ArticlePDF Available

The Labor Market Impacts of Technological Change: From Unbridled Enthusiasm to Qualified Optimism to Vast Uncertainty

Authors:

Figures

Cumulative percentage point changes in real mean weekly earnings of full-time, fullyear workers ages 18-64, United States, 1963-2017 Source: Autor (2019). Note: Figure uses March Current Population Survey Annual Social and Economic Supplement data for earnings years 1963 to 2017. Series correspond to percentage point changes since 1963 in (composition-adjusted) exponentiated mean real (constant $2019) log wages for each group, using data on full-time, full-year workers ages 16 to 64. Data are sorted into sex-education-experience groups of two sexes, five education categories (high school dropout, high school graduate, some college, college graduate, and post-college degree), and four potential experience categories (0-9, 10-19, 20-29, and 30-39 years). Educational categories are harmonized following the procedures in Autor et al. (2008). Log weekly wages of full-time, full-year workers are regressed in each year separately by sex on dummy variables for four education categories, a quartic in experience, three region dummies, black and other race dummies, and interactions of the experience quartic with three broad education categories (high school graduate, some college, and college plus). The (composition-adjusted) mean log wage for each of the 40 groups in a given year is the predicted log wage from these regressions evaluated for whites, living in the mean geographic region, at the relevant experience level (5, 15, 25, or 35 years depending on the experience group). Mean log wages for broader groups in each year represent weighted averages of the relevant (composition-adjusted) cell means using a fixed set of weights, equal to the mean share of total hours worked by each group over 1963-2005. All earnings numbers are deflated by the chain-weighted (implicit) Personal Consumption Expenditure price deflator and exponentiated for plotting purposes. Earnings of less than 67 per week in 1982 dollars are dropped. Allocated earnings observations are excluded in earnings years 1967 forward using either family earnings allocation flags (1967-1974) or individual earnings allocation flags (1975 earnings year forward).
… 
Content may be subject to copyright.
NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
THE LABOR MARKET IMPACTS OF TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE:
FROM UNBRIDLED ENTHUSIASM TO QUALIFIED OPTIMISM TO VAST UNCERTAINTY
David Autor
Working Paper 30074
http://www.nber.org/papers/w30074
NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
May 2022
This paper was prepared for publication by the Brookings Institution under its Global Forum on
Democracy and Technology project. I thank Daron Acemoglu, Bryan Seegmiller, Lauren Fahey,
and Zia Qureshi for thoughtful comments that improved the paper. I acknowledge financial
support from Google.org, the Hewlett Foundation, the Smith Richardson Foundation, and the
Washington Center for Equitable Growth. The views expressed herein are those of the author and
do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been
peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies
official NBER publications.
© 2022 by David Autor. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs,
may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given
to the source.
The Labor Market Impacts of Technological Change: From Unbridled Enthusiasm to Qualified
Optimism to Vast Uncertainty
David Autor
NBER Working Paper No. 30074
May 2022
JEL No. J23,J24,O33
ABSTRACT
This review considers the evolution of economic thinking on the relationship between digital
technology and inequality across four decades, encompassing four related but intellectually
distinct paradigms, which I refer to as the education race, the task polarization model, the
automation-reinstatement race, and the era of Artificial Intelligence uncertainty. The nuance of
economic understanding has improved across these epochs. Yet, traditional economic optimism
about the beneficent effects of technology for productivity and welfare has eroded as
understanding has advanced. Given this intellectual trajectory, it would be natural to forecast an
even darker horizon ahead. I refrain from doing so because forecasting the “consequences” of
technological change treats the future as a fate to be divined rather than an expedition to be
undertaken. I conclude by discussing opportunities and challenges that we collectively face in
shaping this future.
David Autor
Department of Economics, E52-438
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
77 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02139
and NBER
dautor@mit.edu
1
Introduction
Citizens in industrialized countries believe that digital technology is fostering inequality and that
this problem is likely to grow worse in the decades ahead (Smith and Anderson, 2017; Wike and
Stokes, 2018). Although public and expert opinions often diverge on economic questions, survey
data confirm that academic economists share this worry. A 2017 Chicago Booth poll found that
35 to 40 percent of leading U.S. economists believe that robots and artificial intelligence are
likely to substantially increase long- term unemployment rates.1 What is the economic basis for
this concern? In this review, I consider the evolution of economic thinking on the relationship
between digital technology and inequality across four decades, encompassing four intellectually
related but distinct paradigms.
I start from the premise that what workers earn in a market economy depends substantially,
though not exclusively, on their productivitythat is, the value they produce through their labor.
Their productivity depends in turn on two things: first, their capabilities (concretely, the tasks
they can accomplish); and second, their scarcity. The fewer workers that are available to
accomplish a given task and the more that employers need that task accomplished by workers
(rather than by, for example, machines or algorithms), the higher is the workers’ economic value
and thus their potential earnings. In conventional terms, the skill premium depends upon the
supply of skills and the demand for skills.
Stated in these terms, what is the role of technologydigital or otherwisein determining
wages and shaping wage inequality? The answer is not obvious, and the successive evolution of
thinking on this topic reflects the subtlety of the question. I present four answers below,
corresponding to four strands of thinking on this topic, and discuss the distinct implications of
each. I refer to these four paradigms as the education race, the task polarization model, the
automation-reinstatement race, and the era of Artificial Intelligence uncertainty. The nuance of
economic understanding has improved across each of these epochs. Yet, traditional economic
optimism about the beneficent effects of technology for productivity and welfare has eroded as
understanding has advanced. Given this intellectual trajectory, it would be natural to forecast an
even darker horizon ahead. I refrain from doing that, however, because forecasting the
“consequences” of technological change treats the future as a fate to be divined rather than an
expedition to be undertaken. I conclude by discussing the opportunities and the challenges we
collectively face in shaping this future.
1 See https://www.igmchicago.org/surveys/robots-and-artificial-intelligence-2/. European economists are
somewhat less pessimistic, however. See https://www.igmchicago.org/surveys/robots-and-artificial-intelligence/
2
1 The Education Race
Perhaps the most influential conceptual frame for understanding how technology shapes wage
inequality originates with a short article published in 1974 by Dutch economist and Nobel
Laureate, Jan Tinbergen (Tinbergen, 1974) and subsequently popularized by Goldin and Katz’s
magisterial book (Goldin and Katz, 2008).2 Tinbergen was intrigued by the observation that the
wages of Dutch workers with post-high school education (which he called ‘third-level’ education)
had been rising over the course of many decades despite vast increases in their supply. This
pattern is hard to rationalize in a standard competitive setting since it seemingly implies that the
demand curve for skilled labor is upward sloping.
To interpret these facts, Tinbergen offered a simple but remarkably powerful analogy.
Modern economies face an ongoing race between the demand for and supply of skill, with
technological change propelling the demand curve outward and the educational system racing
to push the supply curve outward to match it.3 In this telling, when the demand curve pulls ahead
in the race, inequality between more and less-educated workerscollege and non-college
workers in the contemporary settingrises, since more-educated workers are becoming relatively
scarce. Conversely, when the supply of college-educated workers surges, as occurred during the
1970s, for example, when American men could defer the Vietnam draft by enrolling in college
(Card and Lemieux, 2001b), earnings inequality between college and non-college workers falls.
Notably, there is no “equilibrium” quantity of education that holds inequality constant in this
framework. Rather, technologically advancing countries must keep raising educational
attainment cohort by cohort to keep pace with the moving target of rising skill demands. Or,
quoting Lewis Carroll’s Red Queen, “it takes all the running you can do, to keep in the same
place.”
Tinbergen’s metaphor of a race between education and technology, now formalized
mathematically, has proved remarkably powerful. A series of papers and books, commencing
with Katz and Murphy (1992), demonstrates that the evolution of inequality between education
groups (generally, college-educated versus non-college) in many advanced countries is
remarkably well explained by two forces: steadily rising demand for college workers, who are
needed to perform increasingly sophisticated and skill-intensive jobs (presumably, the
2 Seminal work by Robert Solow in the 1950s demonstrated that technological progress was the central force behind
rising aggregate productivity. But Solow did not consider inequality. Labor’ is an undifferentiated commodity in
the Solow-Swan model, meaning that wage inequality was not a meaningful construct in this model.
3 In Tinbergen’s words, there is a “‘race’ between the demand for skill—that is, demand for third-level manpower
driven by technological development and supply of it due to increased schooling.”
3
technological developments that Tinbergen had in mind); and booms and busts in the rate of
college attendance among young adults that affect supply.4
Figure 1, reproduced from Autor (2014), illustrates the capacity of this simple model to
rationalize the evolution of the U.S. college / high-school earnings premium over the nearly five
decades between 19632012. The model can explain both why the college premium fell during
the 1970s as the rate of college attainment was rising rapidly, and further, why the college
premium surged in the 1980s when college attainment of younger cohorts of U.S. adults
plateaued. In fact, this model can in broad brushstrokes explain the evolution of inequality
between college and non-college workers in the United States over the course of nearly two
centuries (cf. Autor et al., 2020b).
Of course, the college vs. non-college earnings premium is only one component of wage
inequality; most earnings inequality occurs among workers of the same education levels. The
data show, however, that the growth of educational earnings gaps is the predominant
contributor to rising earnings inequality over the last four decades. Specifically, Autor et al.
(2020b) estimate that the growth of education-earnings differentials explains approximately 60%
of the growth of overall earnings inequality between 1980 and 2017 and 40% of the growth
between 2000 and 2017. Hence, if we can understand the causes of rising educational earnings
inequality, we understand a lot about the sources of the overall rise in earnings inequality.
The empirical success of the education-race model raises a foundational question: what is it
about technology that raises the demand for better-educated workers? The model does not
directly address this question. Taken (too) literally, it portrays technological progress as an
autonomous force that intrinsically makes highly educated workers more productive and hence
more in demand. To be sure, researchers have added considerable nuance to this framework as
they have applied it. For example, Goldin and Katz (1998, 2008) offer theory and detailed
historical evidence that early industrial-age factories primarily demanded less-skilled workers.
But as factories adopted continuous-process methods requiring sophisticated machinery, they
increasingly demanded more educated workers with the expertise needed to operate these
sophisticated factories.5 The education race model’s simplicity is both a strength and a limitation.
The model can explain much with littlespecifically, the evolution of two centuries of
educational inequality as a function of only two factors: changes in educational supply and an
ongoing (though not directly measured) technologically-propelled increase in educational
4 This model is further developed, elaborated, and applied in Autor et al. (2020b, 2008, 1998); Card and Lemieux
(2001a); Goldin and Katz (2008); Goldin et al. (2007); Goldin and Margo (1992); Katz and Autor (1999).
5 In a related vein, Krusell et al. (2000) argue that technological change became more skill-demanding when
improvements in the quality-adjusted price of industrial equipment accelerated in the 1970s, a finding that is
refuted by Acemoglu (2002).
