Content uploaded by Andrea Patacconi
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by Andrea Patacconi on Apr 07, 2022
Content may be subject to copyright.
An asset partitioning perspective on corporate groups
Sharon Belenzon
Fuqua School of Business, Duke University, sharon.belenzon@duke.edu
Honggi Lee
Peter T. Paul College of Business and Economics, University of New Hampshire, honggi.lee@unh.edu
Andrea Patacconi
Norwich Business School, University of East Anglia a.patacconi@uea.ac.uk
Abstract
This paper develops an asset partitioning perspective on corporate groups. Asset parti-
tioning refers to the process of dividing assets under common control into separate, legally
independent entities. Thus, when a group incorporates a previously unincorporated busi-
ness unit, its assets are more finely partitioned. We highlight several important costs and
benefits of finer asset partitioning. Benefits include risk compartmentalization, greater in-
ternal transparency, greater autonomy at the subsidiary level, and learning about individual
assets. Costs include stunted resource redeployment and lower headquarters monitoring.
Using data from sixteen countries from around the world, we demonstrate the practical
relevance of our perspective, and contrast its predictions with those of other leading per-
spectives on corporate groups.
Key words : Theory of the firm, limited liability, asset partitioning, decentralization.
1
2
1. Introduction
Economists and management scholars typically ignore the legal organization of the firm. Economists
tend to conceptualize the firm as a “legal fiction”, whose only function is to serve as a nexus
of contracts among individuals (Alchian and Demsetz, 1972; Jensen and Meckling, 1976). In this
conception, contracting within the firm (e.g., the employment relationship) or between a firm and
external entities (e.g., labor outsourcing) is fundamentally identical; thus, “it makes little or no
sense to try to distinguish those things which are ‘inside’ the firm (or any other organization) from
those things that are ‘outside’ of it” (Jensen and Meckling, 1976).1Management scholars similarly
treat the legal organization of the firm as largely irrelevant to their subject: “[T]he legal structure
[of the multinational firm] is designed, in accordance with government regulations, for cash-flow
and tax purposes; it seldom reflects the way in which the enterprise is managed” (Stopford and
Wells Jr, 1972).
In this paper, we challenge these views. We argue that the legal organization of the firm has im-
portant implications for strategic decision making. By choosing the appropriate legal organization,
managers can create value for shareholders and foster innovation and growth.
Legal organization refers to organizational arrangements that determine how shareholders con-
tract with other parties, such as business partners, employees and customers (Bethel and Liebe-
skind, 1998). An aspect of legal organization is the choice of entity type: sole proprietorship,
ordinary partnership, limited liability partnership, company, etc. Another aspect, which is the fo-
cus of this paper, is how shareholders partition their assets into separate legal entities (Hansmann
and Kraakman, 2000a,b). Shareholders often do not hold all their assets in a single legal entity;
instead, they create collections of legally independent entities linked together via ownership ties.
These structures, known as corporate or business groups, are extremely common around the world
(La Porta et al., 1999; Belenzon et al., 2013).
Building on prior work in organizational law (Hansmann and Kraakman, 2000a,b) and strategy
(Bethel and Liebeskind, 1998; Manikandan and Ramachandran, 2015; Belenzon et al., 2019), we
develop an asset partitioning perspective on corporate groups. We conceptualize asset partitioning
as a process of periodically drawing and redrawing firm boundaries, to maximize total group value.
A key distinction we draw is between finer and coarser asset partitioning. Consider an unincor-
porated business unit within a firm. If the management of the firm incorporates the unit, a new
legal boundary is created, and the unit becomes a legally independent entity. In 2016, for instance,
1For instance, Alchian and Demsetz (1972) argue that “[t]he firm [. . . ] has no power of fiat, no authority, no disci-
plinary action any different in the slightest degree from ordinary market contracting between any two people”. Jensen
and Meckling (1976) extend this reasoning to all contractual relationships where the firm is one of the parties, not
just the employer-employee relationship.
3
the self-driving car division of X (formerly Google X) was spun off, and Waymo became a legally
independent subsidiary of the Alphabet group. This is an example of finer asset partitioning: the
assets controlled by Alphabet were more finely partitioned into a greater number of legally inde-
pendent entities.2However, two or more group affiliates could also merge together. For instance,
in 2018 Google and Nest combined their operations, with Nest becoming part of Google. In this
case, the restructuring resulted in coarser asset partitioning.3
This paper identifies several costs and benefits of finer asset partitioning. Benefits of finer asset
partitioning include risk compartmentalization, greater internal transparency, greater autonomy
at the subsidiary level, and learning about individual assets. Costs include stunted resource re-
deployment and lower headquarters monitoring.4Firm boundaries are set to balance these costs
and benefits. By achieving a good fit between legal organization and the external environment
(Lawrence and Lorsch, 1967; Ghoshal and Nohria, 1989; Nohria and Ghoshal, 1997), managers can
mitigate risks and create value for shareholders.
We demonstrate the usefulness of the framework by focusing on two key benefits of finer asset
partitioning: risk compartmentalization (Hansmann and Kraakman, 2000a; Bethel and Liebeskind,
1998) and greater subsidiary autonomy (Manikandan and Ramachandran, 2015; Belenzon et al.,
2019). Risk compartmentalization refers to the ability of groups to compartmentalize their liabil-
ities, thus preventing risks from spreading from one firm to another. We argue that the benefits
of risk compartmentalization and subsidiary autonomy are contingent on the strictness of national
limited liability laws. In virtually every jurisdiction, limited liability is the default rule of law for
corporations; however, there are exceptions, especially when the owner of a corporation is an-
other corporation. Under some circumstances, courts can “pierce the corporate veil” and make the
whole group liable for the debts of one of its subsidiaries. Legal scholars refer to this possibility
as “enterprise liability”, where “enterprise” refers to the “unified economic group of corporations”
(i.e., the corporate group) and “entity” refers to the “single, legal form of the corporation” (i.e.,
the individual firm, or subsidiary) (Dearborn, 2009).5Importantly, countries differ considerably in
2In this paper, we use the terms “firm”, “corporation” and “company” interchangeably. Group affiliates are the
legally independent entities (typically firms) constituting a group. Group affiliates located at the top of a group’s
pyramid are called headquarters. All the other affiliates are called subsidiaries.
3Acquisitions and divestitures are conceptually distinct from asset partitioning. Acquisitions and divestitures imply
a change in the total amount of assets under common control. Asset partitioning is concerned with how a given
amount of assets under common control is divided into separate legal entities. Note also that, as discussed in Section
2.2 below, not all redrawing of firm boundaries result in either finer or coarser asset partitioning.
4In our discussion, we ignore issues of taxation and tax avoidance. These issues are important for profitability, but
they typically do not influence how the group operates.
5This terminology is not universally agreed upon. Some legal scholars (e.g., Bainbridge and Henderson (2016)) use
the term “enterprise liability” narrowly to refer only to the case when sister companies are held liable (a “horizontal”
form of liability, or veil piercing), thus distinguishing these cases from the traditional (i.e., “vertical”) notion of
4
the propensity of their courts to apply enterprise liability. Some countries (e.g., Germany) view
subsidiaries as an integral part of the group that controls them, while others (e.g., Great Britain)
emphasize the legal independence of each individual subsidiary (and hence tend to grant limited
liability to parent and sister companies).
We examine how enterprise liability affects firm boundaries, internal organization, and corporate
group growth. We argue that weaker enterprise liability (i.e., stronger limited liability protection
for parent and sister companies) tends to encourage groups to partition more finely their assets
and to grant their affiliates more decision-making autonomy. Indeed, when enterprise liability
is weak, risks are better compartmentalized and, if the consequences of bad decisions do not
spill over to other units, headquarters can more confidently delegate decision-making authority
to subsidiary managers. Because risks are better compartmentalized, finer asset partitioning also
tends to encourage investment, innovation, and growth.
To test our hypotheses, we use data from sixteen countries in Europe, the Americas, and Asia. In
collaboration with scholars at Duke University School of Law, we constructed a novel country-level
measure of enterprise liability.6Countries are ranked on a scale between 0 and 5 according to the
propensity of their courts to apply enterprise liability and thus “pierce the corporate veil” (PCV)
in cases involving group affiliates. In line with conventional wisdom, Germany has the highest PCV
(or enterprise liability) score of 3.93, and Great Britain has the lowest PCV score of 1.3.
Our estimation sample consists of a panel of 939,679 corporate groups. On average, groups in
our sample have controlling stakes in 2 subsidiaries, with a standard deviation of 9 across sixteen
countries over years 2002 through 2014. (Our sample consists of a “corporate group” with at least
one subsidiary.) We also use data on subsidiary autonomy from the World Management Survey
(WMS) (Bloom and Van Reenen, 2007). The WMS sample contains around 1,790 subsidiaries
across ten countries.
We present three main findings. First, conditional on group size and various country controls,
including legal origin dummies, we show that corporate groups in low-PCV countries (where en-
terprise liability is weak) tend to organize their economic activity using more subsidiaries than
groups in high-PCV countries. Assets are also partitioned more finely especially in industries where
downside risk is high, further supporting the risk compartmentalization mechanism.
Second, using WMS data we show that subsidiaries are granted more autonomy, especially in
making capital investment decisions, when they operate in low-PCV countries than when they
liability involving a company and its owners. In this paper, we follow the majority of commentators and use the term
enterprise liability to encompass both notions of liability (horizontal and vertical) in the context of corporate groups.
See Bainbridge and Henderson (2016) and Dearborn (2009) for more on these issues.
6The full report detailing how the measure is constructed is provided in Supplementary Appendix A.
5
operate in high-PCV countries. This means that weak enterprise liability goes hand-in-hand with
greater decentralization.
Finally, we present evidence consistent with the view that asset partitioning, by compartmen-
talizing risks, can spur investment and growth. The findings show that doubling the number of
subsidiaries, holding assets fixed, is associated with 25 percentage point increase in investment and
30 percentage point increase in the growth rate for revenues.
This paper makes several contributions to strategy and organization theory. Most importantly,
we develop a novel framework—the asset partitioning view—to understand the implications of
legal organization for strategic decision making. Asset partitioning is an important, but largely
underappreciated instrument to foster decentralization in organizations. We argue that asset par-
titioning brings with it specific costs and benefits, and explain when it creates shareholder value.
We illustrate the practical relevance of the theory using several real-world examples.
The asset partitioning view also improves our understanding of the nature and functions of
corporate groups. Groups are typically conceptualized as either a device to magnify the control of
dominant shareholders (e.g., Bebchuk et al. (2000); Bertrand et al. (2002); Baek et al. (2006) or
as a mechanism to redeploy internal resources when external markets function poorly (e.g., Leff
(1978); Capron et al. (1998); Belenzon and Berkovitz (2010); Belenzon et al. (2013); Lieberman
et al. (2017)). While useful, however, these perspectives cannot satisfactorily explain the variety
of group structures that we observe in reality. In particular, they cannot explain the existence and
widespread diffusion of wholly- or almost wholly-owned groups (Manikandan and Ramachandran,
2015; Belenzon et al., 2019). As we will see, the asset partitioning view can explain why these
structures are so common.
The asset partitioning view also yields predictions that are sometimes very different from those
of other leading perspectives. Both the control magnifying and institutional voids perspectives sug-
gest that groups should whither away in countries where legal and economic institutions are highly
developed. In particular, groups should be quite uncommon in Great Britain, where protections
for minority shareholders are strong and external markets are highly developed. The asset parti-
tioning view, by contrast, suggests that Great Britain’s stronger limited liability protections for
corporate parents (i.e., weaker enterprise liability) should encourage finer asset partitioning and
corporate group formation. Our evidence strongly supports the asset partitioning view. Overall,
this paper suggests that risk compartmentalization (as opposed to agency problems or resource
redeployment) is a more important factor in explaining the emergence of corporate groups than
generally acknowledged.
6
2. Theoretical Framework
2.1. Existing Perspectives on Corporate Groups
Corporate groups are collections of legally independent entities (typically firms) under common
control (Khanna and Yafeh, 2007; Belenzon et al., 2013; Kandel et al., 2019). Groups are generally
organized in pyramidal structures whereby an ultimate shareholder (a family, a widely-held corpo-
ration, or the state) controls several units through parent-subsidiary chains. Because many large
corporations own subsidiaries, a very large fraction of economic activity around the world takes
place in corporate groups.
The two leading explanations for the existence of corporate groups are the “control-magnifying”
and the “institutional voids” perspectives. The control magnifying view holds that group structures
are created by powerful owners to extend their control over distant subsidiaries. By creating tall
pyramids powerful owners can enjoy control rights far in excess of their cash-flow rights (Bebchuk
et al., 2000). Consider for instance a family that owns 51% of firm A, which owns 51% of firm
B. Through this “stock pyramid”, the family can fully control firm B while owning only about
25% of its stock. If the family created an even taller pyramid, it could magnify its control over
bottom-level subsidiaries even further. The chief concern with these pyramidal structures is that
they may engender agency problems. In particular, dominant shareholders may take actions that
enrich themselves at the expense of minority shareholders (La Porta et al., 1999; Bertrand et al.,
2002; Morck et al., 2005).
The institutional voids perspective holds instead that groups perform a useful allocative role.
According to this view, group headquarters allocate scarce resources—financial capital, technology,
human resources, and so on—to subsidiaries that need them (Leff (1978); Stein (1997); Capron
et al. (1998); Belenzon and Berkovitz (2010); Lieberman et al. (2017)). This function is particularly
valuable when external markets and legal institutions are underdeveloped because in those situa-
tions standalone firms may not be able to obtain the resources they need (Keister, 1998; Khanna
and Palepu, 1999; Mahmood and Mitchell, 2004; Belenzon et al., 2013).
While both theories are useful to understand why corporate groups exist, they cannot explain
the variety of group structures we observe in reality. Take Google for instance. In October 2015,
Google restructured its operations as the Alphabet group. A single multidivisional firm (the former
Google) was partitioned into a number of legally independent entities (Google, Nest, Calico, X,
etc.) under holding company Alphabet Inc. The control-magnifying view cannot explain why the
Alphabet group was created. Alphabet Inc. wholly owns all its subsidiaries, so control magnification
was not an issue there.
Resource redeployment is also not a plausible explanation for the creation of the Alphabet group.
While there is clearly a lot of resource redeployment inside Alphabet, the same was true for Google
7
and its internal units before 2015. In general, it is not obvious what advantages a group structure
would provide, relative to a multidivisional corporate form. If anything, resource redeployment
should be easier among the divisions of a large, diversified firm than among the subsidiaries of a
group.7Furthermore, the U.S. can hardly be described as a country where external markets and
institutions are underdeveloped, necessitating groups to step in to fill these “institutional voids”.
Importantly, the Alphabet’s case is far from unique. Wholly-owned groups are very common
around the world, especially in developed countries. Using comprehensive data, Belenzon et al.
(2019) show that many large groups in Western Europe are wholly- or almost wholly-owned.
Even in Italy and Spain, a majority of large groups is wholly-owned. Wholly-owned groups are
especially prevalent in the U.S. because of New Deal regulations that greatly discouraged partial
ownership of subsidiaries (Kandel et al., 2019). In short, the control-magnifying and institutional
voids perspectives cannot satisfactorily explain the widespread diffusion of wholly-owned groups
in developed countries.
2.2. The asset partitioning view
To address these limitations and to better understand the reasons for the formation of many groups
such as Alphabet, this paper develops a novel perspective on corporate groups. Just like exist-
ing theories, our perspective conceptualizes corporate groups as collections of legally independent
entities under common control. But unlike existing theories emphasizing the element of common
control, we emphasize the legal independence of group affiliates. The different emphasis naturally
leads to a different choice of a comparison group. While the control-magnifying view and the in-
stitutional voids perspective both compare group affiliates to standalone firms (to emphasize the
costs and benefits of common control, such as expropriation of minority shareholders or resource
redeployment), the asset partitioning view compares group affiliates to the (unincorporated) divi-
sions of large conglomerates. In both a group or a conglomerate business units are under common
control; however, only in a corporate group the units are legally independent.
Consider a collection of assets under common control (these assets could include both physical
and human assets, as well as intellectual property). Asset partitioning refers to the different ways
in which these assets could be divided into legally independent units. For instance, the same set
of assets could be divided into multiple legally independent entities (e.g., Alphabet), or could be
assembled as a single firm with multiple unincorporated divisions (the pre-2015 Google). The first
case corresponds to finer asset partitioning (because there are multiple legally independent units),
the second to coarser asset partitioning (because there are fewer).
7Indeed, Alphabet was created at least in part to mitigate investors’ concerns about excessive resource redeployment
from Google’s core business (internet search and advertising) to the new ventures (the “moonshots”). This suggests
that internal redeployment is actually easier in a multidivisional corporation where investors cannot observe resource
reallocation.
8
Not all types of asset partitioning can neatly be classified as either coarser or finer partitioning.
Keeping the number of legally independent entities constant, assets could be reshuffled among units.
Consider for instance the restructuring in 2015 of Li Ka-shing’s empire.8This restructuring largely
involved two companies: Cheung Kong (Holdings) Ltd. and Hutchison Whampoa Ltd. Before the
restructuring, both companies had property and non-property holdings. After the restructuring,
the real estate holdings of the two original companies were combined into a single company, Cheung
Kong Property Holdings Ltd., while most of the other holdings (energy, ports, telecommunications,
and retail holdings) were combined into CK Hutchison Holdings Ltd. Because the group’s assets
were still divided between two companies, the restructuring did not result in finer (or coarser)
asset partitioning. Nevertheless, the restructuring arguably simplified the group’s structure, as the
property holdings were aggregated into a specialized unit. As we will see, this “simpler” structure is
also a typical outcome of finer asset partitioning, because through finer partitioning conglomerates
can be broken up, and some of their divisions can become specialized units.
Anecdotal evidence suggests that asset partitioning can create shareholder value. Alpha-
bet/Google restructuring was well-received by investors. Class A shares rose 4.10% (GOOGL), and
Class C shares rose 4.27% (GOOG), the day following the announcement.9The restructuring of
Li Ka-shing was also well-received by investors, who appreciated the simpler structure. Shares in
Cheung Kong (Holdings) Ltd. increased by approximately 15% on the first day of trading following
the restructuring announcement (from HK$ 124.80 on Fri 9 Jan 2015 to HK$ 143.20 on Mon 12
Jan 2015); shares in Hutchison Whampoa Ltd. increased by approximately 12.6% (from HK$ 87.40
to HK$ 98.35).
These examples suggest that asset partitioning can create shareholder value. To understand how,
we discuss next some key benefits of finer asset partitioning, as well as its costs.
2.2.1. Benefits of (finer) asset partitioning
Risk compartmentalization. By dividing a common pool of assets into several legally inde-
pendent entities, asset partitioning allows groups to compartmentalize liabilities, thus preventing
risks from spreading across units. We distinguish three channels through which risk compartmen-
talization can create shareholder value.
The first channel is limited liability. As a general default rule of law, the contracts entered
into by a firm are bonded by the assets owned by that firm. Thus, parent or sister companies
are, in principle at least, shielded from the losses incurred by another group member (Hansmann
and Kraakman, 2000a,b; Bethel and Liebeskind, 1998). Bloomberg reports that an advantage of
8See, for instance, The Economist, Jan 17th 2015, “Li Ka-shing. Superman sheds his concubines”.
9https://www.nasdaq.com/articles/what-googles-alphabet-means-investors-and-wall-street-2015-08-13
9
Google/Alphabet’s new structure is that it “helps keep potential challenges in one business from
spreading to another [. . . ] By separating them, it allows the parent company to limit the exposure
of the various obligations of the LLCs”.10 By contrast, a multidivisional firm would be liable for
the losses incurred by each of its (unincorporated) divisions.11
By compartmentalizing risks along divisional or geographical lines, asset partitioning can also
reduce creditor information costs and the group’s overall cost of capital (Hansmann and Kraakman,
2000a,b; Hansmann and Squire, 2016). Through finer asset partitioning, large multidivisional firms
can be broken up and some of their divisions can become specialized units. This allows creditors to
invest only in these specific units, without having to invest in the whole group. This can bring down
creditors’ information acquisition and monitoring costs, ultimately reducing the group’s overall
cost of capital. Note that these benefits also stem from limited liability and entity shielding.12
Creditors can safely specialize in certain units (without having to worry about liabilities in other
segments of the group), because they know that risks will not spread across subsidiaries.
10 See https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2017-09-01/alphabet-wraps-up-reorganization-with-a-new-
company-called-xxvi. Other examples include Manville, a global leader in the manufacture of asbestos-containing
products, which separately incorporated its non-asbestos operations in the aftermath of an asbestos litigation (Roe
(1986)). Philip Morris CEO Hamish Maxwell similarly admitted to analysts that he formed a holding company
“to better insulate each business from obligations and liabilities incurred in unrelated activities” (Roe, 1986, p.5).
Schlissel et al. (2002) also highlight the increasingly common phenomenon of multi-tiered groups owning nuclear
power plants in the U.S. They note that, “[o]ver the last ten years, the ownership of an increasing number of nuclear
power plants has been transferred to a relatively small number of very large corporations. These large corporations
have adopted business structures that create separate limited liability subsidiaries for each nuclear plant, and in
a number of instances, separate operating and ownership entities that provide additional liability buffers between
the nuclear plant and its ultimate owners”. They argue that one goal of these structures is to “provide a financial
shield for the parent/owner if an accident, equipment failure, safety upgrade, or unusual maintenance need at one
particular plant creates a large, unanticipated cost”.
11 The distinction between voluntary and involuntary creditors is important here. Voluntary creditors, also known
as contractual creditors, are those who enter a contractual relationship with the firm. Banks and other institutional
lenders are examples of voluntary creditors. So are employees and some consumers. In general, limited liability does
not externalize the risk of business failure to voluntary creditors but rather facilitates a bargain between the firm and
the creditor. Voluntary creditors agree to bear some of the risk in exchange for higher rate of returns. In principle at
least, they are fully compensated by a higher interest rate, which reflects the additional risk of limited liability.
Involuntary creditors, on the other hand, are those who did not enter a contractual relationship with the firm. Hence,
they are not compensated for the additional risk that they incur under limited liability. The paradigmatic example
for involuntary creditors are tort creditors (e.g., the victims of industrial accidents). Other important involuntary
creditors are environmental creditors and tax authorities, but in effect every creditor who is not in a practical position
to negotiate credit terms can be regarded as an involuntary creditor. These creditors are not compensated for the
risk of default that incorporation brings about. The loss is simply externalized.
Risk compartmentalization is much more valuable to group owners when creditors are involuntary than when they
are voluntary. First, as noted above, voluntary creditors are at least in part compensated for the risk of default
that incorporation brings about through higher interest rates. Second, voluntary creditors can also demand parent
companies and their subsidiaries to guarantee each other’s major outside debts (through intra-group guarantees),
thereby imposing “veil-piercing by contract” (Squire, 2011: 615). These considerations suggest that, empirically, finer
asset partitioning should be especially valuable in situations when tort liabilities (and hence involuntary creditors)
are potentially very significant (relative to other types of liabilities).
12 Entity shielding refers to rules that protect a firm’s assets from the personal creditors of the owners (Hansmann
et al., 2005). It is effectively the converse of limited liability, since limited liability protects the assets of the firm’s
owners from the claims of the firm’s creditors.
10
The reorganization of Li Ka-shing’s empire, while strictly speaking not an example of finer
asset partitioning, did simplify the group structure along divisional lines. After the reorganization,
investors with a preference for pure-play property investments were able to buy shares in Cheung
Kong Property Holdings Ltd., without having to buy also shares in other companies. This appears
to have reduced the group’s diversification discount, thus benefiting the group’s shareholders.
A third channel through which risk compartmentalization can create shareholder value is by
insulating group affiliates from adverse reputational spillovers. Reputation is one of the firm’s most
valuable assets, and managers go to great lengths to protect the good name of their firms. By
creating multiple independent legal entities, reputational spillovers among group members can be
reduced, especially if different affiliates are given different names (Belenzon et al., 2017).
For an illustration of the potential benefits of this “reputational compartmentalization”, consider
the self-driving car division at Google. Anthony Lewandowski, one of unit’s co-founders, noted
that, while “Google was very supportive of the idea, [. . . ] they absolutely did not want their name
associated with it [. . . ] They were worried about a Google engineer building a car that crashes
and kills someone”.13 By placing the project first inside Alphabet’s moonshot subsidiary X, and
then by creating a new, legally independent subsidiary, Waymo, Alphabet arguably reduced the
potential for adverse reputational spillovers that may have arisen if a “Google car” (instead of a
Waymo car) had killed somebody. We suggest that, by mitigating the reputational risks of bold
bets, asset partitioning can boost investment, innovation and growth.14
Greater autonomy at the subsidiary level. Asset partitioning also provides benefits to the
organization in terms of greater autonomy and higher-powered incentives at the subsidiary level.
Because headquarters are protected from unlimited losses, asset partitioning tends to promote de-
centralized decision-making and the use of local information. Incorporation also provides subsidiary
managers with the flexibility and the legal instruments required to make important decisions such
as raising debt, selling equity and writing contracts with third parties. The presence of a separate
board with fiduciary duty to the affiliated firm affords subsidiary managers greater sense of au-
tonomy and control over resources (Lan and Heracleous, 2010; Manikandan and Ramachandran,
2015). Better performance information at the subsidiary level allow headquarters to strengthen the
link between managerial compensation and performance. This, in turn, should increase managerial
initiative and motivation.
13 See The Guardian (19 Aug 2016), https://www.theguardian.com/technology/2016/aug/19/self-driving-car-
anthony-levandowski-uber-otto-google
14 The drawback of reputational compartmentalization is that positive reputational spillovers are also reduced. We
return to this issue later, when we discuss the costs of finer asset partitioning.
11
Google’s co-founder Larry Page argues that decentralization was a major goal in Google’s restruc-
turing. As he puts it: “Fundamentally, we believe this [restructuring] allows us more management
scale, as we can run things independently that aren’t very related [.. . ] Alphabet is about busi-
nesses prospering through strong leaders and independence”.15 The New York Times summarized
Google’s motives as follows: “Google Goal in Restructuring as Alphabet: Autonomy”.16
Greater internal transparency. Another benefit of asset partitioning is that it can improve
internal transparency and quality of financial information. This is because performance is typically
more accurately and reliably measured for subsidiaries than for unincorporated business units.
Unlike business units, where financial information is managed by internal bookkeeping (that bears
no legal liability), financial information by subsidiaries is usually audited by external accounting
firms, which are liable for any inaccurate measurement of financial performance. Second, investors’
ability to evaluate each of the group affiliates’ operating performance is likely to improve given
that the complexity of the original organization is reduced and transactions between affiliates
are more accurately recorded. Gilson (2001) finds a substantial increase in analyst coverage and
earnings forecast accuracy in the three years following a spinoff or an equity carve-out. Huson
and MacKinnon (2003) show that analysts revise their earnings forecasts upward in response to
a spinoff. This evidence suggests that asset partitioning increases transparency, reduces informa-
tional asymmetries, and potentially increases shareholder value. Internal transparency was another
reason why Google reorganized as Alphabet. Alphabet committed to implement segment reporting,
with Google financials being provided separately than those for the rest of Alphabet businesses
as a whole.17 This move was praised by investors, “anticipating that it will provide clarity and
transparency to revenue drivers of Google’s core business”.18 19
Learning about asset values. Finer asset partitioning allows managers and investors to learn
more fine-grained information pertaining specific assets. When assets are pooled together, financial
markets only provide information about the joint value of the assets, not their individual values.
