ArticlePublisher preview available

Giants among us: do we need a new antitrust paradigm?

Authors:
To read the full-text of this research, you can request a copy directly from the author.

Abstract

Traditional antitrust policy was formulated to control pricing and output decisions that were not disciplined by competitive forces, either because of monopoly power or agreements in restraint of trade. Because there is no single criterion for evaluating political policy outcomes, antitrust regulators eventually settled on the “consumer welfare standard,” correctly recognizing that any other standard was incoherent. Recently “platforms” (defined here as firms or apps that solve the key transaction costs problems of triangulation, transfer, and trust) have tended toward giantism. This had led to calls for a new approach to antitrust, restoring the old multiple set of goals. But every platform by definition defines an industry, and is a monopoly within that industry. Such network economies or advantages in managing trust are the reasons platforms exist in the first place. This paper reviews the history of antitrust, defines platforms and the problems of “giantism,” and suggests some policies that certainly won't work and should be abandoned. The problem is power, not monopoly. So power is what the “new paradigm” needs to address.
Vol.:(0123456789)
Constitutional Political Economy (2022) 33:445–460
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-021-09350-w
1 3
Giants amongus: dowe need anew antitrust paradigm?
MichaelC.Munger1
Accepted: 9 September 2021 / Published online: 29 November 2021
© The Author(s), under exclusive licence to Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature
2021
Abstract
Traditional antitrust policy was formulated to control pricing and output decisions
that were not disciplined by competitive forces, either because of monopoly power
or agreements in restraint of trade. Because there is no single criterion for evaluating
political policy outcomes, antitrust regulators eventually settled on the “consumer
welfare standard,” correctly recognizing that any other standard was incoherent.
Recently “platforms” (defined here as firms or apps that solve the key transaction
costs problems of triangulation, transfer, and trust) have tended toward giantism.
This had led to calls for a new approach to antitrust, restoring the old multiple set
of goals. But every platform by definition defines an industry, and is a monopoly
within that industry. Such network economies or advantages in managing trust are
the reasons platforms exist in the first place. This paper reviews the history of anti-
trust, defines platforms and the problems of “giantism,” and suggests some poli-
cies that certainly won’t work and should be abandoned. The problem is power, not
monopoly. So power is what the “new paradigm” needs to address.
Keywords Antitrust· Rules versus discretion· Consumer welfare standard·
Platform economy
The paper is adapted from the “Plenary Presentation” at the annual meetings of the Public Choice
Society March 11-13, 2021, Savannah Georgia. The author thanks, but in no way blames, Thomas
Hazlett, Edward Lopez, Richard Salsman, William Shugart II, Georg Vanberg, and two very helpful
anonymous reviewers for helpful comments and critiques. Roger Congleton, editor of CPE, offered
substantial and important suggestions for improvement, at several stages. The flaws that remain are
largely the result of my inability to incorporate all the useful comments.
* Michael C. Munger
munger@duke.edu
1 Department Political Science, Department ofEconomics, Duke University, Durham, USA
ORIGINAL PAPER
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
... Antitrust laws, such as the Sherman Act in the United States, are designed to prevent such practices and ensure that collaborations do not violate competition standards. 25 Furthermore, competition authorities closely monitor healthcare collaborations to ensure that they do not stifle competition or harm consumer welfare. In some countries, regulations such as the "Sunshine Act" in the United States have been enacted to limit conflicts of interest and prevent undue influence in the healthcare sector. ...
... Political and popular interest in antitrust law enforcement has waxed and waned since the Sherman Act was passed in 1890. Antitrust is back in the headlines nowadays because of worries expressed in some quarters about the rise of tech giants-Amazon, Google, Facebook-thought to wield excessive power in digital markets, power defined not necessarily in the traditional antitrust sense of elevating prices above costs, but rather dominance of speech and access to public-opinion-relevant information (see, e.g., Munger, 2021). Proposals are being considered to rein such power in legislatively or by bold antitrust and regulatory action, especially so at the FTC. ...
Article
Full-text available
Competition policy (antitrust policy in the United States) engages the subfields of microeconomics (price theory), industrial organization, law and economics, and public choice. The last was a latecomer to the list because of the persistence of naïve “public interest” explanations for competition policy’s origins, purposes, and effects. Even after a half-century of policy analyses in general and of public regulation of prices and conditions of entry into myriad industries around the world—showing that such interventions almost always benefit politically powerful special interests rather than society at large—most scholars still carelessly and mistakenly assume that private plaintiffs, attorneys called to the antitrust bar, the public law enforcement agencies, prosecutors, judges and other parties involved in antitrust proceedings have no motivations beyond preserving competitive marketplaces. My aim here is to bring antitrust policy more firmly within the ambit of public choice reasoning, which helps explain why antitrust intervention often either is ineffective or perverse. Competition law enforcement is a first cousin of economic regulation and, hence, should be evaluated as such.
Article
Full-text available