4
demand. The limitation is that the model lacks an underlying notion of why technology affects
skill demand. Specifying this notion is left to successor models that build on Tinbergen’s
foundation.
Figure 1: The supply of college graduates and the U.S. college/high school premium,
19632012
Source: Autor (2014).
Note: Figure uses March CPS data for earnings years 1963 to 2012. The series labeled “Measured Gap” is constructed
by calculating the mean of the natural logarithm of weekly wages for college graduates and noncollege graduates
and plotting the (exponentiated) ratio of these means for each year. This calculation holds constant the labor market
experience and gender composition within each education group. The series labeled “Predicted by Supply -Demand
Model” plots the (exponentiated) predicted values from a regression of the log college/non-college wage gap on a
quadratic polynomial in calendar years and the natural log of college/non-college relative supply. See Autor (2014)
for details.
Beyond its simplicity, another feature of the education-race model has proven conceptually
appealing but less empirically relevant. Technological change in the education-race model, as
conventionally applied, affects labor demand only by raising (i.e., augmenting) the productivity
of specific skill groups (e.g., college or non-college workers). In economic terms, this means that
technological change in the simplest education-race model is factor-augmentingit makes at
least some workers better at the work that they do. The labor market impacts of factor-
5
augmenting technological change are somewhere between benign and benevolent: benign
because no worker is made directly worse off (setting aside envy or other social externalities);
and benevolent because, under conventional assumptions, all workers benefit from
technological progress, at least to some degree.6 Thus, although technological change can raise
inequality in the education-race framework (i.e., when demand surges ahead of supply), it does
so by augmenting some workers more than otherswhich is not a terrible problem to have.
This implication of the modelthat technological change at least weakly augments every
worker’s productivity—is not well supported by the data. Figure 2, reproduced from Autor
(2019), depicts the steep rise of earnings inequality by education group. Between 1979 and 2017,
the real weekly earnings of full-time, full-year working men with a post-baccalaureate degree
rose by 43 percent, and earnings for men with a 4-year degree but no graduate study rose by 12
percent. Conversely, real earnings fell substantially among men without a four-year degree: by
10 percent among men with some-college; by 21 percent among men with exactly a high school
diploma; and by 25 percent among men without a high school diploma. (Real earnings rose
among women of all educational levels, though the increases were very modest among the least
educated women.) If the supply of non-college men and women had increased steeply in this
period, these earnings declines could be consistent with the education-race model. But in reality,
the share of working-age adults possessing less than a four-year degree dropped sharply.7 All else
equal, this should have raised the relative wage of non-college workers, yet the opposite
occurred.
Though not the standard approach, it is entirely possible to generalize the education-race
model so that technological change can either augment or replace factors. Specifically, one can
introduce factor-replacing technological change that reduces the real wages of non-college
workers by reallocating tasks from non-college to college workers (or vice versa). The task
polarization model, outlined below, provides a foundation for understanding when and why such
task reallocation might occur.
6 Formally, all workers necessarily benefit so long as capital is elastically supplied and college and non-college
workers are (at least) weakly substitutable for one another, meaning that when a skill group becomes more
productive (e.g., due to technological augmentation), employers demand more of that group. Considerable
evidence supports the assumption that college and non-college workers are substitutable in this sense. (Katz and
Autor, 1999).
7 The share of labor hours supplied by workers with high school or lower education fell from more than 75 percent
in 1963 to less than 40 percent in 2017. Conversely, the share of labor hours supplied by workers with a bachelor’s
or post-college degree rose from less than 15 percent to more than 35 percent (Autor, 2019)).
Figure 2: Cumulative percentage point changes in real mean weekly earnings of full-time, full-
year workers ages 1864, United States, 19632017
Source: Autor (2019).
Note: Figure uses March Current Population Survey Annual Social and Economic Supplement data for earnings years
1963 to 2017. Series correspond to percentage point changes since 1963 in (composition-adjusted) exponentiated
mean real (constant $2019) log wages for each group, using data on full-time, full-year workers ages 16 to 64. Data
are sorted into sex-education-experience groups of two sexes, five education categories (high school dropout, high
school graduate, some college, college graduate, and post-college degree), and four potential experience categories
(09, 1019, 2029, and 3039 years). Educational categories are harmonized following the procedures in Autor et
al. (2008). Log weekly wages of full-time, full-year workers are regressed in each year separately by sex on dummy
variables for four education categories, a quartic in experience, three region dummies, black and other race dummies,
and interactions of the experience quartic with three broad education categories (high school graduate, some college,
and college plus). The (composition-adjusted) mean log wage for each of the 40 groups in a given year is the predicted
log wage from these regressions evaluated for whites, living in the mean geographic region, at the relevant
experience level (5, 15, 25, or 35 years depending on the experience group). Mean log wages for broader groups in
each year represent weighted averages of the relevant (composition-adjusted) cell means using a fixed set of weights,
equal to the mean share of total hours worked by each group over 19632005. All earnings numbers are deflated by
the chain-weighted (implicit) Personal Consumption Expenditure price deflator and exponentiated for plotting
purposes. Earnings of less than 67 per week in 1982 dollars are dropped. Allocated earnings observations are excluded
in earnings years 1967 forward using either family earnings allocation flags (19671974) or individual earnings
allocation flags (1975 earnings year forward).
7
In short, while the rising wages of college-educated workers in the face of rising relative supply
is consistent with the education-race modelcorresponding to a case in which technology pushes
demand outward faster than supply is risingthe substantial, sustained fall in the real earnings
of non-college workers is less consistent with this model. Other factors aside from technology
may be at play, of course, such as declining unionization, falling real minimum wages, or
accelerating globalization. Nevertheless, I will argue below that technological change is at least
partly responsible, but not in a form that is easily captured in the canonical education-race model.
2 The Task-Polarization Model
Building on this conceptual foundation, a subsequent literature takes up a central question that
the education-race model leaves unanswered: why do recent waves of technology appear to
complement more-educated workers (Acemoglu and Autor, 2011; Autor et al., 2003)? In
answering this question, this research helps to explain why the real earnings of some skill groups
have fallen, even while technological change has augmented the productivity and earnings of
other skill groups. In short, this framework offers a more nuanced but less benign view on the
effects of technological change on earnings levels, inequality, and the value of skills.
The starting point of the task-polarization model (‘task model’) is to conceptualize the process
of accomplishing a job as performing a series of tasks. For example, the tasks that go into writing
a research paper might include managing a research team, collecting data, developing and testing
hypotheses, performing calculations, crafting a report, proofreading that report, and distributing
it to recipients. The second step is to ask which tasks will be carried out by machines and which
by workers. In the pre-digital era, most research and writing tasks would have been accomplished
more or less manually with human labor plus books, calculators, typewriters, and postal mail.
Human expertise would also be heavily applied to leading and managing teams, interpreting data,
forming and testing hypotheses, and writing the report.
Computerization changes this picture by reallocating many of these tasks from human tasks
to machine tasksfor example, collecting (machine-readable) data, performing calculations,
proofreading, and distributing the report. Notice that in this new division of labor, computers
accomplish a distinctive subset of tasks, those involving routine codifiable activities that can be
fully described by a set of rules and procedures, encoded in software, and carried out by non-
sentient machines. Tasks such as data gathering (from machine-readable sources), calculation,
and certain types of error-checking are well-suited for computerization because they follow
deterministic scripts. Conversely, it has proved far more challenging to program computers to
lead teams, develop and test novel hypotheses, draw robust conclusions, and write compelling
reports conveying the findings (though this is changing, more on this below). The simple reason
is that these tasks are not well described by a tightly specified scripts that machines can faithfully
8
execute to achieve successful resultsat least, not without substantial reliance on human
expertise and judgment. Accordingly, such ‘non-routine’ tasks have primarily been performed by
workers rather than machinesuntil recently (more below). Paired with computers, workers can
focus their efforts primarily on the tasks that machines cannot accomplish, which opens the
possibility for faster work, better work, or both.
This simple framing offers two refinements relative to the education-race model. First, it
embraces the reality that automation directly replaces human labor in accomplishing a subset of
taskssomething that does not happen in the canonical education-race model. An immediate
implication is that workers whose most valuable skills are collecting data, performing calculations,
proofreading documents, etc. are potentially made worse off because computers directly
substitute for their skills. Concretely, because the real cost of symbolic processing (i.e., what
computers do) has been falling by double-digits annually for decades (Nordhaus, 2007), what
workers can now earn by carrying out these once well-remunerated but now fully automated
information processing tasks is essentially zero.8.
A second strength of the task framework is that it offers a plausible explanation for why
computerization seems to complement more educated workers. Observe that in the paper-
writing example above, many of the tasks that are not computerized would be considered high-
skill tasks: leading a team, forming a hypothesis, crafting a paper, etc. These “non-routine
cognitive” abstract-reasoning (expert judgment, creativity) and interpersonal (leadership,
management) tasks have proven hard to automate because, simply put, we don’t know “the
rules.” As the philosopher Michael Polanyi observed, “We know more than we can tell” (Polanyi
and Sen, 1966), meaning that there are many things that we regularly accomplishriding a
bicycle, making a compelling argument, recognizing a current friend’s face in their baby
photographthat we understand tacitly but not explicitly how to do. People can achieve mastery
through tacit knowledge because they learn by doing. A child doesn’t need to read up on the
physics of gyroscopes to learn how to ride a bicyclesimple trial and error will do it. For a
computer program to successfully accomplish a task, however, the computer programmer must
usually specify all the relevant steps, branches, and exceptions in advance. For this reason,
non-routine abstract-reasoning and interpersonal communication tasks have remained largely
out of reach for machines (again, until recently).
The argument goes one step further: not only are abstract-reasoning and communication
tasks not substituted by computers, they are generally complemented. The productivity and
8 Concretely, there is no positive price at which an employer would hire someone to add columns of numbers, route
telephone calls between exchanges, or look up the current trading price of a group of stocksyet, these tasks used
to comprise many full-time jobs (see Feigenbaum and Gross (2020) on the elimination of telephone operators by
mechanical and then digital switching).
9
earnings power of workers who specialize in abstract reasoning, expert judgment, and
interpersonal interactions and leadership rises as the inputs into their workinformation access,
analysis, and communicationbecomes less expensive and more productive. Thus,
computerization increases the productivity of better-educated workers whose jobs rely on
information, calculation, problem-solving, and communication, e.g., doctors, architects,
researchers, and stock analysts. But this is a double-edged sword: computerization increases the
productivity of highly educated workers by displacing the tasks of the middle-skill workers who in
many cases previously provided these information-gathering, organizational, and calculation
tasks (e.g., sales workers, office workers, administrative support workers, and assembly line
production workers).
However, not all tasks that are hard to automate would be classified as high-skill tasks. Tasks
such as waiting tables, cleaning rooms, picking and boxing items, or assisting elderly people to
perform acts of daily living, require dexterity, sightedness, simple communications, and common
sense, all of which draw on substantial reservoirs of tacit knowledge.9 Such tasks are commonly
found in personal services jobs, e.g., food service, cleaning, security, entertainment, recreation,
and personal care. Computerization has generally not substituted for workers in performing such
jobs. But neither has it strongly complemented them. Rather, it leaves this work largely
untouched, neither automating the central tasks of this job nor augmenting the workers doing it.