15 See https://abc.xyz/.
16 See https://www.nytimes.com/2015/08/12/technology/autonomy-seen-as-goal-of-restructured-google.html.
17 See https://abc.xyz/.
18 See https://www.nasdaq.com/articles/what-googles-alphabet-means-investors-and-wall-street-2015-08-13
19 We stress, however, that all Alphabet subsidiaries are wholly-owned by Alphabet; therefore, there is no formal
restriction limiting Alphabet’s controlling shareholders’ ability to cross-subsidize different business units. Despite this
caveat, the greater internal transparency through the use of formal accounting and oversight by a Wall Street CFO
arguably reassured investors that the internal allocation of funds would be value-based and not be driven solely by
the discretion of Page and Brin. Based on this logic, Google’s reorganization is a step toward making business units
less dependent on one another. This strategic move unlocked value because it alleviated, to some extent, investors’
concerns around inefficient use of Google’s assets and eliminated negative synergies between business units.
12
Partitioning assets enables top management to get separate signals regarding the quality of specific
units. Such signals are particularly important when top management must make investment deci-
sions in each asset. In these cases, investments may have to be tailored to the value or potential
of each asset. Economists have long emphasized the informational content of asset prices. Prices
matter because they provide accurate signals for resource allocation (Fama and Miller, 1972; Bond
et al., 2012). Finer asset partitioning, by providing more fine-grained information, has the potential
to improve investment decisions, thereby increasing shareholder value.
Finer asset partitioning also allows headquarters to more easily divest assets in the future,
because investors are better informed about the specific value of each assets and because parti-
tioning facilitates tradeability through bundled assignability (Ayotte and Hansmann, 2013). As a
consequence, finer assets partitioning gives corporate groups greater ability to identify valuable
opportunities, and greater flexibility to overcome situations where strong business units subsidize
weak business units. Such situations have been shown by many researchers to be highly detrimental
to multidivisional firms (Chang and Hong, 2000; Shin and Park, 1999). Hence, under finer asset
partitioning, “negative synergies” between business units can be eliminated and greater value can
be unlocked.
2.2.2. Costs of asset partitioning
Finer asset partitioning, despite creating several benefits, also imposes significant costs. These
costs arise because “walls” are created between asset pools controlled by the same ultimate own-
ers. These walls may impede actions that increase group value. We highlight two types of costs
associated with finer asset partitioning: reduced synergies (such as stunted resource redeployment)
and reduced headquarters monitoring.
Stunted resource redeployment. As discussed above, several benefits of asset partitioning stem
from limited liability. To benefit from limited liability, however, the parent must respect formalities
and not inappropriately interfere with the management of the subsidiary. If subsidiary managers
cannot demonstrate that they are autonomous from headquarters, as evidenced for instance by the
subsidiary having separate board meetings and electing separate officers, courts may be inclined
to view the independence of the subsidiary as a legal fiction. As such, they could make the parent
accountable for the liabilities of the subsidiary. Thus, to preserve the benefits of limited liability,
headquarters may refrain from intervening in subsidiary’s matters. This may discourage resource
sharing, which is widely regarded to be a fundamental advantage of corporate groups (Khanna and
Yafeh, 2007).
The risk of stunted resource redeployment is especially salient in partly-owned groups where
headquarters do not fully own all their subsidiaries (Bethel and Liebeskind, 1998). In partly-owned
13
groups, shareholders in one affiliate may oppose resource redeployment to another affiliate because
they are not significant shareholders in the other affiliate and hence do not significantly benefit
from resource redeployment. These conflicts of interests between the shareholders of different group
affiliates cannot arise in wholly-owned groups, because in wholly-owned groups all subsidiaries are
owned by the same shareholders (the headquarters’ owners)
The recent merger between Google and Nest can be understood as an attempt to remove “walls”
between these two Alphabet units and facilitate resource sharing. According to industry observers,
the merger will make it easier to integrate Google’s artificial intelligence technology into new Nest
products and offer bundled packages. It will also allow new Nest devices to become an access point
for the Google Assistant. As Google’s hardware chief Rick Osterloh notes, “All of Google’s invest-
ments in machine learning and AI, they can very clearly benefit Nest products. It just makes sense
to be developing them together”.20 Coarser asset partitioning (reversing finer asset partitioning)
clearly appears to have the potential to boost resource sharing between these two Alphabet units.
Another potential benefit of the merger between Google and Nest is reputational. As part of
Google, Nest (now renamed Google Nest) will most likely enjoy greater brand recognition. This type
of positive reputational spillovers have long been discussed in the marketing literature under names
such as “umbrella branding” (Loken and John, 1993; Erdem, 1998). Earlier we noted that finer
asset partitioning, especially when combined with different names for each subsidiary, may reduce
or prevent negative reputational spillovers. The flip side is that positive reputational spillovers may
be reduced as well.
Reduced headquarters monitoring. Because of limited liability, headquarters bear lower risks
when their subsidiaries fail. As a consequence, headquarters’ incentives to carefully monitor sub-
sidiary managers are also reduced (Aghion and Tirole, 1997; Ayotte, 2017). Headquarters mon-
itoring may also be reduced or constrained because subsidiary managers (with CEO titles) feel
they are entitled to more discretion and autonomy than divisional managers. Overall, finer asset
partitioning tends to promote decentralization and autonomy in organizations. The flip side is that
headquarters monitoring and oversight will also decrease.
To summarize, asset partitioning brings with it costs and benefits. When a group incorporates
a division or sets up a new subsidiary, it enjoys the benefits of risk compartmentalization, greater
autonomy, greater internal transparency, and learning about asset values. On the other hand,
the ability and incentives of headquarters to engage in resource redeployment and monitoring are
diminished. Granting a unit legal independence can be effective to bolster decentralization and
20 See https://www.cnet.com/news/google-and-nest-reunite-in-push-to-add-ai-to-every-gadget/
14
autonomy within a large organization; however, synergies among units may become more difficult
to achieve.21
3. Asset partitioning and enterprise liability
Existing perspectives on corporate groups suggest important causal links between the preponder-
ance of different organizational forms and national legal institutions. The control-magnifying view,
for instance, suggests that groups should be more common in countries where minority shareholder
protections are weak, because in those countries powerful owners can more easily take advantage of
minority shareholders. The institutional voids perspective suggests instead that groups should be
more common in countries where contractual enforcement is weak, because internal redeployment
then becomes a more important substitute for missing external markets.
The asset partitioning view also conceptualizes groups as “hybrid” organizational forms, the
prevalence of which is contingent on national legal institutions. However, while existing theories
emphasize minority shareholder protections or contractual enforcement, the asset partitioning view
highlights limited liability as a key feature of legal independent entities such as group subsidiaries.
Limited liability is important from an economic standpoint because it reassures investors that
their losses will be limited to the amount they have invested in a company. Because downward risk is
bounded, limited liability encourages entrepreneurship, the formation of large firms, the separation
of ownership and control and the development of liquid capital markets. However, limited liability
may also encourage moral hazard and excessive risk taking, because the costs of failed economic
enterprise are partly externalized to other stakeholders.
Because limited liability creates not just benefits but also social costs, virtually every country
allows for exceptions to the general default rule of limited liability. The most notable exception is
the doctrine of piercing the corporate veil.
3.1. Piercing the Corporate Veil (PCV)
Piercing the corporate veil (PCV) is a provision that allows courts to disregard the default limited
liability and separate legal personality of the firm and to impose the debts of the firm on its owners.
In general, modern corporate law recognizes a ‘veil’ separating the firm’s assets and the owners’
personal assets. But, when a plaintiff prevails in a PCV claim, the court effectively ‘pierces’ the
corporate veil by imposing the firm’s debts on its owners.
In general, the PCV doctrine is vague and discretionary. Litigants, both plaintiffs/creditors and
defendants/stock owners, cannot rely on uniform tests to predict how courts will treat their case,
21 To some extent, the benefits of asset partitioning may also be achieved through other means. Reputational com-
partmentalization, for instance, could also be achieved by introducing different brands, without having to create new
subsidiaries. Nevertheless, setting up new companies with independent CEOs and boards may provide additional
insulation in the eyes of the courts, the press, and the public.
15
mainly because veil piercing is an amorphous concept seeking to capture types of owner-corporation
relationships that are illegitimate and thus warrant veil piercing. Typically, PCV laws are intended
to eliminate the protection of limited liability in cases where owners abuse the rationales of incor-
poration. In translating this abstract purpose into concrete guidelines, both courts and legislatures
have struggled to formulate clear rules defining when the veil should be pierced. Rather, they cre-
ated general frameworks where a long list of variables may be factored in under a two- or three-stage
analysis.
For example, a test applied by some U.S. courts consists of two stages of analysis. The plaintiff
must demonstrate, first, a lack of separation between ownership and management, to the extent
that owner completely dominates corporate policy and, second, commitment of fraud or wrong by
the owner that proximately causes plaintiff ’s injury. A problem is that to apply this analysis courts
consider an unspecified number of factors. Among the main factors are: (1) undercapitalization of
the firm; (2) commingling of corporate and personal assets; (3) asset striping/transfer of assets;
(4) disregard for corporate formalities; (5) owner’s control or domination over management issues;
and (6) fraud or misrepresentation of business operations. In some countries courts require demon-
stration of wrongdoing, fundamentally unfair conduct, fraud, or use of the separate personality
principle for unlawful goals as prerequisites in veil piercing suits.
3.2. Enterprise Liability Around the World
The benefits of limited liability extend not only to situations where the owner of a firm is an
individual or a group of individuals, but also to situations when the owner is another corporation
(i.e., when the firm belongs to a group). However, when the owner of a firm is another company,
the rationale for granting limited liability to owners is weaker.
One reason is that the parent company’s individual shareholders are already protected by limited
liability. Thus, it is not clear what social benefits protecting these shareholders twice (at the parent
and at the subsidiary’s level) would bring. Furthermore, unlike most individual investors, parent
companies typically exert very real control over the operations of their subsidiaries. Thus, granting
parent companies limited liability may simply deresponsibilize them (Blumberg, 1985; Strasser,
2004).
Because of these reasons, piercing of the corporate veil is much more common when the owner of
a company is another company than when the owners are individual investors. Legal scholars refer
to situations when a court makes a parent company (or more generally the whole group) liable for
the debts of one of its subsidiaries as “enterprise liability”. Enterprise liability is in some sense the
‘opposite’ of limited liability. If a parent company enjoys limited liability, it is not liable for the
debts of its subsidiaries. By contrast, with enterprise liability, the parent (or the whole group) is
liable.
16
Interestingly, countries differ considerably in their propensity to apply enterprise liability. This
heterogeneity can be ascribed to two broad sets of factors.
First, countries differ in their social, cultural, and institutional norms. Distributing risk between
different stakeholders (e.g., owners versus involuntary creditors) is ultimately a matter of economic
and social priorities, and countries may reach different conclusions regarding the proper allocation
of risk, or the desirability of different social goals (e.g., efficiency versus fairness). These differences
are likely to be reflected in limited liability laws. In Great Britain, for example, PCV is in essence
a very restrictive tool aimed to achieve fairness and to discipline the market. As such, it is invoked
mostly as a sanction against fraudulent behavior. In the Netherlands, however, PCV is used pri-
marily to protect tort creditors from externalization of risk. Thus, it is invoked more prominently
in tort cases than in non-tort cases.
The second set of factors affecting countries’ propensity to pierce the corporate veil relates to the
extent to which groups are perceived as a single economic entity. Comparative examination of PCV
across countries reveals two polar views regarding enterprise liability. At one end of the spectrum
lies the legalistic British approach, by which the parent and the subsidiary are considered to be two
distinct entities that deserve no special treatment compared to any other owner and corporation.
British courts have shown reluctance to ignore legal separation even when plaintiffs demonstrate
that a parent and its wholly-owned subsidiary acted as a single economic enterprise and the parent
sets the broad business policy of the subsidiary. At the other extreme of the spectrum is the German
approach. The German law on Konzernrecht (controlled companies) provides the most developed
statutory scheme applying what the literature refers to as the “enterprise approach” or “single
economic unit approach”. In various cases when a subsidiary is proven to be completely dominated
by the parent or subordinated to the parent’s interests, the law on Konzernrecht provides tools
aimed at limiting intra-group dealings and at holding the parent liable for the losses incurred by
the subsidiary.22
In-between these two extremes, there are several intermediate cases. Italy, France, Netherlands,
and Argentina follow variants of the enterprise approach (albeit, with a narrower legal framework
than in Germany) and as a result provide somewhat easier paths to enterprise liability. In Australia,
courts have recognized a general principle under which “in certain circumstances a corporate group
is operating in such a manner as to make each individual entity indistinguishable, and therefore
22 In essence, the German law creates a trade-off between two key features of corporate groups. On the one hand, the
controlling owner is entitled to give binding instructions to the subsidiary even when the instructions might not be
in the subsidiary’s best interest. On the other hand, to compensate for the additional risk that the subsidiary and
its stakeholders bear, the law provides instruments that hold the parent company liable for losses incurred by the
subsidiary. Specifically, the law imposes additional regulations to protect creditors. Among the duties imposed on the
parent are the duty to make the execution and termination of controlling agreement available to creditors and the
responsibility to maintain money reserves to compensate for potential losses incurred by the subsidiary.
17
it is proper to pierce the corporate veil to treat the parent company as liable for the acts of the
subsidiary” (Ramsay and Noakes, 2001).
The United States, Japan, China, Sweden, and Belgium contain no special rules governing cor-
porate groups. Courts consider parent-subsidiary veil piercing under the general framework used
for other cases, with no reference to an overarching enterprise theory imposing special legal regime.
Nonetheless, the case law seems to draw on some additional policy considerations uniquely applica-
ble in the parent-subsidiary context. For instance, U.S. courts developed some guidelines uniquely
designed to deal with affiliated corporations. Courts in all states commonly agree that the mere full
ownership of stocks by the parent is not a dispositive fact, nor is common identity of the parent’s and
the subsidiary’s officers and directors. Furthermore, demonstration of control over the subsidiary’s
affairs that is consistent with norms of corporate behavior, such as delineating general policies and
performance monitoring, will not satisfy the control requirement for veil piercing. However, when
the parent seems to control day-to-day operations and managerial decision-making and when the
subsidiary abandons common corporate practices while being fully operated by the parent, courts
will be more inclined to pierce the veil. Other factors considered by courts in corporate group cases
are unfair intra-group transactions, excessive dividends, wrongful conduct in the performance of
contracts (e.g., when the parent depletes the subsidiary’s assets to the point that it cannot satis-
factorily perform its contract obligations) and commingling or shuffling of assets.23 Overall, these
efforts have attempted to provide a middle ground between the German Konzernrecht theory and
the British legalistic approach.
3.3. Empirical Predictions
The asset partitioning perspective provides clear predictions regarding how enterprise liability
affects firm boundaries, internal organization, and corporate group investment and growth.24
The benefits from risk compartmentalization are lower in countries where courts are more likely
to apply the doctrine of enterprise liability (i.e., when enterprise liability is strong). If courts
hold the whole group liable for the debts of one of its subsidiaries, risks cannot effectively be
compartmentalized and losses in one unit will spread to other units. The incentives for groups to
more finely partition their assets will therefore be reduced.
Conversely, in countries where courts are less likely to apply the doctrine of enterprise liability
(i.e., when enterprise liability is weak), groups have stronger incentives to partition their assets
23 Another relevant factor is misrepresentation of corporate structure. Misrepresentation arises when a creditor believes
it was dealing with a wealthy parent rather than a thinly capitalized subsidiary. Misrepresentation becomes an issue
especially when the parent takes an active role in it.
24 In the Supplementary Appendix B, we provide an economic model where these predictions are formally derived.
The model is an extension of Aghion and Tirole (1997), the main difference being that we allow for varying degrees
of limited liability protection across units/projects. See also Ayotte (2017) for a related analysis.
18
more finely. By incorporating business units as legally independent subsidiaries, they can prevent
losses in one unit from spreading to other units. These benefits are largest when very significant
losses are possible; that is, when catastrophic, bankruptcy-inducing events can occur. Thus, we
suggest the following.
Hypothesis 1. (Firm boundaries) Corporate groups partition their assets more finely in countries
where enterprise liability is weak. This relationship is stronger for groups that operate in industries
with significant downward risk.
In countries where courts are less likely to apply the doctrine of enterprise liability, groups are
also more likely to grant their subsidiaries more decision-making autonomy. If courts do not hold
the whole group liable for the debts of one of its subsidiaries, risks are better compartmentalized
and groups can enjoy the benefits of decentralized decision-making without having to worry about
the consequences of bad subsidiary decisions spilling over to other units. Thus, we expect that, in
countries where enterprise liability is weak, groups will decentralize their operations more and will
delegate more decision-making authority to subsidiary managers.
Hypothesis 2. (Internal organization) Corporate groups grant their subsidiaries more decision-
making autonomy in countries where enterprise liability is weak.
In countries where courts are less likely to apply the doctrine of enterprise liability, groups can
also invest more and grow faster. By setting up new subsidiaries, liability risks are reduced through
better compartmentalization. As a consequence, headquarters can more confidently invest in risky
new projects, such as self-driving cars or nuclear plants. This is the traditional argument in favor of
limited liability: By limiting the amount of money that investors can lose when starting a new busi-
ness, limited liability laws (or, conversely, weaker enterprise liability) can spur entrepreneurship,
innovation, and growth.
An additional mechanism is suggested by Manikandan and Ramachandran (2015). By fostering
subsidiary autonomy, weak enterprise liability may also foster group affiliates’ ability to sense
and seize growth opportunities. Indeed, Manikandan and Ramachandran argue greater subsidiary
autonomy (relative to the autonomy granted to divisional managers) is a chief benefit of multi-
entity organizations.
Both these arguments lead to the following prediction.
Hypothesis 3. (Corporate group growth) Corporate groups invest more and grow faster in coun-
tries where enterprise liability is weak.
19
We conclude with a remark about social welfare. It may appear that the arguments above imply
that society is always better when limited liability laws are strengthened (or, conversely, when
the doctrine of enterprise liability is weakened). This is not the case. Weak enterprise liability
spurs investment and growth by allowing headquarters to walk away from a subsidiary’s debt
obligations. However, the risks of failed economic enterprise are not eliminated, but rather shifted
from investors to other stakeholders (e.g., debt holders). Society may also want to protect these
other stakeholders. Moreover, limited liability protections may be abused, for instance if owners
engage in excessive risk taking or fraud. In general, the design of limited liability laws requires
societies to compromise between legitimate interests. How this should be done is a question that
economists and lawyers are actively debating.
4. Data
Our sample consists of 939,679 corporate groups across sixteen countries over years 2002 through
2014.25 On average, groups in our sample have controlling stakes (50%) in 2 subsidiaries with a
standard deviation of 8.9. We perform our main analysis at the group-industry-country-year level
(our key results are generally not sensitive to the unit of analysis level). The final estimation sample
includes 3,122,026 observations.
To build our sample, we use historical publications (yearly snapshots) of Bureau Van Djik’s
Orbis database and construct evolving ownership links between corporate headquarters and their
subsidiaries.26 For each headquarter, we retain all of the subsidiaries where the headquarter has
more than a 50% ownership stake according to Orbis’s “direct” and “total” ownership share fields.27
To explore the relationship between enterprise liability and asset partitioning, we use data from
the World Management Survey (WMS). WMS provides survey measures of autonomy corporate
parents grant their subsidiaries (Bloom and Van Reenen, 2007). Subsidiaries in WMS are matched
to subsidiaries in our sample to arrive at 1,752 firm-year observations covering ten countries across
the Americas, Asia, and Europe.28
25 France, Germany, Great Britain, Italy, Sweden, and United States, the countries with the greatest presence in our
sample, account for 22% (699,162), 24% (735,513), 14% (449,112), 9% (289,198), 10% (308,941), and 7% (206,768)
of the sample, respectively.
26 We identify corporate headquarters using the ultimate owner field in the Orbis database and identify all their
subsidiaries using the ultimate owner field associated with the subsidiaries.
27 The sample captures various types of ultimate owners. The most prevalent types are industrial companies (own-
ership type of “C”) at 42%, individuals or families (ownership type of “I”) at 32%, financial institutions (ownership
type of “B” and “F”) at 9%.
28 The survey items we obtain from WMS are: 1) aggregate measure of autonomy based on the questions, “To hire
a full-time permanent shop floor worker what agreement would your plant need from CHQ?”, “How much of sales
and marketing is carried out at the plant level (rather than at CHQ)?”, and “Where are decisions taken on new
product introductions - at the plant, at the CHQ or at both?” (WMS measure: central); 2) measure of investment
autonomy based on “What is the largest capital investment your plant could make without prior authorization from
20
4.1. Piercing The Corporate Veil (PCV) Score
To create proxies for enterprise liability, in collaboration with scholars at Duke University School
of Law, we evaluated relevant legal provisions across sixteen countries in the Americas, Asia, and
Europe. We analyzed an exception to the default limited liability rule - the piercing the corporate
veil (PCV) - that courts use to hold corporate headquarters liable for the debts incurred by their
subsidiaries. Countries were scored on a scale of zero to five according to how inclined their courts
are to pierce the corporate veil in cases involving corporate groups, with a higher score indicating
stronger inclination to pierce the veil. A higher PCV score implies stronger enterprise liability for
corporate headquarters.29
We evaluated five distinct criteria that either implicitly or explicitly affect intra-group veil pierc-
ing and weighted the criteria according to their importance.3031 Table 1 presents the breakdown of
the scores that we assign to each country based on the five criteria as well as the overall PCV scores.
(Supplementary Appendix A further provides details of the comparative analysis performed across
the sample countries to arrive at both the overall and the score breakdown across the criteria.)
First, we examined the extent to which each country applies the “enterprise” (or “economic
unity”) approach in cases involving corporate groups. Application of this legal concept is the most
important criterion in determining the probability of corporate veil piercing, because it shows how
likely courts are to treat subsidiaries and their corporate parents as a single legal entity and thus
to hold parents liable for the losses of their subsidiaries. As shown in Column 1, Germany has the
highest score on this dimension, and Great Britain along with China, Japan, and Sweden have the
lowest score. That is, courts in Germany are more inclined than those in Great Britain to treat
subsidiaries as an integral part of their parent firms.
corporate headquarter?” (WMS measure: central5); 3) measure of product introduction autonomy based on “Where
are decisions taken on new product introductions - at the plant, at the CHQ or at both?” (WMS: central7); 4) measure
of sales and marketing autonomy based on “How much of sales and marketing is carried out at the plant level (rather
than at CHQ)?” (WMS: central6); and 5) measure of hiring autonomy based on “To hire a full-time permanent shop
floor worker what agreement would your plant need from CHQ?” (WMS: central4). We also use indirect measures of
autonomy based on “Number of levels in the firm between the shop floor and the CEO.” (WMS: levels2ceo) and “Is
CHQ on the site being interviewed?” (WMS measure: onsite).
29 In multinational groups, jurisdictional problems arise from the separation between parent firms and subsidiaries.
Claimants may argue that a case is better heard in the home country of the parent rather than in the host country
of the subsidiary. We chose to focus on the PCV score of the country of the subsidiary because in a number of cases
in the US and the UK courts rejected claimants’ attempts to bring proceedings in the home country of the parent,
to prevent “forum shopping” (Muchlinski, 2010).
30 We examine these five criteria rather than the PCV law directly because the law on PCV is often ambiguous,
vague, or subject to judicial discretion. Moreover, in some jurisdictions (e.g., China), the legal concept of PCV is
fairly new and still developing and so data on PCV are limited. Lastly, data on actual enterprise liability rulings are
available only for select countries.
31 As a robustness test, we recalculate the overall PCV score after dropping each of the five criteria as well as by
weighting them equally.
21
The second most important criterion is the number and diversity of factors that courts are willing
to consider when deciding whether to pierce the corporate veil. The more factors that courts are
willing to consider, the more likely that the courts will hold parent firms liable for the losses of their
subsidiaries. Column 2 shows that Great Britain, Sweden, and Denmark have the lowest scores, and
China and the United States have the highest scores on this dimension. Factors that courts might
consider in relation to this criterion include under-capitalization, commingling of corporate and
personal affairs, disregard for corporate formalities, fraud or misrepresentation, unfair or unjust
conduct, extent of owner’s control over subsidiaries, dysfunctional management, and assumption
of risk by creditors.
Third and fourth, some countries limit corporate veil piercing only to bankruptcy and/or fraud
cases while other countries are open to piercing the corporate veil in other cases as well. Thus,
we examine whether countries are willing to hold a corporate parent liable in cases outside of
bankruptcy and fraud and assign separate scores for these two criteria. Columns 3 and 4 show that
courts in Australia, Canada, China, Great Britain, Japan, South Korea, and Switzerland are all
willing to pierce the corporate veil in cases outside of bankruptcy while German courts are most
likely to exercise corporate veil piercing in cases outside of fraud.
Last, we looked at the available empirical evidence on the inclination of courts to pierce the
corporate veil. Actual case data reveal that Australia has the lowest corporate veil piercing rate
of 33%. China has the highest corporate veil piercing rate of 61%. Column 5 shows scores across
countries. The scores range from -5 to 5 with 0 indicating that data were not available.
Column 6 presents the overall PCV scores for each of the sixteen countries in our sample, weighted
by the importance of each criterion. Germany has the highest overall score of 3.93, reflecting its
high willingness to hold a corporate parent liable for the debts of its subsidiaries, and Great Britain
has the lowest overall PCV score of 1.3, reflecting its legalistic regulatory style.
[Insert Table 1 here]
In Supplementary Appendix A, we provide a description of our cross-country measures of enter-
prise liability and the data sources used to construct them.
4.2. Moderating Factors
To better understand the mechanisms driving the relationship between enterprise liability and
asset partitioning, we explore several factors that may moderate this relationship. We discuss these
moderating factors below.
Industry downside risk. In industries where firms face a substantial downside risk protection
against potential losses incurred by subsidiaries should be especially valuable to headquarters. Ac-
cordingly, we expect that the relationship between enterprise liability (PCV) and asset partitioning
22
to be stronger in industries where firms are more likely to face substantial downside risk (see also
Hypothesis 1 above). To test this hypothesis, we construct a measure that captures the level of
industry downside risk faced by group subsidiaries. We construct our measure of downside risk as
the share of firms in an industry that experience an annual drop of at least 50% in revenues.32
On average, 3% of our sample subsidiaries experience a yearly revenue drop of at least 50% (90th
percentile of 9.5%).
