stockhammer, E. (2016) Neoliberal Growth Models, Monetary Union and the Euro Crisis. A
Post-Keynesian Perspective.New Political Economy, Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 36579.
Thatcher, M. (2014) From Old to New Industrial Policy via Economic Regulation.Rivista della
regolazione dei mercati, Vol. 2, pp. 622.
Tisdell, C. (1987) Tourism, the Environment and Prot.Economic Analysis and Policy, Vol. 17,
No. 1, pp. 1330.
UNCTAD (1998) International Trade in Tourism-Related Services: Issues and Options for Devel-
oping Countries (Geneva: UNCTAD).
UNWTO. (2019). Tourism in the MENA Region. Available at: https://www.e-unwto.org/doi/epdf/
10.18111/9789284420896. Accessed 9 June 2022.
The Rise of Tourism-Led Growth in Europes Southern Periphery 257
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
UNWTO. (2020). World Tourism Barometer. Available at: https://webunwto.s3.eu-west-1.
amazonaws.com/s3fs-public/2020-01/UNWTO_Barom20_01_January_excerpt.pdf. Accessed
9 June 2022.
Vernon, R. and Aharoni, Y. (2014) State-Owned Enterprise in the Western Economies (London:
Routledge).
Supporting Information
Additional supporting information may be found online in the Supporting Information
section at the end of the article.
Data S1. Supporting information.
Reto Bürgisser and Donato Di Carlo258
© 2022 The Authors. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies published by University Association for Contemporary European Studies and John Wiley & Sons
Ltd.
14685965, 2023, 1, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jcms.13368 by Readcube (Labtiva Inc.), Wiley Online Library on [15/12/2022]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
... Furthermore, the restrictions imposed on national governments as a result of EMU integration -particularly in terms of maintaining a strong currency regime and limiting fiscal and industrial policies as tools for development strategies -have left these economies with few alternatives. As a result, specialization in the tourism sector has emerged as one of the limited viable options for export-led growth that aligns with the EMU regulatory framework (Bürgisser and Di Carlo 2023;Celi et al. 2018). Bürgisser and Di Carlo (2023) contend that, following the European sovereign debt crisis, peripheral member states have relied more on international tourism for economic growth and to derive export revenues that contribute to balance current account deficits. ...
... As a result, specialization in the tourism sector has emerged as one of the limited viable options for export-led growth that aligns with the EMU regulatory framework (Bürgisser and Di Carlo 2023;Celi et al. 2018). Bürgisser and Di Carlo (2023) contend that, following the European sovereign debt crisis, peripheral member states have relied more on international tourism for economic growth and to derive export revenues that contribute to balance current account deficits. In the post-crisis era, while core member states have enjoyed current account surpluses from exporting manufactured goods or high-tech products, peripheral member states have exhibited rising surpluses in their services balance, primarily due to a surge in tourism exports, which have more than offset goods balance deficits. ...
... (retrieved from https://napsintl.com/manufacturing-in-mexico/theimmex-program-manufacturing-in-mexico/). 16 Specifically, the expansion of low-cost airlines and the ongoing political instability in North Africa following the Arab Spring (Bürgisser and Di Carlo 2023;Martins and Mamede 2022). Nadal (2007a, 2007b) investigated whether the tourism exports of Spanish territories over-specialized in tourism activities, such as the Balearic and Canary archipelagos, could act as the booming tradable sector inducing Dutch disease model spending and resource movement effects. ...
Article
This study analyzes explanations identified in the literature for the subpar economic performance of the so-called peripheral member states of the Euro Area since the mid-1990s, comparing it to those of the core, catch-up, and financial hub member states. It argues that a key factor in the peripherals’ malaise was a financial Dutch disease-like mechanism, as the adoption of the euro led to large and sustained capital inflows. This resulted in a structural shift in the productive structure of peripheral economies away from technologically advanced manufactured goods, which are characterized by higher productivity growth. Consequently, peripheral member states specialized in non-tradable sectors, and in low-technology and labor-intensive tradable goods and services sectors, which largely explains the peripherals’ low economic growth, low productivity growth, and growing macroeconomic imbalances. Furthermore, this study argues that the economic underperformance of catch-up member states can also be explained by a financial Dutch disease mechanism.
