ArticlePDF Available

The Political Economy of Autocratization: The Case of Belarus, 1994–2006

Authors:

Abstract

This is the original, accepted version of the paper prior to editing. The final version of the article is published in the journal Communist and Post-Communist Studies, volume 54, issue 4. Please access the published version and cite it as such. Abstract: In competitive authoritarian systems, aspiring autocrats must win elections and marginalize the political opposition. In Belarus, President Alexander Lukashenko's strategy for political hegemony heavily relied on socioeconomic co-optation, offering privileges to supporters and imposing sanctions on dissenters. In an economy dominated by the state, co-optation had a coercive effect on behavior. Without sizable areas of activity autonomous from the government, citizens could not defy or mitigate the cost of reprisals for openly supporting the political opposition. Through co-optation, Lukashenko weakened the opposition and built an authoritarian regime without resorting to extensive political violence, which could have undermined his claim of public legitimacy.
ARIS TRANTIDIS
University of Lincoln, Lincoln, United Kingdom
The Political Economy of Autocratization
The Case of Belarus, 1994–2006
ABSTRACT In competitive authoritarian systems, aspiring autocrats must win elections and marginalize
the political opposition. In Belarus, President Alexander Lukashenko’s strategy for political hegemony
heavily relied on socioeconomic co-optation, offering privileges to supporters and imposing sanctions
on dissenters. In an economy dominated by the state, co-optation had a coercive effect on behavior.
Without sizable areas of activity autonomous from the government, citizens could not defy or mitigate
the cost of reprisals for openly supporting the political opposition. Through co-optation, Lukashenko
weakened the opposition and built an authoritarian regime without resorting to extensive political
violence, which could have undermined his claim of public legitimacy.
KEYWORDS electoral authoritarianism,competitive authoritarianism,Belarus,post-communist transition,
democratic theory
Competitive authoritarian regimes can move in two opposite directions—toward a higher
level of political competition and possibly a democratization path, or toward lower levels
of political competition and further autocratization (Howard & Roessler, 2006). Auto-
cratization can go as far as the establishment of a political hegemony, a type of regime
that offers a formal structure of political participation but exhibits low levels of political
contestation (Dahl, 1971, pp. 4,8,34). Electoral vulnerability distinguishes a competitive
authoritarian regime from a hegemonic authoritarian one (Donno, 2013). In a hegemonic
regime, citizens have the typical rights to vote, get elected, and join or establish political
parties or civil society organizations but, as political participants, they have few actual
chances to effectively challenge the governing elite and replace it with another political
group. The political opposition is too weak to launch an effective campaign and win an
election. The incumbent has also contained factionalism and defections from the ranks of
the government party or coalition (Bogaards & Boucek, 2010).
This article revisits the story of Belarus as a transition from a competitive authoritar-
ian regime to a hegemonic regime under President Alexander Lukashenko, in the period
between his election as president in 1994—when Lukashenko had his first confrontation
with the political opposition and deployed a plan to increase his presidential power by
reforming the constitution—and the 2006 presidential election, which, after two con-
secutive tenures in office, indicated that his regime had been well consolidated. Like any
other authoritarian regime, Lukashenko never ceased his effort to embed and defend his
hegemonic rule. Throughout this period, typical repression tactics such as arrests and
Communist and Post-Communist Studies,Vol.54,Number4,pp.117136,
ISSN
:0967-067X, e-
ISSN
:1873-6920
©2021 by the Regents of the University of California. All rights reserved. Please direct all requests for permission to
photocopy or reproduce article content through the University of California Press’s Reprints and Permissions web page,
https://www.ucpress.edu/journals/reprints-permissions. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1525/j.postcomstud.2021.54.4.117
117
police violence were deployed against political opponents (White, 2011,p.800; Bedford,
2017). However, the Lukashenko regime avoided the escalation of political violence and
the kind of public backlash that broke up in the so-called color revolutions during the
2000s (Padhol & Marples, 2011,p.3). For over 25 years, Lukashenko succeeded in
preempting the formation of sizable public support for the opposition (Silitski, 2005,
2010b) and currently survives a year of public protests.
Several authors attributed Lukashenko’s political success and longevity to factors that
were present in other post-communist countries where competitive authoritarian systems
did not, however, evolve into hegemonic regimes.
1
Lukashenko is an astute demagogue
(Lindner, 2002,p.81; Marples, 1999a, pp. 103104) who exploited public anxieties over
the collapse of the economy in 1991 and acted against a relatively weak civil society and
a fragmented political elite (To
¨rnquist-Plewa, 2004; cf. Eke & Kuzio, 2000). He forged
the country’s nascent national identity against other competing narratives (Eke & Kuzio,
2000; Marples, 2006; Mihalisko, 1997; Zaprudnik, 2003). He gained the support of
the state nomenklatura (Korosteleva 2003b) and appealed to an electorate that, for the
most part, remained apathetic and distrustful of rapid political and economic change
(Korosteleva, 2000; Belova-Gille, 2003; Rotman & Danilov, 2003; Korosteleva, 2003b;
Silitski, 2006).
This article focuses on another important component of Lukashenko’s autocratization
strategy: socioeconomic co-optation. Co-optation plays a key role in that process through
the distribution of resources and socioeconomic opportunities by the regime to loyal
political supporters and allies (cf. Gerschewski, 2013). Previous studies of Belarus men-
tioned a connection between the lack of economic reforms and several practices classified
as clientelist (Belova-Gille, 2003,p.65; Korosteleva, 2003b, p. 79; Balmaceda, 2002,
2014a). However, co-optation has not been explicitly examined in terms of how it
worked together with typical repressive tactics as part of an explanatory framework, in
particular, the synergies that developed between the co-optation strategy and Lukashen-
ko’s ideology, his political conduct, his institutional record, and the external support he
received from Russia. The purpose here is not to isolate the effect of co-optation against
other pertinent variables but to explore how this practice intersects with other compo-
nents of an autocratization strategy and the broader structural context (cf. Ragin, 1987,p.
20). Of particular interest is the flip side of co-optation, namely, exclusion from socio-
economic rewards and resource distributions, which could act as a form of retaliatory
discrimination against political dissenters and opponents.
The following argument is presented. Lukashenko exploited the powerful role of the
state in Belarus’s society and economy to build an extensive system of co-optation that, in
the absence of considerable areas of activity outside the reach of government discrimi-
nation, affected the vast majority of the population. In such an environment, very few
citizens could mitigate the effects of retaliation that came in the form of exclusion from
1. Evans and Whitefield expected that Belarus, Ukraine, Russia, Bulgaria, Romania, and Slovakia would
experience a decline in terms of their normative commitment to democracy (Evans & Whitefield 1993, pp. 545
546). Among these countries, only Belarus and Russia later developed stable hegemonic regimes.
118 COMMUNIST AND POST-COMMUNIST STUDIES DECEMBER 2021
government-allocated resources and administrative penalties. Most workers in Belarus
were vulnerable to threats of redundancy on political grounds, while owners or managers
of private companies were vulnerable to administrative sanctions and forms of financial
reprisal for demonstrating political behavior the regime would disapprove. In that sense,
co-optation served as a method of political coercion, which was effective in forcing self-
restrictions in the citizens’ choices of political behavior. Working together with typical
authoritarian tactics, co-optation helped the regime discourage any scalable expressions of
political support for the opposition. Without sufficient active supporters and with few
campaign resources, the opposition forces could not project a visible alternative for
government. Lukashenko built a political communication monopoly, presenting himself
as the only credible option for the country’s economic prosperity and social stability.
THE CHALLENGE OF AUTOCRATIZATION
How co-optation facilitates the closure of political competition in a competitive author-
itarian regime is a theoretically important topic of inquiry in the broader study of
autocratization and de-democratization. A transition from competitive authoritarianism
to a hegemony is a particularly challenging task for aspiring autocrats. Competitive
authoritarian systems are not closed autocracies. Incumbents must legitimize their rule
through electoral victories that would signal their popularity and ideological dominance
(Magaloni, 2006; Schedler, 2006). The outcome of these elections is, however, uncer-
tain despite the presence of a political “uneven playing field” (Levitsky & Way, 2012, pp.
2930). Multiparty elections open a turf for the political opposition to challenge the
incumbent despite any irregularities (Lindberg, 2006,2009; Howard & Roessler, 2006;
Brownlee, 2007,2009; Tucker, 2007; Teorell & Hadenius, 2009; Bunce & Wolchik,
2011; Kaya & Bernhard, 2013; Miller, 2015; Edgell et al., 2017; Bernhard et al., 2020).
Opposition parties can exploit existing social divisions and the accumulated public
dissatisfaction with the government.
