ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

Agency has received much attention in recent historical institutionalist theorizing of change processes, but remains largely disconnected from questions about mechanisms that stabilize institutions. To help fill this lacuna, the paper presents bricolage as one key mechanism through which actors stabilize an institutional setup. It suggests that institutions may be defended by keeping intact the institutional logic on which the incumbent coalition is based, but rearrange the salience of the ideational and institutional elements that make up the existing institutional setup. The empirical relevance of the argument is supported through a case analysis of a 1980-reform that could have changed the face of German corporatism, but never was, namely the policy of collective equity funds (Tariffonds). Through process tracing, we explain the fate of the reform with the effectiveness of a last-minute intervention based on a bricolage of the extant institutional logic.
Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at
https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=rjpp20
Journal of European Public Policy
ISSN: (Print) (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rjpp20
The other side of agency: bricolage and
institutional continuity
Martin B. Carstensen & Nils Röper
To cite this article: Martin B. Carstensen & Nils Röper (2021): The other side of
agency: bricolage and institutional continuity, Journal of European Public Policy, DOI:
10.1080/13501763.2021.1936128
To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/13501763.2021.1936128
Published online: 08 Jun 2021.
Submit your article to this journal
Article views: 32
View related articles
View Crossmark data
The other side of agency: bricolage and institutional
continuity
Martin B. Carstensen
a
and Nils Röper
b
a
Department of Social Science and Business, Roskilde University, Roskilde, Denmark;
b
Cluster
of Excellence, The Politics of Inequality, University of Konstanz, Konstanz, Germany
ABSTRACT
Agency has received much attention in recent historical institutionalist
theorizing of change processes, but remains largely disconnected from
questions about mechanisms that stabilize institutions. To help ll this
lacuna, the paper presents bricolage as one key mechanism through which
actors stabilize an institutional setup. It suggests that institutions may be
defended by keeping intact the institutional logic on which the incumbent
coalition is based, but rearrange the salience of the ideational and
institutional elements that make up the existing institutional setup. The
empirical relevance of the argument is supported through a case analysis of
a 1980-reform that could have changed the face of German corporatism, but
never was, namely the policy of collective equity funds (Tarionds). Through
process tracing, we explain the fate of the reform with the eectiveness of a
last-minute intervention based on a bricolage of the extant institutional logic.
KEYWORDS Agency; bricolage; Germany; historical institutionalism; institutional stability; reform
process
Introduction
New institutional analysis has greatly advanced our understanding of the
dynamics underlying the creation of public policy. Most importantly, it pro-
vided a much-needed corrective to the largely unmediated agency of
much behavioralism by oering a range of arguments for why patterns of
human interaction tend to stabilize over long period of times
(Hall & Taylor, 1996). Soon, however, serious questions were raised across
the three new institutionalisms, whether the focus on structure had left too
little room for agency (Schmidt, 2008). As a response, and similar to
debates in rational choice- and sociological institutionalism (Greif & Laitin,
2004; Lawrence & Suddaby, 2006), historical institutionalists have in recent
decades turned their attention to theorizing agency in explanations of insti-
tutional change (Emmenegger, 2021; Fioretos, Falleti, & Sheingate, 2016;
© 2021 Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group
CONTACT Martin B. Carstensen mcar@ruc.dk
JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN PUBLIC POLICY
https://doi.org/10.1080/13501763.2021.1936128
Gerschewski, 2021). Particularly fruitful has been the greater analytical
emphasis on the work perpetuated by actors to change institutions by shift-
ing their coalitional basis (e.g., Béland, 2009; Mahoney & Thelen, 2010; Streeck
& Thelen, 2005). Rather than assuming that institutions automatically
produce action, this body of scholarship suggests that institutions require
interpretation, which may over time lead to gradual, albeit signicant,
shifts in how an institution is practiced.
However, the progress made in injecting agency into accounts of insti-
tutional change so far remains unmatched in how historical institutionalist
scholarship theorizes institutional continuity. That is, in explanations of insti-
tutional continuity, historical institutionalism still relies on a conception of
path dependency as almost automatically produced by increasing returns
and with actors all but gone from theoretical (if not empirical) accounts of
institutional stability. This is not to say that the coalitional approach of histori-
cal institutionalism does not recognize that building coalitions depends on
continued work by agents for their stability (Mahoney & Thelen, 2010).
Early work by Pierson (1996) notably highlighted the importance of adapta-
bility for the stability of institutions. However, the notion that stabilization
requires agency what we call the other side of agency’–remains distinctly
undertheorized (see also Emmenegger, 2021).
Contributing to the broader eort of theorizing agency in institutional
stability and change, this paper conceptualizes what we argue is a key mech-
anism through which actors can stabilize institutions, namely bricolage of the
existing institutional logic to shore up support from the incumbent coalition.
The argument is based on an intuitive proposition: In a situation of pressure
on the coalition of incumbent actors, with key actors close to defecting from
the institutional setup (Culpepper, 2005), ideas are needed that may renew
support and refute competing narratives about the need for change. Since
the stability of the institutional setup rests on the coalitional support it
receives from incumbent supporters (Hall & Thelen, 2009), it is vital that argu-
ments mustered in its support breath new energy into the supporting
coalition without undermining the extant institutional logic and its power-
distributional implications (Hall, 2016). Given this balancing act, we
contend that bricolage here understood as a reorganization of ideational
and institutional elements from the existing institutional logic (see Campbell,
2004; Carstensen, 2011; Hannah, 2020)may work as a viable strategy in
defending the status quo. To do so eectively, requires that the recongured
institutional logic convinces incumbent actors about its continued problem-
solving capacity, distributional attractiveness, and normative acceptability
(see below).
To oer an initial plausibility probe of institutional bricolage as a mechan-
ism of institutional maintenance, we turn to the example of German Vermö-
genspolitik (wealth politics). In 1980, equity funds collectively managed by
2M. B. CARSTENSEN AND N. RÖPER
unions and employers (Tarrionds) all but passed into legislation. These col-
lective stock sharing schemes would have had the potential to change the
face of German corporatism by transforming corporate ownership patterns
over time and altering bargaining channels of industrial relations. We argue
that had it not been for the last-minute introduction of the ordoliberal idea
of open market access to the policy debate by the junior government
coalition partner The Free Democratic Party (FDP), Tarrionds would have
been introduced. Interestingly, we are not seeing here the use of a new
idea to defend the status quo. Rather we are witnessing a bricolage of the
existing institutional logic through the activation of an idea that belongs to
the same tradition on which the dominant approaches to wealth policy is
based, but never before applied in this specic context. Based on process
tracing that draws on archival research, media coverage and interviews
with insiders to the policy process, we show how the benets enjoyed by
incumbent actors including veto points (Mahoney & Thelen, 2010)or
increasing returns from the existing institutional setup (Pierson, 2000)did
not automatically prevent change. Instead, the coalitional foundation under-
lying institutions required active, strategic work to be maintained, particularly
as they were threatened by challengers of the status quo.
The paper is structured in the following way. First, we develop the concept
of bricolage in the context of institutional stabilization. Second, we present
our analysis of the policy of Tarionds. Finally, we conclude.
Bricolage and institutional stabilization
To see how a bricolage of the existing institutional logic may work as a stra-
tegic tool for actorseort to maintain institutional stability, it is important to
rst appreciate the coalitional basis on which institutional stability rests (Hall
& Thelen, 2009). Institutions are distributional instruments that, given their
unequal implications for resource allocation, are fraught with tensions
(Mahoney & Thelen, 2010, p. 8). The stability of such settlements is based
on the durability of compromises among groups of powerful actors, which
requires ongoing work by actors to maintain (Thelen, 2004). Securing
support from the coalition becomes all the more important with shifts in
the distribution of power resources between or within coalitions (Capoccia
& Kelemen, 2007), or through the loosening of functional and political con-
nections between institutional domains, which may bring on a critical junc-
ture with real possibility for major change (Carstensen & Röper, 2019;
Streeck, 2009).
In this view, the ongoing mobilization of supporters of the status quo is
key for maintaining stability (Mahoney & Thelen, 2010; Carstensen & Ibsen,
2021), and in some cases to keep external constituencieswith no particular
interest in the issue unorganized (Emmenegger, 2021). This involves
JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN PUBLIC POLICY 3
defending the reigning institutional logic, understood as the strategies,
routine approaches, and shared decision rules that structure interactions in
the institutional setup (Deeg, 2005). Carving out room for agency means
taking seriously that coalition building and maintenance do not automatically
occur because of common, objective interests. Instead, it suggests that actors
need to shore up common beliefs about the payoof extant institutional
setup (Culpepper, 2008). The stability of coalitions and the institutions they
support thus rely on the ongoing development of ideas, theories and narra-
tives that provide common interpretive lenses through which members of
the coalition can identify with each other (Hall, 2016; Seidl, 2020). Naturally,
this task becomes all the more important and challenging in periods of uncer-
tainty (Blyth, 2002; Hall, 1993) where relative structural indeterminism give
actors greater leeway than normal circumstances permit (Mahoney, 2002).