Moreover, because a large fraction of adults can, with modest training, perform the core tasks of
many non-routine manual jobs, such jobs will generally not pay high wages even when demand
is rising, except when the labor market is very tight (as is presently the case).
There is now a vast literature testing the task framework empirically, extending it
theoretically, and of course, critiquing it vigorously (Acemoglu and Autor, 2011; Acemoglu and
Restrepo, 2021; Autor and Dorn, 2013; Autor et al., 2006; Deming, 2017; Goos and Manning,
2007; Goos et al., 2009, 2014; Gregory et al., 2021; Harrigan et al., 2021; Levy and Murnane, 2004;
and Michaels et al., 2014). A central implication of this framework, one that receives ample
empirical support, is that across firms, industries, and countries, computerization spurs a
‘polarization’ of job growth into traditionally high-wage and traditionally low-wage occupations
at the expense of the middle tier. We see this clearly in the U.S. data: at the high end of the labor
market, a growing cadre of high-education, high-wage occupations offer strong career prospects,
rising lifetime earnings, and significant employment security. At the other end, low-education,
low-wage occupations, often in personal services, provide little economic security and limited
career earnings growth. Traditional middle-tier jobs in production, operative, clerical and
administrative support, and sales are in decline. Figure 3, reproduced from Autor (2019),
9 A hotel employee cleaning a guest room must determine which items are personal and which are trash. A soda can
found on the floor is likely trash; a similarly situated perfume bottle likely fell there by accident.
10
documents this pattern for the United States. Figure 4 shows an analogous pattern in European
data over a shorter time period (Goos et al., 2014).10
Figure 3: Percent changes in occupational employment shares among working-age adults,
United States, 19702016
Source: Autor (2019)
Note: Data source is as in Figure 2. Sample consists of all persons aged 16 to 64 who reported having worked at least
one week in the earnings years, excluding those in the military. For each individual, hours worked are the product of
usual hours worked per week and the number of weeks worked last year. Individual hours worked are aggregated
using CPS sampling weights. Occupational classifications are harmonized following Dorn (2009), and updated
through 2017.
10 Polarization does not, however, describe the experience of developing countries, where the skill levels associated
with different tasks are quite different and computerization is less pervasive and still relatively expensive in
comparison with human labor (Maloney and Molina, 2016).
11
Figure 4: Change in occupational employment shares in European Union Countries,
19932010
Source: Goos et al. (2014).
The evidence on occupational change is clear. The implications of the task framework for
wages are, however, more nuanced. For highly educated workers, those performing non-routine
analytic and interpersonal tasks, the task framework unambiguously predicts higher earnings. By
the same logic, one might surmise that wages in middle-skill routine-task-intensive occupations
should fall while wages in lower-skill service occupations should remain unaffected. This can
occur, but the prediction is ambiguous. The reason why is that when wages in middle-skill
occupations fall, workers who would otherwise do those jobs will tend to enter previously lower-
paid service occupations, thus placing downward pressure on wages in those occupations as
well.11 Thus, while the task model unambiguously predicts the U-shaped pattern of occupational
growth seen in Figures 3 and 4, it is formally ambiguous as to whether this also leads to a U-
shaped pattern of wage growth (Autor and Dorn, 2013; Böhm, 2020; Böhm et al., 2019).
11 Some workers will also transition into higher-paid occupations. However, degree and credential requirements for
these occupations (e.g., law degree, medical degree, engineering certification) will constrain rapid entry.
12
Figure 5: Exposure to task displacement and changes in real wages by demographic group,
United States, 19802016 and 19501980
Source: Acemoglu and Restrepo (2021).
Note: Each marker corresponds to one of 500 demographic groups, defined by gender, age, education, race, and
native/immigrant status. Marker sizes indicate the share of hours worked by each group and different colors indicate
education levels.
Recent work by Acemoglu and Restrepo (2021) makes progress on this empirical challenge by
taking a fresh approach to measuring wage impacts.12 Rather than studying wage changes in the
occupations that workers do at present, they instead study the exposure of different demographic
groups to displacement of routine tasks according to the industries and occupations in which
these groups worked in 1980, before polarization got underway. The simple idea is that if workers
of given education, age, gender, and race/ethnicity tended to work in routine-task-intensive jobs
in 1980 (e.g., production occupations, clerical occupations), and the industries that employ them
apply computers to automate those tasks, then the onset and evolution of widespread
computerization over the ensuing decades would be expected to place downward pressure on
their earnings. Evidence for this mechanism is seen in Figure 5, which reports a striking downward
sloping relationship between exposure to routine task replacement in 1980 and changes in wages
by demographic group between 1980 and 2016 (panel A). Equally striking is that this downward-
sloping relationship is not present in the three prior decades, as shown in Panel B. This adds to
the case that the negative relationship in Panel A reflects the adverse effect of routine-task
displacement on the earnings of workers who, in earlier decades, tended to specialize in routine-
task-intensive jobs.
12 Kogan et al. (2021) develop an alternative approach to assessing wage impacts by exploiting panel data on the
evolution of earnings among individual workers whose occupations are exposed to automation technologies.
13
Notice, however, that this evidence does not imply that most workers are harmed by
computerization. For example, in panel A of Figure 5, only a subset of workersthose most
exposed to task displacementappear to have lost ground (in real earnings terms) between 1980
and 2016. This subset is almost entirely made up of workers with high school or lower education,
consistent with the evidence in Figure 2 that real wages of non-college workers have stagnated
or fallen over the last four decades.13 For the majority of workers, however, real earnings growth
was positive in these decades, reflecting in part the productivity gains emanating from
computerization (though many other factors are at play).
The task model thus underscores that technological change, like most economic
transformations, creates both winners and losers. Akin to the education-race model, the task
model also implies that computerization has contributed to rising inequality. Unlike the
education-race framework, however, the task framework further implies that a substantial
component of this effect stems from the adverse impacts of technological change on the earnings
of less-educated workers rather than (exclusively) the positive effect of factor-augmentation on
the earnings of high-skill workers. How large is that contribution? Acemoglu and Restrepo (2021)
estimate that 50% to 70% of the increase in earnings inequality between education, sex, race, and
age groups during 1980 through 2016and the entirety of the fall in real wages of men without
high schoolare due to the adverse effects of automation on worker groups that were initially
more specialized in routine task-intensive work.
3 New Work and Task Reinstatement
An important limitation of the task framework in its basic form is that it conceptualizes the set of
tasks as static—meaning that none are added or subtracted, it’s only their allocation between
workers and machines that shifts as technology and education evolve. This is a convenient fiction,
but it has significant downsides. First, casual empiricism suggests that work is continually
evolving, with demands for new skills and expertise that were previously unimagined (e.g., drone
pilots, artificial intelligence programmers, vegan chefs, and executive coaches). Second, if the set
of tasks were truly static, then it seems likely that advancing automation would inexorably crowd
humans into an ever-diminishing subset of tasks, perhaps finally making human labor altogether
obsolete, as envisioned by Susskind (2020). While one should not categorically exclude the
possibility that this could occur, it does not accurately reflect the last century of technological
13 In a similar vein, Autor (2019) shows that the polarization of occupational structure primarily reflects the
movement of non-college workers out of middle-skill occupations and into traditionally low-paid services. College-
educated workers remain highly concentrated in professional, technical, and managerial occupations.
14
change, during which the world of work has grown more complex, varied, and intellectually
interesting (Autor, 2015).
An ingenious 2011 paper by Jeffrey Lin brings concrete evidence to these informal
observations (Lin, 2011). Using historical Census documents from 1965 through 2000, Lin shows
that the Census Bureau regularly captures novel job titles based on the occupational descriptions
that survey respondents supply on their Census forms. While many of these novel write-ins are,
of course, simply idiosyncratic descriptions or misspellings, the Census Bureau filters out the chaff
to identify bona fide new job titles, reported by a significant number of Census respondents. Lin’s
work makes two contributions: first, it provides representative evidence on the appearance of
‘new work’; second, if offers a methodology for systematically capturing new work hiding in plain
sight in the Census Bureau’s existing data infrastructure.
What precisely is new work? Table 1, drawn from Autor et al. (2021b), list examples of new
titles added to the Census Bureau’s internal occupational classification manual in each decade
between 1940 and 2018.14 The left-hand column reveals, as intuition would suggest, that many
new titlessuch as textile chemists (added in 1960) or controllers of remotely piloted vehicles
(added in 1980)involve operating, installing, maintaining, integrating, or selling new
technologies. While technology-related new titles are commonplace, just as prevalent are new
titles that do not relate to a technological innovation but instead reflect changing tastes, incomes,
and demographics (right-hand column). For example, beauticians (added in 1950),
hypnotherapists (added in 1980), and sommeliers (added in 2000) provide specialized services.
Surely, many new ‘gig’ titles will soon enter this list of titles: on-demand personal driver (Uber
and Lyft); warehouse pick worker (Amazon); and on-demand shopper (Instacart), among others.
How does new work relate to the task-polarization framework elaborated above? Building on
Lin’s observations, Acemoglu and Restrepo (2018b) fuse the notion of new work (more precisely,
new tasks) into the canonical task model. In their extended framework, automation displaces
workers from existing job tasks as before; but now, new task creation potentially ‘reinstates’
demand for workers by generating new tasks that require human expertise.15 Thus, akin to the
education-race model, the competing forces of task automation and task displacement determine
the net effect of technological change on labor demand: if automation outpaces reinstatement,
labor demand falls; and conversely, if reinstatement outpaces automation, labor demand rises.16
14 New titles introduced in a given decade, say 1940, correspond to those captured by the Census Bureau in the
preceding decade, i.e., between 1931 and 1940.
15 While in the long run, these tasks may also be automated, it appears plausible that many novel activities are first
accomplished and perfected by workers before they are subsequently routinized and automated.
16 This explanation oversimplifies for brevity. The net effect of automation and reinstatement depends not only on
the relative speed of these forces but also their impact on aggregate labor demand through the productivity growth
channel. Automation can raise labor demand even while displacing worker tasks if the resulting productivity boost
15
YEAR
EXAMPLE OF TITLES ADDED
1940
Automatic welding machine operator
Gambling dealer
1950
Airplane designer
Beautician
1960
Textile chemist
Pageants director
1970
Engineer computer application
Mental-health counselor
1980
Controller, remotely piloted vehicle
Hypnotherapist
1990
Certified medical technician
Conference planner
2000
Artificial intelligence specialist
Chat room host/monitor
2010
Wind turbine technician
Sommelier
2018
Pediatric vascular surgeon
Drama therapist
Table 1: Examples of new occupational titles added to the U.S. Census Bureau’s
Classified Index of Occupations between 1940 and 2018 Source:
Autor et al. (2021b).