While typical autocracies survive by using a combination of political repression,
legitimation, and socioeconomic co-optation (Gerschewski, 2013), in a competitive
authoritarian system, the option of political repression is far more limited due to rule-
of-law institutions and the presence of registered political parties and relatively autono-
mous media and civil organizations (Lindberg, 2007). At the onset of an autocratization
strategy, the governing party cannot use the type and scale of repression employed by
typical authoritarian regimes such as the banning of opposition parties and candidates,
the censorship of all expressions of political dissent, the imprisonment and torture of
political opponents, and the abolition of elections altogether. Instead, the system of
political participation permits the political activities of opposition forces and the mobi-
lization of public protest, which raises the risk of electoral defeat for the incumbent
(Howard & Roessler, 2006;Beissinger,2007; Bunce & Wolchik, 2011;Lindberg,
2009; Bernhard et al., 2020). If the government chooses to violently suppress political
protest, particularly on a mass scale, it risks triggering a spiral of public uprisings and,
Trantidis | The Political Economy of Autocratization 119
potentially, a level of turmoil that could undermine its claim of political legitimacy and
jeopardize its political future (Haiduk, 2009,p.22).
In each setting, of course, strategies for autocratization will play out against distinct
structural conditions (Gandhi & Lust-Okar, 2009). In several post-communist coun-
tries, for example, political organizations gave rise to a relatively pluralist multiparty
system thanks to adequate campaign resources (Olson, 1998,p.434; Golosov, 1998).
Economic reforms, constitutional norms, and autonomous societal organizations con-
tributed to the democratization process and protected these societies from an authori-
tarian backlash (Fish, 1999,p.800). Moreover, the wave of color revolutions in several
post-Soviet republics indicates that, even in situations in which conditions had previously
favored aspiring autocrats, when they chose to resort to blatant political violence, they
faced a backlash from the political opposition and civil society organizations that mobi-
lized large public crowds and demonstrated their strength (cf. Schedler, 2002; Bunce &
Wolchik, 2006). Rather than reducing their exposure to political competition, violent
responses to public discontent boomeranged by becoming a critical juncture for the
regime, for instance, in Ukraine with the Orange Revolution in 2004 and the Maidan
Square protests in 2014.
Against this backdrop, aspiring autocrats must find a way to reduce their exposure to
political contestation and must do so by sustaining a public claim of legitimacy, meaning
that they should avoid reaching a situation in which violent repressive tactics would seem
to be the only option effective in preventing the collapse of their government against
intense public protests and an increasingly popular political opposition. The problem
aspiring autocrats face is how to preempt the escalation of public protest or at least
withstand such events once they occur. Public protestations have a self-reinforcing
dynamic when public perceptions of risk from taking part in them are relaxed due to
network effects. As Lindberg (2009) notes, political actors are self-reflexive individuals
and their political calculations, choices, and expectations are conditioned by signals from
their social environment (pp. 317318). When citizens believe that others, including
parts of the elite, would turn against the incumbent and would defend democratic
institutions, even the risk-averse ones may feel more comfortable openly expressing their
political views, joining public rallies and supporting the activities of the opposition
(Lindberg, 2007;2009, pp. 317318).
A possible way for aspiring autocrats to preempt the public expression of dissent is by
gaining the loyalty of political and socioeconomic elites and, at the same time, the
support of large segments of the electorate through socioeconomic co-optation (Giliomee
& Simkins, 1999,p.2; Greene, 2007; Lust-Okar, 2009; Silitski, 2009;Go
¨bel, 2011;
Ambrosio, 2014). Co-optation is usually achieved through the distribution of financial
resources and socioeconomic opportunities by a political agent to supporters in exchange
for their loyalty (cf. Van de Walle, 2006; Lust-Okar, 2009). However, several types of
clientelist rewards that could be used for co-opting larger segments of the population,
such as payouts, jobs, and career promotions, are costly and work more effectively in
relatively poor societies (Magaloni, 2006). Moreover, in several authoritarian systems,
clientelist policies tend to fuel rather than mitigate competition over their distribution
120 COMMUNIST AND POST-COMMUNIST STUDIES DECEMBER 2021
(Lust, 2009). At the same time, co-optation works in a retaliatory way by punishing
dissenters and defectors with exclusion from the same range of benefits offered to
supporters. The flip side of clientelism involves discriminatory measures targeting actual
and prospective dissenters, such as dismissals from state employment, unfavorable job
placements within the public sector, refusal to grant a license to businesses, delay in the
delivery of government services, refusal to provide credit from state-controlled banks, and
discriminatory tax controls. Actual cases of political reprisal have a wider effect across the
population, acting as signals about the kind of costs one would expect for making similar
political choices.
For co-optation to be successful, it must prevent the opposition from gathering
a significant number of organized supporters and enough resources to build a credible
political campaign. This prospect is more likely to occur in an economy dominated by the
state, where the potential structure of co-optation is so extensive that socioeconomic
actors could not easily evade or mitigate the cost of sanctions imposed by the government
(Trantidis, 2015). When rule-of-law protections from government discrimination are not
available to citizens, a governing elite can manipulate the distribution of resources and
the regulatory functions of the government for the purpose of restricting political free-
dom. When citizens find themselves vulnerable to the prospect of discrimination and
exclusion for their political choices, co-optation has a coercive effect on their behavior,
working similarly to how typical threats of violence restrict free choice, because unmit-
igated socioeconomic sanctions would force vulnerable citizens to restrict their political
expression against their own will. An all-encompassing structure of co-optation, in such
a coercive form, will prevent the consolidation of public support for the political oppo-
sition, simultaneously helping the regime avoid a recourse to mass-scale acts or threats of
violence. On these grounds, a political regime that heavily relies on this coercive form of
co-optation should be classified as authoritarian even if it wins elections and claims that it
enjoys public approval (Trantidis, 2015,p.126).
BUILDING UP A REPRESSIVE REGIME IN BELARUS
Lukashenko was elected president of Belarus in 1994 and won consecutive elections,
consolidating an authoritarian regime without facing a considerable political challenge
from the opposition forces (Bennett, 2011; Wilson, 2011). This is puzzling because
Belarus is a country with high levels of socioeconomic development, which tend to
facilitate the development of a vibrant and stable democracy (cf. Korosteleva, Lawson
& Marsh, 2003, pp. 4,6; Dowley & Silver, 2002). In opinion polls, the Belarusian
public featured as the second most pro-democracy electorate after Estonia among the
countries of the former Soviet Union (Haerpfer, 2003; cf. Korosteleva, Lawson &
Marsh, 2003,p.8).
In the final years of the Soviet Union, civil society organizations were formed during
Gorbachev’s political initiative, Glasnost0. After the failure of the August 1991 coup in
Moscow, Stanislau Shushkevich took the office of the chairman of the Supreme Soviet
and proclaimed the independence of Belarus. Prime Minister Kebich, who had resigned
Trantidis | The Political Economy of Autocratization 121
from the Communist Party a day before its dissolution, challenged Shushkevich for the
post of the chairman of the Supreme Council. In September 1991, Kebich dropped out of
the race and failed to oust Shushkevich in a motion of no-confidence in 1993 (Bugajski,
2002,p.7). By the mid-1990s, several competing political parties and movements had
been formed: the Communist Party, which would later split into supporters and oppo-
nents of Lukashenko, the Agrarian Party, the United Civic Party, the People’s Accord
Party (later, the Social Democratic Party of Public Accord), the Belarusian People’s Front
or Belarusian Popular Front (BFP), the Belarusian Social Democratic Party (People’s
Assembly), the Belarusian Christian Democracy movement, and the Belarusian Green
Party. As in other post-communist countries, these nascent political organizations were
expressing various socioeconomic and political divisions in Belarusian society; there were
liberals, conservatives, nationalists, social democrats, and trade unionists representing
farmers and industrial workers (Lewis, 2000, pp. 56,58). During the same period, private
media started broadcasting their programs (Marples & Padhol, 2002). Socioeconomic
cleavages in the Belarusian society could have given rise to a pluralistic political landscape
(Korosteleva, 2003b, pp. 6162).
The political landscape of the period between 1988 and 1994 stands in sharp contrast
to the ensuing years during which the Lukashenko regime effectively marginalized any
political opposition (Silitski, 2006,p.139). In 1994, Lukashenko ran for president
without a party organization to back him but launched an assertive campaign against
corruption and promised to protect Belarus from the painful economic transition which
other post-communist societies were experiencing in that period (Marples, 1999b, p. 575;
2004b, p. 40). Soon after he gained power, Lukashenko clashed with the parliament and
the constitutional court over the extent to which he could use presidential decrees to
legislate. While his presidential powers were already strong, he took action to further
limit the powers of the parliament. Taking advantage of his popularity, he called a series
of constitutional referendums with a proposal for a centralized system of governance,
which the public approved. Using the new powers bestowed by the constitution, Luka-
shenko took steps to control the judiciary and the media (Korosteleva, Lawson & Marsh,
2003, pp. 7,19). Though these actions cost him some of his early allies, Lukashenko
eventually succeeded in gaining the support of most of the members of parliament
(Rontoyanni & Korosteleva 2005,p.211; Silitski 2010a, pp. 282283).