Given that incumbent actors cannot automatically maintain support
among key coalitional members (Capoccia, 2016), mounting an eective
defense is no mean feat. In Capoccia and Kelemens(2007, p. 352) terms,
the goal is the survival and return of the existing institutional setup, i.e., res-
toration of the pre-critical juncture status quo. Reaching this goal requires
treading a tight rope balance between maintaining the thrust of the existing
institutional logic while also re-casting it to the extent that it may act as an
eective response to the challenges leveled at it by a coalition of challengers
(Röper, 2021b). In this situation, given that extant institutions are under
pressure, simply rehashing the same arguments will hardly be a viable strat-
egy. On the other hand, taking on a new narrative based on a competing
institutional logic would likewise threaten to undermine the coalition, since
it would involve caving to the oense of the challengers. In essence, a
viable route involves keeping intact the basis of the institutional logic on
which the institutional setup is based, but couch it in a narrative that
speaks to the challenges leveled at existing institutions.
This mechanism for stabilization may usefully be captured with the
concept of bricolage, understood as a reorganization of ideational and insti-
tutional elements from the existing institutional logic (originally developed in
Levi-Strauss 1966). Working as a bricoleur which may roughly be translated
as a handymanor a jack of all trades’–political actors approach the task at
hand from the perspective of which instruments they have at their disposal,
and not which instruments are rationally most suitable (Baker & Nelson,
2005). This is a satiscing and conservative actor that pragmatically
engages in a dialogue with cognitive and symbolic instruments to decide
what meaning they may gain when combined in new ways (Campbell,
2004). Despite interpretive constraint placed on actors by meanings already
imbued by their previous application (Carstensen, 2011), the bricoleur is
able to creatively come up with ingenious solutions that may reestablish
4M. B. CARSTENSEN AND N. RÖPER
order until it is yet again upset by the arrival of a new problem (Hannah, 2020;
Röper, 2020).
The heterogeneous set of elements at hand are both the ideas and insti-
tutions already actively in use the relative salience of which may be
reshued through bricolage as well as left over ideational and institutional
debris from paths not taken(Schneiberg, 2007) or previously subordinated
or minor set of practices (Crouch & Keune, 2005) that are added to the set
through bricolage. The latter, more expansive form of bricolage holds
greater potential to over time change and not only stabilize institutions
(Campbell, 2004). More generally, the long-term eects of the redeployment
of existing institutional elements are impossible to know in advance. Indeed,
unintentionally laying the seeds for long-term institutional change is a risk
that actors using this mechanism for stabilization must be ready to run (Car-
stensen, 2017).
Although commonly employed to understand change processes (Camp-
bell, 2004), here we redirect the concept of bricolage towards the question
of how support for the extant institutional setup is maintained. We take
from gradualist approaches in historical institutionalism that the enforcement
of institutions varies over time and hinges on the capacity of actors to dom-
inate the interpretation of what the institutions may mean (Streeck & Thelen,
2005). Bricolage as a strategy for stabilization comes into play when incum-
bent actors seek to bolster support for the institutional setup by creatively
re-using existing elements to persuade potential defectors (Culpepper,
2005) of the continued viability of the institutional setup in cognitive, norma-
tive and distributional terms. Bricolage of the existing institutional logic thus
serves to explain the continued support of the incumbent coalition for main-
taining the existing institutional setup in face of eorts by challenging
coalitions to undermine support for it.
Based on the literature on bricolage in public policy, we suggest three
necessary conditions for the capacity of a bricolage to maintain the status
quo, specically that it satises cognitive, distributional and normative con-
cerns in the incumbent coalition. First, the bricolage needs to be cognitively
sound by credibly addressing the problems that were the original reason for
increasing questioning of the problem-solving capacity of the existing insti-
tutional setup (Campbell, 2004; Schmidt, 2008). This is particularly important
in a situation where this capacity is being questioned inside and outside the
incumbent coalition and a joint belief shift(Culpepper, 2005) is threatening
to undermine common conceptions of what the problems are and how they
can plausibly be solved (Béland, 2009). Here it will matter whether a compet-
ing coalition of actors manages to establish that policy anomalies encoun-
tered by the existing institutional setup are beyond repair (Hall, 1993), or
whether the threat of anomalies can be defuzed if the actors involved are
willing to amend their solution sets to a degree deemed satisfactory by
JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN PUBLIC POLICY 5
important observers (Wilder & Howlett, 2014, p. 189). If incumbent actors
manage to convincingly counter competing narratives, they will traverse an
experimental period of trying to gure out the implications of alternative
institutional arrangements, without it resulting in institutional change.
Second, the institutional setup produced through bricolage must be
recongured in a way that answers to power-distributional concerns
among coalition members. The bricolage will give greater prominence to
certain elements in the institutional setup, or insert elements from another
context, and doing so will inevitably raise questions about whether it
satises the preferences of all central actors in the incumbent coalition. As
argued by Culpepper (2008), key for the perseverance of the coalition is
that they can persuasively respond to the most salient features of the
dilemma raised by the contending coalition while appealing across the pre-
ferences of dierent parts of the coalition. To this end, incumbent supporters
will need new elements whether cognitive or symbolic to persuasively
argue that keeping the coalition intact promises the best possible outcome
for coalition members. Particularly important will be the continued support
of actors centrally placed in incumbent networks, since waning support on
their part is likely to lead to wider defection in the rest of the network (Cul-
pepper, 2005).
Third, the stability brought on by reconguration of the incumbent insti-
tutional logic must also speak to dominant values in the coalition as well
as society at large (Schmidt, 2008). This is not as straight forward as it
might appear, since basing ones arguments on dominant values is easier
done when one is merely restating rather than reconguring the institutional
logic. The re-ordering of the elements that make up the existing institutional
logic, or indeed the injection of elements new to the set, will require the
development of new powerful ideas or narratives (Seidl, 2020) that may for-
cefully communicate the embeddedness of the institutional setup in a
broader moral economy (Hansen, 2019). Here, however, incumbent actors
are well placed to strengthen the resistance to change of existing institutions,
since in developing their bricolage, they will be able to draw on entrenched
cultural categories that provide potent weapons against the introduction of
new interpretive frames (Capoccia, 2016).
Empirical analysis: the case of German collective capitalism
that did not happen
To provide an example of how institutional maintenance through bricolage
operates in practice, we turn to the case of a reform that never was: The
German Tarrionds policy of collective stock sharing that all but passed
into legislation in 1980. The case of Tarrionds is particularly well
suited for exploring institutional bricolage as a mechanism for institutional
6M. B. CARSTENSEN AND N. RÖPER
maintenance, since its critical case properties lend weight to a claim of wider
empirical relevance (Flyvbjerg, 2006). In particular, the many circumstances
speaking in favor of the policy passing notably that the governing coalition
had agreed on all the details of the reform proposal and was ready to come
through on one of the chancellors central election promises leverages the
argument that institutional maintenance through bricolage could also take
place in situations without a similar level of alignment of policy preferences.
To support our claim that the ideational intervention of the FDP is a key
explanatory factor for why the Tarionds-policy never passed into law, we
investigate rst the fertile political and institutional terrain for substantial
change to take place. Here we show that shifts in the coalitional basis of
the status quo worked in favor of reform, while at the same time the insti-
tutional interconnectedness that had stymied Vermögenspolitik up until
then was steadily unraveling. Both permissiveand productiveconditions
for a critical juncture thus appeared to be met (Soifer, 2012). To explain
why it turned out to be a mere candidate juncture(Capoccia, 2015, 169),
we identify the development of the idea of open market access, and, using
insider knowledge from actors central to the process, trace the centrality of
this ordoliberal idea for the postponement of Tarrionds. The analysis
draws on a wide range of primary and secondary sources, including docu-
mentation from German parliamentary debates, newspapers, party foun-
dation and federal archives, and in-depth expert interviews.
Critical juncture approaching: growing political agreement and
loosening institutional constraints
The decades preceding the policy debate on Tarrionds witnessed Vermögen-
spolitik i.e., the issue of productive capital in the hands of employees(or
the lack thereof) building as a central concern for left- and right-wing gov-
ernments. Upon the immediate German postwar eorts of reconstruction, in
the mid-1950s the highly concentrated ownership of capital was increasingly
lamented as an economic and social problem across the political spectrum
(Abelshauser, 1996, p. 397). While a series of legislations aiming at private
wealth creation followed, these predominantly subsidized savings plans
and barely contributed to more capital in the hands of employees (Erbe,
1999, p. 421).
What prevented far-reaching reforms that would increase private capital
ownership, which was one of the original goals of Vermögenspolitik? The
limited success was not for a lack of (party) political plans and promises.
Promising far-reaching measures to foster private capital formation had
become a xture of government declarations (Regierungserklärungen) since
at least 1957. Initially the main reason for this series of nondecisions and rela-
tive continuity were stark ideological dierences between conservatives and
JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN PUBLIC POLICY 7
organized business on one side and Social Democrats and unions on the
other. German Vermögenspolitik, after all, has antisocialist roots(Dietrich,
2008c, p. 901), as the initial impetus for the Christian Democrats (CDU) to
push for private capital formation was to politically ank plans to privatize
government-owned rms such as Volkswagen with employee stock
schemes (Der Spiegel, 1959). Unions and Social Democrats not only
opposed privatization plans, but also feared that such schemes would turn
workers into little capitalistsin a society of owners (Dietrich, 2008a, p. 892).