Corruption. A factor that is likely to increase the cost of asset partitioning is the level of cor-
ruption in the regions where a subsidiary operates. Monitoring costs should be higher in more
corrupt regions raising the costs of asset partitioning. We obtain data on corruption from the
Eurobarometer, a collection of surveys conducted for the European Commission. Our measure of
regional corruption is the share of respondents who totally agreed or tended to agree that there is
corruption in regional institution.33
Managerial experience. Monitoring costs should be bigger for inexperienced subsidiary man-
agers. We use the age of executives and senior managers in corporate groups from Orbis to construct
a measure of the yearly average age of the subsidiary managers for our sample groups. The average
age of subsidiary managers is 50.8 ranging from 40.3 (10th percentile) to 61.2 (90th percentile).
Knowledge complexity. The costs of asset partitioning should be higher when the knowledge
base of a firm is more complex and requires greater coordination. As we noted in Section 2.2.2,
asset partitioning raises coordination cost and therefore should be less prevalent in more complex
environments. We measure complexity using patent data. We combine patent numbers and assignee
identifiers from Kogan et al. (2017) with industry codes (3-digit SIC’s) from Compustat and with
Cooperative Patent Classification (CPC) codes from PatentsView.org. We construct a measure
of average generality of patents (a proxy for knowledge complexity) produced by firms in each
industry (3-digit industry) for each year, where generality of a patent is calculated as 1 minus
Herfindahl–Hirschman Index (HHI) based on CPC classes of the patents that the focal patent
cites (Trajtenberg et al., 1997).34 As an alternative measure, we compute the average number of
technology classes (i.e., CPC subclasses) that a patent is assigned to within each industry and year.
A higher value indicates a more complex knowledge base of an industry’s invention for a given
year.35
32 We experiment with different reasonable threshold and with other types of financial assets (i.e., net income, cash,
and current assets). Our results are not sensitive to these changes.
33 On average, the share of respondents who perceived that there is corruption in regional institutions was 78%, with
shares ranging from 66% at the 10th percentile to 89% at the 90th percentile.
34 Average generality is 0.33, ranging from 0.12 (10th percentile) to 0.53 (90th percentile).
35 On average, a patent is assigned to 2.1 CPC subclasses, with the number of CPC subclass assignments ranging
from 1 at the 10th percentile and 3 at the 90th percentile.
23
4.2.1. Headquarters’ Control
To further explore the relationship between enterprise liability and asset partitioning, we examine
how the level of headquarters’ control over subsidiaries moderates the relationship. We construct the
following measures of headquarters’ control: (i) share of managers in subsidiaries that are related
through family ties to the group’s controlling shareholders, (ii) share of subsidiaries with a board
member who is also on the board of the corporate parent, (iii) share of wholly-owned subsidiaries,
and (iv) share of subsidiaries having similar names as their corporate parent. We expect a stronger
relationship between PCV and number of subsidiaries for more independent subsidiaries.
Family managers. When a manager of a subsidiary is related to the group’s controlling share-
holders, interactions between the subsidiary and headquarters are less likely to be arms-length and
close integration is more likely, rendering enterprise liability protection less salient. To test this
hypothesis, we collect names of shareholders in corporate groups along with executive and senior
manager names of subsidiaries from Orbis. We match the last names of the managers to the last
names of the shareholders and calculate (at the group-country-industry-year level) the fraction of
subsidiaries whose executives and senior managers include a family member of the shareholders
(owning at least 5% of stocks).36
Board interlocks. Sharing board members between the parent and its subsidiaries is often indica-
tive of a high level of control that the parent has over its subsidiaries. When board member overlap
is high between a subsidiary and its corporate parent, enterprise liability protection should be less
effective and less prevalent. To test this prediction, for each corporate group and year, we extract
the names of the board members for the subsidiaries and their corporate parent from Orbis. We
then compute (at the group-country-industry-year level) the fraction of the subsidiaries a board
member who is also a board member of the corporate parent.37
Wholly-owned subsidiaries. When a corporate parent wholly owns its subsidiary its level of
control should be higher than in the case of partly-owned affiliates. Consequently, enterprise liability
protection should be less salient for wholly owned subsidiaries relative to partly owned ones. To
explore this hypothesis, for each corporate parent we compute the fraction of its subsidiaries that
are wholly owned. We identify parent-subsidiary pairs where the parent has 100% ownership stake
36 Average share of subsidiaries managed by a family manager is 14% ranging from from 0% (10th percentile) to 100%
(90th percentile).
37 On average, 54% of a subsidiary’s board members are also on the board of the corporate parent ranging from 0%
(10th percentile) to 100% (90th percentile).
24
in the subsidiary and calculate the share of subsidiaries that are wholly owned by the parent firm
at the corporate parent-subsidiary country-industry level for each sample year.38
Parent-subsidiary name sharing. Some subsidiaries have similar names as their corporate
parent. Name sharing should lead to weaker subsidiary independence due to potential reputation
spillovers that would justify strong headquarters’ monitoring. Weaker subsidiary independence
then makes enterprise liability protection less salient. To test this prediction, we extract the names
of subsidiaries and their corporate parents and compute the share of subsidiaries at the group-
country-industry-year level.39 40
4.3. Descriptive statistics
Table 2 presents summary statistics for the main variables used in our analysis. (See Supplementary
Appendix C for variable definitions.) On average, corporate groups in a given industry within
a country control 1.45 subsidiaries (a standard deviation of 3.84). Through these subsidiaries,
corporate groups generate around 78 million US dollars in revenues and control around 300 million
US dollars in assets.41
[Insert Table 2 here]
Figure 1 plots the relationship between country PCV score and average number of subsidiaries per
one million US dollars in revenues. Hypothesis 1 states that a corporate parent should incorporate
its subsidiaries when enterprise liability is weaker (a lower PCV score). The raw data strongly
supports this prediction: subsidiaries are more prevalent in countries where courts are less willing
to pierce the corporate veil (that is, where enterprise liability is weaker). The correlation between
PCV scores and number of subsidiaries is -0.53. In Great Britain, for instance, where enterprise
liability is the weakest, the average number of subsidiaries per one million US dollars is 22, whereas
in Germany, where the enterprise liability is the strongest, the average number of subsidiaries per
one million US dollars is only 1.6.
[Insert Figure 1 here]
38 On average, 45% of the subsidiaries are wholly owned, with the share ranging from 0% (10th percentile) to 100%
(90th percentile).
39 We also check robustness of our results using share of subsidiaries that share exactly the same name as the corporate
parent, and the results are consistent with our main finding.
40 On average, 28% of the subsidiaries operate under the same or partially same name as their corporate parent, with
the share ranging from 0% (10th percentile) to 100% (90th percentiles).
41 Across all industries and countries in a given year, corporate groups generate around 108 million USD (a standard
deviation of 2.6 billion USD). Our sample groups in France, Germany, the Great Britain, Italy, Sweden, and United
States generate 38, 70, 108, 36, 20, 190 million USD in revenues and control 107, 155, 528, 85, 49, and 573 million
USD in assets, respectively.
25
Figure 2a-f present the relationship between PCV score and subsidiary autonomy measures
obtained from the World Management Survey. Because limited liability protects corporate parents
against the losses incurred by their subsidiaries, we expect stronger enterprise liability (higher
PCV score) to be associated with weaker subsidiary autonomy. The general pattern of results is
consistent with our prediction. Figure 2b, for instance, shows that as PCV score increases, capital
investment autonomy decreases. In Great Britain, where the PCV score is the lowest at 1.3, the
maximum capital investment that a plant can make without prior authorization from the corporate
parent, normalized as log(max capital investment / number of employees), is 2.7. In Germany,
where the PCV score is the highest at 3.93, it is around 1.9. The same pattern holds for marketing
and sales autonomy, product introduction autonomy, and hiring autonomy.
[Insert Figure 2 here]
5. Main Econometric Specifications
We turn next to an econometric investigation of our three hypotheses. To test Hypothesis 1, that
a corporate parent is more likely to incorporate its business units when enterprise liability is weak,
we estimate the following specification:
ln(Subs)ij ct =β0+β1P CVc+ ln(Rev)ijct +Z0
ctγ+ηi+µj+τt+ij ct
Subsij ct is number of subsidiaries in corporate group iin three-digit SIC jin country cfor
year t.P CVcis the PCV score of the country cwhere the subsidiaries operate. Revijct is total
group revenue,42 and Zis a vector of country-level controls, including GDP, level of stock market
development, unemployment rate, and strength of employment protection legislation (these have
been used in previous studies as country-level determinants of group affiliation).43 ηi,µjand τt
are complete sets of dummies for corporate groups, three-digit SIC codes, and years. ijct is an iid
error term. The coefficient of interest is β1. Consistent with Hypothesis 1, we expect β1<0.
To test Hypothesis 2, that a corporate parent is more likely to grant greater decision-making
autonomy to its subsidiaries in countries where enterprise liability is weak, we estimate the following
specification:
ln(Autonomy)st =β0+β1P C Vc+ ln(Rev)it +Z0
ctγ+µj+τt+it
42 We use revenues instead of total assets because the coverage of balance sheet items including assets is more sparse,
especially for German and American firms. At any rate, in unreported regressions we find that using total assets
instead of revenues to proxy for group size produces qualitatively similar results to our main findings.
43 GDP and unemployment rate are from the World Bank. Strength of employment protection legislation is from
OECD. Stock market development is defined as the ratio of the total stock market capitalization to GDP.
26
Autonomy is the level of autonomy subsidiary sis granted by its corporate parent taken from
WMS. The coefficient of interest is β1, and consistent with Hypothesis 2, we expect β1<0 (except
for “headquarters presence on site” for which we expect β1>0).
Finally, we explore Hypothesis 3, that weaker enterprise liability leads to greater asset partition-
ing and in turn corporate group investment and growth.44 To test this prediction, we estimate the
following specification:
Growthij ct =β0+β1ln(Subs)ij ct + ln(Rev)ijct-1 +Z0
ctγ+ηi+µj+τt+ij ct
Growth is the percent change in total assets or revenues for corporate group ioperating in
industry jwithin country cover year t-1 to t. The coefficient of interest is β1and we expect β1>0.
We estimate the equivalent specification for investment measured as annual change in fixed assets.
6. Econometric Results
We turn to present the econometric results for the relationship between enterprise liability with
asset partitioning, autonomy and corporate group investment and growth.
6.1. Asset Partitioning and Enterprise Liability
Hypothesis 1 states that corporate groups partition their assets more finely in countries with weak
enterprise liability. We test this prediction by examining the relationship between PCV score and
number of subsidiaries, controlling for size. Table 3 presents the results.
Columns 1 and 2 present between- and within-group estimates, respectively. Consistent with the
raw data (Figure 1) groups that operate in countries with stronger enterprise liability partition
their assets less finely. Estimates from Column 2 indicate that moving from Great Britain (weakest
enterprise liability) to Germany (strongest enterprise liability) leads to around 16% decline in
number of subsidiaries for a fixed group size (evaluated at the sample mean).45
Columns 3-8 show that the negative relationship between number of subsidiaries and PCV score is
robust across different specifications and subsamples. Column 3 includes a complete set of dummies
for group-industry pairs, which raises the effect of PCV close to 32%.46 Columns 4-8 present results
for different sub-samples with similar pattern of results.
44 We acknowledge that a link between weaker enterprise liability and greater corporate group investment and growth
may also arise through greater subsidiary autonomy. The discussion leading to Hypothesis 3 highlights that specific
channel as well. However, the main theoretical argument is undoubtedly that, by setting up new subsidiaries, liability
risks are reduced through better compartmentalization. This is the traditional argument in favor of limited liability:
Limits to the amount of money that investors can lose when starting a new business can spur investment and growth.
More importantly, empirically we do not have enough data to properly test this idea.
45 0.16 = 0.06 ×2.63 where 0.06 is the percent change in the number of subsidiaries per unit change in PCV score and
2.63 is the difference in PCV score between Great Britain and Germany.
46 0.32 = 0.12 ×2.63, where 0.12 is the percent change in the number of subsidiaries per unit change in PCV score,
and 2.63 is the difference in PCV score between Great Britain and Germany.
27
Columns 9-10 test the second part of Hypothesis 1, that the relationship between enterprise
liability and asset partitioning is stronger in industries with a high downside risk. To test this
prediction, we interact PCV score with a dummy variable taking a value of 1 for corporate groups
operating in industries in the top quartile of the industry downside risk distribution and 0 other-
wise. As predicted, the estimates from Column 9 indicate that the relationship between enterprise
liability and asset partitioning is 20% stronger (statistically significant at the 5% level) for corporate
groups operating in industries where downside risk is high.47 Column 10 includes a complete set
of country dummies to control for time-invariant country characteristics that might influence asset
partitioning. The finding that the subsidiaries-PCV relationship is stronger for groups operating
in industries with a high downside risk remains.
[Insert Table 3 here]
6.2. Subsidiary Autonomy
Hypothesis 2 predicts that corporate headquarters are more likely to make their subsidiaries more
independent in countries where enterprise liability is weak. To test this prediction, Table 4 presents
results on the relationship between PCV score and subsidiary autonomy.
Column 1 shows that PCV score has a negative and statistically significant (at the 5% level)
relationship with autonomy score (based on subsidiary autonomy around hiring, sales and market-
ing, and product introduction). Notably, Column 2 shows that subsidiaries operating in countries
with greater enterprise liability (higher PCV score) have lower autonomy in making capital invest-
ments. The results indicate that an average subsidiary in Great Britain can invest 220 thousand
USD more without prior authorization from corporate headquarters than a comparable German
subsidiary.48
The remaining Columns show that a higher PCV score is associated with lower levels of autonomy
in the areas of product introduction (Column 3), sales and marketing (Column 4), and hiring
(Column 5). A higher PCV score is also associated with fewer hierarchical levels from the shop
floor worker to the CEO (Column 6) and a higher probability of a HQ manager being on site at
the subsidiary (Column 7). These results are consistent with the view that subsidiaries operating
in countries with greater enterprise liability have less autonomy.
[Insert Table 4 here]
47 We also performed robustness tests using measures of industry downside risk based on net income, cash, and current
assets and based on a threshold of 30% drop. The results are consistent with the findings presented above.
48 220,294 = 62046 ×1.35 ×2.63, where 62046 is the sample mean of investment amount, 1.35 is the percent increase
in investment amount per unit decline in PCV score, and 2.63 is the difference in PCV score between Germany and
Great Britain.
28
6.3. Additional Moderating Factors
Next, we explore additional factors that may influence the costs of asset partitioning (i.e., regional
corruption, managerial experience, and knowledge complexity), as well as group characteristics
associated with headquarters’ control over its subsidiaries (i.e., family managers, board interlocks,
wholly owned subsidiaries, and parent-subsidiary name sharing).
Costs of asset partitioning. We conjecture that high regional corruption will lead to agency
problems and increase the costs of setting up independent subsidiaries; inexperienced managers
will raise the costs of delegation; and knowledge complexity will increase coordination costs across
subsidiaries. We expect the effects of enterprise liability on asset partitioning to be comparatively
muted when these costs are higher. Intuitively, when these costs are high, subsidiaries will be
tightly controlled by headquarters. Thus, regardless of the degree of enterprise liability in a coun-
try, headquarters will be held responsible for the obligations of their subsidiaries, either legally,
reputationally, or through private means (e.g., intra-group guarantees).
Columns 1-3 of Table 5 present results for regional corruption, managerial experience, and
knowledge complexity, respectively. For regional corruption, we interact PCV score with a dummy
variable taking a value of 1 for subsidiaries operating in regions where at least 75% of survey
respondents agreed or somewhat agreed that there is corruption in regional institutions; for man-
agerial experience, a dummy variable taking a value of 1 for corporate groups whose managers in
the bottom quartile of the manager age distribution of the complete sample of subsidiary managers
and 0 otherwise; and for knowledge complexity, we interact PCV score with a dummy variable
taking a value of 1 for corporate groups operating in industries in the top quartile with respect to
the average generality of patents produced, and 0 otherwise.
As expected, the results show that the relationship between enterprise liability and asset parti-
tioning is weaker (statistically significant at 5% level) for subsidiaries operating in high-corruption
region (column 1), for subsidiaries with low managerial experience (column 2), and for subsidiaries
operating in complex knowledge industries (column 3). However, the economic magnitude of the
effect is small (less than 10% of the PCV level effect) for corruption and managerial experience
(less than 10% of the level PCV effect) and modest for knowledge complexity.49
[Insert Table 5 here]
Headquarters’ control. We expect the relationship between enterprise liability and asset par-
titioning to be weaker when our measures of headquarters’ control are stronger. The intuition is
49 As a robustness test, we also tested the relationship using an alternative measure of knowledge complexity, i.e.,
the average number of technology classes (i.e., CPC subclasses) that a patent is assigned to within each industry and
year. The results are consistent with our main findings.
29
the same as the one discussed above. When measures of headquarters’ control are strong, head-
quarters will be held responsible for the obligations of their subsidiaries, regardless of the degree
of enterprise liability in a country. Thus, effects of enterprise liability will be comparatively muted.
Columns 1-4 of Table 6 present results for family managers, board interlocks, wholly owned
subsidiaries, and parent-subsidiary name sharing, respectively. For family manager, we interact the
PCV score with a dummy a dummy variable taking a value of 1 for corporate groups with at least
50% of subsidiaries managed by family managers and 0 otherwise; for board interlocks, we interact
he PCV score with a dummy variable taking a value of 1 for corporate groups with at least 50%
of subsidiaries with a board member who is also on the corporate parent’s board and 0 otherwise;
for wholly owned subsidiaries, we interact the PCV score with a dummy variable taking a value of
1 for a corporate group with at least 50% of wholly-owned subsidiaries and 0 otherwise; and for
parent-subsidiary name sharing, we interact the PCV score with a dummy variable taking a value
of 1 for a corporate group with at least 50% of subsidiaries using the same or partially same name
as the corporate group and 0 otherwise.
As expected, the results show that the relationship between enterprise liability and asset par-
titioning is weaker (statistically significant at 5% level) when a higher share of subsidiaries are
managed by family managers (column 1), when there is a high level board interlocks between the
subsidiaries and headquarters (column 2), when a high share of subsidiaries are wholly owned (col-
umn 3), and when a high share of subsidiaries share a name with headquarters (column 4). Taken
together, the results suggest that headquarters’ control over subsidiaries plays an important role
in moderating the relationship between enterprise liability and asset partitioning.
[Insert Table 6 here]
6.4. Corporate Group Investment and Growth
Finally, we explore the implications of asset partitioning for investment and revenue growth. Hy-
pothesis 3 states that weaker enterprise liability encourages corporate groups to invest more and
grow faster. We explore the main channel that is likely to give rise to this effect: the one stem-
ming from the creation of new subsidiaries (asset partitioning) and risk compartmentalization. The
main analysis is performed at the corporate group-country-industry level. We also examine the
relationship at the corporate group-country level. Table 7 presents the estimation results.
Column 1 presents the results for the relationship between asset partitioning and investment.
Consistent with Hypothesis 3, doubling of the number of subsidiaries is associated with a 25
percentage point increase (statistically significant at the 5% level) in investment. Columns 2-
3 explore how this relationship varies across dynamic and competitive industries, respectively.
A dynamic industry is defined as high-technology industries from Hall and Vopel (1997) and
30
Saxenian (1994) and a highly competitive industry is defined as an industry in the top half of the
industry profit margin distribution across all industries.50 Corporate groups operating in dynamic
and competitive industries tend to increase their investments by around 17% and 9% more than
those in non-dynamic and less competitive industries, respectively.51
Column 4 presents 2SLS results at the corporate group-country level, with number of subsidiaries
instrumented by the interaction of PCV and industry downside risk. While PCV score or industry
downside risk can independently influence corporate group growth, our identifying assumption
is that their interaction should influence outcomes only through subsidiaries. The 2SLS estimate
implies that doubling of the number of subsidiaries is associated with about 32 percentage point
increase (statistically significant at the 5% level) in investment (compared to 25 percentage point
increase based on the OLS estimate from Column 1).52
Columns 5 through 8 present the equivalent analysis for revenue growth. Column 5 shows that
asset partitioning is positively related to growth – doubling of the number of subsidiaries holding
size fixed is associated with a 31 percentage point increase in growth. Columns 6 and 7 show that
this relationship is stronger in dynamic and competitive industries. Column 8 presents that 2SLS
results. Based on the IV estimate, doubling of the number of subsidiaries holding size constant
leads to a 52 percentage point increase in growth.53
[Insert Table 7 here]
6.5. Robustness Tests
To mitigate concerns about the validity of the PCV scores and the methodological approaches used
in this study, we carried out several robustness tests. The results are available in Supplementary
Appendix D (Tables D2, D3 and D4). Here we provide a brief discussion of the tests we carried
out.
50 Dynamic industries are defined based on SIC codes 357 (computers), 36 (electrical equipment), 37 (transportation
equipment), 38 (instruments), 481 (telephone communication services), and 737 (software and data processing).
51 The relative increase in investment for firms in dynamic industries is: 0.173 = 0.043/0.249, where 0.043 is the
differential increase in investment for firms in dynamic industries and 0.249 is the increase in investment for firms in
non-dynamic industries. The relative increase in investment for firms in competitive industries is: 0.089 = 0.022/0.247,
where 0.022 is the differential increase in investment for firms in competitive industries and 0.247 is the increase in
investment for firms in less competitive industries.
52 The first stage results (reported in Supplementary Appendix Table D1) show a statistically significant, positive
relationship between the number of subsidiaries and the instrument (i.e., interaction between subsidiary country’s
PCV score and industry downside risk) with the Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistic of 255 and Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald
F-statistic 138.
53 The first stage results (reported in Supplementary Appendix Table D1) show a statistically significant, positive
relationship between the number of subsidiaries and the instrument (i.e., interaction between subsidiary country’s
PCV score and industry downside risk) with the Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistic of 904 and Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald
F-statistic 479.
31
To construct the PCV scores, we combined evaluations of five distinct criteria, weighted by the
importance of each criterion. A key concern relates to the robustness of our findings to alternative
weights of the criteria. To address this concern, we took several steps. First, we recalculated the
PVC scores by omitting any of the five criteria used to derive them (Table D2, columns 1-5). For
instance, in column 1 we excluded the criterion “enterprise approach” when calculating the PCV
scores. Second, we recalculated the PCV scores after assigning equal weights to all the five criteria
(Table D2, column 6). Third, we used principal component analysis to test the robustness of our
results (Table D3). The overall pattern of results is robust: corporate groups are more likely to
incorporate their units when enterprise liability is weak.
Table D4 presents additional robustness tests for sample selection, econometric specification, and
measurement. One concern is that our analysis focuses on subsidiaries that are majority owned
by their corporate parents. This is reasonable because affiliates in corporate groups are generally
assumed to be controlled (and not just minority owned) by their parents. However, limited liability
regulations may have different effects for units that are majority versus minority owned. To address
this concern, we reexamined the asset partitioning-enterprise liability relationship after including
all the subsidiaries of each corporate group in our sample (including those where the corporate
parent has less than a 50% ownership share). The results are consistent with our main findings:
moving from Great Britain (with lowest PCV score) to Germany (with highest PCV score) is
associated with 5% drop in the number of subsidiaries (Table D4, column 1).
Another concern is that corporate group size may not be adequately captured by ln(Revenues).
To mitigate this concern, we replaced ln(Revenues) with Revenues and Revenues2in Table D4,
column 2, and with decile dummies for revenues in Table D4, column 3. Our qualitative results
remain unchanged.
Finally, we show that our main results are robust to estimating our main specifications using
Poisson and Negative Binomial, where the dependent variable is number of subsidiaries (Table D4,
columns 4-5).
7. Discussion and Concluding Remarks
The asset partitioning view provides a novel perspective on corporate groups. Existing theories
of the nature and functions of corporate groups largely focus on one aspect of group affiliation -
the control exerted by ultimate shareholders over the affiliates of a group. The control-magnifying
view, for instance, argues that tall pyramids are created by powerful owners to increase their voting
power over distant subsidiaries. The institutional voids perspective holds that common ownership
of a group of firms can facilitate efficient resource sharing. While these theories differ significantly
in their assessments of corporate groups - the first describing groups as “parasites”, the second
32
describing them as “paragons” (Khanna and Yafeh, 2007) - both highlight common control as the
fundamental feature of corporate groups.
In contrast to these perspectives, the asset partitioning view starts from the observation that
the subsidiaries of a group, unlike the unincorporated divisions of a conglomerate, are legally
independent entities. Thus, rather than the element of common control, the asset partitioning view
puts the emphasis on the legal independence or “separateness” of the group’s affiliates.
From this simple observation, many important implications follow. Most obviously, legal inde-
pendence implies that group subsidiaries enjoy, at least in principle, the benefits of limited liability
and entity shielding. Hansmann and Kraakman (2000a,b) were the first to introduce the view of
asset partitioning; they also highlighted different ways in which limited liability and entity shielding
can benefit the affiliates of a group (see also Hansmann and Squire (2016)).
Strategy scholars have largely ignored the issue of the legal independence of group affiliates.
Bethel and Liebeskind (1998) is a notable exception. They note that, in choosing whether to incor-
porate a business unit, firms face a trade-off between the benefits of limited liability and the costs
of stunted resource redeployment. Manikandan and Ramachandran (2015) argue that the group’s
multi-entity organizational form enables group affiliates to better sense and seize growth oppor-
tunities. They highlight the greater autonomy of the group affiliates (relative to unincorporated
divisions) as an important source of these superior capabilities. Masten (1988) provides an analysis
of the firm from a legal standpoint. This work, however, largely focuses on the distinction between
the employment relationship within the firm and market contracting (see also Williamson (1975)).
A key contribution of this paper is to provide a more comprehensive framework of the costs and
benefits of asset partitioning. Specifically, we highlight risk compartmentalization, greater internal
transparency, greater autonomy at the subsidiary level, and learning about individual assets as key
benefits of more finely subdividing assets under common control into separate, legally independent
entities. Drawbacks of finer asset partitioning include stunted resource redeployment and lower
headquarters monitoring.
We argue that ultimate owners must balance these costs and benefits to maximize the total value
of the assets under their purview. This way, an appropriate legal organization for the group can
be selected. Here we emphasize two issues.
First, the appropriate legal organization depends on the strategy that the group is trying to
implement (i.e., “structure follows strategy” (Chandler, 1962)). For instance, an important goals
for the group may be to integrate technologies more tightly across a variety of products and
companies. In this case, coarser asset partitioning may be desirable, as the merger between Alphabet
subsidiaries Nest and Google illustrates. On the other hand, new technologies may expose the
33
group to significant financial liabilities or reputational risks. In this case, finer asset partitioning
may be required, as exemplified by the Waymo spin-off.
Second, an appropriate legal organization depends on the characteristics of the environment
where units of the group operate. That is, the “right” way to organize a group (or a company)
is contingent on external institutional factors (Lawrence and Lorsch, 1967; Ghoshal and Nohria,
1989; Nohria and Ghoshal, 1997). We highlight the strictness of national limited liability laws as
a key institutional factor. By achieving a good fit between legal organization and external legal
institutions, managers can mitigate risks, bolster innovation, and create value for shareholders.