The opposition parties were unable to prevent the institutional changes that made the
post of the president very powerful (Korosteleva, 2003b, pp. 6365), and they did not
pose a threat to Lukashenko’s regime in any of the ensuing elections (Korosteleva, 2000,
2003b; Rotman & Danilov, 2003; Brzozovska, 2004,p.74).
2
They had to operate in an
increasingly hostile environment, facing bureaucratic obstacles as well as the prosecutions
of several politicians, activists, and journalists sympathetic to the opposition (Amnesty
International, 1999; HHRW, 1999). When confronted with domestic and international
criticism for his authoritarian conduct, Lukashenko dubbed these voices an attack on
2. Despite electoral irregularities (OSCE, 2006), Lukashenko retained relatively high levels of popularity. For
instance, in 2001, an independent poll gave Lukashenko a popularity of around 45%(see IISEPS, 2001,p.5).
122 COMMUNIST AND POST-COMMUNIST STUDIES DECEMBER 2021
Belarusian sovereignty (Leshchenko, 2008). Alarmed by these events, several opposition
parties joined forces in the presidential elections of 2001 and 2006 but failed to unseat
Lukashenko, who won 75%of the votes in 2010 and 82.6%in 2006. Foreign observers
described the 2006 election in Belarus as unfair, referring to episodes in which the
government harassed the opposition’s activities (OSCE, 2006). Some opposition candi-
dates and parties were denied electoral registration while some members of the opposi-
tion were arrested (Freedom House, 2007). When public protests broke up in 2006, the
opposition was too weak to take a lead against the government’s counter-mobilization of
political support (Korosteleva, 2009a, p. 328).
BUILDING A DOMINANT IDEOLOGY AND AN AUTHORITARIAN SOCIAL CONTRACT
A central component of Lukashenko’s autocratization strategy was to accommodate
predominant public preferences on the issues of national identity and economic policy.
Described as “egalitarian nationalism,” his ideological message defined the Belarusian
nation in an ethnically inclusive way and promoted a collectivist ethos in the economy
and society (Leshchenko, 2008). On the question of national identity, Lukashenko
endorsed the country’s political independence but recognized Belarus’s cultural affinity
with Russia (Mihalisko, 1997; Zaprudnik, 2003; Brzozovska, 2004,p.105; Allison,
White & Light, 2005; Ioffe, 2007,p.49).
3
He rejected the ethno-Belarusian national
identity that the nationalist forces were advocating and, instead, exploited historical
memories from World War II to discredit the nationalist agenda. Lukashenko’s eco-
nomic rhetoric resonated with widespread public nostalgia for aspects of life during the
Soviet Union (Lindner, 2002,p.81; Marples, 1999a, pp. 103104) when Belarus was
considered a relatively successful case of postwar industrialization (Bakanova et al., 2001,
pp. 413; Bakanova & de Suza, 2002, pp. 35; Lubachko, 1972, pp. 6,7679). He
supported a protectionist role for the state in the economy and proposed a gradual pace
of economic reforms (Ioffe, 2007,p.45), addressing a population fearful of economic
decline (cf. Rose & Haerpfer, 1998,p.36; Marples, 1999a, p. 93), particularly the older
generation, farmers, state employees, industrial workers, and the military (Zlotnikov,
2002a, p. 131; Marples, 2004a, p. 9; Yarashevich, 2014). By pledging to protect Belar-
usians from external and internal economic and political threats (Bennett, 2011,p.289),
Lukashenko offered citizens what has been described as an “authoritarian bargain” or
a type of “social contract” in which citizens are asked to surrender their political freedoms
in exchange for a degree of social protection and welfare provided by the state (Haiduk,
Rakova & Silitski, 2009; Praneviciute-Neliups
ˇiene & Maksimiuk, 2012).
What is particularly interesting, however, is that the opposition forces adopted pop-
ular aspects of Lukashenko’s political and economic ideology. In the 2001 presidential
elections, several parties supported Uładzimir Hanc
ˇaryk (Vladimir Goncharik), a former
3. Belarus drifted to independence rather unwillingly (cf. Garnett & Legvold, 1999,p.2). In the Union
plebiscite of March 1991,83%of Belarusians voted in favor of upholding the USSR (Mihalisko, 1997,p.242;
Marples, 1999a, p. 59).
Trantidis | The Political Economy of Autocratization 123
chairman of the Free Trade Union of Belarus as a candidate for president who chose not
to antagonize Lukashenko’s message for social protection and economic stability. His
electoral manifesto pledged to increase the budget for social policies, raise the minimal
wage, and increase pensions and pay them on time. Hanc
ˇaryk promised the war veterans
and the victims of the Chernobyl accident that he would restore their financial privileges,
which Lukashenko had taken away. At the same time, his campaign sought to expose the
regime’s policy failures and rhetorical inconsistencies on issues such as corruption and
poverty, the multiple administrative and regulatory hindrances which small and medium
enterprises were facing, the country’s isolation from the West, Lukashenko’s haphazard
relations with Russia, and his abuses of human rights and civil liberties. Though this
discourse appeared to be a strategically sensible decision for the opposition, Hanc
ˇaryk
gathered no more than 15%of the votes. With few active supporters, limited campaign
resources, and almost no favorable media coverage to help him run a visible campaign, he
was not seen as a credible contestant for power. The presidential election of 2001
revealed the opposition’s organizational disadvantage against Lukashenko’s political
infrastructure.
4
SOCIOECONOMIC CO-OPTATION
How was co-optation helpful for Lukashenko’s autocratization strategy? In Belarus, the
economy was largely unreformed (Zaprudnik, 1993, pp. 193194; Zlotnikov, 2002b, pp.
125,129; Lawson, 2003; Lisovskaia & Korosteleva, 2003,p.146) and the Lukashenko
government had retained extensive distributive and regulatory powers, which it used to
exert political pressure on businesses and state employees (Feduta, 2005,p.109; Way,
2010,p.250).
Large segments of the Belarusian population were dependent on state employment
and finance (Glambotskaya, 2009,p.96). Most of the working population was em-
ployed by the government. Between 1997 and 2007,5560%of the employed personnel
worked for state-owned firms while part of what was registered as private employment in
official statistics was in enterprises under partial state ownership (EBRD 1995,p.27). In
2007, only 0.4%of the employed worked in foreign-owned companies, while 1.4%
worked in companies that were partially foreign owned. Privatization in Belarus was
limited and tightly controlled by the government. By 2001,3,474 enterprises, which
were employing 21%of the total workforce, had been reformed as joint-stock companies
with the state as the main shareholder. In 2004,82%of industrial output and 74%of
industrial employment remained under government control (World Bank, 2005, pp. 35
36). State factories and farms operated under direct presidential rule (Mihalisko, 1997,p.
269). High taxation, excessive regulation, the inadequate protection of property rights,
4. Hanc
ˇaryk later noticed: “I was promised support from the leaders of a number of large enterprises, material
support, campaigning among people. ...However, I admit, this did not work as expected” (interview with Vı
´tal’
Tsygankou
˘for Tabula Rasa in Russian, on 28 March 2010, available from https://docplayer.com/146012846-
Vladimir-goncharik-ya-nikogda-ne-stremilsya-k-vlasti-radi-vlasti-16-obnovleno-13.html [Last accessed 29 August
2021].
124 COMMUNIST AND POST-COMMUNIST STUDI ES D ECEMBER 2021
and discretionary government interference created an institutional setting hostile to
private business (Bakanova, Estrin, Pelipas & Pukovich, 2006; Bertelsmann Stiftung,
2006). As a result, small and medium-size businesses represented a small share of GDP.
State support to parochial state factories crowded out private investment and raised the
cost for private companies to obtain credit from banks. The private sector remained
dependent on the discretion of state authorities for subsidies or loans from state-managed
banks. The government renationalized several financial institutions, beginning in 1995
with the forced merger of the Belarusbank stock company, the Savings Bank, and the
Interbank Currency Exchange (ICE) (Mihalisko, 1997, pp. 268269).
Belarus’s economic structure offered the regime the opportunity to deploy a mass-scale
system of checks on political behavior (cf. Belova-Gille, 2003;Way,2010,p.249;
Greene, 2009,p.813). Lack of transparency and favoritism governed the allocation of
economic opportunities and fiscal resources (Glambotskaya, 2009,p.96). With defi-
cient rule-of-law norms, large segments of the population were vulnerable to politicized
rewards and sanctions and had good reasons to comply with the regime’s request for
political conformity. The so-called “nomenklatura entrepreneurs” received privileged
treatment in return for their political loyalty (Zlotnikov 2002b, p. 136; Matsuzato,
2004; Yarashevich, 2014). In state-owned factories and the public administration, the
regime could hire and fire state employees on political grounds (Silitski, 2005,p.92;
Rakova & Lisovskaya, 2009,p.135; Frear, 2012,p.23; Yarashevich, 2014,p.1718).