These cleavages, however, became less pronounced throughout the 1960s
as a result of marginally transformative learning processes among central pol-
itical actors. A study from 1968 claiming that 1.7 per cent of German house-
holds own 70 per cent of productive capital, caused a public outcry and
heated debates about wealth inequality (Dietrich, 2008c, p. 892). Indeed,
by the early 1970s, the Social Democratic Party (SPD) competed with the
CDU in its advocacy of private capital formation policies. Overall, we see a
convergence of conservative and Social Democratic positions and an ever-
stronger political will to push through comprehensive reforms (Dietrich,
2008b).
While the political dierences about whether fostering employee capital
ownership dwindled, the underlying motivations and ideas about the how
continued to stand in stark contrast. To summarize crudely, the CDU and
organized business looked to increase employeesattachment to their com-
panies through employee shares or other internal schemes, whereas the SPD
sought to involve organized labor in the process to make employees less
dependent on their employers and empower unions through external
schemes. Left-leaning political forces increasingly eyed Vermögenspolitik as
a way to democratize capitalismthrough widespread employee capital own-
ership (Sjöberg & Dube, 2014, p. 492). As such, Vermögenspolitik was increas-
ingly considered the third waybetween Marxism and a market economy
(Adam, 1976, p. 84).
Continuing political dierences notwithstanding, reforms that would go
beyond piecemeal subsidies increasingly seemed realistic. Why then, do we
see at least nine failed reform initiatives by governments throughout the
1960s and 1970s, a deadlock that we see in no other policy domain (Dietrich,
2008e, p. 715)? To make sense of this, it is important to take into account that
Vermögenspolitik as a policy domain is linked to constraints and impetuses
posed by other domains. Given that Vermögenspolitik is in many ways not a
formally established policy eld, its goals tend to be attached and are
often trumped by those of other elds, including social and economic policy-
making (Dietrich, 2008a, p. 897; 2008b, pp. 8023). This chameleonesque
character(Dietrich, 2008d,p. 854) of the policy eld makes it imperative to
appreciate the implications of the evolution of other elds. The constraints
posed by other institutional domains that inhibited far-reaching reforms
8M. B. CARSTENSEN AND N. RÖPER
toward collective capitalism include wage-focused bargaining, a bank-based
nancial system, an insider-oriented corporate governance regime and a one-
pillar PAYG pension system (Carstensen & Röper, 2019; Röper, 2021a; Streeck,
2009).
Especially in the aftermath of the 1974 recession, however, these con-
straints loosened considerably. Due to the overall economic slowdown, the
maneuvering room for wage increases became smaller, which makes alterna-
tive forms of remuneration like deferred compensation that is linked to the
performance of rms more attractive, in a move away from the traditional
monoculture of cash salary increases(Die Zeit, 1979). The undercapitaliza-
tion of German rms increasingly delegitimized the insider-paradigm and
the overreliance on bank and internal nance (Röper, 2018). This structural
equity-problemof corporate Germany and questions of economic growth
more generally came to dominate debates about fostering private capital for-
mation (Bundestag, 2006; Dietrich, 2008e, p. 715). Taken together, insti-
tutional constraints losing purchase in combination with the learning
processes sketched above, meant that the policy eld of Vermögenspolitik
was ripe for transformative change by the end of the 1970s.
Candidate juncture: Tarrionds postponed indenitely
The standobetween individualistsfavoring rm-internal capital participation
schemes for employees and collectivistsdemanding external investment
funds persisted throughout the 1970s and beyond. In fact, what we see is a
polarization of the political debate about capital sharing (Vermögensbeteili-
gung), which almost turns the choice between internal[betrieblich]orexter-
nal[überbetrieblich] into a question of creed(Toillié, 1977, p. 243). The CDU
and organized business largely remained in the camp of individualists.One
crucial actor, however, displayed a meaningful positional change toward the
end of the 1970s. Formerly a staunch individualist,importantpartsofthe
economically liberal FDP warmed up toward external policy solutions, more
similar to those demanded by unions and the SDP (Dietrich, 2008c,p.892).
1
The FDP positioned itself between the conservatives and the social democrats
by favoring external solutions through collective bargaining channels in prin-
ciple, but insisting on tight restrictions on how Tarionds may invest their
funds (to prevent industrial politics and excessive inuence over rms) and
freedom of choice for employees on how to invest deferred compensation
(in contrast to the SPD, who favored all compensation that was deferred
through collective bargaining agreements to be transferred to the Tarionds)
(FAZ, 1979a). This in-between position of the FDP stemmed from internal dier-
ences with regards to collectivist vs. individualist solutions. It was especially
economics minister Otto Graf Lambsdor, who opposed collectivist solutions
along the lines of Tarionds (FAZ, 1979b).
JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN PUBLIC POLICY 9
On 20 September 1979, the social-liberal government nally agreed on a
reform proposal that included external Tarionds. Subsidies were supposed
to be extended to deferred compensation that may be invested in stocks
of other rms through external equity funds that are governed by organized
labor and business and thus integrated into corporatist structures. The reform
proposal sought to overcome the contradiction between internal and exter-
nal wealth creationby enabling but not mandating external Tarionds, while
also encouraging the issuance of internal employee shares (Funcke, 1979).
Merely the issue of income limits for subsidies was left to be resolved by min-
isterial bureaucrats as a question of detail(FAZ, 1979c). Labor minister
Herbert Ehrenberg (SPD) and economics minister Otto Graf Lambsdor
(FDP) agreed on further details based on this blueprint (Drechsler, 1980).
Even skeptical economists acknowledged that the design took into account
many of the concerns raised by ordoliberal opponents of external schemes
(Cox, 1980).
Large parts of the FDP leadership were outspokenly supportive of the
reform proposal. In January of 1980, foreign minister, vice chancellor and
chairman of the FDP, Hans-Dietrich Genscher, explicitly rearmed his
partys support of external Tarionds and promised to come through on
the reform at the politically important Dreikönigstreen (Genscher, 1980).
Later that month, the chairman of the FDP parliamentary group, Wolfgang
Mischnick, wrote in a letter to a business organization that all of businesses
ordo-political concerns were addressed by the reform proposal (Mischnick,
1980). The nal aspect of contention (income limits for subsidies) was
resolved in a meeting between nance minister Hans Matthöfer (SPD) and
economics minister Otto Graf Lambsdor(FDP), who announced a law propo-
sal to be published within two weeks (BMF, 1980; Bundestag, 1980a; Laux,
1980b). For all intents and purposes, in February of 1980, a far-reaching
reform proposal that would put an end to large parts of the debate about
wealth politics seemed all but certain to be introduced in March (Cox,
1980; FAZ, 1980a).
Yet, on 13 March 1980, the Social Democratic nance minister, Hans Mat-
thöfer, sent out a letter stating that the reform proposal has been withdrawn
and postponed to the next term starting in 1983 (Schneider et al., 2007, p. 46).
Fiscal burdens stemming from the conict in Afghanistan were cited as the
reason for this surprising step (Bundestag, 1980b). This veto on scal
grounds by the nance minister was reiterated by both media outlets and
scholars as the actual reason as to why we did not see the promised paradig-
matic reform in 1980 (e.g., Drechsler, 1980;Der Spiegel, 1982; for an exception
claiming that the scal argument was feigned, see Hesse, 2001, p. 1404). With
the benet of contemporary witnesses who feel free to speak on this now, we
show below that the ocial scal argument is at least implausible. But aside
from new insider accounts, a veto from a SPD politician, clearly the party that
10 M. B. CARSTENSEN AND N. RÖPER
was more invested in the reform, seemed unusual at the time. What is more, it
is doubtful how plausible an argument pointing to the scal burden in the
context of Vermögenspolitik actually is, in light of the design of the reform
proposal compared to the existing, more expensive subsidies (Drechsler,
1980). Perhaps even more dismissive of the scal argument is the fact that
the government declaration in 1976 already ruled out any increases of the
total scal expenditure on wealth formation. Reforms were about restructur-
ing wealth formation expenditures rather than increasing them. After all, the
scal situation had been strenuous since at least the 1974 recession, com-
pared to which the situation in Afghanistan was likely going to present a
minor factor. Already in January of 1980 nance minister Matthöfer had
sent out an alarm letter(Alarmbrief) about the urgent need of scal frugality,
which apparently did not apply to wealth politics, as he still vowed to go
forward with this reform proposal in February (FAZ, 1980b). This begs the
question of what actually prompted the government to retract the reform
proposal.
A bricolage of the institutional logic: the idea of open market access
I remember it as if was yesterday, because I had a t of laughter’–this is how
Manfred Laux, former long-time CEO of the interest group, German Invest-
ment Funds Association (BVI), remembers his reaction to the government
pointing to the Afghanistan crisis when withdrawing the reform proposal
(Laux Email 29.03.2018). Based on insider accounts by Laux and Sighart
Nehring, bureaucrat at the ministry of economics in charge of wealth politics
at the time and later head of economic aairs at the chancellery, we can
revisit what happened in February and March of 1980 and led to the withdra-
wal of the reform proposal.
In January of 1980, Hans Tietmeyer, head of economic policy at the
FDP-led ministry of economics at the time,
2
asked his advisor Sighart
Nehring to kill Tarionds(Laux Email 29.03.2018). This points toward
dierences between the FDP and the SPD that went beyond the mere
details they publicly declared to be concerned with at this point.