Of course, knowing that old work is being automated and new work is being created does not
tell us which effect dominates in net, which occupations or skill groups are most positively or
negatively affected, and what underlying forces guide this process. Evidence is now emerging on
these questions, though much more is needed. Employing an indirect measure of task change
based on changes in labor’s share of income by industry, Acemoglu and Restrepo (2019) conduct
a macroeconomic analysis of task displacement and task reinstatement for two long time
intervals, 19501987 and 19872017. Their analysis suggests that these two forcesautomation
and task reinstatementwere roughly in balance in the first time interval of 19501987, but that
automation subsequently outpaced task reinstatement in the second time interval of 19872017,
which is consistent with labor’s falling share of national income occurring simultaneously (Autor
et al., 2020a; Karabarbounis and Neiman, 2014).17
raises demand sufficiently to offset employment losses due to task displacement. Logically, the impacts of
automation and reinstatement may differ by skill group, as explored in Acemoglu and Restrepo (2021) and Autor
et al. (2021b).
17 Acemoglu and Restrepo (2018b) offer a general theory of new work creation based on changes in the relative price
of capital and labor, where declines in the price of labor spur labor-using innovations (and hence task
16
To analyze representative evidence over a substantial time horizon, Autor et al. (2021b) build
on the approach pioneered by Lin (2011) to analyze data on new work creation in eight decades
of U.S. data from 1940 through 2018. These data suggest that new work is quantitatively
important. Autor et al. (2021b) estimate that more than 60% of employment in 2018 was found
in job titles that did not exist in 1940, as shown in Figure 6.18 The introduction of new work,
however, is not uniform across skill groups. Between 1940 and 1980, most new work that
employed non-college workers was found in construction, transportation, production, clerical,
and sales jobswhich are squarely middle-skill occupations. In the subsequent four decades
(19802018), however, the locus of new work creation for non-college workers shifted away from
these middle-tier occupations and towards traditionally lower-paid personal services. Conversely,
new work creation employing college-educated workers became increasingly concentrated in
professional, technical, and managerial occupations. In combination, these patterns indicate that
new work creation has polarized, mirroring (and in part driving) the aggregate polarization of
employment seen in Figure 3.
What explains the shifting locus of new work creation across occupations and skill groups
during these decades? Autor et al. (2021b) document three critical forces. One is the introduction
of automation innovations. Building on foundational work by Kogan et al. (2021) and Webb
(2020), they document that automation innovations erode employment in occupations that are
most exposed to them. But not all technological innovations are directed at automation. Using
U.S. utility patent data, Autor et al. (2021b) develop a method to distinguish among innovations
that automate the tasks that workers supply versus those that augment the outputs or services
that their work generates. For example, the introduction of photocopying would constitute an
automation innovation since it replaces the labor inputs of workers who previously duplicated
documents using more cumbersome means (e.g., carbon paper). Conversely, the introduction of
an electronic workbook for performing calculations (i.e., a spreadsheet) would constitute an
augmentation innovation since it enhances the services provided by financial analysts, allowing
them to conduct faster and deeper analyses.19 In contrast to the role of automation technologies,
Autor et al. (2021b) document that augmentation innovations spur employment growth in the
reinstatement) and, conversely, declines in the price of capital spur capital-using automation innovations (and
hence task displacement).
18 Using data from Lin (2011), Acemoglu and Restrepo (2018b) estimate a similar fraction of employment in new work
for the shorter time interval of 1980 to 2015.
19 This example also highlights that many innovations contain elements of both automation and augmentation. The
spreadsheet was surely an augmentation innovation for analysts, but it might also have been an automation
innovation for routine bookkeepers.
17
occupations most exposed to them. Given that many occupations are simultaneously exposed to
both augmentation and automation innovations, this finding is particularly striking.20
Figure 6: More than 60% of jobs done in the United States in 2018 had not yet been “invented”
in 1940
Source: Autor et al. (2022).
Note: This figure compares the distribution of employment in 1940 and 2018 across all major occupations,
distinguishing between employment in new job titles added between 1940 and 2018 versus job titles that were
present in 1940.
Alongside these two faces of innovationautomation and augmentationAutor et al.
(2021b) analyze a third factor affecting new work creation: demand and supply forces that directly
shape when and where new work emerges. When occupations are exposed to adverse demand
20 Mann and Püttman (2021) find that automation technology has a net positive effect on employment in local labor
markets, driven by job growth in the service sector. Conversely, Komlos (2016) conjectures that the forces of
creative destruction have become more destructive, leading to smaller net contributions to GDP and labor demand.
18
shocks, for example, the contraction of manufacturing employment in the United States in the
face of the China trade shock of the 1990s and 2000s (Autor et al., 2021a), not only does
employment contract but the pace of introduction of new occupational titles slows. Conversely,
when demand for an occupation expands, as for example has occurred in many personal care and
healthcare occupations in the face of population aging, employment rises and the pace of new
work introduction accelerates.
While much remains to be understood about the potential of new work creation to temper
the task-eroding consequences of automation, it is clear that new work plays a critical role in
shaping and tempering the long-run consequences of technological change for labor demand.
4 The Present Era of Artificial Intelligence Uncertainty
The task framework outlined above is well-suited to understanding the economic consequences
of the last four decades of advancing digital computing. But how well does it fit the current era of
Artificial Intelligence (AI)? Does AI fundamentally change the relationship between technological
change, labor demand, and inequalityand if so, how do we characterize these changes
analytically? The task framework provides a natural starting point both for considering what AI
may do, and for understanding how AI differs from the technologies that preceded it.
The task framework encompasses two conceptual pieces. One is the notion of ‘tasks’ as units
of work that can be accomplished by workers, machines, or potentially by service providers in
other countries (see Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg (2008)). The second is a specific
characterization of what tasks computers can accomplishin particular, routine tasks in the
terminology of Autor et al. (2003). What makes a task routine is that it follows an explicit, fully
specified set of rules and procedures. Tasks fitting this description can in many cases be codified
in computer software and executed by machines. Conversely, tasks that rely on what Polanyi and
Sen (1966) called ‘tacit’ knowledge (e.g., riding a bicycle, telling a clever joke) have historically
been challenging to program because the explicit steps for accomplishing these tasks are often
not formally known.
Artificial intelligence overturns the second piece of the task frameworkspecifically, the
stipulation that computers can accomplish only explicitly understood (i.e., ‘routine’) tasks. AI tools
surmount this longstanding constraint because they can be used to infer tacit relationships that
are not fully specified by underlying software. For example, it is extraordinarily challenging to
explicitly define what makes a chair a chair: must it have legs, and if so, how many; must it have
a back; what range of heights is acceptable; must it be comfortable; and what makes a chair
comfortable, anyway? Writing the rules for this problem is maddening. If written too narrowly,
they will exclude stools and rocking chairs. If written too broadly, they will include tables and
19
countertops. In a well-known paper, (Grabner et al., 2011) argue that the fundamental problem
is that what makes a chair a chair is its suitability for sitting upon. But what makes something
“suitable” for sitting is as elusive as the original problem. Given this morass, this chair
classification task would be categorized as ’non-routine’ for purposes of conventional
computinga human task rather than a machine task.
Fast forward to the present and AI can now ‘solve’ this classification problem. It does not solve
it by following explicit rules, however. Instead, it learns the solution inductively by training on
examples. Given a suitable database of tagged images and sufficient processing power, AI can
infer what image attributes are statistically associated with the label “chair” and can then use
that information to classify untagged images of chairs with a high degree of accuracy (Brynjolfsson
and Mitchell, 2017; Brynjolfsson et al., 2018). What rules does AI use for this classification? In
general, we do not know because the rules remain tacit. Nowhere in the learning process does AI
formally codify or reveal the underlying features (i.e., rules) that constitute “chair-ness”. Rather,
the classification decision emerges from layers of learned statistical associations with no human-
interpretable window into that decision-making process.21 And herein lies an irony: Polanyi’s
paradox survives the paradigm shift in computing, but with a twist. In the pre-AI era,
programmers struggled to imbue computers with the tacit knowledge needed for accomplishing
non-routine tasks; in the present AI-era, computers can readily acquire this tacit knowledge, but
they cannot (in almost all cases) communicate that knowledge explicitly to people. That is,
computers now know more than they can tell us.22
Returning to the task model, how does the relaxation of the tacit knowledge constraint affect
our predictions of what machines and people will do in the future? One potential answer is that
the task model is now irrelevant given that machines are increasingly capable of accomplishing
non-routine tasks.23 An alternative answer is that the task model remains conceptually and
empirically valuable because it provides an analytic tool for rigorously studying the interactions
between human and machine capabilities in accomplishing work (Acemoglu and Restrepo, 2018a;
Autor, 2013)though it makes fewer crisp predictions about what tasks are likely to be
automated in the years ahead. I see three questions as particularly relevant:
Looking through the lens of the task framework, what work tasks will AI prove capable of
accomplishing in the years (and decades) ahead? AI’s applicability is in my assessment
21 Schematically, AI learns by adjusting connection weights among layers of (virtual) nodes on an information
network. The representation of the decision-making process in this network has essentially no relationship to the
formal structure of the problem as a human would understand it.
22 The field of explainable AI seeks to make the tacit knowledge acquired by AI explicit. See, for example,
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Explainable_artificial_intelligence.
23 See Bresnahan (2021) for a strident argument that the task model is irrelevant in the AI era, and perhaps was
irrelevant in all prior eras.
20
sufficiently vast that I find it harder to say what AI cannot do than what it can and will do.24
It is commonly argued, for example, that because AI is blissfully unaware of the rich context
of many real-world problems, it cannot accomplish the high-stakes, multifaceted decision
tasks that humans regularly undertake in their work. This argument would be convincing if
humans were highly effective and reliable at making such decisions. But the evidence
strongly suggests that they are not (Kahneman et al., 2021).
Second, what new demands for human skills and capabilities will emerge as AI displaces a
growing set of traditional human work tasks? As per the discussion above, I am certain that
such new work tasks will emerge, and that many forms of human capability and expertise
will become newly valuable. Because technological advances have always generated new
demands for human specialization, as have rising societal wealth and ongoing changes in
norms, tastes, and institutions, I do not foresee a moment when labor scarcity (and hence,
labor income) is eliminated. Simultaneously, many currently valuable human capabilities
will eventually be rendered obsolete. This will be costly for many and disruptive for society
in general. These disruptions are also characteristic of technological upheavals, but
because of the rapidity with which AI is evolving, they may be particularly acute.
Third, while the task framework offers a useful starting point for analyzing the impact of AI
on labor markets and inequality, it is unlikely to be encompassing enough to reflect all
relevant labor market impacts of AI. And it is certainly insufficient to capture many of the
broader societal impacts. How do we get a fuller analytical grasp on the terrain ahead?