We demonstrate the usefulness of our framework by empirically examining how the strictness of
national limited liability laws affects firm boundaries, internal organization and corporate group
growth. Our evidence provides strong support for the asset partitioning perspective, even when its
predictions differ significantly from those of existing theories. For instance, we show that in Great
Britain groups partition their assets quite finely, compared to groups in several other countries
(e.g., Germany, China or Argentina). This is inconsistent with the control-magnifying and the
institutional voids perspectives, which suggest that in countries where market institutions work
well and protections for minority shareholders are strong, corporate groups should wither away.
Moreover, by showing that both firm boundaries (i.e., asset partitioning) and internal orga-
nization (i.e., managerial autonomy at the subsidiary level) vary systematically with features of
national legal institutions, our research provides further validation for the contingency view of
organizational structure.
The asset partitioning view also advances our understanding of why so many large enterprises
are organized as wholly- or almost wholly-owned corporate groups. The control-magnifying view
cannot explain the widespread diffusion of wholly-owned groups because it assumes that group
structures are created to separate ownership and control. In wholly-owned groups, however, such
separation by definition does not exist.
The institutional voids perspective provides a rationale for the existence of corporate groups by
emphasizing the benefits of intra-group resource sharing (e.g., Leff (1978); Capron et al. (1998);
Belenzon and Berkovitz (2010); Lieberman et al. (2017)). However, as noted also by Manikandan
and Ramachandran (2015), the same benefits could be achieved by organizing a wholly-owned
group as a single multidivisional firm (e.g., the Alphabet group versus Google before October 2015).
Clearly, to explain why sometimes assets are partitioned among subsidiaries, while sometimes a
single multidivisional corporate form is selected, more theorizing is needed. The asset partitioning
view provides such theorizing.
The asset partitioning view suggests that wholly-owned groups can be quite efficient organiza-
tional forms. Their multi-entity structure protects headquarters and their ultimate owners from
34
liability risks. The risks of stunted resource redeployment are also to a significant extent mitigated
because the frictions to resource sharing created by conflicts of interests among shareholders are
largely absent (Bethel and Liebeskind, 1998). In partly-owned groups, in fact, shareholders in one
affiliate may oppose resource redeployment to another affiliate if they are not significant sharehold-
ers in the other affiliate. In wholly-owned groups, however, this situation cannot arise, because all
affiliates are wholly-owned by headquarters and its shareholders.
To conclude, the asset partitioning view provides a novel perspective on corporate groups rooted
in organizational law (Hansmann and Kraakman, 2000a,b) and strategy research (Bethel and Liebe-
skind, 1998; Manikandan and Ramachandran, 2015; Belenzon et al., 2019). Instead of emphasizing
the element of common control, this perspective emphasizes the legal independence or separateness
of group affiliates. We argue that asset partitioning is a largely underappreciated instrument to
foster decentralization in organizations, which brings with it specific costs and benefits. By choos-
ing a legal organization wisely, owners and managers can create value and foster innovation and
growth. We hope that our contribution will spur further research in strategy on legal organization.
35
References
Aghion P, Tirole J (1997) Formal and real authority in organizations. Journal of Political Economy 105(1):1–
29.
Alchian AA, Demsetz H (1972) Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Eco-
nomic Review 62(5):777–795.
Ayotte K (2017) Subsidiary legal entities and innovation. Review of Corporate Finance Studies 6(1):39–67.
Ayotte K, Hansmann H (2013) Legal entities as transferable bundles of contracts. Michigan Law Review
111(5):715–758.
Baek JS, Kang JK, Lee I (2006) Business groups and tunneling: Evidence from private securities offerings
by korean chaebols. Journal of Finance 61(5):2415–2449.
Bainbridge SM, Henderson MT (2016) Limited liability: a legal and economic analysis (Cheltenham, United
Kingdom: Edward Elgar Publishing).
Bebchuk LA, Kraakman R, Triantis G (2000) Stock pyramids, cross-ownership, and dual class equity: the
mechanisms and agency costs of separating control from cash-flow rights. Concentrated Corporate Own-
ership, 295–318 (University of Chicago Press).
Belenzon S, Berkovitz T (2010) Innovation in business groups. Management Science 56(3):519–535.
Belenzon S, Berkovitz T, Rios LA (2013) Capital markets and firm organization: How financial development
shapes european corporate groups. Management Science 59(6):1326–1343.
Belenzon S, Chatterji AK, Daley B (2017) Eponymous entrepreneurs. American Economic Review
107(6):1638–55.
Belenzon S, Hashai N, Patacconi A (2019) The architecture of attention: Group structure and subsidiary
autonomy. Strategic Management Journal 40(10):1610–1643.
Bertrand M, Mehta P, Mullainathan S (2002) Ferreting out tunneling: An application to indian business
groups. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(1):121–148.
Bethel JE, Liebeskind JP (1998) Diversification and the legal organization of the firm. Organization Science
9(1):49–67.
Bloom N, Van Reenen J (2007) Measuring and explaining management practices across firms and countries.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 122(4):1351–1408.
Blumberg PI (1985) Limited liability and corporate groups. Journal of Corporate Law 11:573.
Bond P, Edmans A, Goldstein I (2012) The real effects of financial markets. Annual Review of Financial
Economics 4(1):339–360.
Capron L, Dussauge P, Mitchell W (1998) Resource redeployment following horizontal acquisitions in europe
and north america, 1988–1992. Strategic Management Journal 19(7):631–661.
36
Chandler AD (1962) Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of the American Industrial Enterprise
(Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).
Chang SJ, Hong J (2000) Economic performance of group-affiliated companies in korea: Intragroup resource
sharing and internal business transactions. Academy of Management Journal 43(3):429–448.
Dearborn M (2009) Enterprise liability: Reviewing and revitalizing liability for corporate groups. California
Law Review 97:195.
Erdem T (1998) An empirical analysis of umbrella branding. Journal of Marketing Research 35(3):339–351.
Fama EF, Miller MH (1972) The theory of finance (New York, NY: Holt Rinehart & Winston).
Ghoshal S, Nohria N (1989) Internal differentiation within multinational corporations. Strategic Management
Journal 10(4):323–337.
Gilson RJ (2001) Globalizing corporate governance: Convergence of form or function. American Journal of
Comparative Law 49(2):329–358.
Hall BH, Vopel K (1997) Innovation, market share, and market value. NBER Working paper .
Hansmann H, Kraakman R (2000a) The end of history for corporate law. Georgetown Law Journal 89:439.
Hansmann H, Kraakman R (2000b) Organizational law as asset partitioning. European Economic Review
44(4-6):807–817.
Hansmann H, Kraakman R, Squire R (2005) Law and the rise of the firm. Harvard Law Review 119:1335.
Hansmann H, Squire R (2016) External and internal asset partitioning. The Oxford Handbook of Corporate
Law and Governance.
Huson MR, MacKinnon G (2003) Corporate spinoffs and information asymmetry between investors. Journal
of Corporate Finance 9(4):481–503.
Jensen MC, Meckling WH (1976) Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership
structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3(4):305–360.
Kandel E, Kosenko K, Morck R, Yafeh Y (2019) The great pyramids of america: A revised history of
us business groups, corporate ownership, and regulation, 1926–1950. Strategic Management Journal
40(5):781–808.
Keister LA (1998) Engineering growth: Business group structure and firm performance in china’s transition
economy. American Journal of Sociology 104(2):404–440.
Khanna T, Palepu K (1999) Policy shocks, market intermediaries, and corporate strategy: The evolution of
business groups in chile and india. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 8(2):271–310.
Khanna T, Yafeh Y (2007) Business groups in emerging markets: Paragons or parasites? Journal of Economic
Literature 45(2):331–372.
Kogan L, Papanikolaou D, Seru A, Stoffman N (2017) Technological innovation, resource allocation, and
growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 132(2):665–712.
37
La Porta R, Lopez-de Silanes F, Shleifer A (1999) Corporate ownership around the world. Journal of Finance
54(2):471–517.
Lan LL, Heracleous L (2010) Rethinking agency theory: The view from law. Academy of Management Review
35(2):294–314.
Lawrence PR, Lorsch JW (1967) Differentiation and integration in complex organizations. Administrative
Science Quarterly 1–47.
Leff NH (1978) Industrial organization and entrepreneurship in the developing countries: The economic
groups. Economic Development and Cultural Change 26(4):661–675.
Lieberman MB, Lee GK, Folta TB (2017) Entry, exit, and the potential for resource redeployment. Strategic
Management Journal 38(3):526–544.
Loken B, John DR (1993) Diluting brand beliefs: when do brand extensions have a negative impact? Journal
of Marketing 57(3):71–84.
Mahmood IP, Mitchell W (2004) Two faces: Effects of business groups on innovation in emerging economies.
Management Science 50(10):1348–1365.
Manikandan K, Ramachandran J (2015) Beyond institutional voids: Business groups, incomplete markets,
and organizational form. Strategic Management Journal 36(4):598–617.
Masten SE (1988) A legal basis for the firm. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 4(1):181–198.
Morck R, Wolfenzon D, Yeung B (2005) Corporate governance, economic entrenchment, and growth. Journal
of Economic Literature 43(3):655–720.
Muchlinski P (2010) Limited liability and multinational enterprises: a case for reform? Cambridge Journal
of Economics 34(5):915–928.
Nohria N, Ghoshal S (1997) The differentiated network: Organizing multinational corporations for value
creation (San Francisco, California: Jossey-Bass Publishers).
Ramsay I, Noakes DB (2001) Piercing the corporate veil in australia. SSRN 299488 .
Roe MJ (1986) Corporate strategic reaction to mass tort. Virginia Law Review 72:1–59.
Saxenian A (1994) Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128 (Cam-
bridge, MA: Harvard University Press).
Schlissel D, Peterson P, Biewald B, Economics SE (2002) Financial Insecurity: The Increasing Use of Limited
Liability Companies and Multi-Tiered Holding Companies to Own Nuclear Power Plants (Cambridge,
MA: Synapse Energy Economics).
Shin HH, Park YS (1999) Financing constraints and internal capital markets: Evidence from koreanchaebols’.
Journal of Corporate Finance 5(2):169–191.
Stein JC (1997) Internal capital markets and the competition for corporate resources. Journal of Finance
52(1):111–133.
38
Stopford JM, Wells Jr LT (1972) Managing the multinational enterprise: Organization of the firm and
ownership of the subsidiary (London, United Kingdom: Longman).
Strasser KA (2004) Piercing the veil in corporate groups. Connecticut Law Review 37:637.
Tra jtenberg M, Henderson R, Jaffe A (1997) University versus corporate patents: A window on the basicness
of invention. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 5(1):19–50.
Williamson OE (1975) Markets and hierarchies: analysis and antitrust implications: a study in the economics
of internal organization (New York, NY: Free Press).
39
Figure 1: Number of Subsidiaries and PCV Score
Notes: The figure presents the extent to which asset partitioning (number of subsidiaries per 1M USD in revenues)
varies with enterprise liability (PCV score). A high PCV score indicates a higher likelihood that a corporate parent
will be liable for the mistakes of its subsidiaries.
40
Figure 2: Subsidiary Autonomy Measures and PCV Score
Notes: The figures present how subsidiary autonomy (measures from the WMS) varies with enterprise liability
(PCV score). Capital investment autonomy is the maximum amount of capital that subsidiaries can decide to invest
without prior authorization from the corporate headquarter. Max capital investment is normalized as log(max
capital investment/number of employees). Product introduction autonomy is the extent to which production
introduction decisions are made at subsidiaries. Sales marketing autonomy is the amount of sales marketing
conducted by subsidiaries, compared to CHQ. Hiring autonomy measures the degree of autonomy that subsidiaries
have in hiring new full-time employees. Hierarchical levels to CEO is the number of hierarchical layers between the
shop floor workers at a subsidiary to the CEO. HQ manager on site is the presence of an HQ manager in the
subsidiary being interviewed.
41
Table 1 PCV Scores
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Application of Number and Veil piercing Veil piercing in Empirical Final Score
enterprise / diversity of outside of the absence of Data
economic factors bankruptcy fraud or
unity approach considered cases misconduct
Score Range (0 to 5) (0 to 5) (0 to 5) (0 to 5) (-5 to 5)
Score Weight 0.45 0.25 0.1 0.15 0.05
Argentina 3.5 2.5 2 2 0 2.70
Australia 2.5 3.5 5 2 -1.5 2.73
Belgium 2 3.5 1 4 0 2.48
Canada 2 3 5 2 0 2.45
China 1 4 5 3 2 2.50
Denmark 2.5 1 1 1 0 1.63
France 4 3 1 3 0 3.10
Germany 5 3 2.5 4.5 0 3.93
Great Britain 1 1 5 1 -1 1.30
Italy 4 3.5 3.5 4 0 3.63
Japan 1 3 5 1 0 1.85
Netherlands 3 3.5 2.5 3 0 2.93
South Korea 1.5 3 5 3 0 2.38
Sweden 1 1 4 2.5 0 1.48
Switzerland 2.5 2 5 2.5 0 2.50
United States 2 4 4 2.5 -1 2.63
Notes: The table presents “piercing the corporate veil” (PCV) scores. The scores presented in this
table are based on the evaluation of the likelihood of intra-group veil piercing in each of countries
listed. The higher the final score, the more likely that courts will pierce the corporate veil to
hold the corporate group liable for the debts of the subsidiaries. The final scores are based on
five criteria, for which separate scores are assigned and aggregated. Application of enterprise /
economic unity approach measures the extent to which courts will consider a corporate group as a
single enterprise. The number and diversity of factors considered for relief from general veil piercing
claims indicate the variety of factors that courts are willing to consider to hold the corporate group
liable. Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases and availability of veil piercing in
the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct assess whether courts limit themselves to some
specific types of cases with respect to pierce the corporate veil. The empirical part of the score
assess the likelihood of courts to pierce the corporate veil based on the available empirical data.
42
Table 2 Summary Statistics of Main Variables
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Distribution
VARIABLES No. Obs Mean Std. Dev. 10th 50th 90th
Parent-sub country-industry-year level
Number of subsidiaries 3,122,026 1.45 3.84 1.00 1.00 2.00
Revenues (in mil) 3,122,026 77.9 1,267 0.10 2.51 59.3
Assets (in mil) 2,615,435 301 12,933 0.17 2.30 61.3
Board member interlock 580,237 0.54 0.50 0.00 1.00 1.00
Parent-sub name sharing 2,243,470 0.28 0.38 0.00 0.00 1.00
Share of family managers 449,288 0.14 0.33 0.00 0.00 1.00
Share of wholly-owned subs 2,702,307 0.45 0.49 0.00 0.00 1.00
Group-year level
Managerial experience 662,627 50.8 8.5 40.3 50.6 61.2
Industry-year level
Industry downside risk 2,891 0.03 0.08 0.00 0.00 0.10
Knowledge complexity 1,051 0.33 0.165 0.122 0.326 0.532
Country level
PCV score 16 2.51 0.71 1.48 2.50 3.63
Region (NUTS2) level
Corruption 119 0.78 0.09 0.66 0.79 0.89
Notes: The table presents summary statistics for the main variables used in the analysis.
The sample includes corporate groups at the country-industry (3-digit SIC) pair level
for each year from 2002 to 2014. See Supplementary Appendix C for variable definitions.
43
Table 3 Asset Partitioning and Enterprise Liability
Dependent variable: ln(Number of Subsidiaries)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
Baseline Group Group- Single- Multi- $100M Widely-held Grp-cntry- Ind. Down.
FE ind. FE ind. grps ind. grps assets grps -ind. level Risk
Country PCV score -0.011 -0.060 -0.114 -0.022 -0.062 -0.100 -0.061 -0.061 -0.049
(0.001) (0.003) (0.005) (0.007) (0.003) (0.010) (0.003) (0.004) (0.003)
Country PCV score x
Dummy for high industry downside risk -0.010 -0.009
(0.001) (0.001)
Dummy for high industry downside risk 0.027 0.027
(0.002) (0.002)
ln(Country GDP) 0.063 0.127 0.020 0.068 0.160 0.067 0.063
(0.002) (0.003) (0.004) (0.002) (0.008) (0.002) (0.002)
ln(Country unemployment rate) -0.001 0.012 -0.000 -0.011 0.021 0.008 0.009
(0.002) (0.002) (0.001) (0.003) (0.012) (0.002) (0.002)
Country EPL -0.053 -0.055 -0.082 -0.035 -0.048 -0.048 -0.080
(0.008) (0.014) (0.016) (0.008) (0.026) (0.008) (0.009)
Country stock market development -0.019 -0.027 -0.009 -0.015 0.071 -0.022 -0.007
(0.004) (0.007) (0.009) (0.004) (0.018) (0.004) (0.004)
ln(Group-sub country-industry revenues) 0.023 0.028 0.026 0.007 0.032 0.038 0.028 0.086 0.031 0.031
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000)
Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes
Three-digit SIC dummies Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Corporate group dummies No Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country dummies No No No No No No No No No Yes
Group-industry dummies No No Yes No No No No No No No
Observations 3,122,024 2,702,307 2,451,603 1,230,168 1,423,652 177,205 1,980,705 689,073 2,061,774 2,061,774
R-squared 0.11 0.46 0.76 0.85 0.39 0.56 0.46 0.51 0.49 0.49
Notes: The table presents the relationship between enterprise liability (PCV score) and asset partitioning (number of subsidiaries). The sample contains
corporate groups at the country-industry-year level for years 2002 through 2014 across sixteen countries. Country EPL is the strength of country’s
employment protection law. Country stock market development measures the ratio of total stock market capitalization to GDP. Dummy for high industry
downside risk is a dummy variable taking a value of 1 for corporate groups operating in industries in the top quartile of industry downside risk distribution
and 0 otherwise. All columns include legal origin dummies indicating the legal origin (English, French, German, or Scandinavian) from which each country’s
commercial laws are derived. Standard errors are robust to heteroskedasticity and clustered at the corporate group-subsidiary country-industry level.
44
Table 4 Subsidiary Autonomy and Enterprise Liability
Dependent Variable: Aggregate ln(Invest. Product Sales & Hiring Levels HQ on Site
Amount) Introduction Marketing to CEO
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
Country PCV score -0.142 -0.856 -0.086 -0.180 -0.269 -0.096 0.076
(0.039) (0.157) (0.052) (0.056) (0.047) (0.052) (0.015)
ln(Group revenues) -0.004 0.037 0.002 -0.003 -0.002 0.054 -0.006
(0.006) (0.021) (0.008) (0.008) (0.007) (0.006) (0.002)
ln(Country GDP) 0.056 0.138 -0.057 0.050 0.153 0.387 -0.127
(0.037) (0.129) (0.050) (0.053) (0.047) (0.045) (0.015)
ln(Country unemployment rate) -0.165 1.629 -0.144 -0.248 0.048 -0.515 -0.074
(0.196) (0.786) (0.263) (0.287) (0.246) (0.265) (0.081)
Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Three-digit SIC dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 1,752 1,601 1,588 1,616 1,746 1,573 1,788
R-squared 0.096 0.113 0.088 0.098 0.121 0.242 0.171
Notes: The table presents the relationship between enterprise liability and the level of autonomy granted to
subsidiaries at the subsidiary-year level. The sample includes subsidiaries from the World Management Survey
(WMS) matched to our sample firms. Aggregate autonomy is the average of scores from the following three
questions: “To hire a full-time permanent shop floor worker what agreement would your plant need from CHQ?”,
“How much of sales and marketing is carried out at the plant level (rather than at CHQ)?”, and “Where are
decisions taken on new product introductions - at the plant, at the CHQ or at both?” Investment autonomy
is the amount of capital investment that a subsidiary can make without prior authorization of the corporate
headquarters. Product introduction autonomy is the extent to which production introduction decisions are
made at subsidiaries. Sales marketing autonomy is the amount of sales marketing conducted by subsidiaries.
Hiring autonomy measures the degree of autonomy that subsidiaries have in hiring new fully-time employees.
Levels to CEO is the number of hierarchical layers between the shop floor workers at a subsidiary to the CEO.
HQ on site is a dummy variable taking a value of 1 if a manager from the corporate headquarters was present
at the subsidiary being interviewed. Standard errors are robust to arbitrary heteroskedasticity.
45
Table 5 Additional Moderating Factors: Costs of Asset Partitioning
Dependent variable:
ln(Number of Subsidiaries)
(1) (2) (3)
Corrupt- Manager Knowledge
ion experience complexity
Country PCV score -0.167 -0.058 -0.043
(0.050) (0.003) (0.007)
Country PCV score x
Dummy for high corruption 0.012
(0.005)
Dummy for inexperienced managers 0.004
(0.002)
Dummy for complex knowledge base 0.006
(0.001)
Dummy for high corruption -0.045
(0.014)
Dummy for inexperienced managers -0.019
(0.004)
Dummy for complex knowledge base -0.016
(0.004)
ln(Regional GDP) -0.013
(0.002)
ln(Country GDP) 0.127 0.072 0.066
(0.024) (0.002) (0.004)
ln(Country unemployment rate) -0.107 -0.011 0.080
(0.006) (0.004) (0.006)
Country EPL 0.254 -0.033 -0.126
(0.071) (0.009) (0.015)
Country stock market development -0.072 -0.012 0.061
(0.057) (0.004) (0.011)
ln(Group-sub country-industry revenues) 0.039 0.037 0.071
(0.001) (0.000) (0.001)
Year dummies Yes Yes Yes
Three-digit SIC dummies Yes Yes Yes
Corporate group fixed effects Yes Yes Yes
Observations 654,442 1,087,444 476,044
R-squared 0.53 0.41 0.56
Notes: The table examines how the relationship between enterprise liabil-
ity and asset partitioning is moderated by factors that are related to asset
partitioning costs. The sample consists of corporate groups at the country-
industry-year level for years 2002 through 2014 across sixteen countries.
Dummy for high corruption takes a value of 1 for groups operating in re-
gions (NUTS2) where at least 75% of survey respondents either completely
agreed or tended to agree that there is corruption in regional institution.
Dummy for inexperienced managers takes a value of 1 for groups with
managers in the bottom quartile of the sample manager age distribution.
Dummy for complex knowledge base takes a value of 1 for groups operating
in industries with knowledge complexity value in the top quartile (mea-
sured as the average generality of patents). All columns include legal origin
dummies indicating the legal origin (English, French, German, or Scandi-
navian) from which each country’s commercial laws are derived. Standard
errors are clustered at the group-country-industry level.
46
Table 6 Additional Moderating Factors: Headquarters Control
Dependent variable: ln(Number of Subsidiaries)
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Family Board Whole Parent-
manager member ownership sub name
Country PCV score -0.065 -0.069 -0.078 -0.069
(0.006) (0.005) (0.003) (0.003)
Country PCV score x
Dummy for high share of family managers 0.007
(0.002)
Dummy for high board member interlock 0.007
(0.002)
Dummy for high share of wholly-owned subsidiaries 0.041
(0.001)
Dummy for high share of subsidiaries using parent’s name 0.019
(0.001)
Dummy for high share of family managers -0.014
(0.005)
Dummy for high board member interlock -0.011
(0.006)
Dummy for high share of wholly-owned subsidiaries -0.107
(0.004)
Dummy for high share of subsidiaries using parent’s name -0.085
(0.004)
ln(Country GDP) 0.100 0.072 0.064 0.065
(0.005) (0.004) (0.002) (0.002)
ln(Country unemployment rate) 0.003 0.019 0.000 0.003
(0.006) (0.004) (0.002) (0.002)
Country EPL 0.080 -0.094 -0.050 -0.048
(0.020) (0.014) (0.008) (0.008)
Country stock market development 0.003 -0.018 -0.014 -0.018
(0.009) (0.007) (0.004) (0.004)
ln(Group-sub country-industry revenues) 0.055 0.041 0.028 0.030
(0.001) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000)
Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes
Three-digit SIC dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes
Corporate group dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 449,288 580,237 2,702,307 2,243,470
R-squared 0.54 0.50 0.46 0.45
Notes: The table presents how the relationship between enterprise liability and asset partitioning
is moderated by group factors related to a headquarters’ control over its subsidiaries. The sample
consists of corporate groups at the country-industry-year level for years 2002 through 2014 across
sixteen countries. Dummy for high share of family managers takes a value of 1 for groups with more
than 50% of subsidiaries managed by a family manager. Dummy for high board member interlock
takes a value of 1 for groups with more than 50% of subsidiaries with at least one board member who
serves also on the board of the corporate parent. Dummy for high share of wholly-owned subsidiaries
takes a value of 1 for groups with more than 50% of subsidiaries that are wholly owned. Dummy for
high share of subsidiaries using parent’s name takes a value of 1 for groups with more than 50% of
subsidiaries taking the same or partially same name as its corporate parent. All columns include legal
origin dummies indicating the legal origin (English, French, German, or Scandinavian) from which each
country’s commercial laws are derived. Standard errors are clustered at the group-country-industry
level.
47
Table 7 Corporate Group Investment and Growth
Dependent variable: Investment Growth (%) Revenue Growth (%)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Baseline Industry Industry 2SLS Baseline Industry Industry 2SLS
dynamism competition 2nd stage: dynamism competition 2nd stage:
Instrumenting Instrumenting
ln(Num. subs.) ln(Num. subs.)
ln(Number of subsidiaries) 0.252 0.249 0.247 0.316 0.314 0.311 0.307 0.516
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.147) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.075)
ln(Number of subsidiaries) x
Dummy for a dynamic industry 0.043 0.049
(0.010) (0.009)
Dummy for a highly competitive industry 0.022 0.023
(0.005) (0.005)
Dummy for a highly competitive industry -0.026 -0.032
(0.004) (0.004)
Country PCV score -0.065 -0.129
(0.027) (0.017)
Industry downside risk -2.924 -2.530
(0.089) (0.077)
ln(Country GDP) 0.006 0.006 0.006 -0.150 0.004 0.004 0.007 -0.037
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.033) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.020)
ln(Country unemployment rate) 0.009 0.008 0.013 0.033 -0.033 -0.033 -0.033 -0.105
(0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.010) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.008)
Country EPL -0.071 -0.067 -0.108 0.662 -0.175 -0.168 -0.211 0.873
(0.041) (0.041) (0.044) (0.086) (0.038) (0.038) (0.042) (0.094)
Country stock market development -0.018 -0.019 -0.028 -0.299 -0.008 -0.008 -0.013 -0.179
(0.007) (0.007) (0.008) (0.019) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.014)
ln(Group-sub country-industry revenues)t−1-0.028 -0.028 -0.028 -0.071 -0.098 -0.098 -0.096 -0.222
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.005) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.006)
Cragg-Donald F-stat - - - 255.2 - - - 903.5
Kleibergen-Paap F-stat - - - 137.9 - - - 478.9
Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Three-digit SIC dummies Yes Yes Yes - Yes Yes Yes -
Corporate group dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 1,101,722 1,101,722 1,070,451 534,154 1,200,409 1,200,409 1,121,556 606,091
R-squared 0.23 0.23 0.23 0.33 0.25 0.25 0.26 0.39
Notes: The table presents the relationship between asset partitioning and corporate group growth in investment and revenues. Annual growth in
investment is (assetst−assetst−1)/assetst−1, and Annual growth in revenues is (revenuest−revenuest−1)/revenuest−1. A dynamic industry is defined
using 2- and 3-digit SIC codes (i.e., 357, 36, 37, 38, 481, and 737, which previous studies have defined as high-technology industries). A highly competitive
industry is defined as those in the top half of the industry-wide profit margin distribution across all industries. The instrumental variable regressions are run
at the group-country-year level, and the number of subsidiaries is instrumented with subsidiary country PCV score interacted with the average industry
downside risk within each country. All columns include legal origin dummies indicating the legal origin (English, French, German, or Scandinavian)
from which each country’s commercial laws are derived. Standard errors are robust to heteroskedasticity and clustered at the corporate group-subsidiary
country-industry level for OLS regressions and at the corporate group level for 2SLS regressions.