Backed by Tietmeyer and minister Lambsdor, Nehring developed an
alternative law proposal that aimed to rule out tax privileges for Tar-
iondsand ensure freedom of choice for employees between Tarionds
and other schemes (Nehring telephone interview 13.01.2021; Nehring
Email 13.07.2020). In negotiations with bureaucrats from the other minis-
tries involved in the reform process (mainly the ministry of nance, labor
and justice, and the chancellery), this proposal got rejected (Nehring tele-
phone interview 13.01.2021). Nehring recalls: Danger was coming, I was
standing with my back to the wall. I needed new arguments(Nehring tel-
ephone interview 13.01.2021). He turned to Laux and asked him to
JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN PUBLIC POLICY 11
develop a new line of argument(Laux Email 13.07.2020; Nehring Email
13.07.2020).
Laux had long been involved in debates and lobbying processes regarding
Vermögenspolitik, but was hard-pressed to nd a new argument against Tar-
ionds. Out of desperation he took a step back and started to peruse seminal
ordoliberal works on the foundations of the German market economy. One
morning, reading about Euckens principles that constitute a market econ-
omic order, Laux nally found something he deemed relevant: the ordoliberal
principle of open access to markets (Interview Laux, Görlitz, 30.09.2017). The
principle suggests that barriers to enter markets must be minimized and
open access to markets ensured, so that markets may unfold their coordina-
tive and regulative function (Eucken, 1940). Laux argued that Tarionds
would violate this principle or structural element of our market economy
(Laux, 1982) because they would privilege these funds over other forms of
investment (BVI, 1983, pp. 1718; Laux, 1980a,1980b,1982).
Like the bricoleur, who rearranges existing ideational and institutional
elements for distributional, cognitive and symbolic reasons, Laux placed an
existing idea much more prominently in the argument in favor of maintaining
the existing institutional setup, in eect setting the incumbent coalition on a
much rmer footing in denying the attack that Tarrionds policy constituted.
However, Laux rst had to bring it to bear on the policy debate. Laux penned
a brief that mainly revolved around the principle of open market access and
handed it to Nehring. Nehring then asked Laux to publish his ideas in a non-
confrontational article in Das Handelsblatt, where Nehring would make sure it
would be published (Laux Email 13.07.2020).
The article came out on 29 February 1980 (Laux, 1980a). That same day
Laux received a phone call from the advisor on Vermögenspolitik to the
nance minister, who told him that the article aggravated the minister and
caused a big stir(Laux Email 29.03.2018). This is the same minister who
about two weeks later publicly claimed that he vetoed the reform proposal
for scal reasons and whose parliamentary secretary of state, Rolf Böhme,
on 13 February 1980 in front of lawmakers still underscored the importance
of Tarionds and said that the federal government aims to introduce a law
proposal very soon, during this term(Bundestag, 1980c). Bundestag vice pre-
sident Liselotte Funcke (FDP) read Lauxarticle and a few days later the FDP
parliamentary group and economics minister Lambsdorcame out (in
camera) opposing Tarionds based on the principle of open access to
markets (Laux Email 13.07.2020; Nehring telephone interview 13.01.2021).
Shortly thereafter, the ministry of nance issued the abovementioned
letter, arguing that it was in fact scal constraints posed by the crisis in Afgha-
nistan that led to the withdrawal.
Six days after the nance minister sent out the letter that included the
scal justication, his parliamentary secretary of state appeared before
12 M. B. CARSTENSEN AND N. RÖPER
Bundestag committees (held in camera). Conservative lawmakers asked him
to comment on press reports suggesting that the FDP had in fact blocked the
reform proposal based on ordopolitical objections. The secretary explicitly
said that the reform proposal did not fail due to a veto by the FDP.
However, he then went on to implicitly retreat from the scal argument
and said that to prepare Tarionds more time was necessary because very
complicated questions have to be resolvedand the delay in introducing
the law proposal is rooted in substantial reasons. Conservative lawmakers
were confused by these answers and pressed the secretary by asking
whether there was dissonance between the governing parties regarding Tar-
ionds and whether rumors are true that the minister of economics
demanded more liberal access to deferred compensation (freie Verfügbarkeit
über vermögenswirksame Anlagen), which the secretary categorically denied
(Bundestag, 1980d). The parliamentary group of CDU and CSU criticized the
scal argument as a smokescreen and demanded the resignation of some-
body responsible for this broken promise (Bundestag, 1980e). About a
month later, conservative lawmakers renewed these claims during a
plenary session and expanded on why the scal argument is invalid, not
least given the timeline of the Russian invasion, which had begun three
months prior to the decision to withdraw the reform proposal (Bundestag,
1980a).
One may still wonder: Why did opponents of Tarionds within the FDP
need the idea of open market access to oppose it? From a theoretical
vantage point, this need for ideational elements makes sense: If institutional
constraints are loose enough, party-political dynamics work in its favor, and
learning processes culminate, we see the opportunity for transformative
change even in the absence of exogenous shocks (Capoccia, 2016). This is
the time for agency to have the strongest eect (Mahoney, 2002, p. 7), in
terms of both eecting and preventing change, as we argue. In a situation
where all the arguments against a policy proposal have been countered, or
rather, are perceived to have been countered, a new interpretation is
required as scaolding for the continued vitality of the incumbent coalition.
At this point, actors seeking to defend the status quo have to nd new ways
to legitimize it, and to do so within the parameters of the overall institutional
logic they seek to defend. As intimated above, such an idea need not necess-
arily be new in the sense that it had never been conceived before. In fact, old
ideas that appeal to traditional, longstanding lines of reasoning may enjoy
more legitimacy in political battles, when they are recongured toward
current debates.
By 1980, most arguments against Tarionds had been countered or per-
ceived as invalid. At this point, the main ordoliberal concerns by organized
business regarding these external funds (e.g., Arbeitsring Chemie, 1979;
BVI, 1979) had been taken into account by the government. For example,
JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN PUBLIC POLICY 13
concerns of over-codeterminationwere addressed by ensuring a certain
composition of the governing board of these funds. Complaints about limit-
ations of employeesfreedom of choice in terms of how they invest their
deferred compensation, were addressed by mandating rms to oer at
least one alternative form of investment in addition to Tarionds and
leaving it up to rms to oer more than one alternative (Mischnick, 1980).
As the FDP leadership had declared these ordoliberal concerns to be
suciently addressed by the reform proposal, organized business and the
parts of the FDP that continued to oppose Tarionds found themselves in a
situation where they needed a new argument.
Why was the principle of open market access so eective? Even though
the many concerns raised by organized business had been well-rehearsed,
the idea of open access to markets had never been raised, according to
our extensive search of the documentary evidence. In this sense, the interven-
tion by Laux is based on a new old idea that is deeply rooted in traditional
ordoliberal thinking. In many ways, the idea of open access to markets is a
continuation or rather a more extreme version of the longstanding argument
in Vermögenspolitik debates that people should have freedom of choice when
deciding on how to invest their private savings. The existing regulatory land-
scape constituting the eld of Vermögenspolitik was in many ways the oppo-
site of what ordoliberals had preferred, given its heavy reliance on subsidies
for specic forms of private saving. The one ordoliberal line of reasoning that
was held up throughout previous debates, however, was freedom of choice in
the sense that private households had to be able to choose from various
types of subsidized forms of private saving. This is very much in line with
one of the key ordoliberal concerns: monopolies. The idea of open market
access brought these lines of thinking together in that it argued: Tarionds
could become monopolies, as they would be in a privileged position to
issue equity funds.
As such, the idea was a normatively acceptable ordoliberal principle that
enabled parts of the FDP to veto Tarionds without losing face. Just as impor-
tantly, the idea did not merely shut out Tarionds, but came with an alterna-
tive solution. When asked why the minister of nance was so aggravated
upon reading his newspaper article, Laux replied: He found the article extre-
mely unbecoming, because it pointed toward a system-conformist alternative
to Tarionds(Laux Email 12.11.2020). Laux outlined in this article and sub-
sequent publications that external equity funds for employees could be set
up as regular investment funds managed by investment companies
without involvement of labor or employers (Laux, 1980a,1980b,1982). If a
system-conformist solution is possible, the system-prejudicial plans by the
IG-Metall, the chancellery and the SPD minister of nance Matthöfer were
in jeopardy(Laux Email 12.11.2020).
14 M. B. CARSTENSEN AND N. RÖPER
To be sure, the idea of open market access did not change the preferences
of the FDP, but it gave the central opponent of Tarionds within the FDP
(Lambsdor) new argumentative grounds to stand on, after large parts of
his party had expressed their support of such funds. Lambsdorfundamen-
tally opposed collectivist solutions and required new ideational ammunition
to ward them ointernally. Nehring, a bureaucrat in Lambsdors ministry of
economics at the time recalls: scal reasons can always be advanced if you
cant reach an agreement. It was an ideological discord that was never
quite expressed publicly. It was about economic individualism versus collec-
tivism(Nehring telephone interview 13.01.2021).