Works by Agrawal et al. (2018), Bresnahan (2021), and Korinek and Stiglitz (2018) offer
different lenses on these questions that bring different issues into focus. We are only at
the start of the intellectual journey to understand AI’s implications for work and inequality,
so it would be premature to proclaim that we’ve already found the most promising route
to that destination.
A small but rapidly growing literature that includes Babina et al. (2020), Brynjolfsson and
Mitchell (2017), Brynjolfsson et al. (2018), Felten et al. (2018, 2019), and Webb (2020) applies a
task approach to analyze the labor market impacts of AI adoption.25 These recent papers make an
important break with prior task-based studies. Earlier incarnations of this literature often focused
specifically on whether routine tasks were substituted by computers and non-routine tasks were
complemented. Thus, they applied both the general task framework and the specific
characterization of the intrinsic capabilities and limitations of procedural computing supplied by
24 See Marcus and Davis (2019) for a counterargument.
25 Though not specifically focused on AI, recent papers by Atalay et al. (2020) and Deming and Noray (2020) present
novel, closely related analyses.
21
Autor et al. (2003). In contrast, recent works studying the labor market impacts of AI apply the
task framework generally but do not for the most part characterize analytically precisely what AI
can dowhich makes sense because such a characterization remains elusive.26 Instead, these
papers develop or apply expert or crowd-sourced assessments of the tasks for which AI is
currently suitable to determine which tasks, occupations, firms, and industries are most AI-
exposed.
Figure 7: U.S. establishments whose task structures in 2010 were more suitable for AI
subsequently posted relatively more AI vacancies between 2010 and 2018
Source: Acemoglu et al. (2022a).
Note: This figure shows the relationship between establishment-level AI exposure in 2010, computed using the Felten
et al. (2018) method, and establishments subsequent increase in posting of job positions requiring AI skills between
2010 and 2018. The solid line corresponds to a regression with 2010 establishment vacancies as the weight. Each bin
represents about 50,000 establishments. Point estimates and standard errors are reported at the bottom of the
figure. This analysis excludes vacancies in AI-producing sectors of the economy, specifically Information (NAICS code
51) and Business Services (NAICS code 54).
26 Qualifying these generalizations, Brynjolfsson and Mitchell (2017) and Brynjolfsson et al. (2018) offer a rubric for
assessing the suitability of job tasks to machine learning (their SML index), while Agrawal et al. (2018) offer a formal
characterization of what tasks AI accomplishes. Specifically, they argue that AI is essentially a prediction machine
a tool that forecasts the immediate (or long-term) future based on past inputs.
-20 -10 0 10 20
-2 -1 0 1 2
Establishment AI Exposure in 2010 (Felten et al Measure)
Coefficient is 9.19, SE is 1.21, regressor is standardized
Growth of AI Vacancies (%)
22
Acemoglu et al. (2022a) offer one recent example. This study uses establishment-level job
vacancy postings from the online job-posting aggregator Burning Glass Technologies to assess the
impacts of recent AI adoption on the demand for workers who perform non-AI jobs. For this
analysis, the study defines “AI jobsas those that advertise specific expertise requirements in
contemporary AI tools.27 Conversely, non-AI jobs are the (vast) remainder that do not demand AI-
specific skills but nevertheless may be affected by it. This could include a whole range of jobs,
from financial analysts, to pharmacists, to pilots, to warehouse managers. Drawing on AI-
suitability indexes developed by Brynjolfsson et al. (2018), Felten et al. (2018), and Webb (2020),
the paper first predicts which establishments are likely to adopt AI as a function of the suitability
of their job task structures (visible in job postings) in the pre-AI era. Consistent with this
prediction, the paper documents that establishments whose occupational structures in 2010
made them suitable for AI did in fact differentially increase posting of vacancies for workers with
AI skills as AI took off between 2010 and 2018, as is shown in Figure 7.
With these predictions in hand, Acemoglu et al. (2022a) explore whether AI adoption (spurred
by AI-suitability) is affecting hiring in non-AI jobs. The answer is a qualified yes. They find that as
AI-exposed establishments adopted AI between 2010 and 2018 (particularly after 2014), they
differentially changed their mix of job skill requirements in non-AI positionssuggesting that non-
AI job tasks were affectedand modestly reduced hiring in non-AI positions simultaneously. This
evidence confirms that AI’s imprint can already be seen at the firms and establishments whose
preexisting task structures make them more suitable for using AI. Yet, Acemoglu et al. (2022a)
find that AI is not so far having detectable labor market impacts at the aggregate occupation or
industry level, though such affects appear likely in the future. In net, these conclusions are
evocative but not dramatic; they hint at potential aggregate effects of AI but do not so far confirm
them.
Aggregate effects is a pregnant phrase: what might those effects be? Here, I speculate:
1. One such aggregate effect is that further improvements in AI’s capabilities may accelerate the
process of task automation relative to task augmentation. Broadly, this will mean that labor’s
share of national income will decline further, beyond what has already occurred over the last
two decades as documented in Autor et al. 2020a, and, concomitantly, the share of national
income paid to owners of capital (i.e., machines, robots, algorithms, etc.) will grow. Ironically,
this process of aggregate labor displacement can occur without any reduction in wage
inequality among workersor with wage inequality rising even further. Specifically, all
27 Examples include Machine Learning, Computer Vision, Machine Vision, Deep Learning, Virtual Agents, Image
Recognition, Natural Language Processing, Speech Recognition, Pattern Recognition, Object Recognition, and
Neural Networks, among many others.
23
workers could get a smaller slice of the aggregate economic pie while the proportional
difference among those slices remained just as pronounced. This fall in labor’s share of
national income does not, however, necessarily imply that employment will fall. So as long as
people need to work for a living, falling wages do not preclude stable or rising employment.28
Additionally, a fall in the labor share does not necessarily mean a decline in wages; the same
capabilities that make AI labor-displacing could in theory generate sufficient productivity
growth that average wages would rise even as labor’s share of national income falls. In this
case, the size of the pie grows faster than labor’s share of that pie shrinks. Nevertheless, a fall
in labor’s share of national income is problematic, the simple reason being that the ownership
of capital is far more concentrated than the ownership of labor (i.e., absent coercion, each
person owns only their own labor). Thus, a substantial fall in labor’s share of national income
implies a dramatic rise in income inequalitythat is, wage plus non-wage incomeeven
absent a change in wage inequality.
2. A second scenariowhich could in theory co-occur with the one aboveis that, spurred by
advancing AI, the twin forces of task-automation and task-augmentation reshape the set of
tasks (and associated worker skills) that are complemented and substituted by technologies.
While the last four decades of conventional computing capabilities have fomented
occupational polarization and rising wage inequality, this need not be true going forward, or
at least not to the same degree. It is a near-certainty that AI will increasingly be deployed to
accomplish mid- and high-level decision-making tasks that have historically been performed
by managers and professionals. This is already occurring in finance and investing, inventory
management, credit issuance, fraud detection, and even some fields of design. An expanding
set of these expert and semi-expert tasks will almost surely become technologically
equivalent to the “routine tasks” of earlier years: equally well accomplished by machines, and
with greater rapidity and at lower cost. Accordingly, it is possible that even those with
moderately high levels of educational attainmentthose, for example, with a BA but no post-
graduate degreewill find that their primary work tasks are increasingly substituted by AI.
That some of their tasks are substituted does mean that these workers’ skills are necessarily
devalued. It is in part by displacing a subset of human tasks that, in many cases, automation
makes the remaining set of worker tasks more valuable. (Imagine the value of a statistician
stripped of her computer or a construction crew denied use of power tools.) Whether
workers’ skills are complemented or substituted by new technologies depends in part on their
28 For those skeptical of this point, note that employment rates are generally higher in poor than rich countries and
that hours worked per capita tend to fall among both men and women as countries become wealthier (Bick et al.
2018).
24
ability to adapt to changing task demands. Economists have long understood that education
makes people better at adapting to, and capitalizing on, novel circumstances (Schultz, 1975).
But this resilience is not guaranteed. At the turn of the twentieth century, high school
graduates were an elite education group who commanded substantial premia as bookkeepers
and clerks. In essence, they were the leading “information technology” of big business in that
era (Goldin and Katz, 2008). Today, however, there is little difference in the wages paid to
high school graduates and those without a high school degree. Thus, the high school
credential has lost much of its market value, except as a waypoint on the road to higher
education (Goldin and Katz, 2008; Card, 2009).
Still, there is an upper limit to this substitution process at present. While there is no consensus
on the topic, many experts do not expect artificial general intelligence (AGI) to emerge for
some decades, if at all (Fijelland, 2020). Assuming this expectation is correct (which I believe
it is), humans will continue to have comparative advantage in creativity, judgment, hypothesis
formation, contextual thinking, causal analysis, communication, emotional intelligence, and
many more arenas, the importance of which we likely do not fully appreciate and the difficulty
of which we surely vastly underestimate. I feel confident that the most skilled workers will
likely continue to be complemented by advances in computing and AIsuch as workers who
invent, design, research, lead, entertain, and educate. But this observation is not limited to
those with elite educations. People effortlessly do extraordinary things on an ongoing basis,
such as applying common sense to tease apart otherwise intractable problems; drawing
generalizable inferences from small data; and using abductive reasoning to form plausible
interpretations of a spare set of observations. Such seemingly quotidian tasks are currently
beyond the frontier of the most advanced AI, and yet children accomplish them effortlessly
(Davis and Marcus, 2019). Recalling Polanyi’s observations that we know more than we can
tell, I would add that we do not fully appreciate how much of this tacit knowledge we possess.
3. I similarly do not expect AI to rapidly reach deep into the ranks of low-paid service
occupations, those comprising the left-hand side of the occupational polarization plot show
in Figure 3. There are three reasons why not. First, most service occupations demand
dexterous, fluid, adaptive interactions with people and the environment, whether in care
jobs, services, entertainment, etc. Automating these activities will require substantial
advances in low-cost robots that can navigate in the highly variable human environment
rather than in the predictable engineered environment of a factory floor. These advances will
take place much more slowly than advances in AI, which depend primarily on more of the
same ingredientsmore data, greater computing power. Second, while machines will surely
slowly gain many of these human-like capabilities, their cost may remain high relative to the
25
low cost of labor performing those same activities. This cost comparison makes the
economics of automating many service tasks less attractive.29 Finally, many low-paid service
taskssuch as caregiving, coaching, and advising and sellingare unattractive targets for
automation not only because the technical challenge is steep but because personal attention
from another human being is intrinsically part of the service.
4. Finally, while it is easy to imagine which tasks and what jobs will succumb to automation, it is
far harder to forecast what and where new work will emerge. Millions of workers are
currently employed in order-fulfillment and ride-hailing jobs that were in effect created by e-
commerce and mobile telephony. Similarly, the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics maintains
information on “green jobs” associated with the transformation of the power sector.30 Many
of these occupations are relatively new or rapidly growing, such as solar plumbers, solar site
assessors, and specialized plumbers, pipefitters, and steamfitters. Artificial intelligence itself
has created a host of new skill demands and occupational specialties, as documented in
Acemoglu et al. (2022a). As discussed in Autor et al. (2021b), new innovations almost always
generate new work as people deploy, master, maintain, refine, and improve new
technologies, tools, and services. Nor does new work generation depend exclusively on
innovation. Autor et al. (2021b) further demonstrate that changes in demographics, tastes,
and income levels also drive the generation of new work.