Supplementary Appendix A Corporate Veil Piercing
To construct PCV scores, we collaborated with legal scholars at Duke University School of Law. Together, we began
reviewing notable legal references, particularly corporate law textbooks, the Westlaw database, and highly cited law
review articles. These references provided the necessary theoretical background and led us to the relevant laws and
US court decisions on limited liability and piercing the corporate veil cases. We then used Westlaw's Keycite and
LexisNexis's Shepard, an Internet-based citation tool, to verify that the identified legal precedents were not overturned
and were still considered to be “good law”. Lastly, we focused on legal writings dealing specifically with enterprise
liability.1 For comparative analysis, we began with prominent secondary references and supplemented references with
several comparative law review articles.2 In jurisdictions that follow the civil law traditions (e.g., Germany, Italy and
China), the analysis primarily examined the governing statutory law, which has the final authority on intra-group veil
piercing cases, whereas in jurisdictions that follow the common law tradition (e.g., Great Britain and Canada), the
analysis focused on recent case law.
1. PCV scores
Table E1 presents the overall scores and a rank order of countries according to our qualitative analysis on how readily
the courts within each country might pierce the corporate veil (PCV) in a lawsuit involving corporate group limited
liability. The overall score ranges from 0 to 5, with a higher value indicating a stronger tendency of courts to pierce
the corporate veil. According to our assessment, Germany has the highest PCV score (3.93) reflecting its unique
attitude of considering a subsidiary an integral part of the corporation that controls it. At the other extreme of the PCV
score is Great Britain (1.30), which places more emphasis on the legal boundary between a subsidiary and its corporate
parent.
Table A1. Overall “PCV” scores and a rank order of countries according their “PCV” scores
Rank
Country
Overall s
core
1
Germany
3.9
3
2
Italy
3.6
3
3
France
3.
10
4
Netherlands
2.9
3
5
Australia
2.7
3
6
Argentina
2.7
0
7
The U.S.
2.63
8
China
2.5
0
-
Switzerland
2.5
0
10
Belgium
2.4
8
11
Canada
2.45
12
South Korea
2.
3
8
13
Japan
1.85
14
Denmark
1.63
15
Sweden
1.48
1
6
Great Britain
1.30
Table E2 presents individual scores for five criteria examined to derive the overall PCV scores. Each criterion is given
a weight according to its importance in determining how readily courts might pierce the corporate veil in a corporate
1 E.g., the conceptual analysis by Philip L. Blumberg, Stephen B. Presser, and Kurt A. Strasser and the empirical
analysis by Robert B. Thompson and Peter B. Oh (Blumberg, 1985; Oh, 2010; Oh, 2013; Strasser, 2004; Thompson,
1990)
2 E.g., Navarro Lezcano and Maria José's “Piercing the corporate veil in Latin American jurisprudence: a
comparison with the Anglo-American method” (Lezcano, 2015)
liability lawsuit. The first criterion we assessed is the extent to which a legal system of a country applies the “enterprise
approach” (also known as the “economic unity approach”). This criterion was assigned the highest weight as its
application is based on the premise that a corporate parent and its subsidiaries constitute a single entity and thus
directly contradicts limited liability provisions.
Second, we account for the various legal provisions that courts might consider in holding the corporate parent and
individual owners liable for the losses of the firms they own. The number of avenues available to the plaintiff for a
relief indicates how inclined the courts are to hold the corporate parent and owners liable for the mistakes of the firms
they own.
We also assessed the extent to which corporate veil piercing is closely tied to bankruptcy or fraudulent cases.
Bankruptcy and fraudulent behaviors often are procedural evidential barriers to holding owners liable for losses of
the firms they own and bear special importance to the assessment of the strength of limited liability provisions. For
this reason, we single them out from the second criterion.
Finally, we looked at the fraction of corporate liability cases in which the corporate veil was pierced in existing
empirical studies. Because this evidence is limited to few countries and results are difficult to compare, it is assigned
the least weight.
Table A2. Individual scores for five criteria examined to derive the overall PCV scores
Criterion
Country
Application
of
enterprise
approach
Factors
considered
in veil
piercing
cases
Veil
piercing
outside of
bankruptcy
cases
Veil
piercing
outside of
fraudulent
behaviors
Empirical
data
Final Score
Possible
Score 0-5 0-5 0-5 0-5 (-5)-5
Weight 0.45 0.25 0.1 0.15 0.05
Argentina 3.5 2.5 2 2 0 2.70
Australia 2.5 3.5 5 2 -1.5 2.73
Belgium 2 3.5 1 4 0 2.48
Canada 2 3 5 2 0 2.45
China 1 4 5 3 2 2.50
Denmark 2.5 1 1 1 0 1.63
France 4 3 1 3 0 3.10
Germany 5 3 2.5 4.5 0 3.93
Great
Britain 1 1 5 1 -1 1.30
Italy 4 3.5 3.5 4 0 3.63
Japan 1 3 5 1 0 1.85
Netherlands
3 3.5 2.5 3 0 2.93
South
Korea
1.5 3 5 3 0 2.38
Sweden 1 1 4 2.5 0 1.48
Switzerland 2.5 2 5 2.5 0 2.50
United
States 2 4 4 2.5 -1 2.63
2. PCV by country
The following sections provide detailed analyses of countries based on the five criteria used to derive our
PCV scores. The sections are organized by country and by criterion for each of the countries.
a. Argentina
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
Argentinian law regulates corporate groups based on the economic unity approach (the unidad juridica theory). It
provides that under certain circumstances the law will look at the parent and its subsidiary as one economic enterprise.3
Argentinian jurisprudence recognizes three situations that warrant intra-group veil piercing under the economic unity
theory: when the enterprise engages in fraudulent behavior, when the subsidiary is merely an agent or instrumentality
of its parent, and when a member of the corporate group engages in commercial conduct that harms the entire
enterprise and worsens its state of bankruptcy. In such cases, creditors may seek relief by bringing claims against the
corporate parent as an extension of bankruptcy.4
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
Argentinian law views the corporate veil piercing doctrine as a remedy for the violation of Art. 2 of the Corporations
Act, which provides that a corporation is a “technical means” through which individuals may attain their lawful goals.
Argentinian courts pierce the veil when incorporation was conducted to achieve unlawful goals and to abuse the right
of incorporation.
Art. 54 of the Business Corporations Act 1972 provides that “the liabilities of a corporation used to seek a purpose
beyond the corporate goals, as a mere instrument to defraud the law, the public policy or the good faith, or to frustrate
rights of third persons, will be imputed directly to its shareholders or to the controlling persons who facilitated such
activities”.5 Argentinian courts have invoked this statutory tool most often when the corporation was involved in an
illegal act that constitutes fraud, abuse of rights, and acts against morality and decency.6
Fraud is a central concept in veil piercing cases. The law provides three situations in which incorporation or a
particular business conduct may facilitate fraud and thus justify veil piercing. First is the concept Dolus (Deceit). In
the context of incorporation, Dolus is invoked when the owners use the company’s form as a shelter to evade
contractual obligations or to prejudice third parties, for example when the company is incorporated to perform legal
actions which the owner is not allowed to pursue.7 Second, a company with a single owner is considered under
Argentinian law fictitious and will not warrant limited liability.8 Third type of conduct is Actio Pauliana (Fraudulent
Conveyance), i.e. a fraudulent transfer to third parties in order to avoid debt. An Actio Pauliana claim is useful when
the owners of a company in financial difficulties have provided capital in the form of secured loans in order to gain
better standing as a creditor in case of bankruptcy.9
3 Claudia M. Pardinas, The Enigma of the Legal Liability of Transnational Corporations, 14 Suffolk Transnt'l L. J. 405 (1991);
Stephen B. Presser, Piercing the Corporate Veil (Thomson Reuters 2017).
4 Presser, 2017, at §5:2; Juan M. Dobson, Lifting the Veil in Four Countries: The Law of Argentina, England, France and the
United States, 35 INT. COMP. L. QUARTERLY 839, 859 (1986); Pardinas, 1991, at 427-32. The Unidad Juridica theory was first
introduced in the Parke Davis case (1973). In Parke Davis the Argentinian Supreme Court invalidated royalty payments made by
an Argentinian subsidiary to its Detroit based parent upon finding that the subsidiary lacked independence to take the decision.
In another decision handed down in 1973, Frigorifico Swift de la Plata , the court found a parent and sister companies liable for
the debts of the subsidiary under the same rationale. Frigorifico Swift de la Plata, involved Deltec International Ltd., a Canadian
corporation, and Swift, the largest Argentinian meatpacking company, which Deltec had acquired. When Swift faced financial
difficulties Deltec negotiated with its creditors and provided cash advances, hoping to prevent Swift from going bankrupt. When
the efforts failed and Swift filed for bankruptcy, Deltec and some of its other subsidiaries brought debt claims. The court denied
their claims and extended bankruptcy proceedings on Deltec and the subsidiaries, finding that the entire group formed a single
economic unit. The case went up the appellate chain and ultimately affirmed at the Supreme Court.
5 Jose Maria Lezcano Navaro, Piercing the Corporate Veil in Latin American Jurisprudence: A comparison with the Anglo-
American method, 116 (2015).
6 Navaro, 2015, at 119-20.
7 Dobson, 1986, at 844
8 Dobson, 1986,, at 841-43.
9 Dobson, 1986, at 845; Pardinas, 1991, at 426-27.
When veil piercing is sought in bankruptcy proceedings, Argentinian bankruptcy law allows courts to extend
bankruptcy of the company to its owner when the owner demonstrated abusive control of the company. An example
of an abusive conduct is owners promoting their personal interests with the company assets at the expense of the
company’s own interests.10
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
Argentinian courts invoke veil piercing most often in bankruptcy cases. Nonetheless, fraud cases may be brought
outside of bankruptcy cases.
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
As described above, fraudulent behavior is a central factor in intra-group veil piercing claims according to current
case law.11
b. Australia
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
Australian courts have recognized a general principle under which the courts may hold the parent company liable for
the acts of its subsidiary when individual entities within a corporate group is indistinguishable.12 Bluecorp Pty Ltd (in
liq) v ANZ Executors and Trustee Co. Ltd. (1995) 18 ACSR 566 provides important factors considered by the courts
in corporate veil piercing cases. Among them are relationship between corporate entities, corporate parent’s control
over its subsidiaries, participation in a common enterprise, use of the corporate form for fraud, and a deliberate attempt
to shield the corporate parent from an existing legal obligation.
The mere exercise of control over a subsidiary by the corporate parent is insufficient to pierce the corporate veil.
Furthermore, when a creditor and a subsidiary consensually enter into a contractual relationship, courts tend to respect
their mutual agreement.13
Sec. 588V of the Australian Corporations Act provides a cause of action for imposition of liability on a corporate
parent for debts of an insolvent subsidiary when the subsidiary trades while it is insolvent and certain other conditions
are satisfied.
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
Corporate debts can potentially be imposed on shareholders under the common law and also under 588V of the
Corporations Act 2001. Notwithstanding the lack of a coherent and principled veil piercing analysis under Australian
law, courts have recognized a number of discrete factors that may lead to piercing of the corporate veil.14 These factors
can be grouped into the following broad categories: (1) agency (where the shareholder has such a degree of dominance
that the company acts as an agent of the shareholder in the sense that the company has no separate existence from the
shareholder); (2) Fraud (where the company is established by the shareholder for a fraudulent purpose); (3) Avoiding
an existing legal obligation (where the company is established to enable the shareholder to avoid an existing legal
obligation); and (4) unfairness/justice grounds (when veil piercing is necessary to achieve a just result).15
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
10 The Insolvency Act of 1972 (revised in the Insolvency Reform Act of 1983). See also, Dobson, 1986, at 852-57.
11 Dobson, 1986, at 840.
12 Ian Ramsay & David Noakes Piercing the Corporate Veil in Australia (2002) (Available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=299488
13 In Briggs v James Hardie & Co Pty Ltd (1989) 16 NSWLR 549, a former employee of a subsidiary who was allegedly poisoned
with asbestos brought legal action against the parent claiming that the parent had exercised complete dominion and control over
its direct employer. The court (Rogers AJA) dismissed this argument as “entirely too simplistic,” noting that “every holding
company has the potential and, more often than not, in fact, does, exercise complete control over a subsidiary”. Under this
rationale, using control as the benchmark for veil piercing would be equivalent to removing the veil altogether. See further in
Helen Anderson, Piercing the veil on corporate groups in Australia: the case for reform, 33 MELBOURNE U. L. REV., 333, 353
(2009).
14 Briggs v James Hardie & Co Pty, (1989) 16 NSWLR 549 (Rogers J.) (“there is no common, unifying principle, which underlies
the occasional decision of the courts to pierce the corporate veil”); Commissioner of Land Tax v Theosophical Foundation Pty
Ltd. (1966) 67 SR (NSW) 70 Herron J. (“[t]he cases merely provide instances in which courts have on the facts refused to be
bound by the form or fact of incorporation when justice requires the substance or reality to be investigated)”
15 Ramsay & Noakes, 2002.
Bankruptcy is not a prerequisite to commence veil piercing proceedings.
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
Although not considered to be a prerequisite, misconduct and fraudulent behavior are central factors in veil piercing
claims. For example, in order to prevail in a veil-piercing claim, the plaintiff may need to show that the defendant
sought to use the corporate structure to deny the plaintiff some pre-existing legal right.16
5) Empirical data17
General piercing rate is around 39% of total claims (104 cases examined). Piercing rates differ according to the
identity of the controller of the company whose veil is sought to be pierced. When human shareholders stand behind
the company, courts pierce the corporate veil in about 42.5% of cases. When a parent company is behind the
corporate veil, courts are less inclined to pierce (about 32.5%). Group enterprise arguments prevail in only 24% of
the cases.
c. Belgium
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
Belgian law follows the entity theory.18 A Belgian court may impose liability on the corporate directors for
continuation of loss making activities.19 In the event of a bankruptcy, any person who exercised “effective
management powers” with respect to the company may incur personal liability if it is established that a clear and
gross negligence has contributed to the bankruptcy. The choice of the phrase “any person” extends the possible
application of the provision to parent companies. However, the plaintiff must show that the parent suppressed the
autonomy of the subsidiary's management and has effectively imposed its own decisions on the subsidiary.20 The
Companies Code further provides that directors can be held liable for the increase in company debts from the date
when the shareholders should have been convened to deliberate on the liquidation of the company if its net assets fall
below 50 per cent of the issued share capital (and again in case the net assets fall below 25 per cent of the issued share
capital).21
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
Belgium regulates shareholders’ liability through statutory provisions that apply exceptions and limitations to the
general limited liability rule, and through judge-made doctrines dealing with veil piercing in the context of bankruptcy
laws. Art. 456(4) and 229(5) of the Belgian Company Code mandate the imposition of liability on a founder of a
company with limited liability when the company files for bankruptcy within three years of its incorporation and its
initial capital was manifestly inadequate for the conduct of its operations in the regular course of business during the
first two years.22
Art. 646 provides that collection of all shares of a stock company by one shareholder entails, if not remedied within
one year, a joint liability of that shareholder for the company’s debts.23
The judge made 'Extension of Bankruptcy' doctrine provides that when an individual demonstrates a complete control
of a corporation and uses the control to conduct business activities behind the curtain of the corporation, the individual
shareholder may be declared bankrupt and become liable for the insolvency of the corporation.24
16 John Kluver, Entity vs Enterprise Liability: Issues for Australia, 37 CONN. L. REV. 765, 766 (2005).
17 The data presented here is based on Ramsay and Noakes, 2002.
18 Belgian Company Code, articles 210 and 438. See also, Karen Vandekerckhove, Piercing the Corporate Veil, 28 (2007).
19 Belgian Company's Code, Art. 530; Art. 265.
20 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 319. Nevertheless, Belgian courts demonstrate restraint in intervening in intra group transactions. In
a 2003 case, the Antwerp court of Appeals held that a parent company can validly pursue its own interests through an investment
policy at odds with the entire group interests.
21 Belgian Companies Code, Art. 633.
22 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 30-31, 113-118. Founders’ liability requires neither causal link between the undercapitalization and
the bankruptcy nor a fault on behalf of the founder.
23 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 30-31
24 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 29-30. Courts have applied the doctrine inter alia when found that the bankrupt company constitutes
merely a screen or a straw-man for the operations of the master ('maitre de l'affire') and when the bankrupt company was a 'dummy
company'; namely, a mere instrument in the hands of the master. See Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
(OECD), Responsibility ot Parent Companies for their Subsidiaries, 50 (1980).
Courts have also held owners liable in cases of material undercapitalization, tort claims, disregard for corporate
formalities and when a company was administrated as a mere branch of its parent company.25
The Belgian Tax Code holds shareholders of companies liable for corporate tax debts. Shareholders owning at least
1/3 of the shares may be held liable for tax debts of the company in case of a transfer of at least 75% of the shares
within one year.26
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
Most statutory and judge-made law requires bankruptcy as a prerequisite to hold the shareholders liable to the
obligations of their subsidiaries.27 Liability for reunion of all shares under the control of one shareholder, as prescribed
under Art. 646 of the Belgian Company Code, seems to be a narrow exception allowing veil piercing outside
bankruptcy proceedings.
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
Statutory law does not include requirement of fraud or intentional misconduct. On the contrary, the invocation of the
judge-made abuse of rights doctrine or imposition of liability under tort law may include in some cases considerations
of shareholder misconduct.28
d. Canada
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
Following its British heritage, Canadian law generally adheres to the entity theory. The dominant view in the case
law is that intra-group veil piercing appears to be possible if it is established that a parent company had exercised
complete domination and control over the affairs and activities of the subsidiary, and the subsidiary is being used to
shield an improper conduct.29 A less widely held approach relaxes the requirement for impropriety in specific cases.30
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
Canadian courts commonly adhere to a two-pronged analysis mandating both domination (to the level that the
controlled corporation has no independent function) and the use of that domination to conceal egregious wrongdoing.
Under this view, the courts disregard the separate legal personality of a corporate entity only when it is completely
dominated and controlled and is used as a shield for a fraudulent or improper conduct. Specific factors that may
amount to impropriety are thin capitalization, failure to maintain adequately separate records for different entities,
overlap between affiliated entities with respect to access to funds, corporate function, employees, directors etc., and
an attempt to avoid pre-existing legal obligations through an incorporation of a company.31 In a handful of cases,
25 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 32-33; 118-24. Undercapitalization claims can be pursued as a tort claim under Art. 1382 of the civil
Code. Plaintiffs are required to show that founders could not reasonably assume that their contribution constitutes sufficient
amount of capital for the operation of the business. Another cause of action might be abuse of rights, under which the plaintiff
claim is required to demonstrate that the owners have exceeded the normal exercise of the right of separate legal personality or
the right of limited liability. Courts frequently avoid piercing the veil based on undercapitalization alone, but rather ask for
additional indications of shareholders' misconduct. In one case, a court considered an abuse of legal rights claim in circumstances
when shareholders authorize transfer of the loss-making part of their company’s activities to a new company they incorporated
without providing sufficient capitalization. The court held that the separation between the two entities did not correspond to
reality because both companies were in effect dependent departments of the same entity.
26 Art. 441 of the Belgian Tax Code.
27 The statutory rules concerning founder’s liability for undercapitalization (Art. 456(4) and 229(5) of the Belgian Company
Code) are triggered by commencement of bankruptcy proceedings upon the company. The judicial doctrine of Extension of
Bankruptcy and abuse of rights claims are more equipped to deal with bankruptcy situations.
28 For example, see Art. 1382 of the Civil Code (establishes tort liability for undercapitalization).
29 642947 Ontario Ltd. v. Fleischer, 2001, 56 O.R. (3d) 417, Ont. C.A. at para. 68. For critical accounts of court decisions applying
a more liberal approach for corporate groups see Mohamed F. Khimji and Christopher C. Nicholls, Corporate Veil Piercing and
Allocation of Liability: Diagnosis and Prognosis, 30(2) Banking & Finance Law Review, 211, note 132 and accompanying text
(2015).
30 Manley Inc. v. Fallis, 1977 CarswellOnt 56, 2 B.L.R. 277, 38 C.P.R. (2d) 74, [1977] O.J. No. 1080 (Ont. C.A.)
31 Khimji & Nicholls, 2015, at 232-33.
courts have argued that impropriety is not a prerequisite to piercing the corporate veil, specifically when the court
finds it necessary to prevent a flagrantly unjust result.32
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
Bankruptcy is not a prerequisite to commence veil piercing proceedings.
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
Veil piercing is often granted when false representations are made or a fraudulent or other objectionable, illegal or
improper activity is undertaken. As noted, in a few cases courts have settled for the showing of owner’s dominance
and have waived the requirement of impropriety when it is necessary to achieve justice.33
e. China
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
China adheres to the entity theory. Courts seem to apply the same standards of veil piercing for corporate groups as
they do for other types of companies.
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
The central provision of the Chinese veil piercing law34 is contained in Article 20(3) of the Company Law,35 which
mandates three accumulative requirements for veil piercing: (1) misconduct: a conduct that amounts to an abuse of
the separate legal personality (e.g., undercapitalization). It is uncertain whether the provision requires fraudulent
behavior (like in some other countries, France for example). From a textual perspective, the law does not appear to
require proof of fraud; (2) intent: the abusive behavior was intended to evade the debt payment; and (3) consequence:
the abuse caused serious damage to the creditors' interests.36
Article 64 of the Company Law sets out further rules under which the shareholder of a one-person limited liability
company bears joint liabilities for the debts of his company when he is unable to prove that the property of the
company is independent from his own.37 The provision adds two important elements to the veil piercing doctrine
which applies to a single shareholder companies. First, it introduces the commingling of assets as a valid
consideration; second, this provision in effect shifts the burden of proof from the plaintiff creditor to the defendant
shareholder of a one-member company, making it much easier to substantiate a veil piercing argument.
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
Bankruptcy is not a prerequisite to commence veil piercing proceedings.38
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
32 Thomas G. Heintzman, Q.C. & Brandon Kain, Through the Looking Glass: Recent Developments in Piercing the Corporate
Veil, 28 B.F.L.R. 525, 539-40 (2013).
33 Khimji & Nicholls, 2015.
34 Veil piercing is a new concept in Chinese law. In 2006, China had gone through a massive legal reform by introducing a new
company law. Until then, veil piercing had no statutory authority, and the concept was rarely used by some enterprising Chinese
judges in selected provincial courts and under extremely narrow circumstances. In the 2006 overhaul, much of the previous
Company Law was revised or eliminated, with many new provisions added. This development was much anticipated by Chinese
and foreigners alike, as China’s previous corporate law was unable to keep pace with its fast growing economy. One of the
highlights of the new Company Law is its formal establishment of the concept of “piercing the corporate veil” in Chinese law
(Mark Wu, Piercing China's Corporate Veil: Open Questions from the New Company Law, 117 YALE L.J. 328, 329 (2007)).
35 Art. 20(3) reads “Where any of the shareholders of a company evades the payment of its debts by abusing the independent
status of juridical persons or the shareholder’s limited liabilities, and thus seriously damages the interests of any creditors, it shall
bear joint liabilities for the debts of the company.”
36 Hui Huang, Piercing the Corporate Veil in China: Where Is It Now and Where Is It Heading, 60 AM. J. COMP. L. 743, 746
(2012).
37 Art. 64 reads “If the shareholder of a one-person limited liability company is unable to prove that the property of the one-person
limited liability company is independent from his own property, he shall bear joint liabilities for the debts of the company.”
38 The presence of bankruptcy in a veil piercing action is required under neither Art. 20(3) nor Art. 64 of the Company Law.
Article 20(3) of the Company Law requires the demonstration of a misconduct by the owner. It has yet to be settled
whether the requirement amounts to a fraudulent behavior.39 Fraud or improper conducts are the most successful
grounds for corporate veil piercing in Chinese courts (62.50% piercing rate when invoked).
5) Empirical data40
A survey conducted between 2006 and 2010 reports the corporate veil piercing rate of 63%. In 2006, courts pierced
the veil in 53% of the cases examined; in 2008 the rate was increased to 62% and in 2010 the rate soared to a
captivating 83% (note, however, that the study in 2010 recorded only 12 cases). Chinese courts’ decision to pierce
the corporate veil appears to have been influenced by the number of shareholders involved: the piercing rate declined
as the number of shareholders increased. The veil was pierced in all cases involving one-member companies. The
largest group of cases involved companies with two shareholders but showed a lower rate of piercing (75%). The
lowest rate was found for companies with three to five shareholders (about 42%). None of the target companies had
six or more shareholders. This suggests that small companies are more susceptible to veil piercing. The study
examined 18 corporate group cases, and, in 11 of the cases, courts have decided to pierce the veil (61% rate). When
the target shareholder was a parent company, the veil was pierced in 6 out of 7 cases; when the target shareholder was
a sibling company, the veil was pierced 4 out of 10 cases; and in the only case when the target company was a
subsidiary, the court granted the plaintiff's request to pierce the veil.
f. Denmark
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
Danish law does not include direct reference to enterprise or a single economic unit approach. The Danish corporate
veil piercing jurisprudence has been developed almost exclusively in the parent-subsidiary context, but the
presumption of limited liability applies to corporate groups as well as any other limited liability company.
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
Limited liability is a statutory right (codified under § 1.2 of the Danish Companies Act) applicable to shareholders in
private and public Danish companies.41 Courts have relied on three legal constructions to disregard limited liability
and hold shareholders liable, these are PCV (“hæftelsesgennembrud”), identification (aka in Denmark, mixing of
assets) and tort law principles, under which parent corporations that exercise complete control over their subsidiaries
have a fiduciary duties toward the subsidiaries.42
39 Huang, 2012, at 746.
40 Huang, 2012, at 748-54.
41 Danish law recognizes several corporation organizations that feature limited liability. These are public limited liability
companies “aktieselskaber” (A/S), private limited liability companies “anpartsselskaber” (ApS), cooperative organizations with
limited liability (A.m.b.a) as well as limited liability companies (S.m.b.a). Limited partnerships (K/S) (in Danish:
kommanditselskab) and Partner companies (P/S) (in Danish: partnerselskab) are a hybrid between the personal liability
companies and the limited liability companies. Here, there are general partners (kommanditist) and limited partners
(komplementar). These types of business organizations are regulated differently but share the principle of limited liability with
the limited liability companies.