... It must be noted that not all countries in Europe that were hard hit by the 2008 GFC experienced a similar transformation. For example, in Spain-which has been classified as a wage-led growth regime until recently (Alvarez et al. 2019)-the growth policy change also accommodated exports (Bulfone andTassinari 2021, Burgisser anddi Carlo 2022) and moderate fiscal expansion (Kohler and Stockhammer 2021). This hybrid model emerged in the absence of an authoritarian intervention where the political cost of repression remained higher than redistribution. ...
... Indeed, recent findings point to the emergence of hybrid growth models in Southern Europe following the 2008 GFC(Bulfone and Tassinari 2021, Burgisser anddi Carlo 2022). ...
Article
Full-text available
This study shows that in peripheral economies that are linked into circuits of global capital on unequal terms, attempts to change the core features of an existing growth regime without broader political support intensify externally induced conflict among the ruling coalition. Under these circumstances, a transition to a new demand regime within a short time frame is more likely to take place via authoritarian intervention when the political cost of repression is lower than the cost of redistribution. In developing these points, the analysis builds on evidence from Turkey: following the 2008 global credit crunch, the Justice and Development Party's (Adalet ve Kalkinma Partisi, AKP) domestic demand-led and credit-fueled growth under dependent financialization has experienced a major crisis. However, the subsequent push to replace this regime with a profit-led model with an emphasis on exports worsened the conflict among the political coalition supporting the party as their preferences over monetary policy began to diverge. A temporary resolution of this deepening rift has been possible by way of an authoritarian intervention under R.T. Erdogan's presidential bid in 2017-18. By situating the debate on the relationship between growth regimes and political institutions, the study further unpacks the nexus between democratic backsliding, dominant social blocs, and economic growth in the periphery of Europe.
... During the last decade, there has been increasing interest within the field of comparative political economy (CPE) in the study of national growth models (Baccaro and Pontusson 2016;Stockhammer and Kohler 2022) and growth regimes (Hassel and Palier 2021). Various related topics have been analyzed, ranging from growth models' varieties across countries (Baccaro and Höpner 2022;Bürgisser and Di Carlo 2023;Schedelik et al. 2020;Vukov 2023), the economic and fiscal policies underpinning growth models (Haffert and Mertens 2021), or growth model-specific patterns of inequality (Behringer and van Treeck 2022), financialization (Ban and Helgadóttir 2022), and comparative advantages in the green transition (Driscoll 2023). ...
Research
Full-text available
Comparative political economy scholarship struggles to categorize Italy’s model of capitalism between a mixed-market economy and a hybrid, stagnant economic system. To enhance our understanding of the Italian political economy, this paper employs the analytical framework of growth regimes to study Italy’s regional economic systems. Our analysis indicates that Italy can hardly be defined as a “national growth regime” due to the presence of two diametrically opposed regional growth regimes: northern regions conform to a manufacturing-based, export-led growth regime supported by competitiveness-enhancing territorial institutions; southern regions conform to a particular variety of the consumption-led growth regime, that is, an administrative Keynesianism regime, which we theorize to typify a regime where growth and employment are systematically dependent on the state’s role as employer of last resort, the state’s consumption-enhancing social policies, and economic forbearance of labor and corporate tax regulations. The paper suggests that studying regional growth regimes is desirable when marked internal diversity in economic outcomes or productive structures exists across regions within (generally larger) countries, and when subnational governments have powers to develop their own major institutions/policies in support of regional growth regimes.
... This suggests that other explanations not included in our estimates (i.e., among our independent variables) have contributed to the surplus of balance of goods and services from 2012 to 2019 and in 2023 and to the surplus of balance of current account from 2013 to 2019 and in 2023, respectively. During that time, the greater dynamism of the tourism sector in Portugal, particularly due to the liberalisation of airlines and the consequent emergence of low-cost air companies and low-cost flights, could be one of the main reasons behind this improvement in the Portuguese external imbalances during that time(Bürgisser and Di Carlo, 2023). Third, the Portuguese external imbalances tend to be highly persistent primarily because the lagged values of the balance of goods and of the balance of goods and services exert a positive influence on the contemporaneous values of that balance. ...