The idea of open market access was new yet familiar and was corroborated
by an alternative solution that was at least hard to dismiss out of hand. In light
of these qualities, the SPD understandably opted to shelve the reform to
prevent a prolonged discussion about an election promise not kept. An elec-
tion promise not kept would have likely been perceived by the public as
another indicator of the inner turmoil plaguing the government coalition.
By publicly recurring to the scal argument, the SPD invoked structural
reasons for the withdrawal of the reform, which is a well-known discursive
strategy of blame avoidance (Vis, 2016). It is important to note how fragile
the government coalition already was at this point and that it broke up
two years later over fundamental disagreements regarding economic policies
that culminated in the manifesto of the market economyby economics min-
ister Lambsdor(Feld, 2013).
Taken together, the bricolage based on the idea of open market access
meets the three necessary conditions we propose. First, it was cognitively
sound, as it addressed the key concern of the incumbent coalition (CDU, orga-
nized business and parts of the FDP), namely to foster capital ownership
among employees and boost capital market development. The proposed
alternative to Tarionds in the form of private equity funds aligned with
those goals. Second, power-distributional concerns were unlikely to
emerge, given that such subsidized private equity funds would not conceiva-
bly have taken anything away from members of the incumbent coalition and
therefore hardly bore the potential for new conicts. Third, a credible ordo-
liberal idea, the school of economics that shapes German political debates
to this day, speaks to dominant values.
Conclusion
This paper has sought to develop a deeper understanding of how agency
plays into the stabilization of institutions. The primary analytical contribution
is to show how the concept of bricolage which has traditionally been
employed to analyze successful bids of policy entrepreneurs for eecting
change may fruitfully be adapted to the context of institutional
JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN PUBLIC POLICY 15
stabilization. Doing so, highlights that upholding coalitions requires active
work on the part of agents. One way in which this may take place is
through the furbishing of the incumbent institutional logic with a re-acti-
vated ideational or institutional element.
The case of Tarrionds provides a fertile empirical terrain for exploring the
workings of this strategy, because it so clearly demonstrates the mechanisms
through which bricolage may work to stabilize the institutional setup. The
analysis has shown that the presentation of the idea of open market access
was a necessary condition for the upholding of the coalition behind the
status quo. In turn, without the successful deployment of a bricolage of the
existing institutional logic, the coalition looked poised to destabilize,
opening the way for a signicant change in German capitalism.
It is worth noting that the way agents deployed a bricolage of the existing
institutional logic in the case of the Tarrionds policy where the incumbent
coalition was provided with an ideational weapon in the shape of the ordolib-
eral idea of open market access places the discursive eects of the bricolage
front and center. In other cases, the eects could be more signicant in terms
of additions of new institutional elements that, however, would not upset the
existing institutional logic, but instead serve to fortify existing institutions. In
short, the concept of bricolage of the institutional logic as laid out in this
paper allows for some exibility in terms of how it may apply in other circum-
stances. Future research could well focus on parsing out the variety of brico-
lage strategies and the boundary conditions for their successful activation.
Furthermore, the role of agency in processes of institutional continuity is
worth exploring in mechanisms beyond bricolage such as drift,where
change is said to come about through nondecisions (Hacker & Pierson,
2010). This points toward a broader research agenda that probes into the
ways in which ideas and narratives might be deployed to bring about
continuity.
Notes
1. The FDP formed a social-liberal government coalition with the SPD between
1969 and 1982.
2. Later state secretary at the ministry of nance and president of the Bundesbank.
Acknowledgements
The authors gratefully acknowledge the very useful comments from reviewers and
editors that did much to clarify and strengthen the arguments of the paper. All
remaining errors are ours.
16 M. B. CARSTENSEN AND N. RÖPER
Disclosure statement
No potential conict of interest was reported by the author(s).
Funding
Nils Röpers work on the paper was funded by the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft
(DFG German Research Foundation) under Germanys Excellence Strategy EXC-
2035/1-390681379
Notes on contributors
Martin B. Carstensen is Professor MSO in Public Administration and Politics at Depart-
ment of Social Science and Business, Roskilde University.
Nils Röper is a postdoctoral research fellow in the Cluster of Excellence The Politics of
Inequalityat the University of Konstanz.
References
Abelshauser, W. (1996). Erhard oder Bismarck? Die Richtungsentscheidung der
deutschen Sozialpolitik am Beispiel der Reform der Sozialversicherung in den
fünfziger Jahren. Geschichte und Gesellschaft,22(3), 376392.
Adam, H. (1976). Macht und Vermögen in der Wirtschaft. Bund-Verlag.
Arbeitsring Chemie. (1979, December 12). Stellungnahme zum gegenwärtigen Stand
der Vermögensbildungsdiskussion. Arbeitsring der Arbeitgeberverbände der
Deutschen Chemie.
Baker, T., & Nelson, R. E. (2005). Creating something from nothing: Resource construc-
tion through entrepreneurial bricolage. Administrative Science Quarterly,50(3), 329
366.
Béland, D. (2009). Ideas, institutions, and policy change. Journal of European Public
Policy,16(5), 701718. https://doi.org/10.1080/13501760902983382
Blyth, M. (2002). Great transformations: Economic ideas and institutional change in the
twentieth century. Cambridge University Press.
BMF. (1980, February 7). German Ministry of Finance, BMF-Nachrichten, no. 7/89.
Bundestag. (1980a, May 13). Plenary Debate, 16th Session, Bonn.
Bundestag. (1980b, April 18). Beschlußempfehlung und Bericht des
Finanzausschusses. Drucksache 8/3915.
Bundestag. (1980c, March 19). Kurzprotokoll der 80. Sitzung des Finanzausschusses,
Deutscher Bundestag.
Bundestag. (1980d, March 19). Kurzprotokoll der 85. Sitzung des Ausschusses für
Arbeit und Sozialordnung, Deutscher Bundestag.
Bundestag. (1980e, February 13). Kurzprotokoll der 81. Sitzung des Ausschusses für
Arbeit und Sozialordnung, Deutscher Bundestag.
Bundestag. (2006). Staatliche Sparförderung in Deutschland. Wissenschaftliche
Dienste des Deutschen Bundestages, Sachstand WF IV G - 014/06.
BVI. (1979, February 20). Investment Information. Bundesverband Deutscher
Investment-Gesellschaften. Frankfurt am Main.
BVI. (1983). Investment 83. Bundesverband Deutscher Investment-Gesellschaften.
Frankfurt am Main.
JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN PUBLIC POLICY 17
Campbell, J. L. (2004). Institutional change and globalization. Princeton University
Press.
Capoccia, G. (2015). Critical junctures and institutional change. In J. Mahoney & K.
Thelen (Eds.), Advances in Comparative Historical Analysis (pp. 147179).
Cambridge University Press.
Capoccia, G. (2016). When do institutions bite? Historical institutionalism and the
politics of institutional change. Comparative Political Studies,49(8), 10951127.
https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414015626449
Capoccia, G., & Kelemen, R. D. (2007). The study of critical junctures: Theory, narrative,
and counterfactuals in historical institutionalism. World Politics,59(3), 341369.
https://doi.org/10.1017/S0043887100020852
Carstensen, M. B. (2011). Paradigm man vs. the bricoleur: Bricolage as an alternative
vision of agency in ideational change. European Political Science Review,3(1),
147167. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1755773910000342
Carstensen, M. B. (2017). Institutional bricolage in times of crisis. European Political
Science Review,9(1), 139160. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1755773915000338
Carstensen, M. B., & Ibsen, C. L. (2021). Three dimensions of institutional contention:
Eciency, equality and governance in Danish vocational education and training
reform. Socio-Economic Review.http://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwz012
Carstensen, M. B., & Röper, N. (2019). Invasion from within: Ideas, power and the trans-
mission of institutional logics between policy domains. Comparative Political
Studies,52(9), 13281363. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414019830713
Cox, H. (1980). Tarionds in der Tarif-und Vermögenspolitik. Wirtschaftsdienst,60(1),
4656.
Crouch, C., & Keune, M. (2005). Making use of institutional diversity in Hungary and the
United Kingdom. In W. Streeck & K. Thelen (Eds.), Beyond continuity: Institutional
change in advanced political economies (pp. 83102). Oxford University Press.
Culpepper, P. D. (2005). Institutional change in contemporary capitalism: Coordinated
nancial systems since 1990. World Politics,57(2), 173199. https://doi.org/10.1353/
wp.2005.0016
Culpepper, P. (2008). The politics of common knowledge: Ideas and institutional
change in wage bargaining. International Organization,62(1), 133. https://doi.
org/10.1017/S0020818308080016
Deeg, R. (2005). Change from within: German and Italian nance in the 1990s. In W.
Streeck & K. Thelen (Eds.), Beyond continuity: Institutional change in advanced politi-
cal economies (pp. 169202). Oxford University Press.
Der Spiegel. (1959, February 18). Volksaktie contra Sozialismus. Der Spiegel, 8/1959.
Der Spiegel. (1982, April 26). Verzicht versüßen. Der Spiegel, 17/1982.
Dietrich, Y. (2008a). Vermögenspolitik. In G. Schulz (Ed.), Geschichte der Sozialpolitik in
Deutschland seit 1945 (Band 3) (pp. 887898). Nomos Verlag.