42 The Satair case, U.1997.364H.
Danish courts have considered the following factors in PCV cases: (1) owner’s control/dominance, when involving
mismanagement; (2) assets stripping; (3) incorporation as a shell company43; (4) incorporation with the sole purpose
of circumventing legal obligations44; (5) asset mixing45; and (6) undercapitalization46.
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
Under Danish law, bankruptcy is not a prerequisite to commence veil piercing proceedings or any of the other
doctrines that allow imposition of liability on the parent. However, the entire Danish PCV case law has been
developed in cases of insolvency. Consequently, plaintiffs are most likely to prevail when the original debtor is
insolvent.
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
Most Danish PCV case law is grounded in tort law principles. Courts have more often than not reasoned their decision
to impose liability by referring to the defendant’s gross negligence or intent to commit fraud or circumvent the law.
Sec. 363 of the Danish Companies Act provides that “a shareholder is liable for any loss inflicted intentionally or with
gross negligence on the company, the other shareholders or any third party”.
g. France
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
French law generally follows the entity theory but has several exceptions that follow the enterprise approach in the
context of corporate group limited liability. French courts have applied the doctrine of economic unity as a variant of
the doctrine of appearance. These situations arise typically in cases of misrepresentation where a creditor is misled to
believe that he is dealing with an entity other than the real corporation. For instance, in a parent-subsidiary context, a
parent company might appear to contract with a good faith third party, but it is actually the subsidiary who signs the
contract.47 Two or more entities may be regarded as an economic unity when multiple entities reasonably appear to
form an economic unit.
French courts may also impose liability on the corporate parent when the assets and affairs of the parent and those of
its subsidiary have been so closely intertwined so that the latter is can be considered a mere instrumentality of the
former. At the same time, courts recognize that usual group organization and functioning, such as cash flow advances,
cannot establish abnormal financial relations required for imposition of liability on the corporate parent.48 Ultimately,
both the doctrine of appearance and the commingling of assets and affairs require something more than mere economic
43 In Frigor (U.1980.806V), the High Court held that when a subsidiary has no actual economic rationale and is only used to
avoid certain obligations of the parent company, the latter can be held liable. It is of importance to note that in the instant case
the creditors were employees of the subsidiary, a class of creditors that generally enjoys increased legal protection. See Krüger
Andersen, K2, 2010, at 538, Hansen & Krenchel, DS1, 2010, at 114f and U.2001.100H, section 2.4.1.1.
44 Frigor (U.1980.806V). The Court found that the subsidiary had not had any real content since its balance only contained the
salary to workforce which was matched by a corresponding payment by the parent company. The subsidiary met the legal
requirements to management, financial statements, etc., but had not been independently registered for VAT. The Board of
Directors of the subsidiary had never engaged in real decision-making and had not influenced lending of capital to the parent
company or any subsequent decisions. Thus, in reality the parent company's board of directors made the decisions. In addition,
the company was structured to avoid employee representation on the board of directors of the parent company and the subsidiary
constituted only an intermediary for the payment of wages.
45 The Midfynsfestival case, U.1997.1642H.
46 The Midfynsfestival case, U.1997.164. The Danish Supreme court emphasized that the two companies were not regarded as
two separate entities to the public and that the companies’ finances were mixed together. In addition, the company structure was
organized in a way that profit was kept in R and the risk was mostly allocated in F, which was heavily undercapitalized.
47 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 441-42 (arguing that French courts invoke the doctrine of appearance when the corporations in a
group create the impression that they are one entity); Presser, 2017, § 5:7. (noting that lack of distinctive features among the
group members (e.g., same address, similar names, overlapping business activities) may mislead third parties acting in good
faith).
48 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 437-38 (suggesting that only an entire commingling of all group assets may trigger identification of
the members as one single unit); Karl Hofstetter, Parent Responsibility for Subsidiary Corporations: Evaluating European
Trends, 39 INT’L & COMP. L. Q. 577 (1990); Presser, 2017, § 5:7..
unity to pierce the corporate veil. That “something more” might well include findings of misrepresentation or
abnormal financial relations.49
Additionally, under the Bankruptcy law, French courts have found that when a parent corporation has a predominant
influence over its subsidiary and exercises a de facto authority over its directors, the parent may be considered a de
facto director of its subsidiary. This construction enables creditors of an insolvent subsidiary to seek relief from the
corporate parent. Furthermore, the law provides a possibility to declare the de facto director (the corporate parent) of
a bankrupt subsidiary also bankrupt.50
French law further applies specific statutory rules for shared liability in specific bodies of law such as competition,
labor relations, and environmental law. Some French courts have invoked the economic unity theory independently
from the instruments cited above. Under this approach, when the financial and economic features of the group
members are intermingled, they are treated as one legal entity. However, this approach has been widely criticized and
was never accepted by the Supreme Court.51
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
The Bankruptcy Statute and a variety of less frequently invoked court doctrines such as doctrine of appearance
(“thééorie de l'apparence”) and Paulienne action (“actio pauliana”) provide most of the PCV regulation under French
law.
French bankruptcy law provides several grounds for shareholder liability claims: (1) “asset insufficiency”, which
applies directly to managers and implicitly to controlling shareholders in companies where separation between
ownership and management is absent; (2) cessation of payments to creditors due to actions or inactions of the
managers per Art. 652-1, which mandates the court to hold de-facto or de-jure manager liable; (3) incorporation of a
fictitious company;52 (4) comingling of assets of the owners and the corporation.53
The doctrine of appearance is invoked typically in cases of misrepresentation, where a creditor is misled to believe
that he is dealing with an entity other than the real corporation.54 Paulienne action (“actio pauliana”) enables creditors
to challenge a debtor’s fraudulent transfer of assets to a third party for additional claims.55
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
Bankruptcy proceedings are the only settings in which veil piercing is available under French law. Even when claims
are made under the fictitious corporation doctrine, veil piercing is available exclusively in bankruptcy cases. The only
exception to this rule is when the doctrine of appearance is invoked to impose liability on the corporate parent.
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
Article L 652-1 of the French Commercial Code on bankruptcy requires the manager or the director to have engaged
in a misconduct to impose liability on them. The provision accommodates mostly claims against shareholders in small,
closed corporations with practically no separation between ownership and management.
49 In the Metaleurope case (2005), the French Supreme Court contemplated on a parent’s liability for the subsidiary’s
environmental law violations. The Court held that identification between members of a group will be examined based on two
criteria. First, mingling of assets among the group members to the extent that a professional accountant would not be able to tell
which debt whose is. Second, findings of abnormal financial relations between the group members (e.g., transfer of funds without
consideration), which exceed usual group dealings. The Court’s refusal to extend bankruptcy proceedings of the subsidiary to the
parent demonstrates flexible approach to the term “abnormal financial relations” in the parent-subsidiary context. See, Presser,
2017, § 5:7.; Vandekerckhove, (2007), at 438.
50 Art. L 651-2 of the French Commercial Code (“Where the judicial liquidation proceedings of a legal entity reveals an excess
of liabilities over assets, the court may, in instances where management fault has contributed to the excess of liabilities over
assets, decide that the debts of the legal entity will be borne, in whole or in part, by all or some of the de jure or de facto managers,
or by some of them who have contributed to the management fault. If there are several managers, the court may, by way of a
reasoned ruling, declare that they are liable in solidarity”.)
51 Art. L 651-2 of the French Commercial Code.
52 Vandekerckhove, (2007) at 434-35.
53 Presser, 2017, § 5:5-7..
54 Presser, 2017, § 5:6-7..
55 Larry Catá Backer, Comparative corporate law: United States, European Union, China, and Japan: cases and materials 1073
(2002); Presser, 2017, § 5:5-6..
The fictitious corporation doctrine, under which French courts may impose liability on shareholders, is most often
invoked in situations where the incorporation of the entity is aimed to withdraw assets from creditors' reach and for
fraudulent purposes.56
h. Germany
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
The Stock Corporation Act (Aktiengesetz) provides special provisions regulating intra-group liability. The law defines
Konzern as “controlling and one or more controlled enterprises [that] are subject to the common direction of the
controlling enterprise”. If enterprises are parties to a control agreement or if one enterprise has been integrated into
the other, such enterprises are considered to be subject to common management. In other words, the controlling and
controlled entities are presumed to constitute a konzern (group).57
The law on Konzernrecht (“controlled companies”) provides that a corporate parent may be liable for the obligations
of its controlled subsidiaries either through express agreement or when the corporate parent had a complete control
over its subsidiary to the detriment of the subsidiary (de-facto konzern). In essence, the law promotes a trade-off
between two unique features of intra-group relations. On the one hand, the corporate parent is entitled to give binding
instructions to the subsidiary even when they are not in the interest of the subsidiary. On the other hand, to compensate
for the additional risk that the subsidiary and its stakeholders bear, the law provides ways to hold the corporate parent
liable for the losses incurred by its subsidiary. Specifically, the law imposes an additional regulation for the protection
of creditors. For example, among the duties imposed on the corporate parent are the duty to make the execution and
termination of controlling agreement available to creditors and the responsibility to maintain money reserves to
compensate for losses incurred by the subsidiary.58
Unlike in the case of public corporations, the law governing private companies (GH) has been developed through
judicially made doctrines and thus is not regulated through the Stock Corporation Act. In 2001, the Federal Supreme
Court’s decision on Bremer Vulkan substantially limited the application of the enterprise theory to private companies
by abandoning the application of Konzern law for a qualified de facto konzern, in which subsidiaries are controlled
by the corporate parent without a controlling agreement between them. The Supreme Court held that liability of a
private corporate parent is to be determined according to the “existence destroying encroachments” concept, under
which a corporate parent removes assets from its subsidiary without guaranteeing the latter of sufficient assets to
satisfy its liabilities.59
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
Germany applies the doctrine of Durchgriffshaftung to impose corporate liability on owners outside of the context of
Konzern law that controls corporate groups.60 The underlying justification for shareholder liability is the abuse by the
owners of the legal personality principle. Creditors are protected in four different situations that generally coincide
with American case law: commingling of assets (the ownership of the shareholder and the company is
indistinguishable); failure to follow corporate formalities (most commonly when the failure to follow formalities
makes a company's identity unclear to creditors); undercapitalization; and total domination of a company by another.61
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
German courts invoke veil piercing most often in bankruptcy cases. Nonetheless, there is no statutory or judicially
prescribed prerequisite for bankruptcy.
56 Presser, 2017, § 5:6.
57 Art. 16-19 of the Stock Corporation Act (Aktiengesetz).
58 German law regulates various forms of corporate. The Aktiengesetz distinguishes between (1) domination based on agreements
(a contractual Konzern, Art. 291-310), (2) de facto domination (Art. 311-318), and (3) integrated entities (Art. 319-327).
Additionally, there is the concept of qualified (centralized) de facto domination which has no statutory basis and was developed
by German court, in the context of a dominated private companies (GH). For detailed analysis on the law on Konzerns see Carsten
Alting, Piercing the Corporate Veil in American and German Law - Liability of Individuals and Entities: A Comparative View,
2 TULSA J. COMP. & INTL. L. 187, 233-40 (1995); Sandra K. Miller, Piercing the Corporate Veil Among Affiliated Companies in
the European Community and in the U.S.: A Comparative Analysis of U.S., German, and U.K. Veil piercing Approaches, 36 AM.
BUS. L.J. 73, 99-108 (1998).
59 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 54-60.
60 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 62-65.
61 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 63-64; Alting, (1995), at 201; 207-210; 214-218.
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
German law does not require showing of a fraudulent intention to establish shareholder liability. However, more
recent legal cases suggest that corporate veil piercing is enforced mostly when the corporate parent exercises a control
over its subsidiary in an abusive manner and against the interest of the subsidiary.62
i. Great Britain
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
The UK strictly adheres to the entity theory under which each corporation in the group is a separate juridical entity
with its own rights and duties distinct from those of its shareholders.63 In the past some court decisions had relied on
a single economic unit theory as an independent basis for imposing liability on the parent.64 The theory was considered
and rejected on the merits of Adams v Cape Industries Plc. (1990), a leading authority in Britain until 2013,65 and was
officially overruled in the seminal Prest decision.
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
UK courts have taken a minimalist approach to corporate veil piercing, even questioning whether the doctrine has
ever existed in British law.66 In Prest v Petrodel (2013), the Supreme Court handed down what is emerging as the
seminal decision in PCV in British law. While making clear that veil piercing is available, the Court introduced two
guiding principles that have circumvented the availability of the doctrine.67 First is the evasion principle. Prest
provides that “the principle that the court may be justified in piercing the corporate veil if a company’s separate legal
personality is being abused for the purpose of some relevant wrongdoing is well established in the authorities. [...] I
think that the recognition of a limited power to pierce the corporate veil in carefully defined circumstances is necessary
if the law is not to be disarmed in the face of abuse68. Abuse, the Court followed, may arise only when the
incorporation had been made or used for deliberately evading a legal obligation or liability: “[t]hese considerations
reflect the broader principle that the corporate veil may be pierced only to prevent the abuse of corporate legal
personality. It may be an abuse of the separate legal personality of a company to use it to evade the law or to frustrate
its enforcement” 69 The second guiding principle provides that veil piercing will be considered only as a remedy of
last resort, when all other avenues for relief have been exhausted.
In an effort to define the scope of the doctrine, Lord Sumption noted: “I conclude that there is a limited principle of
English law which applies when a person is under an existing legal obligation or liability or subject to an existing
legal restriction which he deliberately evades or whose enforcement he deliberately frustrates by interposing a
62 For example, in the ITT case the Supreme Court held that a controlling shareholder bears a special duty to conduct its affairs
with the subsidiary in corporate good faith. When the duty is breached, the parent may be held liable. Vandekerckhove, 2007, at
54.
63 Bank of Tokyo v. Karoon, [1986] 3 WLR 414 (refusing to treat a parent and its subsidiary as one single economic unit despite
the claim they were functioning as one economic enterprise. The court held that “counsel suggested beguilingly that it would be
technical for us to distinguish between parent and subsidiary company in this context; economically, he said, they were one. But
we are concerned not with economics but with law. The distinction between the two is, in law, fundamental and cannot here be
bridged”). In Adams v. Cape Indus. 2 WLR. 657 (C.A.1990)), the court denied a claim to lift the corporate veil in a group of
companies engaged in mining operations. Although it was found that the group had operated as a single integrated mining division
with the parent setting the broad business policy of the subsidiaries, the court held that a parent and subsidiary should not be
regarded as one enterprise because of the single integrated nature of the business.
64 Consider two examples. In DHN Food distributions Ltd v. Tower Hamlets London Borough Council [1976] WLR 852 a parent
company distributed the operation of a business between two wholly owned subsidiaries, one of them held the title of the land in
which a warehouse used for the business was located. The land was compulsorily acquired by the council, but no compensation
was paid as the council claimed that the owner of the land (the subsidiary) did not have an interest in the business. The court
agreed with the plaintiff that in these circumstances the council should have treated the business as one economic unit and
consequently ordered the veil to be lifted. Woolfson v. Strathclyde Regional Council 1978 SC (HL) 90 presented similar facts.
An individual held the majority of shares in two companies where one company owned the property and another operated the
enterprise. Once again, the council compulsorily acquired the land without paying compensations. This time however, the court
refused to consider the companies as one single economic unit, and rejected the precedential value of DHN Food distribution.
65 Adams v Cape Industries Plc. [1990] Ch 433.
66 VTB Capital Plc v Nutritek International Corp and others [2013] UKSC 5.
67 See, Alexander Schall, The New Law of Piercing the Corporate Veil in the UK, ECFR 2016, 549–574, at 550.
68 Prest v Petrodel Resources Ltd. [2013] UKSC, at ¶ 27 (Lord Sumption).
69 Prest v Petrodel Resources Ltd. [2013] UKSC, at ¶ 34.
company under his control. The court may then pierce the corporate veil for the purpose, and only for the purpose, of
depriving the company or its controller of the advantage that they would otherwise have obtained by the company's
separate legal personality.”70
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
Bankruptcy is not a prerequisite to commence veil piercing proceedings. However, under the rule of last resort, courts
may refuse to pierce the corporate veil when other avenues for relief are available.
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
The corporate veil is pierced only in extreme cases of misconduct including those that involve fraud.
5) Empirical data
Average piercing rate is around 47% of the total claims (290 cases from 1859 to 1998).71 Critically, many decisions
that granted veil piercing can no longer stand as good law after Prest.
j. Netherlands
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
The Netherlands regulates affiliated corporations primarily through the doctrine of identification, under which the
law considers affiliated corporations as one legal person in various situations. Other constructions for imposition of
parent liability are liability as de facto director and rules concerning asset transfers. However, unlike in Germany, the
default regime between affiliated corporations relies on the entity theory. In general, parents will not be held liable
when the subsidiary' management have given its full consent to acts carried out by the parent.
The identification doctrine allows courts to treat the parent and subsidiary as one entity when some factors are found
to be present. Courts identify affiliated corporations in situation such as parent dominance, intensive involvement in
the management of the controlled corporation, commingling of assets and intermingling in corporate formalities (e.g.,
identity in addresses, letterhead and directors/shareholders). Moreover, courts examine whether treating the
corporations separate would lead to consequences contrary to good faith. The Dutch Supreme Court has traditionally
treated the identification doctrine with restraint, while the lower courts have applied it more frequently.72 It will
usually take a combination of factors to trigger corporate veil piercing. A mere commingling of assets among
corporate group entities or even some indications of economic unity are not enough to justify veil piercing in most
cases.73
Dutch law does not recognize specific rules limiting intra-group asset transfers. The general policy is that as long as
a subsidiary may draw benefits from the group relationship in the long term, and so long as a transaction is in the
70 Prest v Petrodel Resources Ltd. [2013] UKSC, at ¶ 35. Earlier cases have mentioned additional factors to be considered, such
as commingling of assets and disregard to corporate formalities, although it is not clear to what extent they still constitute good
law after Prest. For example, in Creasey v. Breachwood Motors Ltd. [1993] BCLC 480, a general manager brought an action
against his employer, Breachwood Welwyn Ltd., for wrongful dismissal. After the claim was filed all of the defendant’s assets
and business activity were transferred into a new corporation, Breachwood Motors Ltd. The plaintiff then moved to enforce the
judgment against the new corporation. In lifting the veil and imposing the debt on Breachwood Motors Ltd., the court held that
the shareholders and directors demonstrated total disregard of their duties. The court further held that the new corporate form
cannot be used to avoid the old entity’s legal obligations.
71 Charles Mitchell, Lifting the Corporate Veil in the English Courts: An Empirical Study, 3 COMPANY FIN. & INSOLVENCY L.
REV. 15 (1999).
72 The Bato’s Erf Case provides an example of the narrow approach taken by the Supreme Court in comparison to lower courts.
The case involved a company that transferred its operations to a wholly owned subsidiary to avoid liability for soil pollution. The
court of appeals found that both companies were closely intermingled and identified them in order to impose liability on the
parent. On an appeal before the Supreme Court the decision was reversed. The court held that the mere showing of control on
behalf of the parent should not identify the acts of the subsidiary with the parent. Vandekerckhove, (2007), at 424.
73 See generally, Vandekerckhove, (2007) at 410-411. For instance, in the Koenrades case a Dutch court identified a group of
affiliated companies with their sole (natural person) shareholder for debts to an employee after it was held that the owner abused
the legal personality of its companies. The plaintiff was successful in showing that the shareholder intentionally caused one of
his companies to go bankrupt for the sole purpose of thwarting the execution of a monetary judgment against it.
interests of the group, the dealing is valid. However, shareholders may incur liability in extreme cases where acts
conducted by the parent endanger the existence of the subsidiary.74
Imposition of liability as de facto director is regulated under Art. 2:138, 248(7) of the Dutch Civil Code. The law
provides for liability of de facto directors in cases of gross mismanagement that has important contribution to the
bankruptcy of the subsidiary. A parent corporation may be considered de facto director when it has had a direct
influence over the subsidiary's management and when in reality the subsidiary's management has been set aside. When
the parent imposes its own will (actively engages in management functions) while ignoring the subsidiary's formal
management, it may be responsible for a part or all of the subsidiary’s debts in bankruptcy proceedings.75
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
Dutch law applies corporate veil piercing for remedial purposes in tort cases. Under Dutch law, a tort consists of an
act or omission that violates rights of another person or is contrary to a legal obligation, good morals or expected
prudence between persons in society.76 To pierce the veil, a court would review whether (1) the owner of a corporation
knew or should have known that his act or omission would harm the creditors of the corporation; (2) the degree of
involvement / control that the owner exercised in the management was substantial.77 Among the factors courts have
considered in establishing the owner’s liability are continuation of loss making activities, selective payment practices,
unjustified refusal to pay creditors, unjust dividend policy, and frustration of creditors' security rights.78
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
Courts pierce corporate veil typically in bankruptcy cases. The doctrine of identification may be applied in cases not
involving bankruptcy.79
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
Dutch law does not require fraudulent behavior or other intentional shareholder misconduct to hold shareholders
liable. However, in most veil piercing cases, acts or omissions that prejudice creditors seem to be a key factor in
imposing corporate debts on shareholders.80
The doctrine of identification views some kind of misconduct (e.g., abuse of rights, fraudulent intent or wrongful
creation of false representations) as a necessary condition (albeit not sufficient) for identifying the controlled entity
and the shareholder.81
k. Italy
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
Italian law regulates corporate groups differently from independent entities. Art. 2497 of the Company Law prescribes
a rule under which the corporate parent is held liable for mistakes of its subsidiary if the parent causes damages to the
integrity of the subsidiary’s assets. Furthermore, other stakeholders of the corporate group (e.g., sister subsidiary, the
parent’s shareholders) that benefit from the parent’s control over its subsidiary and participates in a harmful activity
may also be held liable.
74 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 207.
75 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 331-32. Vandekerckhove points however, that “a normal central management in corporate groups,
characterized by an overall coordination of central financing and a definition of policies on the longer term does not amount to
quasi management.”
76 Article 2:5 of the Dutch Civil Code.
77 Osby-Pannan A/B v. Las Verkoopmaatschappij BV, NJ 1982 no. 443, Supreme Court (Hoge Raad). Quoted in
Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 33-35.
78 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 33-35
79 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 37-38.
80 In the aftermath of Osby, a flow of judgments established the notion that parent corporations bear responsibility to take into
account the interests of their subsidiaries' creditors. In order to pierce the veil, a court would review whether (1) the parent knew
or should have known that its act or omission would harm the creditors; (2) the degree of involvement/control that the parent
exercised in the management of the subsidiary. Vandekerckhove, (2007), at 34-35.
81 Vandekerckhove, 2007, at 433.
Art. 2325 and 2462 also provide that single-owner companies82, which constitute the majority of the subsidiaries,
must meet certain capital formalities in order to qualify for limited liability.
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
Italian law considers several veil piercing criteria for both public and private limited liability corporations. Main
reasons for corporate veil piercing include a disregard for corporate formalities and commingling of assets.83 The de-
facto Director doctrine is invoked in bankruptcy cases most often when shareholders disregard corporate structure
and formalities, interfere directly with management, and comingle personal and corporate assets.84
Additionally, Company Law 2003 (Civil Code Art. 2476) mandates that shareholders and directors who intentionally
decide or authorize activities that damage their company may incur joint liability for debts incurred by their company.
Bankruptcy Law 2006 (Art. 147) also regulates the joint liability of members of unlimited partnerships. It further
imposes liability on “shadow or secret partners” who act in the capacity of a partner without formally being introduced
as one. Italian jurists argue that this construction may be extended to a “tyrant” or a dominating shareholder who
comingles personal and corporate assets.
Finally, Italian courts are more inclined to pierce the corporate veil when a limited liability company is incorporated
solely to dodge legal obligations assumed by the corporate parent (e.g. non-compete obligation).85
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
Bankruptcy is not a prerequisite to commence veil piercing proceedings, but it is required for actions brought under
Art. 147 of the Bankruptcy law and is a relevant factor in proceedings taken under Art. 2467 of the Companies Law.
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
Italian law does not require a fraudulent intent to hold shareholders liable for the obligations of their subsidiaries. At
the same time, intent to commit wrongdoing is a factor considered under Art. 2476 of the Companies Law, which is
applicable to private limited liability companies. This rule holds shareholders and directors jointly liable for the debts
incurred by their company if they intentionally authorize actions that are damaging to the company. However, under
the governing law of corporate groups, neither intent nor fraudulent behavior is required to establish liability.
l. Japan
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
Japan adheres to the entity theory. Courts seem to apply the same standards of veil piercing for corporate groups as
they do in other cases.86
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
The emergence of the piercing the veil doctrine in Japanese law came in 1969 when the Supreme Court held that
“where the legal personality of [a company] is nothing more than a mere shell, or where it is misused in order to avoid
the application of legislation…it will be necessary to pierce the corporate veil.”87
The general test for veil piercing requires demonstration of a total control by the owner and an additional factor, such
as commingling of assets, repeated overlap of business transactions or activities, failure to follow corporate
formalities, inadequate capitalization, lack of a separate identity between corporation and individual,
82 Italian Companies law sets out two main types of incorporated entities: the Società per Azioni (SPA), a company limited by
shares, and the Società a Responsabilità Limitata (SRL), a company limited by ‘quotas’.
83 See generally, Marco Speranzin, Piercing the Corporate Veil in Italian Company and Banking Law (2008).
http://www.academia.edu/10285563/Piercing_the_corporate_veil_in_Italian_company_and_banking_law.
84 See, e.g., Cass. 23 aprile 2003, n. 6478 (Italian High Court).
85 Speranzin, 2008.
86 The Sendai District Court held in 1970 that the instrumentality theory may be applied more easily upon corporate groups than
individual shareholders when the parent parents possess the right to control the assets of subsidiaries. In another case, 111
employees of an insolvent subsidiary brought a claim seeking to pierce the veil of the parent in order to collect their salaries. The
court ruled in their favor, finding that the subsidiary's officers had been seconded from the parent, the business of the two firms
had often been intermingled and the parent firm had made all significant (and even many minor) business and personnel decisions
for the subsidiary. J. MARK RAMSEYER AND MINORA NAKAZATO, JAPANESE LAW: AN ECONOMIC APPROACH, 117 (1999)
87 Presser, 2017, § 5:10.
misrepresentation of the real entity dealing with the plaintiff, or an incorporation to avoid a legal duty.88 Impropriety
and fraud are central factors in veil piercing claims.89 The application of the PCV doctrine is generally confined to
closely held corporations.
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
Bankruptcy is not a prerequisite to commence veil piercing proceedings.