What these observations imply is that the work of the future is not an empty setnot even
remotely. In Autor et al. (2022), we write that No compelling historical or contemporary evidence
suggests that technological advances are driving us toward a jobless future. On the contrary, we
anticipate that in the next two decades, industrialized countries will have more job openings than
workers to fill them, and that robotics and automation will play an increasingly crucial role in
closing these gaps. Nevertheless, the impact of robotics and automation on workers will not be
benign. These technologies, in concert with economic incentives, policy choices, and institutional
forces, will alter the set of jobs available and the skills they demand.It is that adaption that
creates both challenge and opportunity. The problem that industrialized countries face in the
29 An exception to this dictum is that service tasks that are done at large scale may attract automation. For example,
Amazon, which employs hundreds of thousands of warehouse workers, has invested heavily in robotics to
automate part of the product fulfillment process. Similarly, White Castle restaurants have deployed fryolator-
operating robots in some of their many stores. This same economic logic may drive robotics in table-waiting, hotel
room cleaning, shelf-stocking, and checkout operations, even though all are low-paid tasks that require substantial
human flexibility. The attractiveness of automation will increase if the cost of human labor in these tasks risesa
healthy economic process. The scenario to be concerned about is one where automation makes formerly scarce
labor broadly abundant (and hence cheap); not one in which scarce labor makes automation more attractive at
the margin.
30 https://www.bls.gov/green/overview.htm
26
immediate decades ahead is not a shortfall in the quantity of jobs. It is rather that many of the
jobs may be of low quality, use only generic human capacities, and provide little opportunity for
skills acquisition, specialization, and rising lifecycle productivity. This is not a new problem,
however. It has been unfolding over four decades. And in general, the U.S. has adapted to it
poorly.
5 Conclusions
I began by asking what the role of technologydigital or otherwiseis in determining wages and
shaping wage inequality. I presented four answers corresponding to four strands of thinking on
this topic: the education race, the task-polarization model, the automation-reinstatement race,
and the era of AI uncertainty. The nuance of economic understanding has improved substantially
across these epochs. Yet, traditional economic optimism about the beneficent effects of
technology for productivity and welfare has eroded as understanding has advanced.
Fundamentally, technological change expands the frontier of human possibilities, but one should
expect it to create many winners and many losers, and to pose vast societal challenges and
opportunities along the way.
What are the policy implications of these observations? The question is so broad that almost
any answer is bound to appear vague and inadequate. One can reliably predict that technological
innovations will foster new ways of accomplishing existing work, new business models, and
entirely new industries, and these in turn will generate new jobs and spur some productivity gains.
But absent complementary institutional investments, technological innovation alone will not
generate broadly shared gains. Autor et al. (2022) sketch a long-form policy vision of what form
these investments may take, focusing on three domains: education and training; labor market
institutions; and innovation policy itself. I provide a capsule summary of those conclusions here,
stopping short of policy recommendations.
As a starting point, educating and training the workforce to meet the demands of the moment
can improve access to good jobs for workers who would otherwise face barriers and boost the
quality of existing jobs by creating opportunities for career ladders. While boosting the supply of
skills is never controversial, pure supply-side policies are inadequate to meet the gravity of the
labor market challenge. In 1979, 60% of U.S. males at the median of the wage distribution
possessed high school or lower education, whereas 21% had some college, and 20% held a
bachelor’s degree or above. By 2019, 31% of males at the median of the earnings distribution had
some college, 36% had attained at least a four-year college degree a 75% increase and only
27
one-third had high school or less education.31 Despite this dramatic skill upgrading, the real
earnings of the median male rose by only 10% in these forty years.
More broadly, over more than four decades, the link between rising productivity and
commensurate improvements in job opportunities and earnings has decoupled for the majority
of U.S. workers. The poor quality of jobs available to workers lacking four-year college degrees or
specialized credentials provides one of the starkest examples of this failure. Low-wage U.S.
workers earn substantially less than low-wage workers in almost all other wealthy industrialized
countries.32
The divergence between the upward path of productivity growth and the near plateauing of
median wage growth among U.S. workers was not an inevitable consequence of technology,
globalization, or market forces (Autor et al. 2022). Rather, a set of U.S.-specific institutional and
policy choices failed to bluntand in some cases magnifiedthe consequences of technological
and globalization pressures on the U.S. labor market. To contend effectively with these challenges
would require institutional and policy reforms that realign labor market opportunities with the
rising productivity and societal wealth that the U.S. has reaped from decades of innovation and
investments in human and physical capital.
Thus, a second locus for investment would be to revitalize the governmental,
nongovernmental, and private sector institutions that translateor fail to translaterising
productivity into shared prosperity. Some such steps might include updating and more vigorously
enforcing labor standards, recalibrating federal minimum wage policies, extending the scope and
flexibility of the unemployment insurance system, and transforming the U.S. employer-based
health insurance provision into a system with portable benefits. Autor et al. (2022) further call for
reevaluating the U.S.’ uncritical embrace of pure shareholder capitalism. While shareholder
capitalism can plausibly be credited with some of the productive dynamism of the U.S. economy,
it has also arguably helped fuel the drive to curtail wages and benefits for low-wage workers and,
more broadly (Acemoglu et al. 2022b).
A third potential domain for policy is to directly shape innovation itself to speed productivity
growth and complement the skills of the labor force. It is well known that the U.S. has a strong
national innovation system, fueled by federal R&D investments, to develop fundamental science
and new technologies, that has led to scientific leadership and new industries (Gross and Sampat,
2020). Less recognized, however, is the crucial link between those new industries as complements
to the inevitable loss of jobs that results from productivity-enhancing technologies. New
industries grew out of a flourishing innovation ecosystem that created new companies and new
31 These statistics from Donovan and Bradley (2020, Table 5) refer to male workers at the 45th-55th percentiles of
the male wage distribution in the corresponding year.
32 This paragraph and the next excerpt from Autor et al. (2022), p101-102.
28
applications, alongside older industries that increased mechanization and automation as they
matured. Arguably, the U.S. has let those important R&D investments wither (Bloom et al. 2019).
Through increased and targeted R&D investments supported by a reinvigorated federal R&D
program, as well as a tax policy that keeps workers and social challenges at the forefront, the
country’s innovation system could be put to work for a broader number of people and regions
than it has in recent decades (Gruber and Johnson, 2019).33
Although I would prefer to end this essay with optimistic assurances, I will instead end with
one uncertainty, one certainty, and one admonition. The uncertainty is that we have less clarity
about our technological future than we did two decades ago. AI has extended the frontier of
technological possibility towards boundaries that are barely visible at present. The tasks that
machines will be able to accomplish, the rate at which new innovations may emerge, and the
speed with which socially impactful technological innovations may diffuse is unknown. But the
range of possibilities has surely gotten broader, and our certainty about the boundaries has
accordingly diminished.
Conversely, the certainty is that these technological advances will expand the set of desirable
possibilities that are within the reach of humanity. Artificial Intelligence has the potential to help
humanity tackle some of its most pressing challenges: climate change, disease, poverty,
malnutrition, and inadequate education. But whether societies will successfully realize this
potential, or instead squander it or, worse, disastrously misuse it, is highly uncertain and, I would
argue, fundamentally indeterminate.
The admonition is this: given the potential applicability of AI to a vast set of purposes, we
collectively (meaning individuals, organizations, and governments) should not simply be asking
what AI will accomplish but what we want it to accomplish. How can we use AI most productively
to complement workers, raise productivity, and more broadly, tackle humanity’s most pressing
challenges? Simultaneously, how can we blunt or reshape the commercial incentives to use AI for
socially counterproductive objectives such as displacing workers, preying upon people’s cognitive
and emotional frailties, or consolidating the power of governments or corporations to exercise
social control (Acemoglu and Restrepo, 2020)? As we ponder our uncertain AI future, our goal
should not merely be to predict that future but to create it.
References
Acemoglu, D. (2002). “Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market. Journal of Economic
Literature 40(1):7-72.
33 This paragraph excerpts from Autor et al. (2022), p121.
29
Acemoglu, D., Autor, D., Hazell, J., and Restrepo, P. (2022a). AI and Jobs: Evidence from Online
Vacancies. Journal of Labor Economics, 40(S1):S293-S340.
Acemoglu, D., He, Alex X., and Le Maire, D. (2022b). “Eclipse of Rent-Sharing: The Effects of
Managers' Business Education on Wages and the Labor Share in the US and Denmark.” NBER
Working Paper No. 29874, March.
Acemoglu, D. and Autor, D. H. (2011). Skills, Tasks and Technologies: Implications for
Employment and Earnings. Handbook of Labor Economics, 4(11):10431171.
Acemoglu, D. and Restrepo, P. (2018a). Modeling Automation. American Economic Review:
Papers and Proceedings, 108:4853.
Acemoglu, D. and Restrepo, P. (2018b). The Race between Man and Machine: Implications of
Technology for Growth, Factor Shares, and Employment. American Economic Review,
108(6):14881542.
Acemoglu, D. and Restrepo, P. (2019). Automation and New Tasks: How Technology Displaces
and Reinstates Labor. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 33(2):330.
Acemoglu, D. and Restrepo, P. (2020). The Wrong Kind of AI? Artificial Intelligence and the
Future of Labor Demand. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, 13(1):25
35.
Acemoglu, D. and Restrepo, P. (2021). Tasks, Automation, and the Rise in U.S. Wage
Inequality. NBER Working Paper No. 28920, June.
Agrawal, A., Gans, J., and Goldfarb, A. (2018). Prediction Machines: The Simple Economics of
Artificial Intelligence. Harvard Business Press.
Atalay, E., Phongthiengtham, P., Sotelo, S., and Tannenbaum, D. (2020). The Evolution of Work
in the United States. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 12(2):134.
Autor, D. (2013). The Task Approach to Labor Markets: An Overview. Journal for Labour
Market Research, 46(3):185199.
Autor, D., Dorn, D., and Hanson, G. H. (2021a). On the Persistence of the China Shock.
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, forthcoming.
Autor, D., Dorn, D., Katz, L. F., Patterson, C., and Van Reenen, J. (2020a). The Fall of the Labor
Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 135(2):645709.
Autor, D., Goldin, C., and Katz, L. F. (2020b). Extending the Race between Education and
Technology. In AEA Papers and Proceedings, volume 110, pages 34751.
Autor, D., Mindell, D., and Reynolds, E. (2022). The Work of the Future: Building Better Jobs in an
Age of Intelligent Machines. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Autor, D., Salomons, A., and Seegmiller, B. (2021b). New Frontiers: The Origin and Content of
New Work, 1940 2018. MIT Working Paper, July.