Dietrich, Y. (2008b). Vermögenspolitik. In M. Ruck & M. Boldorf (Eds.), Geschichte der
Sozialpolitik in Deutschland seit 1945 (Band 4) (pp. 797817). Nomos Verlag.
Dietrich, Y. (2008c). Vermögenspolitik. In H. G. Hockerts (Ed.), Geschichte der
Sozialpolitik in Deutschland seit 1945 (Band 5) (pp. 889907). Nomos Verlag.
Dietrich, Y. (2008d). Vermögenspolitik. In M. H. Geyer (Ed.), Geschichte der Sozialpolitik
in Deutschland seit 1945 (Band 6) (pp. 853858). Nomos Verlag.
Dietrich, Y. (2008e). Vermögenspolitik. In M. G. Schmidt (Ed.), Geschichte der
Sozialpolitik in Deutschland seit 1945 (Band 7) (pp. 715723). Nomos Verlag.
Die Zeit. (1979, March 2). Nicht nur um Prozente feilschen. Die Zeit, 10/1979.
Drechsler, W. (1980, March 21). Mit Genuß Gewinn verteilen. Die Zeit, 13/1980.
18 M. B. CARSTENSEN AND N. RÖPER
Emmenegger, P. (2021). Agency in historical institutionalism coalitional work in the
creation, maintenance, and change of institutions. Theory and Society.https://doi.
org/10.1007/s11186-021-09433-5
Erbe, R. (1999). Vermögensbildungspolitik in der Bundesrepublik: eine Bilanz.
Wirtschaftsdienst,79(7), 421428.
Eucken, W. (1940). Grundlagen der Nationalökonomie. Gustav Fischer.
FAZ. (1979a, September 11). Letzter Anlauf zur Vermögensbildung. Frankfurter
Allgemeine Zeitung.
FAZ. (1979b, September 13). Ministergespräch ohne Ergebnis. Frankfurter Allgemeine
Zeitung.
FAZ. (1979c, September 22). Vermögensinitiative kommt langsam voran. Frankfurter
Allgemeine Zeitung.
FAZ. (1980a, February 16). Schritte zur Vermögensbildung. Frankfurter Allgemeine
Zeitung.
FAZ. (1980b, March 14). Die Koalition vertagt Pläne zur Vermögensbildung. Frankfurter
Allgemeine Zeitung.
Feld, L. P. (2013). Zur Bedeutung des Manifests der Marktwirtschaft oder: Das Lambsdor-
Papier im 31. Jahr (No. 13/9). Freiburger Diskussionspapiere zur
Ordnungsökonomik.
Fioretos, O., Falleti, T. G., & Sheingate, A. (2016). Historical institutionalism in political
science. In O. M. Fioretiós, T. G. Falleti, & A. Sheingate (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of
historical institutionalism (pp. 328). Oxford University Press.
Flyvbjerg, B. (2006). Five misunderstandings about case-study research. Qualitative
Inquiry,12(2), 219245. https://doi.org/10.1177/1077800405284363
Funcke, L. (1979, July 3). Letter from Liselotte Funcke to Wolfgang Mischnick. Bonn.
Genscher, H. D. (1980, January 6). Speech by Hans-Dietrich Genscher at
Dreikönigstreen, Stuttgart.
Gerschewski, J. (2021). Explanations of institutional change: Reecting on a missing
diagonal.American Political Science Review,115(1), 218233. https://doi.org/10.
1017/S0003055420000751
Greif, A., & Laitin, D. D. (2004). A theory of endogenous institutional change. American
Political Science Review,98(4), 633652. https://doi.org/10.1017/
S0003055404041395
Hacker, J. S., & Pierson, P. (2010). Winner-take-all politics: Public policy, political organ-
ization, and the precipitous rise of top incomes in the United States. Politics &
Society,38(2), 152204. https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329210365042
Hall, P. (1993). Policy paradigms, social learning, and the state: The case of economic
policymaking in britain. Comparative Politics,25(3), 275296. https://doi.org/10.
2307/422246
Hall, P. A. (2016). Politics as a process structured in space and time. In O. Fioretos, T.
Falleti, & A. Sheingate (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of historical institutionalism
(pp. 3151). Oxford University Press.
Hall, P. A., & Taylor, R. C. (1996). Political science and the three new institutionalisms.
Political Studies,44(5), 936957.
Hall, P. A., & Thelen, K. (2009). Institutional change in varieties of capitalism. Socio-
Economic Review,7(1), 734. https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwn020
Hannah, A. (2020). Evaluating the role of bricolage in US Health Care policy reform.
Policy and Politics,48(3), 485502.
Hansen, M. (2019). The moral economy of activation: Ideas, politics and policies. Policy
Press.
JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN PUBLIC POLICY 19
Hesse, W. E. (2001). Die Weichenstellung für die neue Vermögenspolitik in den achtzi-
ger Jahren. Kreditwesen, 24/2001, 14031412.
Laux, M. (1980a, February 29). Bonner Vermögenspolitik: Koalition streitet um neues
Konzept. Handelsblatt.
Laux, M. (1980b). Kritische Würdigung der vermögenspolitischen Diskussion. Der lang-
fristige Kredit, 8/1980, 233236.
Laux, M. (1982). Vermögenspolitik: Eine systemkonforme Lösung des Konikts
zwischen Vermögensbildung und Mitbestimmung. Der langfristige Kredit,33(19),
598601.
Lawrence, T. B., & Suddaby, R. (2006). 1.6 institutions and institutional work. In S. R.
Clegg & C. Hardy, T. Lawrence, and W. R. Nord (Eds.), The Sage handbook of organ-
ization studies (pp. 215254). Sage.
Mahoney, J. (2002). The legacies of liberalism: Path dependence and political regimes in
Central America. Johns Hopkins University Press.
Mahoney, J., & Thelen, K. (2010). A theory of gradual institutional change. In J.
Mahoney & K. Thelen (Eds.), Explaining institutional change: Ambiguity, agency,
and power (pp. 137). Cambridge University Press.
Mischnick, W. (1980). Letter from Wolfgang Mischnick to Arbeitsring der
Arbeitgeberverbände der Deutschen Chemischen Industrie. Bonn.
Pierson, P. (1996). The path to European integration: A historical institutionalist analy-
sis. Comparative Political Studies,29(2), 123163. https://doi.org/10.1177/
0010414096029002001
Pierson, P. (2000). Increasing returns, path dependence, and the study of politics.
American Political Science Review,94(2), 251268. https://doi.org/10.2307/2586011
Röper, N. (2018). German nance capitalism: The paradigm shift underlying nancial
diversication. New Political Economy,23(3), 366390. https://doi.org/10.1080/
13563467.2017.1371120
Röper, N. (2020). Between substantive and symbolic inuence: Diusion, translation
and bricolage in German pension politics. Review of International Political
Economy,120. https://doi.org/10.1080/09692290.2020.1790405
Röper, N. (2021a). Between competition and cooperation: Financial incumbents and
challengers in German pension politics. Business and Politics,23(2), 243263.
https://doi.org/10.1017/bap.2020.13
Röper, N. (2021b). Capitalists against nancialization: The battle over German pension
funds. Competition & Change,125. https://doi.org/10.1177/1024529421993005
Schmidt, V. A. (2008). Discursive institutionalism: The explanatory power of ideas and
discourse. Annual Review of Political Science,11(1), 303326. https://doi.org/10.
1146/annurev.polisci.11.060606.135342
Schneiberg, M. (2007). Whats on the path? Path dependence, organizational diversity
and the problem of institutional change in the US economy, 19001950. Socio-
Economic Review,5(1), 4780.
Schneider, H. J., Fritz, S., & Zander, E. (2007). Erfolgs- und Kapitalbeteiligung der
Mitarbeiter. Symposion Publishing.
Seidl, T. (2020). The politics of platform capitalism: A case study on the regulation of
Uber in New York. Regulation and Governance.https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12353
Sjöberg, S., & Dube, N. (2014). Economic democracy through collective capital for-
mation: The cases of Germany and Sweden, and strategies for the future. World
Review of Political Economy,5(4), 488515. https://doi.org/10.13169/
worlrevipoliecon.5.4.0488
20 M. B. CARSTENSEN AND N. RÖPER
Soifer, H. D. (2012). The causal logic of critical junctures. Comparative Political Studies,
45(12), 15721597. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414012463902
Streeck, W. (2009). Re-forming capitalism: Institutional change in the German political
economy. Oxford University Press.
Streeck, W., & Thelen, K. (2005). Introduction: Institutional change in advanced political
economies. In W. Streeck & K. Thelen (Eds.), Beyond continuity: Institutional change in
advanced political economies (pp. 139). Oxford University Press.
Thelen, K. (2004). How institutions evolve. Cambridge University.
Toillié, B. (1977). Dezentrale Vermögensbildungsfonds. Duncker & Humboldt.
Vis, B. (2016). Taking stock of the comparative literature on the role of blame avoid-
ance strategies in social policy reform. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis:
Research and Practice,18(2), 122137. https://doi.org/10.1080/13876988.2015.