Research
Full-text available
Portugal has historically displayed strong external imbalances, which have already resulted in three requests for international financial assistance from the International Monetary Fund, the European Commission and the European Central Bank. Stemming from the framework of mainstream economics literature, these institutions imposed demanding austerity measures based on internal devaluation, huge wage restraint policies and strict control on government balance in order to contain the Portuguese domestic demand and to promote Portuguese external competitiveness. Accordingly, Portuguese labour costs have registered a general decreasing trend, and government balance has substantially improved in the last four decades, but the Portuguese external imbalances remain unsolved, which suggests that we need to go beyond the conventional economic literature in order to better ascertain the right determinants of external imbalances. This paper aims to contribute to the current theoretical debate about the determinants of the external imbalances by relying on the post-Keynesian economics literature and performing a time series econometric analysis for Portugal from 1988 to 2023. Results evidence that the fall of labour costs and the surge of both stock and housing prices are the main drivers behind the Portuguese external imbalances over the last four decades.
... Services play a pivotal role in both cases. While emphasis is often placed on the specialization in low-level services linked to labor deregulation, tourism (Bürgisser & Di Carlo, 2023), and the wealth effects, high-level services also constitute a significant source of job creation. Another common feature between these economies is that construction has been a major employment driver, especially in Spain, where a speculative bubble boosted the sector excessively, resulting in significant job destruction later on. ...
Article
Full-text available
This article explores how the impact of the 2022–2023 inflationary episode was managed in Greece, and explains how labour market governance framed public policy responses. Greece resembles other southern European countries in the chronic weakness of its institutional preconditions for managing emerging inflationary pressures in a coordinated manner. Greece is also different, however, in that the previous two economic shocks had left a legacy of drastically diminished collective bargaining, financially vulnerable households and a public debt-to-GDP ratio close to 200 per cent. We show that, in a context of weakened trade unions and collective bargaining institutions, the response of wages to inflation was anaemic, while profits grew strongly, especially in oligopolistic product markets. We also discuss how, in order to ease the cost-of-living crisis, the government resorted mainly to untargeted support measures with a regressive distributional impact. We conclude by reflecting on what our findings imply for Greece’s quest for a more sustainable and more inclusive growth model.
Article
Full-text available
The return of inflation in Western economies has fueled the debate on its main drivers, bringing sector-specific shocks and supply chain bottlenecks to the forefront. Building on the seminal approach of Weber et al. (2024), this paper develops a method to assess the degree of exposure to these shocks in EU countries. Using inter-country input-output data stemming from the FIGARO database, we identify systemically significant sectors in four regions within the EU: Core, Southern Periphery, Eastern Periphery, and financial hubs. We also analyze exposure to foreign shocks. Two main conclusions can be drawn: on the one hand, periphery countries are more exposed to shocks originating in the EU core than the other way around; on the other hand, all EU regions are considerably exposed to price shocks originating from non-EU countries (namely, Russia and China). The strategic dependencies of the block pose challenges for price stability and require targeted policies.
Article
This article examines the relationship between national growth models and voters’ economic preferences. We theorise that centre-left voters are cross-pressured between a demand for higher wages and concerns about competitiveness, but the impact varies by growth model: the more a country is export-led, the more the competitiveness motive is internalised, moderating worker demands for wage increases. As a result, we expect a convergence in preferences between centre-left and centre-right voters as the reliance on export-led growth increases. We corroborate these claims through three sets of empirical analyses: a cross-sectional analysis of individual wage dissatisfaction in nineteen Western countries, a panel analysis of wage dissatisfaction in a typical export-led (Germany) and a typical consumption-led economy (UK), and an analysis of preferences for export-led growth in these two countries. Our findings contribute to the emerging literature on the politics of growth models and the waning of economic conflict in advanced capitalist democracies.
Preprint
Full-text available
The impact of international economic integration on social protection is conditional on the monetary regime. This key insight of both Polanyi and Ruggie has been neglected in the Polanyi-inspired debate on the social consequences of European integration. Focusing on the European Court of Justice and the European Commission as the supranational enforcers of the legal logic of integration, the literature has paid insufficient attention to the role of the European Central Bank (ECB) as the supranational enforcer of the economic logic of integration since monetary union. While Polanyi conceptualized central banking as an institution of non-market coordination that evolved to protect the domestic economy from gold standard pressures, the ECB has acted as an enforcer of disembedding “euro standard” pressures vis-`a-vis national labor market and welfare state institutions. Performing a mixed-methods analysis of public speeches, parliamentary hearings, central bank publications, and interviews with senior decision-makers, we provide the first comprehensive study of the ECB’s advocacy of structural reforms during the period 1999–2019. Despite lacking the mandate or the authority to override national legislation, the ECB, strategically pursuing its organizational and systemic interests, pushed for structural reforms via discursive advocacy and conditionality. Our results show that Europe’s prospects for Polanyian non-market coordination are determined by Frankfurt as much as by Luxembourg and Brussels.