30
Autor, D. H. (2014). Skills, Education, and the Rise of Earnings Inequality among the Other 99
Percent’.” Science, 344(6186):843851.
Autor, D. H. (2015). Why are There Still So Many Jobs? The History and Future of Workplace
Automation. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 29(3):330.
Autor, D. H. (2019). Work of the Past, Work of the Future. AEA Papers and Proceedings,
volume 109, pages 132.
Autor, D. H. and Dorn, D. (2013). The Growth of Low Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of
the U.S. Labor Market. American Economic Review, 103(5):15531597.
Autor, D. H., Katz, L. F., and Kearney, M. S. (2006). The Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market.
American Economic Review, 96(2):189194.
Autor, D. H., Katz, L. F., and Kearney, M. S. (2008). Trends in U.S. Wage Inequality: Revising the
Revisionists. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(2):300323.
Autor, D. H., Katz, L. F., and Krueger, A. B. (1998). Computing Inequality: Have Computers
Changed the Labor Market? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(4):11691213.
Autor, D. H., Levy, F., and Murnane, R. J. (2003). The Skill Content of Recent Technological
Change: An Empirical Exploration. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4):12791333.
Babina, T., Fedyk, A., He, A., and Hodson, J. (2020). Artificial Intelligence, Firm Growth, and
Industry Concentration. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3651052.
Bick, A., Fuchs-Schündeln, N., & Lagakos, D. (2018). How Do Hours Worked Vary with Income?
Cross-Country Evidence and Implications. American Economic Review, 108(1), 170-99.
Bloom, N., Van Reenen, J. and Williams, H. (2019). “A Toolkit of Policies to Promote Innovation.”
Journal of Economic Perspectives 33, no. 3: 163184.
Böhm, M. J. (2020). The Price of Polarization: Estimating Task Prices under Routine-Biased
Technical Change. Quantitative Economics, 11(2):761799.
Böhm, M. J., von Gaudecker, H.-M., and Schran, F. (2019). Occupation Growth, Skill Prices, and
Wage Inequality. CESifo Working Paper No. 7877.
Bresnahan, T. (2021). Artificial Intelligence Technologies and Aggregate Growth Prospects” in
Diamond, John, and George Zodrow (eds.), Prospects for Economic Growth in the United
States, Cambridge University Press.
Brynjolfsson, E. and Mitchell, T. (2017). What Can Machine Learning Do? Workforce
Implications.” Science, 358(6370):15301534.
Brynjolfsson, E., Mitchell, T., and Rock, D. (2018). What Can Machines Learn, and What Does it
Mean for Occupations and the Economy?AEA Papers and Proceedings, 108:4347.
31
Card, D. and Lemieux, T. (2001a). Can Falling Supply Explain the Rising Return to College for
Younger Men? A Cohort-Based Analysis. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(2):705
746.
Card, D. and Lemieux, T. (2001b). Going to College to Avoid the Draft: The Unintended Legacy
of the Vietnam War. American Economic Review, 91(2):97102.
Card, D. (2009). Immigration and Inequality. American Economic Review: Papers &
Proceedings, 99(2), 1-21.
Deming, D. J. (2017). The Growing Importance of Social Skills in the Labor Market. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 132(4):15931640.
Deming, D. J. and Noray, K. (2020). Earnings Dynamics, Changing Job Skills, and STEM Careers.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 135(4):19652005.
Donovan, Sarah A, and David H Bradley. (2020). “Real Wage Trends, 1979 to 2019.
Congressional Research Service, Report R45090, December.
Dorn, D. (2009). Essays on Inequality, Spatial Interaction, and the Demand for Skills (Doctoral
dissertation, University of St. Gallen).
Feigenbaum, J. and Gross, D. P. (2020). Answering the Call of Automation: How the Labor
Market Adjusted to the Mechanization of Telephone Operation. NBER Working Paper No.
28061. November.
Felten, E., Manav, R., and Seamans, R. (2018). A Method to Link Advances in Artificial
Intelligence to Occupational Abilities. American Economic Association Papers and
Proceedings, 108(54):5457.
Felten, E., Raj, M., and Seamans, R. C. (2019). The Effect of Artificial Intelligence on Human
Labor: An Ability-Based Approach. In Academy of Management Proceedings, volume 2019,
page 15784. Academy of Management Briarcliff Manor, NY 10510.
Fjelland, R. (2020). Why General Artificial Intelligence Will Not Be Realized. Nature:
Humanities and Social Sciences Communications, 7(1):1-9.
Goldin, C. and Katz, L. F. (1998). The Origins of Technology-Skill Complementarity. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(3):693732.
Goldin, C. and Katz, L. F. (2008). The Race Between Education and Technology. Harvard
University Press.
Goldin, C., Katz, L. F., et al. (2007). Long-Run Changes in the Wage Structure: Narrowing,
Widening, Polarizing. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 38(2):135168.
Goldin, C. and Margo, R. A. (1992). The Great Compression: The Wage Structure in the United
States at Mid-Century. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(1):134.
32
Goos, M. and Manning, A. (2007). Lousy and Lovely Jobs: The Rising Polarization of Work in
Britain. Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(1):118133.
Goos, M., Manning, A., and Salomons, A. (2009). Job Polarization in Europe. American
Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 99(2):5863.
Goos, M., Manning, A., and Salomons, A. (2014). Explaining Job Polarization: Routine Biased
Technological Change and Offshoring. American Economic Review, 104(8):2509 2526.
Grabner, H., Gall, J., and Van Gool, L. (2011). What Makes a Chair a Chair? In CVPR 2011, pages
15291536. IEEE.
Gregory, T., Salomons, A., and Zierahn, U. (2022). Racing with or Against the Machine?
Evidence on the Role of Trade in Europe. Journal of the European Economic Association,
20(2):869-906.
Gross, Daniel P., and Bhaven N. Sampat. (2020). “Inventing the Endless Frontier: The Effects of
the World War II Research Effort on Post-War Innovation.” NBER Working Paper No. 27375,
June.
Grossman, G. M. and Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2008). Trading Tasks: A Simple Theory of Offshoring.
American Economic Review, 98(5):197897.
Gruber, J. and Johnson, S. (2019). Jump-Starting America: How Breakthrough Science Can Revive
Economic Growth and the American Dream. Public Affairs.
Harrigan, J., Reshef, A., and Toubal, F. (2021). The March of the Techies: Technology, Trade,
and Job Polarization in France, 1994-2007. Research Policy, 50(7).
Kahneman, D., Sibony, O., and Sunstein, C. R. (2021). Noise: A Flaw in Human Judgment. Little,
Brown.
Karabarbounis, L. and Neiman, B. (2014). The Global Decline of the Labor Share. The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 129(1):61103.
Katz, L. F. and Autor, D. H. (1999). Changes in the Wage Structure and Earnings Inequality.
Handbook of Labor Economics, 3:14631555.
Katz, L. F. and Murphy, K. M. (1992). Changes in Relative Wages, 19631987: Supply and
Demand Factors. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(1):3578.
Kogan L., Papanikolaou D., Schmidt L.D., Seegmiller B. (2021). “Technology-skill
complementarity and labor displacement: Evidence from linking two centuries of patents
with occupations.” NBER Working paper No. 29552, December.
Komlos, J. (2016). “Has Creative Destruction Become More Destructive?” The B.E. Journal of
Economic Analysis & Policy, 16(4).
33
Korinek, A. and Stiglitz, J. E. (2018). Artificial Intelligence and its Implications for Income
Distribution and Unemployment. In The Economics of Artificial Intelligence: An Agenda,
pages 349390. University of Chicago Press.
Krusell, P., Ohanian, L. E., Ríos-Rull, J.-V., and Violante, G. L. (2000) Capital-Skill
Complementarity and Inequality: A Macroeconomic Analysis. Econometrica, 68(5): 1029-
1053.
Levy, F. and Murnane, R. J. (2004). The New Division of Labor: How Computers are Creating the
Next Job Market. Princeton University Press; Russell Sage Foundation.
Lin, J. (2011). Technological Adaptation, Cities, and New Work. The Review of Economics and
Statistics, 93(2):554574.
Marcus, G. and Davis, E. (2019). Rebooting AI: Building Artificial Intelligence We Can Trust. New
York: Vintage Press.
Mann, K., and Püttmann, L. 2021. “Benign Effects of Automation: New Evidence from Patent
Texts.” The Review of Economics and Statistics.
Maloney, William F., and Carlos Molina. (2016). Are Automation and Trade Polarizing
Developing Country Labor Markets, Too? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 7922.
Michaels, G., Natraj, A., and Van Reenen, J. (2014). Has ICT Polarized Skill Demand? Evidence
from Eleven Countries over Twenty-Five Years. Review of Economics and Statistics,
96(1):6077.
Nordhaus, W. D. (2007). Two Centuries of Productivity Growth in Computing. The Journal of
Economic History, 67(1):128159.
Polanyi, M. (1966). The Tacit Dimension. Doubleday.
Schultz, T. W. (1975). The Value of the Ability to Deal with Disequilibria.” Journal of Economic
Literature, 13(3):827-846.
Smith, A. and Anderson, M. (2017). Automation in Everyday Life. Pew Research Center.
Susskind, D. (2020). A World Without Work: Technology, Automation, and How We Should
Respond. Metropolitan Books, New York, N.Y.
Tinbergen, J. (1974). Substitution of Graduate Labor by Other. Kyklos, 27(2):217226.
Webb, M. (2020). The Impact of Artificial Intelligence on the Labor Market. Working paper.
Wike, R. and Stokes, B. (2018). In Advanced and Emerging Economies Alike, Worries about Job
Automation. Pew Research Center, Global Attitudes & Trends.
... On the top, there are the risk that AI takes over existential activities, allowing no longer intelligible (and therefore hardly controllable) machines to be in charge of vital decisions in areas such as defence, security or health care. These concerns reflect a pessimistic view on technological progress, which is related to the risk that the diffusion of AI may turn into a new wave of technological unemployment, bringing back to the fore the same fears surrounding previous automation and digitalization waves (Frank et al., 2019;Autor, 2022). 2 Similar concerns are influencing policy making at the EU level. ...
... In this context, empirical research is struggling to provide policy-makers robust evidence that could prove useful in tailoring AI-related policies and regulations (Acemoglu, 2021;Autor, 2022). As the diffusion of AI gains momentum and its potential applications flourish across sectors (e.g., education, finance, legal counselling, insurance), attempts to assess its employment impact multiply (among others, see Brynjolfsson et al. 2018;Felten et al. 2018Felten et al. , 2021Webb, 2020;Acemoglu et al., 2022;Albanesi et al., 2023). ...