Private enterprises were vulnerable to unfair and arbitrary treatment, facing the spectrum
of confiscation, asset freezing, and forced re-nationalization (World Bank, 2005, pp. 174,
176; Glambotskaya, 2009,p.106). The menu of sanctions involved fines, the denial of
registration, and the imprisonment of entrepreneurs on several bureaucratic grounds
(World Bank, 2005, pp. 174,176). For entrepreneurs who might have wanted to contest
government policies, public protest was a costly and uncertain option compared to what
they could achieve in private deals with government officials (Glambotskaya, 2009,p.
107). When a number of small-business entrepreneurs organized a strike against the
newly introduced value-added tax (VAT) and a public rally in Minsk in 2005, their
protest did not assume an anti-government character. Representatives from this group
refused to engage with the political opposition and directly negotiated with the govern-
ment. Likewise, in September 2007, there was a public rally of entrepreneurs in Banhalor
Square in Minsk, but this event did not develop into a political protest act against the
government.
The Lukashenko regime also targeted civil society organizations and the media. Their
activities were subjected to systematic surveillance and harassment (OSCE et al., 2001;
Marples, 2006,p.358; Forbrig et al., 2006,p.11). State companies took over the
publication and distribution of newspapers and, on several occasions, refused to publish
and distribute the pro-opposition press (UNCHR, 1996; Garnett & Legvold, 1999,p.4;
Marples 1999a, pp. 80,81,100; Freedom House, 2006). All TV channels remained
under state control and their political programs were censored by the government. In
2005, Reporters Without Borders ranked Belarus 152nd out of 167 countries in its press
freedom index. The government shut down institutions with a Western and liberal-
Trantidis | The Political Economy of Autocratization 125
democratic ideological orientation, such as the European Humanities University, the
Yakub Kolas National Humanities Lyceum, and the Institute of Social-Economic and
Political Research (NISEPI). NGOs were banned from raising independent revenue
through business activities. Their operation was monitored by the government. These
organizations could be liquidated by an administrative act. In 1995, the new Law on
Public Associations in Belarus required the re-registration of all NGOs. As a result, 400
of the 700 previously associations were excluded from the official registry. Civil society
organizations critical of the government could not easily find financial sponsors from the
private sector whose entrepreneurs and managers were understandably fearful of the
consequences from upsetting the government. To curtail the financing of NGOs from
outside Belarus, foreign contributions had to be officially registered and could be pro-
hibited if the government claimed that they would support “subversive activities” and the
“meddling into the internal affairs of Belarus” (Freedom House, 2006). At the same
time, the government sponsored the creation of “puppet” organizations controlled by the
regime itself (Marin, 2012,p.20) or receiving donations from government allies (Free-
dom House, 2006; Marples, 1999a, pp. 100101).
In this environment, the political opposition could not secure enough funding, get
favorable media coverage for its activities and programmatic agenda, and recruit a larger
number of active supporters in order to run an effective electoral campaign. Without
adequate resources, the opposition forces were not able to send a visible political message
and capitalize on public discontent. Subsequently, most of the public did not see the
opposition as a reliable alternative for government. Lukashenko gained a monopoly in
political organization and communication and succeeded in heavily distorting the con-
ditions in which the electorate formed political opinions and voting preferences.
RUSSIA AND THE SUSTAINABILITY OF BELARUS’S AUTOCRATIZATION MODEL
Lukashenko justified the nature of the control he exercised over society and the economy
with a conservative vision of economic policy skeptical of market liberalization. This
discourse was not countered by an alternative narrative from the side of the opposition.
Lukashenko’s economic message remained popular, in large part, thanks to the relative
economic stability Belarus enjoyed. In the first years of Lukashenko in power, industrial
output and exports rose and the country registered relatively low levels of unemployment.
With a good record of growth and poverty reduction, Belarus escaped the economic
malaise that plagued most post-communist economies during the early years of their
transition (World Bank, 2005,p.8). The improvement in economic performance was
particularly noticeable between 1995 and 2004 in sharp contrast to the deteriorating
economic circumstances of the previous years.
5
The poverty rate fell from 46.7%in 1999
to 17.8%in 2004, largely due to the growth of labor-intensive sectors supported by
5. Real per capita income in 1995 was 56%of the 1990 income level (UNDP, 1997,p.15). The real wage in
1995 fell to 55.3%of what it was in 1990 (UNDP, 1997,p.16).
126 COMMUNIST AND POST-COMMUNIST STUDIES DECEMBER 2021
government wages and income policies (World Bank, 2005,p.3).
6
Inflation rates
dropped significantly while budget deficits and debt remained moderate (World Bank,
2005,p.5). Thanks to relative economic success, the government periodically increased
the basic wage and the maternity pay. Real wages grew higher than the GDP (World
Bank, 2005, pp. 2223).
By the beginning of the 2000s, the government could boast that the economy had
been growing at a pace higher than that of all other former Soviet Union republics.
Between 1996 and 2004, overall GDP growth averaged 6.6%per annum or 77.4%
cumulatively (World Bank, 2005,p.1). Belarus grew faster than the Baltic countries and
Russia. By 2004, Belarus and Uzbekistan were the only countries of the Commonwealth
of Independent States (CIS) to exceed their GDP levels in the year 1989.
7
By the same
year, Belarus had surpassed its real gross industrial output in 1989 by 41.2%against the
average performance of the CIS of –24.6%(UNECE, 2005,p.72). Employment grew
from 58.4%in 2000 to 60.6%in 2003 (UNDP, 2005,p.31). A World Bank Report
(2005, pp. 2233) confirmed that economic growth was genuine and robust.
Belarus’s relatively good economic performance heavily relied on the economic assis-
tance from Russia mainly in the form of cheaper energy prices and preferential access to
its internal market (Balmaceda, 2002; Brukoff, 2002,p.111; Sahm & Westphal, 2002;
World Bank, 2005,p.138).
8
In return, Belarus offered Russia a transit route for the
supply of oil and gas to Europe, granted preferential access to its own market, and favored
Russian companies in government purchases.
9
Revenues produced by the energy sector
gave the regime the resources necessary to secure the support of the political and eco-
nomic elite (Balmaceda, 2014a, p. 526;2014b). Yet the relationship between the two
countries was on several occasions tense over disputes about energy prices. Lukashenko
considered the Russian pipelines on the territory of Belarus as a source of bargaining
strength in his negotiations with Putin (Hancock, 2006,p.119) and exploited the fact
that Belarus was strategically important for Russia as a bulwark against the NATO’s
eastward enlargement (Nikonov, 1999,p.112).
While Lukashenko benefited from the special economic privileges Russia was offering
to Belarus, he did not want to undermine the country’s political autonomy and, conse-
quently, his unrivaled grip on Belarusian politics. The political relationship between
Belarus and Russia was cumbersome (Deyermond, 2004). In the mid-1990s, the two
governments started an inconclusive dialogue on the prospect of unification, with the
signing of a series of treaties, such as a pact on the Russia and Belarus Community
6. However, poverty was unevenly distributed with the lowest concentration in Minsk (10.4%in 2003) and
the urban centers, and the highest in rural areas (UNDP, 2005,p.33).
7.By13.4%, with Uzbekistan 19.5%, while the total GDP growth in the CIS was –19.8%(UNECE, 2005,p.
70).
8. “Belarus large-scale businessmen did not have access to sources of income independently of the president,
which meant much more limited freedom of action than in the Ukrainian case” (Balmaceda, 2014a, p. 527).
9. The degree of dependence was illustrated by several studies published by the Institute for Privatisation and
Management (IPM), available from http://eng.research.by/publications/dp/ [Last accessed 29 August 2021]. A hike
in gas prices would have caused substantial losses in the Belarusian economy and could have forced the Belarusian
government to draw revenue through extensive privatization (cf. Hawser, 2007).
Trantidis | The Political Economy of Autocratization 127
(1996), a treaty on the Russia-Belarus Union, the Union Charter (1997), a treaty on
equal rights for Russian and Belarusian citizens (1998), a treaty on the Union State
(1999), and a treaty toward the creation of a customs union (1999). Talks were held
about the creation of a currency union but the final agreement was postponed several
times. In April 2005, Belarus and Russia signed a foreign policy action program for their
prospective union. Belarus also joined the Collective Security Treaty under the Com-
monwealth of Independent States (CIS) and entered negotiations to join a Single Eco-
nomic Space with Russia, Ukraine, Kazakhstan, and Belarus, granting free movement for
goods, capitals, services, and workers. But Lukashenko rejected Putin’s idea of a fully
integrated political union with Russia (Marples, 2004a, p. 17).
For Lukashenko, this prospect could have offered him a share in power much beyond
the limits of Belarusian politics (see Marples, 2004a, p. 16;To
¨rnquist-Plewa, 2004,p.
24), but, with Russia under the iron rule of Putin, this became an unrealistic ambition.
Moreover, as the Russian government was increasingly more aggressive toward several of
its neighboring countries, Lukashenko grew anxious with the prospect of political sub-
ordination to Moscow, especially when Russia clashed with Georgia in 2009 and Putin
called Belarus to recognize the autonomy of Abkhazia and South Ossetia, and a few years
later, when Putin supported a secessionist rebellion in Ukraine and forced the annexation
of Crimea.