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
Subjective intent to commit wrongdoing is typically required to establish veil piercing claims. Bad motives of the
shareholder seem to play a critical role in the determination of corporate veil piercing.90
m. South Korea
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
South Korea’s economy is predominantly structured around corporate groups called Chaebol groups. Chaebol groups
are family-controlled global conglomerates with a highly centralized management structure.91 In most cases,
companies operating under the same group are intertwined by either cross-company shareholding or intra-group
loans.92
Korean law, nonetheless, features hardly any rules governing parent-subsidiary relations, particularly regarding
creditors and minority shareholders. Art. 412(5) of the Korean Commercial Code prescribes rules allowing a statutory
audit of the subsidiary’s business but only under very specific conditions. There are also few restrictions on
subsidiary’s granting credit to its controlling company as long as the subsidiary is publicly listed93 and on dealings
that may benefit the parent or other affiliates at the expense of the subsidiary’s other shareholders.94
Other than the particular provision in the Commercial Code, Korean case law strictly recognizes the legal separation
between wholly owned subsidiaries and their owners. For example, in one case, a wholly owned subsidiary approved
resolutions in a shareholders meeting that never took place. The court decided that such resolutions would be upheld
as long as the owner kept written minutes regardless of whether the meeting actually took place.95
Korean courts apply the Shadow Director doctrine on controlling companies in corporate groups and controlling
family members. Under Korean law, a parent will not be rendered the shadow director of its subsidiary merely
because of its capacity to impose common policies on the subsidiary96 but may incur liability for having issued
wrongful instructions to the subsidiary.97 As of 2011, no parent was held shadow director by Korean courts, the main
reason is the evidentiary hurdle to prove the influence of the parent.98
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
88 Presser, 2017, § 5:10.
89 Larry Catá Backer, Comparative corporate law: United States, European Union, China, and Japan: cases and materials, at 1,114
(2002). In that vein, Presser cites the Japanese Supreme Court decision of October 26, 1973 to support the view that “subjective
intent is key. The Court held that there was an abuse which justified piercing the veil because the intent of establishing the
particular corporation was to avoid the liabilities of a prior corporation. Instances that may constitute such an abuse of the
corporate form, the court explained, include avoidance of debt, inadequate capitalization, unfair labor practices and violations of
non-competition agreements.” Presser, 2017, § 5:10.
90 Backer, 2002, 1,114; Presser, 2017, § 5:10..
91 As of 2011, 62 corporate groups were responsible for more than 52% of Korea’s national turnover. See Hyeok-Joon Rho,
Corporate Groups in Korea, in GERMAN AND ASIAN PERSPECTIVES ON COMPANY LAW 307, 308 (HOLGER FLEISCHER ET. AL.
EDS., 2015).
92 Jack B. Jacobs, The Utility of the “Piercing The Corporate Veil” Doctrine In American and South Korean Corporate Law: An
Essay (unpublished manuscript), at *1.
93 Art. 542-9 of the Korean Commercial Code.
94 Art 398 of the Korean Commercial Code requires such dealings to qualify as “fair trade” and be approved by two thirds majority
of the board.
95 Supreme Court, 11 June 1993 Da 8702 (quoted in Rho, 2015, at 318).
96 Rho, 2015, at 329-30.
97 Rho, 2015, at 330.
98 Rho, 2015, at 330.
Korean corporate law is based on the entity approach, according to which every corporation is a distinct legal entity
having its own assets and liabilities. The Commercial Code mandates the corporate entity (Art. 171 provides that a
company “shall be a juristic person”) and provides limited liability to its owners (Art. 331).99
Veil piercing law has been created and developed in a number of court decisions beginning in the late 1970s. To date,
a principle doctrine setting the conditions for corporate veil piercing (“the denial of corporate status” as referred by
Korean judges) cannot be extracted from the case law.
The case law includes instances in which the corporate veil was pierced when the controlling shareholder completely
dominated the business and the management. Comingling of assets, abuse of the corporate entity (e.g., incorporating
a wholly owned foreign subsidiary merely to insulate from liability100), and disregard for corporate formalities (e.g.,
failure to hold board of director meetings or to maintain an operating office101) were also invoked to justify decisions
to pierce the corporate veil.
Controlling shareholders may also be held liable for company’s obligations under the Shadow Director doctrine. Art.
401-2 of the Commercial Code provides that a person who uses its influence to direct another officer in the company
(e.g., director, president, vice-president etc.) and to conduct the company’s business may be held liable for the
company’s acts.
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
Bankruptcy is not a prerequisite to commence veil piercing proceedings.
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
Korean law does not require a fraudulent intent to establish shareholder liability. Abuse of the corporate entity, which
in most cases will involve some level of subjective intent has played a role in veil piercing case law.
n. Sweden
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
No specific findings were available for application of different veil piercing policy on corporate groups. Courts seem
to apply the general standards of veil piercing in all cases.102
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
Swedish law has recognized veil piercing in a restrictive manner. To complement the protection of creditors, Swedish
law further provides specific statutory schemes for creditor protection outside of the context of ex-post shareholder
liability.103
Piercing the corporate veil doctrine seems to follow a totality of the circumstances analysis, focusing mostly on
undercapitalization, dependency (dominance), and impropriety (unfair or inequitable conduct).104 In addition,
imposition of liability on shareholders usually requires causality (between the damage and the ground for piercing the
veil), and good faith on behalf of the plaintiff.105
99 South Korea’s legal system is based mostly on statutory laws created by the legislative branch (in the legal community this
approach is commonly known as the civil law tradition, in contrast to the common law tradition under which the law is developed
by judicial decisions).
100 Judgment of November 22, 1988, 87-Daka-1671.
101 Judgment of January 19, 2001, 97-DA-21604.
102 Swedish Supreme Court Decision NJA 1947 s. 647.
103 Richard Ramberg, Piercing the Corporate Veil: Comparing the United States with Sweden, 17 NEW ENG. J. INT'L & COMP. L.
159. (2011)
104 The impropriety test provides that when the defendant's conduct is fraudulent or in violation of a statutory or other positive
legal duty, or a dishonest and unjust act in contravention of plaintiff's legal rights, veil piercing may be warranted. Ramberg,
2011, at 182.
105 Ramberg, 2011, at 182.
There is a general support for the claim that undercapitalization is absolutely required (but not sufficient) in order to
pierce the corporate veil (NJA 1947 s. 647).106 Even scholars who do not share this view consider undercapitalization
a fundamental factor determining corporate veil piercing.107
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
Bankruptcy is not mandatory in veil piercing claims. Nonetheless, bankruptcy does seem to become a factor within
the Mandatory Creditor Protection Rules. If the company has entered into liquidation or bankruptcy proceedings, the
liquidator/trustee may prosecute on the company's behalf. If a refund cannot be made in full, shareholders (and others)
may be deemed a liable pursuant under 17 Ch. 7 § ABL for the remaining amount if they knew of or were grossly
negligent with regard to the transfer.
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
The common three-prong analysis includes the impropriety requirement, under which the plaintiff must show unfair
or inequitable conduct. When the defendant's conduct is fraudulent or in violation of a statutory or other positive legal
duty, or dishonest and unjust in contravention of plaintiff's legal rights, veil piercing may be warranted. While this
factor is not imperative for veil piercing, it is central to the Swedish veil piercing doctrine.108
o. Switzerland
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
Swiss law does not include a codified provision regulating the relationship between a corporate parent and its
subsidiaries. General PCV conventions apply to corporate groups as they do to all other owner-corporation relations.
Under Swiss law, additional legal doctrines may be invoked in order to impose liability on the parent. A legal entity
that decides on matters that ought to be subject to the approval of a board of directors and thus preponderantly
influence the decision-making in the subsidiary, may be considered as the "de facto corporate body".109 Therefore, if
the subsidiary is unable to repay the debt, the creditors may file a suit against the management and also the de facto
corporate body. The only exception is when the de facto corporate body provides a proof that the damages were not
preventable.110
The concept of inspiration of trust is not codified but is a judicial convention. Generally, it describes a situation in
which the parent implicitly suggests to the creditor that it will become liable for the debts of the subsidiary if the
subsidiary is not able to pay. The doctrine folds five cumulative elements, which has been interpreted rather strictly
by Swiss courts111: (1) a lack of an agreement to establish liability between the parties (parent, subsidiary, and
creditor); (2) a trust relationship was inspired by the parent; (3) the creditor undertook an investment due to the trust
inspired; (4) the trust was violated; (5) a consequential damage occurred as a result of the violation of the trust.
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
Swiss PCV doctrine is a judicial convention derived from Art. 2 of Swiss Civil Code. The courts apply a two- (or
three-) prong test to determine the applicability of the PCV doctrine. First, the shareholder / defendant must control
106 NJA 1947 s. 647 was a Supreme Court case in which the court held the parents of a subsidiary formed for regulating certain
activities connected with power production personally liable for the debts of the subsidiary. In NJA 1947, a city and four
companies who all owned power plants next to a stream, formed a company together with the purpose of acquiring a pond and
regulating it to the advantage of the power plants. A neighboring land owner who incurred damages from the pond brought legal
action against the parent after he had learned that the subsidiary does have sufficient capital. The court held the shareholders
personally liable, stating that the company had been a joint body of execution for managing the water conservation and that it had
no independent business. Commentators emphasized that the company's inadequate capitalization in relation to the operation it
was formed to carry out was central to the court's holding. Considering this, and "other circumstances," the shareholders” were
held personally liable. See further, Ramberg, 2011, at 178-80.
107 Ramberg argues that undercapitalization is viewed more narrowly in Sweden than in the U.S. The Swedish scholars' use of
expressions such as "clearly insufficient" or "obviously insufficient," resonates a more restrictive view of undercapitalization than
what is applied in the United States. The traditional view of adequate capitalization in the United States is the amount of capital
necessary to cover reasonably foreseeable risks of the business. Consequently, any capitalization insufficient to cover the
reasonably foreseeable risks of the business is relevant, without it being clearly or obviously insufficient. Ramberg, 2011, at 181.
108 Ramberg, 2011.
109 BGE 132 III 523. See also Bsk-OR-Gericke/Waller Art. 754 N 5.
110 Bsk-OR-Gericke/Waller Art. 754 N 5.
111 BGE 120 II 331. See also Sethe, Konzernrecht, 2009, 7 f.
the relevant legal entity.112 Second, the person must have acted maliciously.113 Third, the plaintiff must prove
consequent injury.114
Furthermore, courts may pierce the corporate veil in cases of abuse of rights. Art. 2(1-2) of the Swiss Civil Code
stipulates that rights should be exercised in good faith. A shareholder acting in bad faith abuses his legal right and
may be held liable from the debts of the corporation.115
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
Bankruptcy is not a prerequisite to commence corporate veil piercing proceedings, or any other doctrines that allow
imposition of liability on the parent.
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
Malicious act is a prerequisite in veil piercing claims according to current case law. Nonetheless, in the intra-group
context, the de facto corporate body may be triggered even without specific intent of fraud / malice by the parent.
p. The United States116
1) Application of enterprise / economic unity approach
Setting aside a limited number of cases considering affiliated companies as single-business enterprises, American
courts adhere to the entity approach which considers each member of a corporate group as a single distinct legal entity
with liability limited to the undertakings of other group members.117
In a limited number of states such as Louisiana and Texas (until 2008), courts have applied an enterprise approach as
an independent basis for ignoring limited liability.118 Louisiana courts, in particular, treat affiliated corporations as a
single business enterprise if the level of control reaches a certain threshold, regardless of whether the parent abused
the corporate form. In other states, courts have made a reference to the concept of single business enterprise but used
the concept as another factor within a broader corporate veil piercing analysis. Thus, the courts still required a proof
of some form of abusive conduct by the parent to pierce the corporate veil. For example, in North Carolina, courts
consider under the general veil piercing analysis the “[e]xcessive fragmentation of a single enterprise into separate
corporations.”119
112 BGer 5A_498/2007 E. 2.2. See also Kobierski, Der Durchgriff im Gesellschafts- und Steuerrecht, 2012, 111; Sethe,
Konzernrecht, 2009, 6 et seq.; Koller, Schnyder & Druey, Das schweizerische Obligationenrecht, Zürich 2000, § 65 N 18 et seq.
113 Sethe, Konzernrecht, 2009, 7; Koller, Schnyder & Druey, Das schweizerische Obligationenrecht, Zürich 2000, § 60 N 47
114 Dennler, Durchgriff im Konzern, 32; Sethe, Konzernrecht, 2009, 7.
115 Swill Civil Code, Art. 2 (2).
116 In the US, courts apply the PCV doctrine on both Federal and State levels. This summary of American law covers rules
common to most states laws, with some emphasis on Delaware and New-York’s laws, which govern most of the publicly traded
companies in the US. In addition, a reference is made to federal jurisprudence on PCV. Federal PCV law is applied when a
particular federal statute or policy is involved in a case.
117 Phillip I. Blumberg, Accountability of Multinational Corporations: The Barriers Presented by Concepts of the Corporate
Juridical Entity, 24 HASTINGS INT'L & COMP. L. REV. 297, 302-03 (2000) (arguing that courts have never paused to consider
whether the doctrine of limited liability should be extended to shield parent corporations from the debts of their subsidiaries.
Rather, they automatically “applied concepts and policies designed to separate investors from liability for the risks of the business
to protect as well each of the upper-tier companies of the enterprise from liability for the debts incurred by their lower-tier
subsidiaries in conducting the common business of the group”).
118 In Grayson v. R.B. Ammon and Associates, Inc., the Court of Appeals of Louisiana held that when clear and convincing
evidence demonstrates the existence of a single business enterprise, courts can pierce the veil between the entities forming the
enterprise. Grayson v. R.B. Ammon and Associates, Inc., 778 So. 2d 1, 15 (La. App. 1st Cir. 2000), writ denied, 782 So. 2d 1026
(La. 2001), and writ denied, 782 So. 2d 1027 (La. 2001). In the mid 80’s, Texas courts advanced a theory by which plaintiffs
were allowed to pierce the veil of affiliated corporations which have “integrated their assets to achieve a common business
purpose (Paramount Petroleum Corp. v. Taylor Rental Center, 712 S.W.2d 534 (1986)).” However, in 2008 the Supreme Court
abrogated the theory, saying it was inconsistent with Texas veil-piercing laws (see SSP Partners v. Gladstrong Investments (USA)
Corp., 275 S.W.3d 444, 455 (Tex. 2008)). Following the SSP Partners decision, a party seeking to impose parent’s liability must
show (i) that the persons or entities upon whom a claimant seeks to impose liability are alter egos of the debtor, and (ii) that the
corporate fiction was used for illegitimate purposes, i.e., to perpetrate fraud. See Tryco Enters., Inc. v. Robinson, 390 S.W.3d 497
(Tex.App.– Houston 2012, pet. dism’d).
119 See, Glenn v. Wagner, 329 S.E.2d 326, 331 (N.C. 1985).
In other jurisdictions, courts consider parent-subsidiary cases under the general corporate veil piercing framework,
with no reference to an overarching enterprise theory.120 Nonetheless, unique features of corporate groups are
considered under the general framework.121 While full ownership of stocks by the parent is not a dispositive fact, nor
is common identity of the parent's and the subsidiary's officers and directors,122 when abusive practices are also
present, courts will be more inclined to pierce the veil between the parent and the subsidiary. Important factors
considered by the courts are control of day-to-day operations and managerial decision-making. Misrepresentation of
the corporate structure may also warrant intra-group veil piercing.123 Other factors considered by courts in corporate
group veil piercing cases are unfair intra-enterprise transactions, excessive dividends, wrongful conduct in the
performance of contracts (e.g., when the parent depletes the subsidiary's assets to the point that the subsidiary cannot
satisfactorily perform its contract obligations), and commingling or shuffling of assets.124
2) Variety of factors considered by in veil piercing cases
Both Federal and state courts apply an array of standards, tests, and theories in adjudicating veil piercing claims.
There are essentially two leading frameworks: the alter-ego theory and the instrumentality theory. The alter-ego
framework contains three steps for concluding that liability should be imposed on the owner: “(1) Control, not mere
majority or complete stock control, but complete domination, not only of finances but of policy and business practice
in respect to the transaction attacked so that the corporate entity as to this transaction had at the time no separate mind,
will or existence of its own; and (2) Such control must have been used by the defendant to commit fraud or wrong, to
perpetrate the violation of a statutory or other positive legal duty, or dishonest and unjust act in contravention of
plaintiff's legal rights; and (3) The aforesaid control and breach of duty must proximately cause the injury or unjust
loss complained of.”125 The instrumentality framework includes a two-part analysis: (1) that there be such unity of
interest and ownership that the separate personalities of the corporation and the individual [shareholders] no longer
exist [and the corporate entity is a mere instrumentality for advancing the personal interests of the owner]; and (2)
that, if the acts are treated as those of the corporation alone, an inequitable result will follow.”126
Most US courts follow a two/three prong analysis based on either of these theories or a combination of them. A widely
accepted synthesis was offered in an influential book by Frederick J. Powell in 1931. The Powell test, while
formulated to address parent-subsidiary relationship, influenced many US jurisdictions and has been adopted regularly
by courts in general veil piercing cases. It contain three prongs: “(1) the ‘alter ego,’ or ‘mere instrumentality’ test,
120 See, e.g., Mesler v. Bragg Management Co., 39 Cal. 3d 290, 216 Cal. Rptr. 443, 702 P.2d 601 (1985). See also Miller, (1998),
at 86 (claiming that as a general rule the business risk of multi intra-firm incorporation is limited on an entity-by-entity basis.)
121 Berkey v. Third Ave. Ry. Co., 155 N.E. 58 (N.Y. 1926).
122 For example, in United States v. Bestfoods, 524 U.S. 51, 61-62, (1998) the U.S. Supreme Court discussed parent corporations’
liability for environmental problems caused by their subsidiaries under the Comprehensive Environmental Response,
Compensation and Liability Act. The court rejected the notion that parents should incur liability for violations made by their
subsidiaries merely for having “actual control” of the subsidiary. It further noted that “it is hornbook law that the exercise of the
‘control’ which stock ownership gives to the stockholders ... will not create liability beyond the assets of the subsidiary. That
‘control’ includes the election of directors, the making of by-laws ... and the doing of all other acts incident to the legal status of
stockholders. Nor will a duplication of some or all of the directors or executive officers be fatal”. Ultimately, the court held that
liability will be imposed only under the narrow circumstances when the parent could be viewed as operating a subsidiary's facility.
123 Quarles v. Fuqua Indus., Inc., 504 F.2d 1358, 1364 (10th Cir. 1974) (establishing a standard of domination of day to business
decisions to pierce the veil between a parent and its subsidiary). Example of such level of domination was present in McKinney
v. Gannett Co. (817 F.2d 659 (10th Cir. 1987)). In McKinney, a publisher of a newspaper brought action against the parent of the
direct owner of the newspaper for alleged breach of employment contract. The Court of Appeals for the 10th Circuit ruled in favor
of the publisher by holding that dominion in this case was virtually complete and was moreover used for improper purposes. It
was found, inter alia, that in addition to complete stock ownership, the parent controlled the subsidiary’s board of directors,
treated the subsidiary as a division with little operating control, that all revenues were paid to the parent, all expenditures were
approved by the parent, and that the parent had in fact directly negotiated, drafted, and breached the employment contract at issue
although it was signed by the subsidiary.
124 FMC Finance Corp. v. Murphree (632 F.2d 413, 423 (5th Cir. 1980) (“[w]hen the shareholder or affiliate, however, engages
in conduct likely to create in the creditor the reasonable expectation that he is extending credit to an economic entity larger than
the corporation he actually contracted with, and the creditor reasonably relies to his detriment on his reasonable belief concerning
who or what he was dealing with, then the corporate veil can be pierced”). See also Kurt A. Strasser, Piercing the Veil in Corporate
Groups, 37 CONN. L. REV. 637, 652-54 (2005).
125 Consumer's Co-op. of Walworth County v. Olsen, 419 N.W.2d 211, 217-218 (Wis. 1988).
126 Consumer's Co-op., 419 N.W.2d 211, at 217-218 (footnote 5). Also see, Fontana Builders, Inc. v. Assurance Co. of Am., 882
N.W.2d 398, 414 (Wis. 2016), reconsideration denied (Sept. 12, 2016).
requiring that the subsidiary be completely under the control and domination of the parent, (2) the ‘fraud or wrong’
or ‘injustice’ test, requiring that the defendant parent's conduct in using the subsidiary have been somehow unjust,
fraudulent, or wrongful towards the plaintiff, and (3) the ‘unjust loss or injury’ test requiring that the plaintiff actually
have suffered some harm as a result of the conduct of the defendant parent.”127
In considering the different tests, courts weigh a wide range of factors. Among them are (1) undercapitalization; (2)
commingling of corporate and personal affairs; (3) disregard for corporate formalities; (4) fraud/misrepresentation;
(5) unfair/unjust conduct; (6) owner control/dominance; (7) Dysfunctional management; (8) whether incorporation
was made to avoid legal duties or debts of other entities; and (9) assumption of risk by creditor.128
3) Availability of veil piercing outside of bankruptcy cases
Bankruptcy is not a prerequisite, but bankruptcy and insolvency are relevant factors under the general court’s
analysis.129 Some courts, nonetheless, employ an “exhaustion rule” under which creditors may not recover from the
parent or its stockholders until they have exhausted their legal remedy against corporation, unless they show that such
remedy was impossible or would have been useless. Use of the “exhaustion rule” is more common in federal courts
in New York and Washing ton, D.C.130
4) Availability of veil piercing in the absence of fraudulent behavior or misconduct
Most state courts insist on a proof of some form of abuse or wrong committed by the owner before piercing the
corporate veil. Under the common two/three prong analyses veil piercing is frequently associated with intentional acts
of fraud. Nonetheless, other misleading conducts could trigger veil piercing as well.131 While some states such as
Delaware and Maryland strictly require a showing of a fraudulent behavior, other states that opt for a more liberal
approach such as Tennessee and Oregon settle for milder forms of misconduct.
5) Empirical data132
Corporate veil piercing rates range from 35% to 49% of the total claim, but the rates and the number of cases examined
vary across studies. Average veil piercing rate for corporate groups is 20%, and the U.S. has seen the largest number
of veil piercing cases.
3. Bibliography
Primary sources
Adams v. Cape Indus. 2 W.L.R. 657 (C.A.1990)
Aluminum Co of Canada v Toronto (1944) 3 DLR 609
Berkey v. Third Ave. Ry. Co., 155 N.E. 58 (N.Y. 1926)
Bluecorp Pty Ltd (in liq) v ANZ Executors and Trustee Co Ltd (1995) 18 ACSR 566
Briggs v James Hardie & Co Pty, (1989) 16 NSWLR 549
Chatterley v. Omnico 485 P.2d 667 (Utah 1971)
127 Presser, 2017, § 1:6.
128 For a discussion of the different factors see, John H. Matheson, Why Courts Pierce: An Empirical Study of Piercing the
Corporate Veil, 7 BERKELEY BUS. L.J. 1 (2010) (provides empirical examination of the piercing factors); Vandekerckhove, 2007,
at 82 (citing Powell’s “laundry list” of factors to be examined by courts in veil piercing cases); Cathy S. Krendl & James R.
Krendl, Piercing the Corporate Veil: Focusing the Inquiry, 55 DENVER L.J. 1, 52-55 (1978) (citing factors considered by courts).
129 Strasser, 2005, at 654-55 (justifying intra-group veil piercing in circumstances when the parent depletes the subsidiary from
assets thus causing it to become insolvent).
130 See, e.g., Eskimo Pie Corp. v. Whitelawn Dairies, Inc., 266 F. Supp. 79, 82 (S.D.N.Y. 1967); Vuitch v. Furr, 482 A.2d 811,
819 (D.C. 1984).
131 Blumberg, 2004; Miller, 1998.
132 A number of studies, published in recent decades, engaged in empirical analysis of veil piercing in US courts. The data
provided in this table is based upon the following scholarship: John H. Matheson, Why Courts Pierce: An Empirical Study of
Piercing the Corporate Veil, 7 BERKELEY BUS. L.J. 1 (2010); Robert B. Thompson, Piercing the Corporate Veil: An Empirical
Study, 76 CORNELL L. REV., 1036 (1991); C. Hodge & Andrew B. Sachs, Empirical Study, Piercing the Mist: Bringing the
Thompson Study into the 1990s, 43 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 341 (2008); Peter B. Oh, Veil-Piercing, 89 TEXAS L. REV. 81 (2010);
John H. Matheson, The Modern Law of Corporate Groups: An Empirical Study of Piercing the Corporate Veil in the Parent-
Subsidiary Context, 87 N.C. L. REV. 1091, 1093-95 (2009).
Code de commerce (2010) (France)
Code des sociétés (updated ver. May 7, 2012) (Belgium)
Commissioner of Land Tax v Theosophical Foundation Pty Ltd. (1966) 67 SR (NSW) 70
Companies Law of the People's Republic of China (2014)
Conseil de la Santé (Montréal) v City of Montréal (1994) 3 SCR 29
Creasy v. Breachwood Motors, Ltd., (1993] BCLC
Eagle Air, Inc. v. Corroon & Black Dawson & Co. 648 P.2d 1000 (Alaska 1982)
FMC Finance Corp. v. Murphree, 632 F.2d 413 (5th Cir. 1980)
German Stock Corporation Act (Aktiengesetz)
In Re Polly 2 All E.R. 433 (1996)
Kinney Shoe Corp. v. Polan, 939 F.2d 209 (4th Cir. 1991)
Laya v. Erin Homes Inc., 352 S.E.2d 93 (W.Va. 1986)
Le Car GmbH v Dusty Roads Holdings Ltd., 22 Carswel INS 138 (S.C. 2004)
Lowendahl v. Balt. & Ohio R.R., 287 N.Y.S. 62, 272 N.Y. 360 (1936)
M. Germain, V. Magnier, Traite de droit commercial-Les societes commerciales, L.G.D.J. (2009)
McKinney v. Gannett Co., 817 F.2d 659 (10th Cir. 1987)
Merchandise Transport Ltd. v. British Transport Commission, 2 Q.B. 173 (1962)
NJA 1947 s. 647 (Sweden)
Ontario Ltd. v. Fleischer, 56 O.R.3d 417 (Ont. C.A. 2001)
Prest v Petrodel Resources Ltd., UKSC 34 (2013)
Re A Company Ltd., 205 BCLC 333 (C.A. 1985)
Salomon v. Salomon & Co., A.C. 22 (1897)
Sea-Land Services Inc. v. Pepper Source, 941 F.2d 519 (7th Cir. 1991)
Sharrment Pty Ltd. V. Official Trustee in Bankruptcy, 82 ALR 530 (1988)
Smith, Stone and Knight Ltd. V. Birmingham Corporation, 4 All ER 116 (1939)
United States v. Milwaukee Refrigerator Transit Co., 142 F. 247, 249 (C.C.E.D. Wis. 1905)
Walkovszky v. Carlton, 18 N.Y.2d 414 (N.Y. 1966)
Dutch Civil Code, Book 2 (Holland)
Osby-Pannan A/B v. Las Verkoopmaatschappij BV, no.443 (N.J. Supreme Court 1982)
Secondary sources
Alting, C. (1995) Piercing the corporate veil in American and German law - Liability of individuals and entities: A
comparative view, Tulsa Journal of Comparative and International Law, 2:187.
Anderson, H. (2009) Piercing the veil on corporate groups in Australia: The case for reform, Melbourne University
Law Review, 33:333.