Article
Full-text available
Even when subject to comparable exogenous constraints during the Eurozone crisis and in its immediate aftermath, governments in Southern Europe have pursued distinct labour market reform agendas. What room for manoeuvre did governments of crisis‐struck peripheral countries really have in shaping their labour market reform strategies, and how can we account for the observed variation? We address these questions by making a twofold contribution to the debate on the political economy of austerity in the Eurozone periphery. First, through the first systematic analysis of all labour market and collective bargaining reforms implemented in Portugal, Spain, Italy and Greece over 2009–2019, we identify those elements of core labour market deregulation common across Southern European countries (namely, the loosening of employment protection for workers on open‐ended contracts and the decentralisation of collective bargaining to the firm level); and those elements of variation, both cross‐country and cross‐party, in the content of corollary labour market interventions that accompanied this core deregulation. Second, we explain these similarities and variations in reform outcomes as the product of the interaction of two factors: economic constraints and electoral dynamics. We argue that the implementation of the common core of deregulation is linked to the exogenous pressure to improve export competitiveness to which Southern European countries have been subjected since the crisis. Through the combination of survey data analysis and qualitative evidence, we then show empirically how the variation in the corollary measures accompanying deregulation is linked to the class composition of the electoral social blocs Southern European partisan governments rely on or aim to assemble. Based on this analysis, we identify four ideal‐typical labour market reformist strategies attempted by Southern European governments during the decade of the Great Recession. The analysis highlights that although domestic politics plays a crucial role in shaping structural adjustment under crisis conditions, not all reform strategies are equally viable within the framework of Economic and Monetary Union. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved
Article
The aim of this special issue is to take a nuanced look at the political economy of development across the European Union since the financial crisis. In contrast to much of the literature on the EU since the financial crisis, which is largely concerned with macro-issues, and engages in normative critiques of EU policies, this issue focuses on multiple levels (including the micro-level of firms and banks), and the institutional make-up of member states, to restore the balance between EU, national and sub-national analysis. It also eschews normative critique. It focuses on the following two themes: the need for a more nuanced understanding of centre‒periphery relations in the EU; and the need for a closer analysis of the interaction effects between European and national/sub-national levels in explaining the crisis and understanding its impact.
Article
Many African states are relying on or have identified tourism to accelerate their growth and the continent has become the world’s second fastest growing tourist industry. However, African states have also not been spared by increasing terrorism attacks during the past decades, probably hindering the growth of this sector to certain extent. This study examines the relationship between terrorism and tourism for a sample of selected African countries over the period 1995 to 2017. Given the dynamic nature of tourism demand and the possibility of endogenous relationships in the terrorism-tourism nexus, dynamic panel data analysis, namely a Panel vector error correction model (PVECM) is employed. The results confirm that terrorism negatively affects tourism demand in Africa and this can be explained by the reactive psychology of tourists to the various aggravated terrorist attacks in the countries. Moreover, the findings show that an increase in tourism may have resulted in an increase in terrorist attacks, hence confirming a bi directional causality between tourism and terrorism.
Article
This article argues that the quiet politics of informal business-state interaction explains the political determinants of growth regimes. Building on the business power literature within the study of comparative capitalism, it shows that the noisy politics of elections often leads to changes of government but rarely to fundamental changes in the growth regime. Rather, growth models can be traced to the interactions and interests of dominant corporations within a country and its policymaking elites. The argument is developed through a comparative case study research design, using the case of foreign direct investment–led (FDI-led) growth in Ireland and Hungary. FDI-led growth regimes are a universe of cases that rely on state-led industrial and enterprise policies targeting the capital investment of foreign-owned multinational firms. Despite periods of noisy electoral politics challenging basic tenets of the FDI-led growth model in both Hungary and Ireland, the continuity of FDI-oriented growth is traced to the corporate politics of business-state elite deals.