1005955
Wilder, M., & Howlett, M. (2014). The politics of policy anomalies: Bricolage and the
hermeneutics of paradigms. Critical Policy Studies,8(2), 183202. https://doi.org/
10.1080/19460171.2014.901175
JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN PUBLIC POLICY 21
... Recent HI contributions have criticised both strands for giving too much prominence to structural factors (e.g., McAdam, 2022) and their role in reproducing order (Carstensen & Röper, 2022;Jabko & Sheingate, 2018). The 'coalitional turn' (Emmenegger, 2021;Hall, 2016) in HI seeks to incorporate social coalitions as the basis of institutional genesis and change, as well as of continuity. ...
... The article seeks to make two contributions to the literature. First, it addresses a recent development in the HI literature pointing towards unexpected stability (Carstensen & Röper, 2022;van der Heijden & Kuhlmann, 2017;Jabko & Sheingate, 2018), and documents how a coalition actively works to sustain and stabilise the overall institution through firstand second-order changes (Hall, 1993). Second, the article connects the unexpected stability to the concept of ideational multidimensionality (Skogstad & Wilder, 2019), and shows how this contributes to enabling broad support for the institution from diverse interests within the coalition. ...
... It is the latter type of activity in which we are interested in this study. Maintaining institutional stability may involve the active rearrangement of ideational and institutional elements on the part of the coalition (Carstensen & Röper, 2022). This activity has been referred to as a 'change-but-no-change' strategy (Fitch-Roy et al., 2020, p. 96) and as 'practices of dynamic order', as a means of changing things in order for them 'to stay as they are' (Jabko & Sheingate, 2018, pp. ...
Article
Full-text available
This article contributes to the Historical Institutionalism literature on stability and change by unpacking how an institution has persisted for more than 70 years despite substantial contextual changes. The overall stability of the institution comes both through changes in policy instruments and their settings, and through the incorporation of differing, but aligned rationales. Ideational multidimensionality yields stability by providing leeway to recondition the institution in response to changing circumstances. This allows for different interests in the coalition to stimulate overall institutional stability by supporting incremental changes in policy instruments whilst avoiding institutional exhaustion and third order changes. This shows that policies initiated under a certain set of circumstances may be better equipped to persist when circumstances change if they are able to incorporate differing, but aligned, rationales and to respond to upcoming issues through policy instrument changes. The theoretical arguments are exemplified through a case study analysis of Norwegian agricultural policy.
... Political actors perform three principal tests to determine the usefulness of a particular set of ideas in dealing with policy problems relative to cognitive, normative and strategic standards (cf. Carstensen & Röper, 2022). Most scholarship focuses on cases where policy ideas pass these tests and end up being successfully institutionalized, but naturally a more common occurrence is that a policy idea is explored and found wanting in one or more of the three tests. ...
... Test situations give rise to political struggle because their resolution comes to structure the interpretation and handling of policy problems. To reach a compromise that may temporarily resolve uncertainty and satisfy actor preferences, political actors perform three principal tests to determine the usefulness of a particular set of ideas in dealing with policy problems relative to cognitive, normative and strategic standards (see also Carstensen & Röper, 2022). ...
Article
Full-text available
Literatures on institutional, ideational and policy change have made great strides in dynamically conceptualizing agency within structure. What continues to be insufficiently understood, however, is how actors actually work with ideas, that is, how broad policy ideas become concrete and implementable. One concept that has gained some traction in understanding actors' application of ideas is bricolage, understood as the stabilization or changing of institutions through a creative recombination of existing ideational and institutional resources. We theorize bricolage as a process of working with ideas by testing their cognitive, normative and strategic capacity. In contrast to much of the existing literature, we theorize this ideational policy entrepreneurship as collective agency. This gives greater analytical weight to how different bricoleurs work together—simultaneously and across time—to develop the ideas that come to shape policy. The empirical relevance of the theoretical argument is corroborated with an analysis of the work of bricoleurs in the paradigm shift of German pension policy.
... The work that goes into making these shared repertoires actionable under ever-changing circumstances is cognitive, normative, and strategic. That is, it concerns figuring out what may work to solve the problem at hand, defining solutions within what is deemed normatively acceptable, and building the necessary coalitions to get it through the policy process (Carstensen & Röper, 2022). The plastic and fungible nature of ideas enables bringing together contradictory ideas that render them less susceptible to attacks from rival interpretive frameworks (Best, 2020;Jabko, 2006), which provides an important source of ideational robustness (Schmidt & Thatcher, 2013). ...
... By 2012, the Council moved from a discourse focused on "stability" alone to acceptance of the need for "growth," pushed by Italian Prime Minister Monti and supported by French President Hollande, which led to Merkel's agreement to "growth and stability." By 2014, the Council adopted a discourse of "flexibility, pushed by Italian PM Renzi and supported by Hollande, which led to Merkel's insistence on 'flexibility within the stability rules'" (Carstensen & Röper, 2022;Schmidt, 2020, Ch. 5). Importantly, although this might appear to be "just talk," since no money was attached, the change in discursive practices empowered the Commission to continue with its increasingly loose interpretations of the rules. ...
Article
Full-text available
Is it possible to develop a robust crisis management response in a system where governance is characterized by coercive power and adversarial bargaining rather than the diversity, inclusion, and openness highlighted by extant scholarship as conducive factors for robustness? Using two instances of crisis in the European Union—the Eurozone crisis (2010‒2015) and COVID-19 pandemic (2020‒2022)—the paper argues that how actors reinterpret existing rules and institutions offers an important source of robustness in crisis management. Based on the employment of a disaggregation of robustness into degrees of robustness, as well as the concepts of ideational and institutional power, we show how actors can counter the coercive power of dominant coalitions and open up for rule adaptation through reinterpretations of existing rules that, at least in the short term, can solidify the functioning of existing institutions faced by turbulence. In the context of the Eurozone crisis, ideational and institutional power thus enabled a moderately robust response without treaty reform. In the case of the pandemic, it was possible to convince (particularly German) policymakers of the need to employ new ideas about common debt. This meant less need to employ ideational and institutional power by other actors, leading to significantly more effective crisis management than in the Eurozone crisis, what the paper terms maximal robustness.
... The response of historical institutionalists came in the shape of the 'coalitional turn' (Hall and Thelen, 2009). From this perspective, institutions are not self-sustaining but depend for their stability on the continued support from agents and the coalition they are part of (Capoccia, 2016;Carstensen & Röper, 2021). Simply put, if institutions are supported by coalitions, coalitions have to be built and maintained by sentient actors. ...
... Yet, such coalitions are not set in stone. Rather, constant agency is needed to maintain these coalitions (Carstensen & Röper, 2021). Similarly, whereas new coalitions might be created to further institutional change, such new coalitions are hard to build. ...
... That is, rather than focusing on developing a perfect solution to the problem at hand, the bricoleur focuses on creating a solution that may 'hold' for now. In a political context this means that the solution needs to be considered cognitively sound as a credible way of dealing with the problem (Campbell, 2004;Boakye and Béland, 2022); it must speak to the dominant values within society and the specific policy area(s) (Carstensen and Hansen, 2019); and it must be strategically viable by gaining sufficient political support from coalitions of actors (Carstensen and Röper, 2022). This also means that the creativity often involved in bricolage should not be mistaken for a situation of no limits on actors. ...
Article
Full-text available
What kind of political agency is necessary to foster radical political-economic transformations towards ecological sustainability? Focusing on the radical ecopolitical project of degrowth, this article starts from the observation that a prerequisite for degrowth policies to materialise is political agency that is bold and visionary yet pragmatic; agency that seeks radical change yet does so based on what is already in existence. To capture the nature of the ideal-typical political agent that could exercise this sort of agency, this article builds on scholarship on policy entrepreneurship to develop the concept of the radical bricoleur. It proposes that an important key to 'radicalising' the bricoleur lies in putting greater emphasis on Levi-Strauss' (1966) pre-modern, holistic understanding of what kind of order it is that the bricoleur is seeking to rebuild. Doing so opens the way for redefining the goal of the bricoleur from being the reinstatement of the current capitalist and non-sustainable societal order, to being the reinstatement of an order defined by a logic of balance and harmony between and within humans, as well as humans and nature.
... Some scholars have used it to explain policy transfer and diffusion (Röper, 2021). Others see it as a key mechanism for maintaining institutional stability and continuity (Carstensen and Röper, 2022). The latter use contrasts with yet another approach to bricolage, which conceives it as a concept of change (Copeland, 2022). ...
Article
Full-text available
This article provides a novel conceptualization of bricolage as a strategy for incremental supranational self‐empowerment. It argues that the cumulative effects of different bricolage tools employed by the Commission have been central for progressively strengthening its role in EU security and defence, which culminated in the establishment of the European Defence Fund (EDF) and the Commission's Directorate‐General Defence Industry and Space (DG DEFIS). Building communication upon communication, the Commission used discursive bricolage to set the conditions for employing existing EU financial and organizational resources to advance its interests. Specifically, with its incremental bricolage approach, the Commission has managed to mitigate sovereignty concerns of member states, progressively nudging them towards deeper integration. Overall, our article shows how the Commission has strengthened its influence through the cumulative bricolage tools even in the intergovernmental domains of security and defence.