Classical approaches to the law, even statutory law, teach that its purpose is to codify behavioral rules creating clear expectations about the consequences of human interactions. Stability and predictability are the rule of law’s hallmarks. The present essay explores those principles within the context of the origins and development of antitrust (competition) policy in the United States, with special attention to mergers and acquisitions. The old antitrust question was whether size alone offends the law. The burden of the argument is that the discretion granted to the law enforcement agencies and the courts in identifying and sanctioning impermissible accumulations of economic market power creates climates of uncertainty for the owners of private business enterprises, thereby undermining the rule of law. Moreover, if the laws have not been applied consistently in ordinary economic markets, enforcers can be expected to err even more frequently in responding to undesirable accumulations of political power or social influence in modern digital information markets.
Article
Full-text available
Perhaps the most important element of James Buchanan’s contribution to constitutional economics is his differentiation between pre- and post-constitutional levels of decision-making. At first glance, a tension may appear between those two levels of analysis. In one, the rules by which we live are up for debate, allowing us to exercise our creative and imaginative capabilities in constitutional construction. In the other, the rules are viewed as fixed, and we are left simply to treat them as constraints. This paper explores three key elements of Buchanan’s thought that allow him to navigate successfully between the two levels. The first is the importance of “the relatively absolute absolute”, a concept learned from his mentor, Frank Knight. The second is Buchanan’s approach to “truth judgments” in politics, and their status in our political discussions. Third, we draw on Buchanan’s insights in his 1959 paper “Positive Economics, Welfare Economics, and Political Economy” to show how political economists should participate in this decision-making process—not as expert philosopher-kings, but as co-equals with their fellow citizens. Finally, we illustrate Buchanan’s system of thought in action by presenting two case studies: Virginia education policy in the wake of Brown v. Board of Education, and the 1928 Supreme Court ruling in Miller v. Schoene.
Article
Full-text available
Forthcoming, Advances in Austrian Economics. The platform economy reflects the business model of some of the largest and fastest-growing firms in the economy. Platform business models emerge and thrive because of the potential profit in taking advantage of transactions cost reductions to connect people for mutual benefit, and this value creation is best understood by thinking about the epistemology of decentralized market processes. Three essential aspects of knowledge are relevant to platform business models: (1) knowledge can be private and diffuse; (2) knowledge can be contextual; (3) knowledge may not exist outside of the economic process. After defining and analyzing the technology, economic, and institutional aspects of platforms I define and apply market epistemology to explore how platforms harness technological and organizational features to create value-enhancing market platforms by exploiting the epistemic benefits of technology-enabled decentralized market processes. I conclude by using this epistemic framework to propose an electricity distribution platform business model-the retail electricity industry is undergoing a process of technological dynamism, and as a regulated infrastructure industry, evolving into a decentralized market industry is presenting challenges to which this epistemic framework can bring increased understanding. This paper has benefited from comments from an anonymous referee, and from conversations on these topics with
Book
The very logic of majority rule implies unequal treatment or discrimination. If left unconstrained, majority coalitions will promote the interests of their own members at the expense of other persons. This book focuses on the effects of applying a generality constraint on the political process. Under this requirement, majorities would be constitutionally prohibited from treating different persons and groups differently. The generality principle is familiar in that all persons are to be treated equally. In summary, this book extends the generality norm to politics. Several defences of equal treatment or generality are developed and applied. These include the familiar intuition that invokes fairness. But the primary argument here is centred on political efficiency, which is increased when governments are constrained to treat persons or groups generally rather than differentially. The political efficiency defence of the generality constraint is based on a public choice analysis of the implication of majoritarian discrimination.
Article
This article presents an historical analysis of the antitrust laws. Its central contention is that the history of antitrust can only be understood in light of U.S. economic history and the succession of dominant economic policy regimes that punctuated that history. The antitrust laws and a subset of other related policies have historically focused on the negative consequences resulting from the rise, expansion, and dominance of big business. Antitrust specifically uses competition as its tool to address these problems. The article traces the evolution of the emergence, growth, and expansion of big business over six economic eras: the Gilded Age, the Progressive Era, the New Deal, the post–World War II Era, the 1970s, and the era of neoliberalism. It considers three policy regimes: laissez-faire during the Gilded Age and the Progressive Era, the New Deal, policy regime from the Depression through the early 1970s, and the neoliberal policy regime that dominates today and includes the Chicago School of antitrust. The principal conclusion of the article is that the activist antitrust associated with the New Deal that existed from the late 1930s to the 1960s resulted in far stronger economic performance than have the policies of the Chicago School that have dominated antitrust policy since the 1980s.