Backer, L.C., (2002) Comparative corporate law: United States, European Union, China, and Japan: cases and
materials, Durham, NC: Carolina Academic Press.
Ballantine, H.W. (1925) Separate entity of parent and subsidiary corporations, California Law Review, 14.
Ballantine, H.W. (1946) Ballantine on corporations, Chicago, IL: Callaghan & Co.
Blumberg, P.L. (1985) Limited liability and corporate groups, Journal of Corporation Law, 11:573.
Blumberg, P.L. (2004) The transformation of modem corporation Law: The law of corporate groups, Connecticut
Law Review, 37:605.
Cataldo, B.F. (1953) Limited liability with one-man companies and subsidiary corporations, Law and
Contemporary Problems, 18(4):473-504.
Cheng, T.K. (2011) The corporate veil doctrine revisited: A comparative study of the English and the U.S. corporate
veil doctrines, Boston College International and Comparative Law Review, 34:329.
Clarke, R.C. (1986) Corporate law, Boston, MA: Little, Brown and Company.
Dobson, J.M. (1986) Lifting the veil in four countries: The law of Argentina, England, France and the United States,
International and Comparative Law Quarterly, 35:839.
Douglas, W.O., Shanks, C.M. (1929) Insulation from liability through subsidiary corporations, Yale Law Journal,
39:193
Easterbrook, F.H., Fischel D.R. (1985) Limited liability and the corporation, The University of Chicago Law
Review, 52(89).
Fu, T. (1993) Legal person in China, American Journal of Comparative Law, 41:261.
Hargovan, A., Harris, J. (2007) Piercing the corporate veil in Canada: A comparative analysis. Company Lawyer,
28(2):58-62.
Hargovan, A., Harris, J. (2011) Cutting the Gordian knot of corporate law: revisiting veil Piercing in corporate
groups, Australian Journal of Corporate Law, 26:39.
Heintzman, T.G., Kain, B. (2013) Through the looking glass: Recent developments in piercing the corporate veil,
Banking and Finance Law Review, 28:525.
Hodge, L.C., Sachs, A.B. (2008) Empirical study, piercing the mist: Bringing the Thompson study into the 1990s,
Wake Forest Law Review, 43:341.
Hofstetter, K. (1990) Parent responsibility for subsidiary corporations: Evaluating European trends, International
and Comparative Law Quarterly, 39(3):577.
Horton, R.A. (1966) Liability of corporation for torts of subsidiary, American Law Reports, 7:1343.
Huang, H. (2012) Piercing the corporate veil in China: Where is it now and where is it heading, American Journal
of Comparative Law, 60:743.
Landers, J.M. (1975) A unified approach to parent, subsidiary, and affiliate questions in bankruptcy, The University
of Chicago Law Review, 42: 589.
Lezcano, Jose Maria (2015) Piercing the corporate veil in Latin American jurisprudence: A comparison with the
Anglo-American method: Routledge
Liability of a corporation for acts of a subsidiary or affiliate (1958), Harvard Law Review, 71:1122.
Matheson, J.H. (2008) The modern law of corporate groups: An empirical study of piercing the corporate veil in the
parent-subsidiary context. North Carolina Law Review, 87:1091.
Matheson, J.H. (2010) Why courts pierce: An empirical study of piercing the corporate veil, Berkeley Business Law
Journal, 7:1.
Miller, S.K. (1998) Piercing the corporate veil among affiliated companies in the European community and in the
U.S.: A comparative analysis of U.S., German, and U.K. veil piercing approaches, American Business Law
Journal, 36:73.
OECD (1980) Responsibility of Parent Companies for their Subsidiaries.
Oh, P.B. (2010) Veil-piercing, Texas Law Review, 89:81.
Oh, P.B. (2013) Veil-piercing unbound, Boston University Law Review, 93:89.
Pardinas, C.M. (1991) The enigma of the legal liability of transnational corporations, Suffolk Transnational Law
Journal, 14:405
Posner, R.A. (1975) The rights of creditors of affiliated corporations, The University of Chicago Law Review, 43:
499.
Presser, S.B. (2015) Piercing the corporate veil - Database (Westlaw), Thomson Reuters.
Ramberg, R. (2011) Piercing the corporate veil: Comparing the United States with Sweden, New England Journal
of International and Comparative Law, 17:159.
Ramsay, I.M., Noakes, D.B. (2001) Piercing the corporate veil in Australia, Company and Securities Law
Journal, 19:250.
Ramseyer, J.M., Nakazato, M. (1999) Japanese law: An economic approach, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago
Press.
Schall, A. (2016) The new law of piercing the corporate veil in the UK, European Company and Financial Law
Review, 13(4): 549.
Schwartz, J.A. (2008) Piercing the corporate veil of an alien parent for jurisdictional purposes: A proposal for a
standard that comports with due process, California Law Review 96: 731.
Shishido, Z. (2014) Enterprise law: contracts, markets, and laws in the US and Japan, Northampton, MA: Edward
Elgar Publishing, Inc.
Siems, M.M., Cabrelli, D. (2013) Comparative company law: A case-based approach, Portland, OR: Hart
Publishing.
Squire, R. (2011) Strategic liability in the corporate group, The University of Chicago Law Review, 78:605.
Strasser, K.A. (2005) Piercing the veil in corporate groups, Connecticut Law Review. 37:637-641.
Thompson, R.B. (1991) Piercing the corporate veil: An empirical study, Cornell Law Review, 76:1036.
Vandekerckhove K. (2007) Piercing the corporate veil. The Netherlands: Kluwer Law International.
Wu, M. (2007) Piercing China's corporate veil: Open questions from the new company law, Yale Law Journal,
117:328.
Supplementary Appendix B: Formal Model
In this Appendix, we develop a simple model to inform our empirical analysis. In the model, headquarters
located in a ‘core’unit must decide whether to invest in a safe or risky project. The core unit produces
large, certain pro…ts Core >0. The safe project consists of further investment in the core unit and yields
pro…ts Rwith certainty. The risky project involves the creation of a new experimental unit which can
produce positive pro…ts but can also yield losses. In the Alphabet group, the core unit would be Google
(the search engine) and the experimental unit could be Verily (biotechnology and medical instruments)
or Waymo (self-driving cars). Our goal is to understand how enterprise liability— the extent to which
headquarters is insulated from losses in the experimental unit— a¤ects project choice as well as the legal
form and autonomy of the experimental unit.
The model has three stages.
1. Project choice. In stage 1, headquarters chooses between the safe and the risky project. If
headquarters chooses the safe project, then it gets C ore +Rand the game ends. If headquarters
chooses the risky project, then the experimental unit is created.
2. Legal form. In stage 2, headquarters chooses a legal form for the experimental unit. Headquarters
can set up the new unit as an unincorporated division of the core unit, or can incorporate the unit. If
the unit is incorporated, then it becomes a wholly-owned subsidiary of the core unit. Incorporation
involves a …xed cost K > 0. This may include costs of complying with the law (e.g., legal costs,
external auditing), additional taxes, the cost of hiring new directors, and so on.1The advantage of
incorporation is that a legally independent subsidiary may bene…t from limited liability. Because the
experimental unit is owned by the core unit, these bene…ts are more likely to accrue when enterprise
liability is weak.
3. Implementation. In stage 3, the experimental unit must select a course of action. This stage
follows closely Aghion and Tirole’s (1997) model of formal and real authority in organizations.2
First, both headquarters and the experimental unit’s manager gather information about the payo¤
consequences of di¤erent actions. Then the manager makes a recommendation to headquarters,
1Less direct incorporation costs may include the fact that a manager with a CEO title may demand higher pay, or the
fact that resource redeployment from one unit to another may be hindered when units are legally independent.
2There are many models of authority and delegation in organization, including Alonso, Dessein and Matouschek (2008),
Alonso and Matouschek (2008), Baker, Gibbons and Murphy (1999), Dessein (2002) and Melumad, Mookherjee and Reichel-
stein (1995). We use Aghion and Tirole (1997) to capture the simple idea that headquarters is likely to monitor more, and
grant a manager less discretion, when the consequences of bad managerial decisions are more serious.
1
which headquarters can either accept or reject. If the recommendation is rejected, then headquarters
selects a course of action, which the experimental unit must implement. We interpret the probability
that headquarters rejects the manager’s recommendation as an inverse measure of the experimental
unit’s autonomy.
Below we describe the model in greater detail and solve the game backwards starting from stage 3.
Implementation. In stage 3, the experimental unit must implement one of n+ 1 actions, indexed by
i= 0;1; :::; n,n3. Each action iis associated with a pair (Vi; vi), where Viis the payo¤ that accrues
to headquarters and viis the payo¤ or private bene…t that accrues to the manager if action iis selected.
Action 0 yields a known payo¤ (0;0) to headquarters and the manager and can therefore be interpreted
as ‘doing nothing’. The consequences of actions i= 1; :::; n appear identical ex ante to headquarters and
the manager and can only be discovered by exerting information gathering e¤ort. Ex ante, the players
only know that, with probability , two of these actions yield (B; b)and (L; 0) and the n2other
actions yield (M; m). With probability 1, however, two actions yield (B; 0) and (L; b)and the
n2other actions yield (M; m).B,b,L,M,mare all strictly positive. We assume that n,Mand
mare ‘large enough’that, with no additional information about the consequences of these actions, both
headquarters and the manager prefer action 0 to randomly picking one of the other actions.
The parameter can be interpreted as a measure of congruence between the preferences of headquar-
ters and those of the manager. Suppose in fact that the manager perfectly knew the consequences of
selecting each of the possible actions i= 0;1; :::; n. Then, with probability , the manager would select
the action yielding (B; b), which is also the headquarters’ preferred action. However, with probability
1, he would select the action yielding (L; b), which would give headquarters a negative payo¤.
By gathering information, the headquarters and the manager can learn the consequences associated
with actions. Let ebe the information gathering e¤ort exerted by the manager, and Ethe information
gathering e¤ort exerted by headquarters. The cost of e¤ort is 1
2ce2for the manager and 1
2CE2for
headquarters. By exerting e¤ort e, we assume that the manager learns the payo¤s associated with all the
actions with probability e, and with probability 1ehe learns nothing. Similarly, by exerting e¤ort E,
headquarters learns the payo¤s associated with all the actions with probability Eand, with probability
1E, it learns nothing. These probabilities are independent.
We adopt an incomplete contracting approach (Grossman and Hart, 1986) and assume that actions
cannot be described and contracted on ex ante. Players interact as follows. First, the manager and head-
quarters simultaneously and non-cooperatively choose e¤ort levels eand E. Then the manager proposes a
2
course of action. Headquarters can reject the manager’s proposal and pick a di¤erent action, which is then
implemented. Aghion and Tirole (1997) refer to this case as ‘integration’or ‘P-formal authority’. Head-
quarters always retains the formal authority to select an action, but the manager can enjoy real authority
because headquarters is uninformed. Because of the timing, we can interpret the manager’s proposal as
an ‘initiative’ originating from the experimental unit, and the headquarters’ information gathering and
evaluation as ‘monitoring’.
Let B (1 )L0and suppose that, when indi¤erent between two actions, players always pick
the one that maximizes the utility of the other player. Given these assumptions, headquarters’expected
payo¤ from the experimental unit is
Exp =EB + (1 E)e[B (1 )L]1
2CE2(1)
and the manager’expected payo¤ is
UExp =Eb + (1 E)eb 1
2ce2:(2)
To obtain (1) and (2), note that, if headquarters is informed (which occurs with probability E), then it
will always select the action yielding B(and b in expectation to the manager). However, if headquarters
is uninformed and the manager is informed (which occurs with probability (1 E)e), the manager will
recommend the project that yields bto himself and B (1 )Lin expectation to headquarters. Of
course, headquarters can reject this recommendation and obtain 0 by selecting project 0. However, because
we assumed that B (1 )L0, headquarters will always optimally rubber-stamp the manager’s
recommendation if uniformed. Finally, if both headquarters and the manager are uninformed, project 0
yielding 0 to both will be selected.
In equilibrium, headquarters maximizes (1) with respect to E, and the manager maximizes (2) with
respect to e. Assuming interior solutions, this yields
e=b
c(1 E) = b
c 1Bb
c[B (1 )L]
Cb
c[B (1 )L]!(3)
and
E=Bb
c[B (1 )L]
Cb
c[B (1 )L]:(4)
Intuitively, an increase in headquarters’monitoring Ereduces managerial initiative because headquarters
is better informed and less likely to simply rubber-stamp the manager’s proposal (that is, the manager
has less real authority). From the point of view of headquarters, reducing monitoring has the advantage
of encouraging managerial initiative, but comes at the cost of loss of control.
3
The probability that a manager’s proposal is rejected, conditional on being made, is E(1 ). Thus,
it is natural to interpret E(1 )as an inverse measure of managerial autonomy. The smaller E(1 )
is, the greater the autonomy of the experimental unit from headquarters. Because eand Eare inversely
related, in equilibrium greater autonomy will be positively related to greater managerial initiative.
Legal form. In stage 2, headquarters chooses a legal form for the experimental unit. If the experimental
unit is incorporated, then it becomes a subsidiary of the core unit. Because the organization’s assets are
divided into two distinct …rms, we refer to this case as asset partitioning. Alternatively, the experimental
unit remains an unincorporated internal division of the core …rm. We explore the potential of asset
partitioning to compartmentalize and mitigate downward risk.
The cost of incorporating the unit is K > 0. The advantage is that headquarters may enjoy limited
liability protection if the subsidiary makes losses. The magnitude of this advantage depends on the
strength of enterprise liability; that is, the propensity of courts to hold the whole group liable for the
obligations of one of its subsidiaries.
Let Ldenote the expected losses incurred by headquarters if the ‘bad’ action is selected, and Lthe
maximum losses. Let
Exp (L)be headquarters’expected payo¤ from the experimental unit when eand
Eare chosen optimally and expected losses are L. That is,
Exp (L)is equal to (1) with (E; e)replacing
(E; e).
If the experimental unit is not incorporated and the bad action is selected, then headquarters incurs
the full losses L. This is because the pro…ts of the core business are large enough to cover these losses:
Core L. Thus, headquarters’expected payo¤ from the unit is
Exp (L), since L=L.
If however the experimental unit is incorporated, losses may be externalized. The extent to which
headquarters is shielded from losses depends on the propensity of courts to pierce the corporate veil.
Let 2[0;1] be the probability that courts pierce the corporate veil. Thus, a higher means stronger
enterprise liability or, equivalently, weaker limited liability protection for headquarters. If the experimental
unit is incorporated, then with probability the losses Lare paid in full by headquarters; however, with
probability 1, headquarters pays 0. Thus, the expected payo¤ that accrues to headquarters when
running an incorporated experimental unit is
Exp (L)K, since L=L.
Headquarters incorporate the experimental unit if the cost of incorporation Kis lower than or equal
to the expected gains from greater limited liability protection:
K
Exp (L)
Exp (L):(5)
Note that headquarters’pro…ts when the experimental unit is incorporated decrease with the strength of
4
enterprise liability: d
Exp (L)=d < 0.3We assume that Kis low enough this condition holds for some
. Thus, there exists a threshold T2(0;1) such that, for all T, headquarters incorporates the
experimental unit, and for all > T, headquarters does not incorporate the experimental unit.
Project choice. In stage 1, headquarters invests either in a safe project yielding pro…t Ror in a risky
project (the experimental unit). We have that, if T, headquarters chooses the experimental unit if
Exp (L)KR: (6)
If > T, headquarters chooses the experimental unit if
Exp (L)R: (7)
Unsurprisingly, weaker enterprise liability (lower ) increases headquarters’incentives to invest in the
risky project. Note that, as declines, a new subsidiary is more likely to be created (equation (6) is more
likely to hold), because incorporation allows headquarters to reap the bene…ts of limited liability. Group
pro…ts also tend to increase, since
Exp (L)KR. Thus, weaker enterprise liability shifts corporate
group behavior towards more risky projects, more subsidiaries (greater asset partitioning), and greater
expected pro…ts (because losses are to some extent externalized).
0.1 Empirical predictions of the model
We are now ready to state the main empirical predictions of the model.
Hypothesis 1 (Firm boundaries). Weaker enterprise liability promotes asset partitioning. Units are
more likely to be incorporated when is low.
This follows immediately from equation (5).
Hypothesis 2 (Internal organization). Weaker enterprise liability promotes decentralization. Sub-
sidiary managers enjoy greater autonomy from headquarters when is low.
3To see this, totally di¤erentiate
Exp (L)with respect to . Note that
d
Exp (L)
d =@
Exp (L)
@E
@E
@
| {z }
=0
+@
Exp (L)
@e
| {z }
>0
@e
@
|{z}
<0
+@
Exp (L)
@
| {z }
<0
<0:
@
Exp (L)
@E= 0 follows from the …rst order conditions. @
Exp (L)
@e>0and @
Exp (L)
@ <0follow from inspection of (1).
@e
@ <0follows from inspection of (3).
5
From (3) and (4), it is clear that headquarters monitors more, and the manager displays less initiative,
when potential losses Lare larger: @E
@L >0and @ e
@L <0. This also implies that managers enjoy greater
autonomy from headquarters when the experimental unit is incorporated (L=L) and enterprise liability
is weak (lower ), since @(E(1))
@()>0. Intuitively, when enterprise liability is weak, headquarters are
not likely to be held liable for their subsidiaries’losses, and monitoring is reduced. Subsidiary managers
enjoy greater real authority.
Hypothesis 3 (Corporate group growth). Weaker enterprise liability encourages riskier investment,
the creation of new subsidiaries, and spurs corporate group growth.
This follows from equation (6). As decreases, new subsidiaries are more likely to be created, the riskiness
of the investment increases, but corporate group pro…ts also increase (from Rto
Exp (L)K).
References
[1] Aghion P, Tirole J. 1997. Formal and real authority in organizations. Journal of Political Economy,
105(1):1–29.
[2] Grossman SJ, Hart OD. 1986. The costs and bene…ts of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral
integration. Journal of political economy 94(4): 691–719.
6
Supplementary Appendix C Variable Definitions
Table C1: Variable Definitions
Variable Definition Source
PCV score A country-level measure of enterprise liability based
on evaluation of legal provisions across sixteen coun-
tries in Americas, Asia, and Europe. It is a com-
posite measure based on scores (0-5) assigned to i)
application of enterprise approach, ii) factors con-
sidered in veil piercing cases, iii) veil piercing out-
side of bankruptcy cases, iv) veil piercing outside of
fraudulent behaviors, and v) empirical data on veil
piercing. The weights assigned to the five criteria
for evaluation are 0.45, 0.25, 0.1, 0.15, and 0.05, re-
spectively, and the weights reflect the importance of
each criterion in determining enterprise liability.
Legal references, cor-
porate law textbooks,
Westlaw database, law
review article, West-
law’s Keycite and Lex-
isNexis’s Shepard
Industry
downside risk
An industry-level measure of downside risk com-
puted as the share of firms operating in a given in-
dustry (3-digit SIC) that experience more than 50%
drop in revenues in a given year.
Standard & Poor’s
CRSP / Compustat
Corruption A measure of regional corruption reflecting the share
of survey respondents who totally agreed or tended
to agree that there is corruption in regional institu-
tions.
Eurobarometer,
NUTS2 classifica-
tion for EU countries,
cross-sectional data for
2008
Managerial
experience
Computed as the annual average age of executives
and senior managers of group subsidiaries.
Orbis historical publi-
cation, annual data
Table C2: Variable Definitions (Continued)
Variable Definition Source
Knowledge
complexity
A patent-based measure of complexity of firms’
knowledge computed as the average generality of
patents produced by firms in each industry (3-digit
industry) for each year, where generality of a patent
is calculated as 1 minus Herfindahl–Hirschman In-
dex (HHI) based on CPC classes of the patents that
the focal patent cites.
Standard & Poor’s
CRSP / Compustat,
Kogan et al. (2017),
PatentsView.org
Family man-
agers
The share of corporate group’s subsidiaries that
are managed by a family member of a corporate
group’s shareholder. A family manager is identified
by matching the last names of the top and senior
managers of each subsidiary to the last names of the
corporate group’s shareholders who own at least 5%
of headquarters stocks.
Orbis historical publi-
cation, annual data
Board mem-
ber interlock
The share of corporate group’s subsidiaries with a
board member who is also a board member of the
corporate parent.
Orbis historical publi-
cation, annual data
Wholly-
owned sub-
sidiaries
The share of corporate group’s subsidiaries that are
wholly owned by the corporate parent.
Orbis historical publi-
cation, annual data
Parent-
subsidiary
name sharing
The share of corporate group’s subsidiaries that op-
erate under the same or, partially the same, name as
the corporate parent.
Orbis historical publi-
cation, annual data
Supplementary Appendix D Additional Tables
Table D1: First-stage Results for 2SLS Analysis
for Corporate Group Investment and Growth
Dependent variable: ln(Numb. subsidiaries)
(1) (2)
Investment Growth
PCV score x Industry downside risk 0.341 0.623
(0.029) (0.028)
Country PCV score -0.183 -0.213
(0.021) (0.012)
Industry downside risk 0.004 -0.213
(0.048) (0.046)
ln(Country GDP) 0.219 0.249
(0.012) (0.008)
ln(Country unemployment rate) 0.046 0.030
(0.007) (0.006)
Country EPL 0.050 0.276
(0.151) (0.121)
Country stock market development 0.082 -0.003
(0.032) (0.016)
ln(Group-sub country-industry revenues)t−10.036 0.079
(0.001) (0.002)
Cragg-Donald F-stat 255.2 903.5
Kleibergen-Paap F-stat 137.9 478.9
Legal origin dummies Yes Yes
F-statistic 140.1 158.3
Year dummies Yes Yes
Corporate group dummies Yes Yes
Observations 534,154 606,091
R-squared 0.75 0.75
Notes: The table presents the first-stage results for the instrumental
variable regressions presented in Table 7. Legal origin dummies in-
dicate the legal familes (English, French, German, and Scandinavian)
from which the country’s commercial laws are derived. Standard errors
are robust to heteroskedasticity and clustered at the corporate group-
subsidiary country-industry (3-digit SIC) level.
Table D2: Alternative Measures of PCV Score
Dependent variable: ln(Number of subsidiaries)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Excl. enterp. / Excl. divers. Excl. bankrupt. Excl. fraud. Excl. empir. Equally
econ. unity of factors case case data weighted
Country PCV score -0.108 -0.063 -0.052 -0.071 -0.060 -0.093
(0.005) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003)
ln(Country GDP) 0.052 0.058 0.063 0.066 0.064 0.055
(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
ln(Country unemployment rate) 0.001 -0.005 -0.002 -0.002 -0.001 0.003
(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
Country EPL -0.137 -0.020 -0.038 -0.056 -0.052 -0.109
(0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008)
Country stock market development -0.020 -0.011 -0.014 -0.016 -0.019 -0.026
(0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004)
ln(Group-sub country-industry revenues) 0.028 0.028 0.028 0.028 0.028 0.028
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Three-digit SIC dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Corporate group dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 2,702,307 2,702,307 2,702,307 2,702,307 2,702,307 2,702,307
R-squared 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.46
Notes: The table presents the relationship between enterprise liability and asset partitioning. The sample consists of corporate
groups at the country-industry-year level for years 2002 through 2014 and across sixteen countries. PCV scores are recalculated after
dropping each of the five criteria (columns 1-5) and also after dropping the weights used for the criteria (column 6). All columns
include legal origin dummies indicating the legal origin (English, French, German, or Scandinavian) from which each country’s
commercial laws are derived. Standard errors are robust to heteroskedasticity and clustered at the corporate group-subsidiary
country-industry level.
Table D3: Principal Components of PCV score
Dependent variable: ln(Number of subsidiaries)
(1) (2)
Principal Principal
components 1-3 components 1-4
Principal component 1 -0.013 -0.017
(0.002) (0.002)
Principal component 2 -0.031 -0.032
(0.002) (0.002)
Principal component 3 -0.016 -0.007
(0.004) (0.004)
Principal component 4 -0.015
(0.002)
ln(Country GDP) 0.051 0.048
(0.002) (0.002)
ln(Country unemployment rate) 0.001 0.002
(0.002) (0.002)
Country EPL -0.141 -0.118
(0.011) (0.011)
Country stock market development -0.019 -0.021
(0.004) (0.004)
ln(Group-sub country-industry revenues) 0.028 0.028
(0.000) (0.000)
Year dummies Yes Yes
Three-digit SIC dummies Yes Yes
Corporate group dummies Yes Yes
Observations 2,702,307 2,702,307
R-squared 0.46 0.46
Notes: The table presents the relationship between enterprise liability and
asset partitioning. The sample consists of corporate groups at the country-
industry-year level for years 2002 through 2014 across sixteen countries. Prin-
cipal components 1-4 are latent variables derived from the scores of the five
criteria underlying the Country PCV score. The Kaiser rule is followed, and
thus eigenvalue of 1 is set as the threshold in selecting relevant principal com-
ponents. All columns include legal origin dummies indicating the legal origin
(English, French, German, or Scandinavian) from which each country’s com-
mercial laws are derived. Standard errors are robust to heteroskedasticity
and clustered at the corporate group-subsidiary country-industry level.
Table D4: Other Robustness Tests
Dependent variable: ln(Number of subsidiaries) Number of subsidiaries
All Revenue Rev. decile Poisson Neg.
subs. polynom. dummies binomial
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Country PCV score -0.019 -0.060 -0.052 -0.080 -0.081
(0.002) (0.003) (0.003) (0.006) (0.006)
ln(Country GDP) 0.078 0.058 0.062 0.101 0.094
(0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.005) (0.004)
ln(Country unemployment rate) 0.023 -0.017 0.011 -0.051 -0.058
(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.009) (0.008)
Country EPL -0.100 -0.076 -0.071 0.016 -0.023
(0.006) (0.009) (0.009) (0.020) (0.016)
Country stock market development -0.017 -0.026 -0.023 -0.017 -0.023
(0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.007) (0.006)
ln(Group-sub country-industry revenues) 0.031 0.107 0.093
(0.000) (0.002) (0.001)
Group-sub country-industry revenues 0.000
(0.000)
Group-sub country-industry revenues2-0.000
(0.000)
Revenue decile dummies No No Yes No No
Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Three-digit SIC dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Corporate group dummies Yes No No No No
Observations 4,906,668 3,134,701 3,134,701 3,122,026 3,122,026
R-squared 0.43 0.46 0.49 - -
Notes: The table presents the relationship between enterprise liability and asset partitioning using al-
ternative samples, controls, and empirical methods. The sample consists of corporate groups at the
country-industry-year level for years 2002 through 2014 across sixteen countries. Column 1 includes
all subsidiaries of the corporate parent in our sample regardless of corporate parent’s ownership stakes.
Columns 2 and 3 include a sales polynomial and sales deciles, respectively. Columns 4 and 5 present
results based on Poisson and negative binomial regressions. All columns include legal origin dummies
indicating the legal origin (English, French, German, or Scandinavian) from which each country’s com-
mercial laws are derived. Standard errors are robust to heteroskedasticity and clustered at the corporate
group-subsidiary country-industry (3-digit SIC) level.