Despite tensions in the relationship between Lukashenko and Putin, Belarus’s eco-
nomic dependence on Russia was vital for the sustainability of Lukashenko’s model of
autocratization. A close political relationship with Russia required that Belarus keep
a distance from the West, rejecting any association with NATO and the prospect of
membership in the European Union. Although Lukashenko initially expressed his sym-
pathy with the prospect of accession to the European Union (EU) during a visit to
Brussels a few months after becoming president (Lindner, 2002,p.87), he soon adopted
an anti-Western rhetoric that was congruent with the country’s dependence on economic
assistance from Russia. Belarus was originally excluded from a closer association with the
EU under the European Neighborhood Policy (Korosteleva, 2009b), but, a few years
later, it became a member of the EU Eastern Partnership in 2009, a political forum
promoting closer trade relationships between post-Soviet states and the European Union.
However, further institutional association, such as obtaining the status of a candidate
state for EU membership, was conditional on the implementation of economic and
political reforms. This trajectory would have undermined the foundations of Lukashen-
ko’s autocratization strategy, including his political relationship with Moscow. It would
have ended the Russian subsidies and privileges that sustained both Belarus’s unreformed
economy and the regime’s practice of socioeconomic co-optation.
CONCLUSION
This article’s analysis of the Belarusian case is addressing the following question: What
sustains a transition from competitive authoritarianism to a hegemonic regime? Aspiring
autocrats must win elections in order to support a claim of popular legitimacy. They can
128 COMMUNIST AND POST-COMMUNIST STUDIES DECEMBER 2021
use repression tactics to attack the opposition and stifle expressions of political dissent,
but, in the presence of electoral competition, repression alone does not guarantee success.
Violent and blatant acts of repression, such as bans on political activity, mass-scale
electoral fraud, and incarcerations, can actually backfire by triggering protests and steering
public sympathy with and support for the opposition, ultimately undermining the gov-
ernment’s stability, popularity, and image of public legitimacy. Aspiring autocrats must
find a way to reduce their exposure to political competition in an environment in which
the political opposition could exploit social cleavages, ideological divisions, and policy
failures as favorable conditions for its electoral campaign. A successful strategy of auto-
cratization requires subtler tactics that would deprive the political opposition of resources
necessary for launching a viable campaign without undermining the regime’s image as
legitimate and popular.
The case of Belarus demonstrates how co-optation works as a key strategic tool for
propelling a process of autocratization and, in particular, how the dominant role of the
state in the economy and society facilitates the use of co-optation in a coercive fashion.
The dependency of the majority of the Belarusian population on government distribu-
tions and regulations enabled Lukashenko to manufacture a political system of low
contestability. In an economy dominated by the state, the vast majority of Belarusians
could not evade government discrimination or mitigate the cost of exclusion from
socioeconomic resources and opportunities. Few citizens would openly express their
support for the opposition or make a contribution to its campaign. Against a weak
opposition, Lukashenko was able to pass institutional reforms with public approval,
further undermining rule-of-law protections and entrenching an illiberal mode of
governance.
This analysis also helps us understand why, as of June 2021, the Lukashenko regime
has endured several months of sizable protests amid an economic crisis and despite his
careless handling of the COVID-19 pandemic. As in the events of the Arab Spring in the
early 2010s, social media platforms in Belarus were less susceptible to state censorship
and facilitated networked interactions leading to mass public protests after a long period
of relative political stagnation (cf. Howard & Hussain, 2013). We also discern key factors
of authoritarian resilience at play, as identified by the literature: the mobilization of the
state apparatus against the protesters (cf. Slater & Fenner, 2011; Andersen et al., 2014),
an aggressively conspiratorial rhetoric against the opposition, aiming to defend the
government’s legitimacy claim (cf. Gerschewski, 2013), and the intervention of Russia
as an external factor providing guidance and support to the Lukashenko regime (cf.
Burnell & Schlumberger, 2010; Jamal, 2012). It is plausible to suggest that a key reason
why the regime still secures the cohesion and loyalty of the state apparatus is that Russia
keeps offering the kind of political reassurance that helps Lukashenko claim that his
system of socioeconomic co-optation would remain in place.
From a theoretical point of view, Belarus demonstrates that socioeconomic co-
optation is a key component in the political economy of autocratization. A social and
economic structure prone to discretionary allocations of resources by the government, if
sustained financially, will allow aspiring autocrats to skew the terms in which political
Trantidis | The Political Economy of Autocratization 129
competition takes place heavily in their favor. By offering socioeconomic rewards to
supporters and imposing sanctions on dissenters, they signal to the rest of the population
the type of benefits and costs they should expect depending on their political behavior. In
the absence of sizable spheres of socioeconomic activity autonomous from government,
co-optation practices and signals have a coercive effect on political behavior, forcing
citizens to demonstrate complacency with the regime and abstain from openly supporting
the political opposition. This way, aspiring autocrats can reduce their exposure to polit-
ical and electoral competition without resorting to systematic and large-scale violence,
which could undermine their claim of public legitimacy. n
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
The author wants to thank the reviewers, the editor, and the participants of the ECPR
workshop on personalistic politics at the Joint Sessions in Mons, Belgium, in April 2019
for the valuable comments offered for prior versions of this article. Special thanks to
Uladzislau Belavusau and Ales
´Łahviniec for reviewing parts of this article.
Corresponding author’s email: Atrantidis@lincoln.ac.uk
REFERENCES
Allison, R., White, S. & Light, M. (2005) Belarus between East and West. Journal of Communist
Studies and Transition Politics. 21 (4), 487511.
Ambrosio, T. (2014) Beyond the transition paradigm: A research agenda for authoritarian consol-
idation. Demokratizatsiya: The Journal of Post-Soviet Democratization. 22 (3), 471495.
Amnesty International. (1999) Concerns in Europe, July–December 1998, EUR 01/01/99. Avail-
able from: https://www.amnesty.org/en/documents/eur01/001/1999/en/ [Accessed 10 Septem-
ber 2020].
Andersen, D., Møller, J., Rørbæk, L. L. & Skaaning, S.-E. (2014) State capacity and political regime
stability. Democratization. 21 (7), 13051325.
Clem, J. I., Balmaceda, M. M. & Tarlow, L. L. (eds.) (2002)Independent Belarus: Domestic deter-
minants, regional dynamics, and implications for the West. Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press.
Bakanova, M. & de Souza, L. V. (2002) Trade and growth under limited liberalization: The case of
Belarus. Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper 2002-053/2. Available from: http://ssrn.com/
abstract¼316339 [Accessed 29 August 2021].
Bakanova, M., de Souza, L. V., Kolesnikova, I. & Abramov, I. (2001) Explaining growth in Belarus.
Paper presented for the Global Development Network (GDN) and Economic Education and
Research Consortium (EERC) project “Explaining Growth in CIS.” Rio de Janeiro.
Bakanova, M., Estrin, S., Pelipas, I. & Pukovich, S. (2006) Enterprise restructuring in Belarus.
William Davidson Institute Working Paper No. 823. Available from: http://ssrn.com/
abstract¼918081 [Accessed 29 August 2021].
Balmaceda, M. (2002) Belarus as a transit route: Domestic and foreign policy implications. In:
Balmaceda, M., et al. (eds.) Independent Belarus: Domestic determinants, regional dynamics, and
implications for the West. Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press, pp. 162196.
Balmaceda, M. (2014a) Energy policy in Belarus: Authoritarian resilience, social contracts, and
patronage in a post-Soviet environment. Eurasian Geography and Economics. 55 (5), 514536.
130 COMMUNIST AND POST-COMMUNIST STUDIES D ECEMBER 2021
Balmaceda, M. (2014b) Living the high life in Minsk: Russian energy rents, domestic populism and
Belarus’ impending crisis. Budapest, Central European University Press.
Bedford, S. (2017) “The election game”: Authoritarian consolidation processes in Belarus. Demok-
ratizatsiya: The Journal of Post-Soviet Democratization. 25 (4), 381405.
Beichelt, T. (2004) Autocracy and democracy in Belarus, Russia and Ukraine. Democratization.11
(5), 113132.
Beissinger, M. R. (2007) Structure and example in modular political phenomena: The diffusion of
Bulldozer/Rose/Orange/Tulip Revolutions. Perspectives on Politics. 59 (2), 259276.
Belova-Gille, O. (2003) Difficulties in elite formation in Belarus after 1991. In: Korosteleva, E. A.,
Lawson, C. W. & Marsh, R. J. (eds.) Contemporary Belarus: Between democracy and dictatorship.
New York, Routledge Curzon, pp. 5367.
Bennett, B. (2011)The last dictatorship in Europe: Belarus under Lukashenko. New York, Columbia
University Press.
Bernhard, M., Edgell, A. B. & Lindberg, S. I. 2020. Institutionalising electoral uncertainty and
authoritarian regime survival. European Journal of Political Research.59 (2), 465487.