Article
Full-text available
This study provides evidence of the employment impact of AI exposure in European regions, addressing one of the many gaps in the emerging literature on AI’s effects on employment in Europe. Building upon the occupation-based AI-exposure indicators proposed by Felten et al. (2018, 2019, 2021), which are mapped to the European occupational classification (ISCO), following Albanesi et al. (2023), we analyse the regional employment dynamics between 2011 and 2018. After controlling for a wide range of supply and demand factors, our findings indicate that, on average, AI exposure has a positive impact on regional employment. Put differently, European regions characterised by a relatively larger share of AI-exposed occupations display, all else being equal and once potential endogeneity concerns are mitigated, a more favourable employment tendency over the period 2011-2018. We also find evidence of a moderating effect of robot density on the AI-employment nexus, which however lacks a causal underpinning.
... The empirical evidence clearly shows that aggregate demand shapes productivity growth and makes expansionary fiscal policies key to foster long-term economic growth. Moreover, fiscal policies must consider that robotisation impacts on industrial employment dynamics both directly and through spillovers between upstream and downstream sectors, with related implications in terms of education and training of the labour force, and wide institutional reforms to narrow the decoupling between productivity and earnings (Bessen, 2019;Autor, 2022). Secondly, the evidence of some macroeconomic technological unemployment, though weak and of uncertain magnitude, calls for safety nets to protect the workers displaced by an increasing diffusion of robots. ...
... In this case, the education and training of the workforce to better meet firms' demand may improve the possibility to have access to good jobs for workers that otherwise would face barriers ). Yet, this supplyside policy should be paired with institutional reforms able to break the rising decoupling between productivity attainments and earnings, e.g., a minimum wage policy (Autor, 2022). The positive effect on aggregate demand from an increased consumption would allow to reap capital and innovative investments through higher productivity growth. ...
Article
This paper contributes to the literature around the Kaldor–Verdoorn law and analyses the impact of robotisation on the channels through which the law shapes labour-productivity growth. We start with a simple evolutionary reinterpretation of the law that combines Kaldorian and neo-Schumpeterian arguments. We then apply a GMM estimator to a panel of 17 industries in 25 OECD capitalist economies for the period 1990–2018. After elaborating on the general evidence of the evolutionary interpretation of the law, the estimates suggest a positive influence from robotisation: a higher robot density strengthens both the channel that ties labour productivity dynamics with mechanisation, and the one connected with the general advancement of science and technology which joins productivity to aggregate demand. This overall result is robust to several specifications of the underlying econometric model. Moreover, we find some evidence of technological unemployment out of the macroeconomic factor. Results agree with the empirical literature that suggests different impacts from robotisation on the basis of the level of economic activity considered.
... In the same work, he also found that such new work is overwhelmingly concentrated in large urban centers. Additional recent research on technology and job creation can be found in Bloom et al. (2021), Autor (2022) and Autor et al. (2022). The latter match information in patent texts to texts ('micro titles') that census examiners use to update occupational definitions. ...
... In addition, new work can emerge from expanding markets, where scale effects allow further development of the economy-wide division of labor. Autor (2022) finds that frontier work is increasingly polarized between high-skill high wage tasks, and low-skilled (mostly service) tasks and occupations, and is a source of the well-known phenomenon of wage polarization. Taking the lead from this work, the research in this article is interested in a particular Frontier workers and the seedbeds of inequality 3 subset of new work: that which is linked, through complementarity or augmentation, to new technologies, and hence will tend to be highly skilled and highly paid. ...
Article
This article examines the role of work at the cutting of technological change—frontier work—as a driver of prosperity and spatial income inequality. Using new methods and data, we analyze the geography and incomes of frontier workers from 1880 to 2019. Initially, frontier work is concentrated in a set of ‘seedbed’ locations, contributing to rising spatial inequality through powerful localized wage premiums. As technologies mature, the economic distinctiveness of frontier work diminishes, as ultimately happened to cities like Manchester and Detroit. Our work uncovers a plausible general origin story of the unfolding of spatial income inequality.
... Interestingly, the domain which digitalisation and AI have left relatively untouched is the domain of person-facing jobs. This is particularly true for interpersonal service jobs such as hospitality, health care, food service, etc., where job functions demand physical dexterity, interpersonal skills, as well as constant improvisation (Autor, 2022). ...
... In 2023, digitally-enabled automation has changed labour markets in noticeable ways, even if it has not yet led to mass job displacement. Digitalisation and especially AI have amplified the long-term trend toward the polarisation of jobs into the higher wage and lower wage ends of the occupational spectrum (Autor, 2022). So, as long as it generates economic gains from which only a small portion of the population in economically developed countries benefit (Acemoğlu, 2021), uncontrolled digitally-enabled automation will deepen economic inequalities. ...
Article
Full-text available
Risky behaviours are precursors of deviant behaviours and psychopathology in youth. On the other hand, identity formation is a critical process during adolescence and emerging adulthood, which is linked with various important psychosocial outcomes in youth. A stable sense of identity relates to adjustment and lower chances of risky behaviours. Therefore, the main aim of this study is to investigate the relationship between the identity processing styles of Albanian students and risky behaviours. The participants consisted of 274 students, who filled in an online survey. The results taken from the multiple regression analyses showed that risky behaviours are associated positively with diffused-avoidant identity style, and negatively with normative identity style. No results were found for informational identity style. The findings emphasise the important role of identity formation in youth and extend the current literature on identity formation and delinquency in a new cultural context.
... Additional recent research on technology and job creation can be found in Bloom et al. (2021), Autor (2022, and Autor et al. (2022). The latter match information in patent texts to texts ('micro titles') that census examiners use to update occupational definitions. ...
... In addition, new work can emerge from expanding markets, where scale effects allow further development of the economy-wide division of labor. Autor (2022) finds that frontier work is increasingly polarized between high-skill high wage tasks, and low-skilled (mostly service) tasks and occupations, and is a source of the well-known phenomenon of wage polarization. Taking the lead from this work, the research in this paper is interested in a particular subset of new work: that which is linked, through complementarity or augmentation, to new technologies, and hence will tend to be highly skilled and highly paid. ...
Preprint
Full-text available
This paper examines the role of work at the cutting of technological change – frontier work – as a driver of prosperity and spatial income inequality. Using new methods and data, we analyze the geography and incomes of frontier workers from 1880 to 2019. Initially, frontier work is concentrated in a set of ‘seedbed’ locations, contributing to rising spatial inequality through powerful localized wage premiums. As technologies mature, the economic distinctiveness of frontier work diminishes, as ultimately happened to cities like Manchester and Detroit. Our work uncovers a plausible general origin story of the unfolding of spatial income inequality.
... First, in what Autor (2022, 19) calls "Polyani's revenge", "computers now know more than they can tell us," at least in some domains. While generative AI has shrunk the set of tasks where workers' tacit knowledge or creativity is critical to performance, it also generates new errors (Frey and Osborne, 2023), resulting in uncertainty about the limits of its capabilities (Autor, 2022). It is also increasingly likely that there is not a linear relationship between task complexity and gains from generative AI, which Dell' Acqua et al. (2023) have characterized as a "jagged frontier" of AI capabilities. ...
... First, in what Autor (2022, 19) calls "Polyani's revenge", "computers now know more than they can tell us," at least in some domains. While generative AI has shrunk the set of tasks where workers' tacit knowledge or creativity is critical to performance, it also generates new errors (Frey and Osborne, 2023), resulting in uncertainty about the limits of its capabilities (Autor, 2022). It is also increasingly likely that there is not a linear relationship between task complexity and gains from generative AI, which Dell' Acqua et al. (2023) have characterized as a "jagged frontier" of AI capabilities. ...
... The recent wave of robotization has brought the 'robot-workers race' back to the fore. As in the past, economists are divided between optimists and pessimists, the latter envisaging new risks of mass technological unemployment (Autor, 2022). The available evidence is inconclusive, though. ...
Article
This work analyses the impact of robots on employment testing for the presence of different robotization regimes. Focusing on European manufacturing industries, we find that robot adoption positively affects total employment. Heterogeneous patterns are detected across both countries and occupational groups, however. The labour-friendly impact of robotization is detected only in core and service-oriented countries and for those at the top of the occupational structure (i.e. managers and technicians). In turn, peripheral countries and manual workers do not seem to benefit at all from robotization.
... Expanding upon this, considering AI as a potent tool capable of proficiently accomplishing specific tasks inherent in human professions, extensive research has elucidated various mechanisms through which AI interfaces with labor markets (Agrawal et al. 2019). Firstly, AI might serve as a direct substitute for human workers, particularly those engaged in routine tasks susceptible to full automation by AI (Gallego and Kurer 2022, Autor 2022, Paolillo et al. 2022 Article submitted to Information Systems Research; manuscript no. ISRE-0000-0000.00 ...
Preprint
With the advent of general-purpose Generative AI, the interest in discerning its impact on the labor market escalates. In an attempt to bridge the extant empirical void, we interpret the launch of ChatGPT as an exogenous shock, and implement a Difference-in-Differences (DID) approach to quantify its influence on text-related jobs and freelancers within an online labor marketplace. Our results reveal a significant decrease in transaction volume for gigs and freelancers directly exposed to ChatGPT. Additionally, this decline is particularly marked in units of relatively higher past transaction volume or lower quality standards. Yet, the negative effect is not universally experienced among service providers. Subsequent analyses illustrate that freelancers proficiently adapting to novel advancements and offering services that augment AI technologies can yield substantial benefits amidst this transformative period. Consequently, even though the advent of ChatGPT could conceivably substitute existing occupations, it also unfolds immense opportunities and carries the potential to reconfigure the future of work. This research contributes to the limited empirical repository exploring the profound influence of LLM-based generative AI on the labor market, furnishing invaluable insights for workers, job intermediaries, and regulatory bodies navigating this evolving landscape.
Article
We evaluate the duration of the China trade shock and its impact on a wide range of outcomes over the period 2000 to 2019. The shock plateaued in 2010, enabling analysis of its effects for nearly a decade past its culmination. Adverse impacts of import competition on manufacturing employment, overall employment-population ratios, and income per capita in more trade-exposed U.S. commuting zones are present out to 2019. Over the full study period, greater import competition implies a reduction in the manufacturing employment-population ratio of 1.54 percentage points, which is 55% of the observed change in the value, and the absorption of 86% of this net job loss via a corresponding decrease in the overall employment rate. Reductions in population headcounts, which indicate net out-migration, register only for foreign-born workers and the native-born 25-39 years old, implying that exit from work is a primary means of adjustment to trade-induced contractions in labor demand. More negatively affected regions see modest increases in the uptake of government transfers, but these transfers primarily take the form of Social Security and Medicare benefits. Adverse outcomes are more acute in regions that initially had fewer college-educated workers and were more industrially specialized. Impacts are qualitatively - but not quantitatively - similar to those caused by the decline of employment in coal production since the 1980s, indicating that the China trade shock holds lessons for other episodes of localized job loss. Import competition from China induced changes in income per capita across local labor markets that are much larger than the spatial heterogeneity of income effects predicted by standard quantitative trade models. Even using higher-end estimates of the consumer benefits of rising trade with China, a substantial fraction of commuting zones appears to have suffered absolute declines in average real incomes.