Book
Growth and Welfare in Advanced Capitalist Economies takes stock of the major economic challenges that advanced industrial democracies have faced since the early 1990s and the responses by governments to them. It has three goals: firstly, to further our understanding of how political economies have transformed over the past decades; secondly, to analyse the contribution of governments to these changes, by looking at their growth strategies and thirdly, to highlight and analyse the role of the reforms of welfare systems in this transformative change.In a nutshell, this book maps and provides general understanding of the evolution of growth regimes in advanced capitalist countries. It identifies five main growth regimes in contemporary advanced capitalist economies (three export-led and two domestic demand-led ones). To do so the book combines a supply side approach to economic growth as advocated by the Varieties of Capitalism Literature (OUP, 2001) with a demand side perspective as the recent discussion on growth models has exemplified. It argues that all political economies consist of growth regimes, which are based on a set of institutions that shape the supply side of the economy as well as on demand drivers such as government spending and private consumption. Both supply and demand are heavily shaped by the welfare state which provides for skills through education systems and stimulates demand through high social spending and private pension funds. The book focuses on the analysis of welfare reforms as growth strategies pursued by governments in an era characterised by financialization and the rise of the knowledge economy.
Article
The countries of the MENA region cover an area with a diverse geography and a diverse tourist capital. The natural and cultural assets of the region appeal to different target groups, but have not yet been fully exploited, are not usable or have been irrevocably destroyed by unrest, uprisings, and wars. In many countries in the region, structural problems in tourism policy and the economy aggravate the situation. As a result, international tourist arrivals and income from tourist expenditures have developed differently in the various countries of the region. Using selected examples, this special issue provides a deeper but necessarily selective insight into the many facets of tourism in the countries of the MENA region and highlights at least some of the broad spectrum of phenomena associated with tourism geography. This editorial provides a framework to position the selected case studies within broader aspects of tourism development in the MENA region. It assesses the spatial differentiation of tourism supply and demand and looks at the political situation, especially since the so-called ‘Arab Spring’ and the related challenges for the tourism industry. The current effects of the so-called coronavirus crisis are not considered, as the special issue was conceived before the crisis began.
Book
Applying the new economics of organization and relational theories of the firm to the problem of understanding cross‐national variation in the political economy, this volume elaborates a new understanding of the institutional differences that characterize the ‘varieties of capitalism’ found among the developed economies. Building on a distinction between ‘liberal market economies’ and ‘coordinated market economies’, it explores the impact of these variations on economic performance and many spheres of policy‐making, including macroeconomic policy, social policy, vocational training, legal decision‐making, and international economic negotiations. The volume examines the institutional complementarities across spheres of the political economy, including labour markets, markets for corporate finance, the system of skill formation, and inter‐firm collaboration on research and development that reinforce national equilibria and give rise to comparative institutional advantages, notably in the sphere of innovation where LMEs are better placed to sponsor radical innovation and CMEs to sponsor incremental innovation. By linking managerial strategy to national institutions, the volume builds a firm‐centred comparative political economy that can be used to assess the response of firms and governments to the pressures associated with globalization. Its new perspectives on the welfare state emphasize the role of business interests and of economic systems built on general or specific skills in the development of social policy. It explores the relationship between national legal systems, as well as systems of standards setting, and the political economy. The analysis has many implications for economic policy‐making, at national and international levels, in the global age.
Chapter
This 2001 book charts the evolution of clientelist practices in several western European countries. Through the historical and comparative analysis of countries as diverse as Sweden and Greece, England and Spain, France and Italy, Iceland and the Netherlands, the authors study both the 'supply-side' - the institutional context in which party leaders devise and implement their political strategies - and the 'demand-side' - the degree of 'empowerment' of civil society - of clientelism. This approach contends that clientelism is a particular mix of particularism and universalism, in which interests are aggregated at the level of the individual and his family 'particularism', but in which all interests can potentially find expression and accommodation 'universalism'. In contrast, 'consociationalism' and 'corporatism' are systems of interest representation in which interests are aggregated at the level of 'social pillar' or the functional association 'universalism', but in which not all interests can find representation and accommodation 'particularism'.