Bertelsmann Stiftung. (2006) Bertelsmann transformation index 2006. Available from: https://bti-
project.org/en/meta/downloads.html?&cb¼00000 [Accessed 12 September 2021].
Bogaards, M. & Boucek, F. (2010)Dominant political parties and democracy. London, Routledge.
Brownlee, J. (2007)Authoritarianism in an age of democratization. Cambridge, Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.
Brownlee, J. (2009) Portents of pluralism: How hybrid regimes affect democratic transitions.
American Journal of Political Science. 53 (3), 515532.
Brukoff, P. (2002) The Belarusian economy: Is it sustainable? In: Balmaceda, M., et al. (eds.)
Independent Belarus: Domestic determinants, regional dynamics, and implications for the West.
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press, pp. 109121.
Brzozovska, A. (2004) Discourses of empowerment: Understanding Belarus’ international orienta-
tion. In: Rindzeviciute, E. (ed.) Contemporary Change in Belarus. Stockholm, So
¨derto
¨rns Ho
¨gs-
kola, pp. 73108.
Bugajski, J. (2002) Political parties of Eastern Europe: A guide to politics in the post-communist era.
New York, M. E. Sharpe.
Bunce, V. J. & Wolchik, S. L. (2006) International diffusion and post-communist electoral revolu-
tions. Communist and Post-Communist Studies. 39 (3), 122.
Bunce, V. & Wolchik, S. L. (2011)Defeating authoritarian leaders in postcommunist countries. Cam-
bridge, Cambridge University Press.
Burnell, P. & Schlumberger, O. (2010) Promoting democracy – Promoting autocracy? International
politics and national political regimes. Contemporary Politics. 16 (1), 115.
Dahl, R. (1971)Polyarchy: Participation and opposition. New Haven, CT, and London, Yale Uni-
versity Press.
Deyermond, R. (2004) The State of the Union: Military success, economic and political failure in
the Russia-Belarus Union. Europe-Asia Studies. 56 (8), 11911205.
Donno, D. (2013) Elections and democratization in authoritarian regimes.” American Journal of
Political Science. 57 (3), 703716.
Dowley, K. M. & Silver, B. D. (2002) Social capital, ethnicity and support for democracy in the post-
communist states. Europe-Asia Studies. 54 (4), 505527.
EBRD. (1995)Transition Report 1995: Fixed investment and enterprise development. London, Euro-
pean Bank of Reconstruction and Development.
Edgell, A. B., Mechkova, V., Altman, D., Bernhard, M., & Lindberg, S. I. (2017) When and where do
elections matter? A global test of the democratization by elections hypothesis, 19002010.
Democratization. 25 (3), 422444.
Trantidis | The Political Economy of Autocratization 131
Eke, S. M. & Kuzio, T. (2000) Sultanism in Eastern Europe: The socio-political roots of author-
itarian populism in Belarus. Europe-Asia Studies. 52 (3), 523547.
Evans, G. & Whitefield, S. (1993) Identifying the bases of party competition in Eastern Europe.
British Journal of Political Science.23 (4), 521548.
Feduta, A. (2005)Lukashenko: politicheskaya biografiya [Lukashenka: a political biography]. Mos-
cow, Referendum.
Fish, S. M. (1999) Postcommunist subversion: Social science and democratization in East Europe
and Eurasia. Slavic Review. 58 (4), 794823.
Forbrig, J., Marples, D., & Demes, P. (2006) Introduction.” In: Forbrig, J., Marples, D. & Demes, P.
(eds.) Prospects for democracy in Belarus,2nd ed. Washington, DC, The German Marshall Fund,
pp. 1119.
Frear, M. (2012) Opposition strategies for the 2012 elections in Belarus. Baltic Rim Economies. 19
(6), 23.
Freedom House. (2006) Nations in transit: Belarus. Available from: www.freedomhouse.org [Ac-
cessed 1September 2017].
Freedom House. (2007) Freedom in the world—Belarus. Available from: http://www.
freedomhouse.org [Accessed 1September 2017].
Gandhi, J. & Lust-Oker, E. (2009) Elections under authoritarianism. Annual Review of Political
Science.12,403422.
Garnett, S. W. & Legvold, R. (eds.) (1999)Belarus at the crossroads. Washington, DC, Carnegie
Endowment for International Peace.
Gerschewski, J. (2013) The three pillars of stability: Legitimation, oppression and co-optation in
autocratic regimes. Democratization. 20 (1), 1338.
Giliomee, H. & Simkins, C. (1999)The awkward embrace: One-party domination and democracy.
Reading, UK, Harwood Academic.
Glambotskaya, A. (2009) Social contract: Business. In: Haiduk, K., Rakova, E. & Silitski, V. (eds.)
Social contracts in contemporary Belarus. Vilnius, Belarusian Institute for Strategic Studies, pp.
94114.
Go
¨bel. C. (2011) Authoritarian consolidation. European Political Science. 10 (2), 176190.
Golosov, G. V. (1998) Who survives? Party origins, organizational development, and electoral
performance in post-communist Russia. Political Studies. 46 (3), 511543.
Greene, K. F. (2007)Why dominant parties lose: Mexico’s democratization in comparative perspective.
New York, Cambridge University Press.
Greene, K. F. (2009) The political economy of authoritarian single-party dominance. Comparative
Political Studies. 43 (7), 807834.
Haerpfer, C. W. (2003) Electoral politics of Belarus compared. In: Korosteleva, E. A., Lawson, C.
W. & Marsh, R. J. (eds.) Contemporary Belarus: Between democracy and dictatorship. New York,
Routledge Curzon, pp. 8599.
Haiduk, K. (2009) Social contract: A conceptual framework. In: Haiduk, K, Rakova, E. & Silitski, V.
(eds.) Social contracts in contemporary Belarus. Vilnius, Belarusian Institute for Strategic Studies,
pp. 825.
Hancock, K. J. (2006) The semi-sovereign state: Belarus and the Russian neo-empire. Foreign Policy
Analysis. 6(2), 117136.
Hawser, A. (2007) Newsmakers: Belarus outlines privatization plans. Global Finance,18 July 2007.
Available from: https://www.gfmag.com/magazine/march-2007/newsmakers-belarus-outlines-
privatization-plans [Accessed 29 August 2021].
Helsinki Human Rights Watch (HHRW). (1999) Human rights developments: Republic of Belarus.
Available from: http://www.hrw.org/worldreport99/europe/belarus.html [Accessed 29 August
2021].
132 COMMUNIST AND POST-COMMUNIST STUDIES DECEMBER 2021
Howard, P. N. & Hussain, M. M. (2013)Democracy’s fourth wave? Digital media and the Arab
Spring. Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Howard, M. M. & Roessler, P. G. (2006) Liberalizing electoral outcomes in competitive authori-
tarian regimes.” American Journal of Political Science. 50 (2), 365381.
Independent Institute of Socio-Economic Studies (IISEPS). (2001) IISEPS News: Belarus: prospects
in the XXI century, results of a national opinion poll in October 2001.4(22), December.
Available from: http://www.iiseps.org/?p¼2277&lang¼en [Accessed 29 August 2021].
International Monetary Fund (IMF). (2006)World Economic Outlook Database 2006.April.
Washington, DC.
Ioffe, G. (2004) Understanding Belarus: Economy and political landscape. Europe-Asia Studies.56
(1), 85118.
Ioffe, G. (2007) Unfinished nation-building in Belarus and the 2006 presidential elections. Eur-
asian Geography and Economics. 48 (1), 3758.
Jamal, A. A. (2012)Of empires and citizens. Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press.
Kaya, R. & Bernhard, M. (2013) Are elections mechanisms of authoritarian stability or democrati-
zation? Evidence from postcommunist Eurasia. Perspectives on Politics. 11 (3), 734752.
Korosteleva, E. A. (2000) Electoral volatility in postcommunist Belarus: Explaining the paradox.
Party Politics. 6(3), 343358.
Korosteleva, E. A. (2003a) Is Belarus a demagogical democracy? Cambridge Review of International
Affairs. 16 (3), 525533.
Korosteleva, E. A. (2003b) Party system development in post-communist Belarus. In: Korosteleva,
E. A., Lawson, C. W. & Marsh, R. J. (eds.) Contemporary Belarus: Between democracy and
dictatorship. New York, Routledge Curzon, pp. 6884.
Korosteleva, E. A. (2004) The quality of democracy in Belarus and Ukraine. Journal of Communist
Studies and Transition Politics.20 (1), 122142.
Korosteleva, E. (2009a) Was there a quiet revolution? Belarus after the 2006 presidential election.
Journal of Communist Studies and Transition Politics.25 (23), 324346.
Korosteleva. E. (2009b) The limits of EU governance: Belarus’s response to the European Neigh-
bourhood Policy. Contemporary Politics.15 (2), 229245.
Korosteleva, E. (2012) Questioning democracy promotion: Belarus’ response to the “colour revolu-
tions.” Democratization. 19 (1), 3759.
Korosteleva, E. A., Lawson, C. W. & Marsh, R. J. (2003)Contemporary Belarus: Between democracy
and dictatorship. New York, Routledge Curzon.
Lawson, C. W. (2003) Path-dependence and the economy of Belarus: The consequences of the late
reforms. In: Korosteleva, E. A., Lawson, C. W. & Marsh, R. J. (eds.) Contemporary Belarus:
Between democracy and dictatorship. New York, Routledge Curzon, pp. 125136.
Leshchenko, N. (2008) The national ideology and the basis of the Lukashenka regime in Belarus.
Europe-Asia Studies. 60 (8), 14191433.
Levitsky, S. & Way, L. A. (2012)Competitive authoritarianism: Hybrid regimes after the cold war.
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Lewis, P. G. (2000)Political parties in post-communist Eastern Europe. London, Routledge.
Lindberg, S. I. (2006)Democracy and elections in Africa. Baltimore, MD, Johns Hopkins University
Press.
Lindberg, S. I. (2007) Democratization by elections in Africa revisited. Paper presented at American
Political Association’s 103rd Annual Meeting, 30 August–2September 2007.
Lindberg, S. (2009)Democratization by elections: A new mode of transition. Baltimore, MD, Johns
Hopkins University Press.
Lindner, R. (2002) The Lukashenka phenomenon. In: Balmaceda, M., et al. (eds.) Independent
Belarus: Domestic determinants, regional dynamics, and implications for the West. Cambridge, MA,
Harvard University Press, pp. 77108.
Trantidis | The Political Economy of Autocratization 133
Lisovskaia, N. & Korosteleva, J. (2003) Economic policy in Belarus from official and oppositional
perspectives. In: Korosteleva, E. A., Lawson, C. W. & Marsh, R. J. (eds.) Contemporary Belarus:
Between democracy and dictatorship. New York, Routledge Curzon, pp. 137151.
Lubachko, I. (1972)Belorussia under Soviet rule. Lexington, Kentucky University Press.
Lust, E. (2009) Democratization by elections? Competitive clientelism in the Middle East. Journal of
Democracy. 20 (3), 122135.
Lust-Okar, E. (2009) Legislative elections in hegemonic authoritarian regimes: Competitive clien-
telism and resistance to democratization. In: Lindberg, S. I. (ed.) Democratization by elections: A
new mode of transition. Baltimore, MD, Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 226245.
Magaloni, B. (2006)Voting for autocracy: Hegemonic party survival and its demise in Mexico. New
York, Cambridge University Press.
Marin, A. (2012) Sociological study on the composition of the Belarusian society. Directorate-
general for external policies of the union. European Parliament Working Paper.
Marples, D. (1999a) Belarus: A denationalized nation. Amsterdam, Harwood Academic.
Marples, D. (1999b) National awakening and national consciousness in Belarus. Nationalities Papers.
27 (4), 565578.
Marples, D. (2004a) The Lukashenka presidency and the future of Belarus. In: Rindzeviciute, E.
(ed.) Contemporary change in Belarus. Stockholm, So
¨derto
¨rns Ho
¨gskola, pp. 720.
Marples, D. (2004b) The prospects for democracy in Belarus. Problems of Post-Communism. 51 (1),
3142.
Marples, D. (2006) Color revolutions: The case of Belarus. Communist and Post-Communist Studies.
39 (3), 351364.
Marples, D. & Padhol, U. (2002) The opposition in Belarus: History, potential, and perspectives. In:
Balmaceda, M. (ed.) Independent Belarus: Domestic determinants, regional dynamics, and implica-
tions for the West. Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press, pp. 5576.
Matsuzato, K. (2004) A populist island in an ocean of clan politics: The Lukashenka regime as an
exception among CIS countries. Europe-Asia Studies.56 (2), 235261.
Mihalisko, K. J. (1997) Retreat to authoritarianism. In: Dawisha, K. & Parrott, B. (eds.) The
consolidation of democracy in East-Central Europe. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, pp.
223281.
Miller, M. K. (2015) Democratic pieces: Autocratic elections and democratic development Since
1815.British Journal of Political Science.45 (3), 501530.
Nikonov, V. (1999) The place of Belarus on Russia’s foreign policy agenda. In: Garnett, S. W. &
Legvold, R. (eds.) Belarus at the crossroads. Washington, DC, Carnegie Endowment for Interna-
tional Peace, pp. 131173.
Olson, D. M. (1998) Party formation and party system consolidation in the new democracies of
Central Europe. Political Studies.46 (3), 432464.
Organization for Social and Economic Cooperation in Europe (OSCE), Parliamentary Assembly,
Council of Europe, European Union, and International Limited Election Observation Mission.
(2001)Presidential election in the Republic of Belarus: Statement of preliminary findings and
conclusions, Minsk, 10 September 2001.
OSCE (Office for Democratic Institutions and Human Rights). (2006)Republic of Belarus. Pres-
idential election 19 March 2006, OSCE/ODIHR Election Observation Mission Report, Warsaw, 7
June 2006.
Padhol, U. & Marples, D. (2011)The2010 presidential election in Belarus. Problems of Post-
Communism.58 (1), 316.
Praneviciute-Neliups
ˇiene, J. & Maksimiuk, Z. (2012) Authoritarian bargain in Belarus: The system
of social benefits as a factor of regime stability. Politologija. 4(68), 106140.
Ragin, C. C. (1987)The comparative method: Moving beyond qualitative and quantitative strategies.
Berkeley, University of California Press.
134 COMMUNIST AND POST-COMMUNIST STUDIES DECEMBER 2021
Rakova, E. & Lisovskaya, T. (2009) Social contract: Civil servants. In: Haiduk, K., Rakova, E. &
Silitski, V. (eds.) Social contracts in contemporary Belarus. Vilnius, Belarusian Institute for Strategic
Studies, pp. 115145.
Rontoyanni, C. & Korosteleva, E. A. (2005) Belarus: An authoritarian exception from the model of
post-communist democratic transitions? In: Flockhart, T. (ed.) Socialising democratic norms: The
role of international organisations for the construction of Europe. Basingstoke, UK, and New York,
Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 209231.
Rose, R. & Haerpfer, C. (1998)New Democracies Barometer V: A 12-Nation Survey, Center for the
Study of Public Policy. Glasgow, Scotland, University of Strathclyde, no. 306.
Rotman, D. G. & Danilov, A. N. (2003) President and opposition: Specific features of the Belar-
usian political scene. In: Korosteleva, E. A., Lawson, C. W. & Marsh, R. J. (eds.) Contemporary
Belarus: Between democracy and dictatorship. New York, Routledge Curzon, pp. 100111.
Sahm, A. & Westphal, K. (2002) Power and the Yamal Pipeline. In: Balmaceda, M. (ed.) Indepen-
dent Belarus: Domestic determinants, regional dynamics, and implications for the West. Cambridge,
MA, Harvard University Press, pp. 270301.
Sebastia
´n, S. (2005) The Belarusian challenge: Context for a democratic strategy in Europe’s last
dictatorship. International Affairs Review. 14 (1), 7798.
Schedler, A. (2002) The nested game of democratization by elections. International Political Science
Review. 23 (1), 103122.
Schedler A. (ed.) (2006)Electoral authoritarianism: The dynamics of unfree competition. Boulder,
CO, Lynne Rienner.
Silitksi, V. (2005) Preempting democracy: The case of Belarus. Journal of Democracy.16 (4), 8397.
Silitski, V. (2006) Belarus: Learning from defeat. Journal of Democracy.17 (4), 138152.
Silitski, V. (2009) What are we trying to explain? Journal of Democracy. 20 (1), 8689.
Silitski, V. (2010a) Contagion deterred: Preemptive authoritarianism in the former Soviet Union
(the case of Belarus). In: Bunce, V., McFaul, M. & Stoner-Weiss, K. (eds.) Democracy and
authoritarianism in the postcommunist world. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, pp.
274299.
Silitski, V. (2010b) Survival of the fittest: Domestic and international dimensions of the authori-
tarian reaction in the former Soviet Union following the colored revolutions. Communist and
Post-Communist Studies. 43 (4), 339350.
Slater, D. & Fenner, S. (2011) State power and staying power: Infrastructural mechanisms and
authoritarian durability. Journal of International Affairs. 65 (1), 1529.
Teorell, J. & Hadenius, A. (2009) Elections as levers of democratization: A global inquiry. In:
Lindberg, S. I. (ed.) Democratization by elections: A new mode of transition. Baltimore, MD, Johns
Hopkins University Press, pp. 77100.
To
¨rnquist-Plewa, B. (2004) The union between Belarus and Russia in the context of Belarusian
nation-building. In: Rindzevciute, E. (ed.) Contemporary change in Belarus. Stockholm, So
¨der-
to
¨rns Ho
¨gskola, pp. 2139.
Trantidis, A. (2015) Clientelism and the classification of dominant party systems. Democratization.
22 (1), 113133.
Tucker, J. A. (2007) Enough! Electoral fraud, collective action problems and post-communist
colored revolutions. Perspectives on Politics. 5(3), 537553.
UN Commission on Human Rights (UNCHR). (2006)Report on the situation of human rights in
Belarus,16 January 2006. E/CN.4/2006/36.
UN Development Program (UNDP). (1997)Belarus: A state for people. National Human Devel-
opment Report, Minsk.
UN Development Program (UNDP). (2005)Belarus: Addressing imbalances in the economy and
society. National Human Development Report 20042005,Minsk,UND.Availablefrom:
http://un.by/pdf/1321_eng.pdf [Accessed 29 August 2021].
Trantidis | The Political Economy of Autocratization 135
UN Economic Commission for Europe (UNECE). (2005)Economic survey of Europe, No 2.United
Nations, New York and Geneva.
Van de Walle, N. (2006) Tipping games? When do opposition parties coalesce? In: Schedler, A.
(ed.) Electoral authoritarianism: The dynamics of unfree competition. Boulder, CO, Lynne Rienner,
pp. 7794.
Way, L. A. (2010) Resistance to contagion: Sources of authoritarian stability in the former Soviet
Union. In: Bunce, V., McFaul, M. & Stoner-Weiss, K. (eds.) Democracy and authoritarianism in
the postcommunist world. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, pp. 229252.
White, S. (2011) Debating Belarus: A framing comment. Eurasian Geography and Economics. 52 (6),
799808.
Wilson, A. (2011)Belarus: The last European dictatorship. New Haven, CT, Yale University Press.
World Bank. (2005)Belarus: Window of opportunity to enhance competitiveness and sustain economic
growth, a country economic memorandum for the Republic of Belarus. Report No. 32346-BY, 8
November 2005, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Unit, Europe and Central Asia
Region. Washington DC, World Bank.
Yarashevich, V. (2014) Political economy of modern Belarus: Going against mainstream? Europe-
Asia Studies. 66 (10), 17031734.
Zaprudnik, J. (1993)Belarus: At a crossroads in history. Boulder, CO, San Francisco, and Oxford,
Westview Press.
Zaprudnik, J. (2003) Belarus. In search of national identity between 1986 and 2000. In: Koroste-
vela, E. A., Lawson, C. W. & Marsh, R. J. (eds.) Contemporary Belarus: Between democracy and
dictatorship. New York, Routledge Curzon, pp. 112124.
Zlotnikov L. (2002a) In the noose of populism: Eleven years of the Belarusian economic model.
19912001. In: Lewis, A. (ed.) The EU and Belarus. Between Moscow and Brussels. London,
Federal Trust, pp. 127154.
Zlotnikov, L. (2002b) Possibilities for the development of a private economic sector and a middle
class as a source of political change in Belarus. In: Balmaceda, M. (ed.) Independent Belarus:
Domestic determinants, regional dynamics, and implications for the West. Cambridge, MA, Harvard
University Press, pp. 122161.
136 COMMUNIST AND POST-COMMUNIST STUDIES DECEMBER 2021
Article
Full-text available
Authoritarian incumbents routinely use democratic emulation as a strategy to extend their tenure in power. Yet, there is also evidence that multiparty competition makes electoral authoritarianism more vulnerable to failure. Proceeding from the assumption that the outcomes of authoritarian electoral openings are inherently uncertain, it is argued in this article that the institutionalisation of elections determines whether electoral authoritarianism promotes stability or vulnerability. By ‘institutionalisation’, it is meant the ability of authoritarian regimes to reduce uncertainty over outcomes as they regularly hold multiparty elections. Using discrete‐time event‐history models for competing risks, the effects of sequences of multiparty elections on patterns of regime survival and failure in 262 authoritarian regimes from 1946 to 2010 are assessed, conditioned on their degree of competitiveness. The findings suggest that the institutionalisation of electoral uncertainty enhances authoritarian regime survival. However, for competitive electoral authoritarian regimes this entails substantial risk. The first three elections substantially increase the probability of democratisation, with the danger subsequently diminishing. This suggests that convoking multiparty competition is a risky game with potentially high rewards for autocrats who manage to institutionalise elections. Yet, only a small number of authoritarian regimes survive as competitive beyond the first few elections, suggesting that truly competitive authoritarianism is hard to institutionalise. The study thus finds that the question of whether elections are dangerous or stabilising for authoritarianism is dependent on differences between the ability of competitive and hegemonic forms of electoral authoritarianism to reduce electoral uncertainty.
Article
Full-text available
The view of clientelism as an abuse of state power casts doubt on the democratic credentials of highly clientelistic political systems. The question is particularly relevant for the classification of dominant party systems that heavily rely on clientelism to elicit popular support and retain a relatively open structure of participation. Knowing that clientelism is a widespread practice in modern democracies too, how do we evaluate the impact of clientelism on political competitiveness in order to sort out the position of these regimes along the lines of democracy and authoritarianism? This task requires identifying the conditions under which clientelism becomes an essentially authoritarian practice and qualifies these regimes as such. The article puts forward two propositions about the circumstances under which clientelism infringes basic democratic standards under a thin and a thick definition of democracy. Clientelism under one-party monopoly engenders authoritarianism when it thwarts and punishes the contesting voice of citizens by effectively blocking exit from its incentives and sanctions.
Article
President Aleksandr Lukashenko has embraced Belarusian nationalism to bolster his flagging legitimacy.
Article
This paper explores energy policy in Belarus during the Presidency of Aleksander Lukashenka (1994-present), focusing on his adroit use of revenues produced by that sector of the economy to secure the loyalty of his political base and the countrys elites. With a valuable energy infrastructure (pipelines and refineries) inherited from the Soviet period and subsidized commodity imports from Russia, Lukashenka has taken advantage of price differentials, transit fees, taxes, and re-exports to generate rents that are then redistributed among domestic actors, enhancing the popularity of the incumbent and the furtherance of the social contract obtaining there. This is contrasted with the case of neighboring Ukraine, where the same geographic energy legacy resulted instead in an era of rampant corruption and political instability.
Article
A British political scientist and eminent specialist on the politics of the post-Soviet states comments on the divergent perspectives offered in the two preceding papers in the symposium on Belarus in the same issue of Eurasian Geography and Economics. He first briefly reviews the diverse approaches to the study of Belarus evident in the academic literature, and the reasons scholars might be led to the country as a topic of study, especially its suitability as a test bed for several issues of importance in comparative studies (e.g., the nature of presidential power and of political "charisma," of governance without political parties, and an economic model that has appeared until now to have resisted the path of accelerated market reform). Probing more deeply, the author identifies issues of the comparative method of particular relevance to the exchange that warrant further investigation, and goes on to present his own survey data (from early 2011 for Belarus and from 2010 in Ukraine and Russia) in an effort to advance the debate on these issues. In concluding, he suggests a line of further enquiry for understanding better the seeming paradox that is Belarus-the role played by retention of "Soviet" institutions (e.g., trade unions, local councils) that offer a means of communication between ordinary citizens and the authorities.
Article
The president of Belarus, Alyaksandr Lukashenka, claimed victory in the elections held in December 2010 but at great cost. The savage government response to his opponents and subsequent crackdown, widely condemned by Western observers, suggest that Lukashenka realizes his iron grip is slipping.
Article
Two recent strands of research have proposed that state capacity facilitates autocratic and democratic survival, respectively. While convincing arguments sustain each of these expectations, prior research has neglected a crucial distinction with respect to state capacity: that between monopoly on violence and administrative effectiveness. In this article, we first formulate propositions about the relationship between each of these different aspects of state capacity and political regime stability. We then subject these propositions to empirical assessment through cross-national, statistical analysis. Our findings show that state capacity does indeed tend to enhance regime stability in both autocracies and democracies. Yet, the analyses also reveal that what primarily matters in autocracies is the monopoly on violence whereas administrative effectiveness is what stabilizes democracies. Finally, we discuss alternative interpretations of the patterns and conclude that our results go a long way toward making sense of apparent inconsistencies in the findings of previous studies.
Article
Our political malaise is due to the same cause as our social malaise: that is, to the lack of secondary cadres to interpose between the individual and the State. We have seen that these secondary groups are essential if the State is not to oppress the individual: they are also necessary if the State is to be sufficiently free of the individual. –Émile Durkheim, Professional Ethics and Civic Morals Human progress never rolls in on the wheels of inevitability –Martin Luther King, Jr., A Knock at Midnight
Article
This article overviews the history of autocratic elections since 1815 and then tests how a country's experience with autocratic elections influences both democratization and democratic survival. To comprehensively capture this history, the study employs original measures of Robert Dahl's electoral dimensions of contestation and participation. First, it shows that autocratic elections have been common for centuries, but that their character has changed dramatically over time. Whereas high contestation almost always preceded high participation prior to 1940, the opposite occurs in modern regimes. Secondly, it demonstrates that a country's history of contestation predicts both democratization and democratic survival, whereas participation is positive for survival but generally negative for democratization. Thus, democracies are more likely to survive if they experience autocratic elections prior to democratizing, which has implications for democracy promotion and future political development.