... Andando oltre i modelli di punctuated equilibrium, in letteratura vi sono stati significativi progressi nel teorizzare il cambiamento incrementale con risultati comunque trasformativi. Concetti quali layering (nuovi elementi 'aggiunti' a un insieme di istituzioni già esistenti ne cambiano l'effettivo funzionamento), drift (il funzionamento di assetti istituzionali già esistenti cambia a causa di mutevoli circostanze), e conversion (istituzioni esistenti vengono reindirizzate verso nuovi obiettivi, funzioni o scopi) sono ben radicati in letteratura (Béland, 2007;Campbell, 2004;Capano, 2019;Carstensen & Röper, 2021;Hacker et al., 2015;Kay & Baines, 2019;Streeck & Thelen, 2005a;Terlizzi, 2019aTerlizzi, , 2019b. Sebbene tali concetti si configurino come processi di cambiamento, alcuni di essi possono essere (re)interpretati come modalità di disegno istituzionale, organizzativo, e di policy che possono eventualmente avere effetti trasformativi. ...
Preprint
Full-text available
This article explores the impact of COVID-19 on the governance of pension policy in the European Union (EU) and investigates the main characteristics of both stability and change in the EU strategies for pension policy. The governance of pensions has attracted the interest of many analysts. Pensions are in fact one of the milestones of the welfare state in EU Member States, while they have been the target of the EU strategy for the retrenchment and modernization of national social policies. The article focuses on three different areas of intervention: the European Semester; the European Pillar of Social Rights; and the Next Generation EU. Drawing from the extensive literature on institutional change, we argue that, whereas significant changes in priorities and instruments have occurred, these have been the result of a process of rapid evolutionary change through layering, suspension, and updating which has resulted in ideational and institutional bricolage. All these changes seem consistent with the potential revision of the EU strategy and priorities in pension policy.
Article
Full-text available
Understanding the origins of policy ideas can be crucial when trying to explain dynamics of political change and continuity. Paradigmatic changes in the German pension system have been attributed to the import of "foreign" neoliberal policy ideas from transnational organizations and other countries. The literature describes such processes as policy diffusion, transfer, or translation. In contrast, this article argues that foreign pension ideas did not have a substantive influence on local policy innovations and preference-formation processes. Instead, pension policy pioneers developed their ideas predominantly "from within" through bricolage by reconfiguring long-standing domestic schools of thought. Drawing on a wide range of primary and secondary sources, the analysis combines a broad historical perspective with case studies of individual policy makers. This sheds new light on the careers of ideas and why significant actors pick them up at certain points.
Article
The concept of robustness has received increasing scholarly attention regarding public policy and governance, where it has enhanced our understanding of how policies and governance are adapted and innovated in response to disruptive events, challenges, and demands associated with heightened societal turbulence. Yet, we know little about the robustness of the ideas undergirding the efforts to foster robust policymaking and public governance. Based on a review of recent strands of governance theory and the ideational turn in public policy research, we define a new ideational robustness concept, which can help us to explain why some governance and policy ideas persist, while others disappear. As the contributions to this special issue demonstrate, studying ideational robustness opens new avenues for reflecting on how the robustness of ideas may affect the robustness of public policy and governance.
Article
Full-text available
Despite renewed interest in the role of business in shaping the welfare state, we still know little about how factions of capital adapt their strategies and translate these into political infighting and coalition building. Based on a detailed process tracing analysis of the political battle over German pension funds, this paper shows that cleavages within business do not necessarily run along the lines of finance vs. non-finance. While 'financial challengers' (banks and investment companies) advocated financialized pension funds, 'financial incumbents' (insurers) defended a conservative understanding of old age provision. Tremendous political momentum toward financialization notwithstanding, challengers remained largely unsuccessful. Incumbents elicited support from the wider business community by adjusting their strategic goals and engaging in discursive reformulations to effectively fight pension financialization from within capital. To accommodate such competition politics and coalition building, the paper argues for a more dynamic understanding of business strategizing and highlights the importance of discursive political strategies. It shows that some capitalists may act as antagonists of elements of financialization and problematizes the actual mechanisms of coalition building through which business plurality affects political outcomes.
Article
Full-text available
Institutionalism gives priority to structure over agency. Yet institutions have never developed and operated without the intervention of interested groups. This paper develops a conceptual framework for the role of agency in historical institutionalism. Based on recent contributions following the coalitional turn and drawing on insights from sociological institutionalism, it argues that agency plays a key role in the creation and maintenance of social coalitions that stabilize but also challenge institutions. Without such agency, no coalition can be created, maintained, or changed. Similarly, without a supporting coalition, no contested institution can survive. Yet, due to collective action problems, such coalitional work is challenging. This coalitional perspective offers a robust role for agency in historical institutionalism, but it also explains why institutions remain stable despite agency. In addition, this paper forwards several portable propositions that allow for the identification of who is likely to develop agency and what these actors do.
Article
Full-text available
It has long been overlooked that factions of finance such as banks and insurers can have opposing policy interests. This paper is concerned with the preferences and strategies of private financial actors in the context of private prefunded pensions. To capture the “tug of war” among these actors, this paper identifies their different financial business models (insurance- and investment-orientation), political roles (financial incumbents and challengers), and levels at which infighting may occur (political and product-market level). For the German case, it shows that product-market competition among financial incumbents and challengers over retirement savings products only turned into competition politics during the 1990s, when shifting political winds provided an opening to insert path-shaping instruments in line with the program of finance capitalism. Financial actors’ preferences are not a derivative of economic or functional incentives, but socially embedded in that they are crucially shaped by interactions with their competitors and the political environment. The analysis disentangles the complex web of competition, cooperation, and ownership among factions of finance and discerns their genuine preferences from those strategically adjusted to context. This sheds doubt on functionalist explanations of (pension) financialization and enhances our understanding of how financial actors form and pursue their preferences.
Article
Full-text available
Previous research on institutional change has concentrated on two types of explanations. On one hand, the dualism of path dependency and critical junctures has advanced our understanding of how institutional change occurs due to sudden exogenous shocks. On the other hand, more recent critiques have established a better understanding of endogenous, gradual change. This article is motivated by observations that current research tends to overlook what I call the “missing diagonal.” I argue that we need to disentangle the sources of a cause (exogenous vs. endogenous) from its time horizon (sudden vs. gradual). By cross-tabulating these two dimensions, the proposed typology of institutional change explanations is able to capture complex multilayered as well as sequential arguments of institutional change. The typology urges scholars to be more precise with their social science language of erosion and decay, while serving as a generator for an innovative research agenda on endogenous ruptures.
Article
Full-text available
Diffusion, transfer and translation literatures assume that policy ideas are conceived exogenously, while domestic perspectives such as bricolage consider policy innovations as reactivated local ideas. Cases where foreign ideas do not shape local actors' preferences, but still feature saliently in public discourse therefore appear in a conceptual blind spot. This paper develops a distinction into symbolic and substantive functions of foreign ideas. For the case of German pension politics it argues that foreign ideas can be causally consequential as (symbolic) framing devices, even if their underlying ideas had (substantively) long been conceived and advocated in the domestic context. The analysis finds that the foreign-frame 'Anglo-American pension funds'-a most likely case for translation or diffusion-was initially employed by change agents to advance their longstanding preference for more financialized pension policies. During the ensuing political struggles, continuity agents successfully reinterpreted and utilized the same frame to prevent pension financialization and veneer continuity as the transfer of a foreign policy innovation in what is best described as label localization. Thinking of foreign ideas in substantive and symbolic terms specifies how ideas emerge and how they are used in political conflict, which bridges global and domestic perspectives on policy change.
Chapter
Debates surrounding institutional change have become increasingly central to Political Science, Management Studies, and Sociology, opposing the role of globalization in bringing about a convergence of national economies and institutions on one model to theories about ‘Varieties of Capitalism’. This book brings together a distinguished set of contributors from a variety to examine current theories of institutional change. The chapters highlight the limitations of these theories, finding them lacking in the analytic tools necessary to identify the changes occurring at a national level, and therefore tend to explain many changes and innovations as simply another version of previous situations. Instead a model emerges of contemporary political economies developing in incremental but cumulatively transformative processes. The contributors shoe that a wide, but not infinite, variety of models of institutional change exist which can meaningfully distinguished and analytically compared. They offer an empirically grounded typology of modes of institutional change that offer important insights on mechanisms of social and political stability, and evolution generally. Beyond Continuity provides a more complex and fundamental understanding of institutional change, and will be important reading for academics, researchers, and advanced students of Political Science, Management Studies, Sociology and Economics.
Chapter
Debates surrounding institutional change have become increasingly central to Political Science, Management Studies, and Sociology, opposing the role of globalization in bringing about a convergence of national economies and institutions on one model to theories about ‘Varieties of Capitalism’. This book brings together a distinguished set of contributors from a variety to examine current theories of institutional change. The chapters highlight the limitations of these theories, finding them lacking in the analytic tools necessary to identify the changes occurring at a national level, and therefore tend to explain many changes and innovations as simply another version of previous situations. Instead a model emerges of contemporary political economies developing in incremental but cumulatively transformative processes. The contributors shoe that a wide, but not infinite, variety of models of institutional change exist which can meaningfully distinguished and analytically compared. They offer an empirically grounded typology of modes of institutional change that offer important insights on mechanisms of social and political stability, and evolution generally. Beyond Continuity provides a more complex and fundamental understanding of institutional change, and will be important reading for academics, researchers, and advanced students of Political Science, Management Studies, Sociology and Economics.
Book
This book picks up where Karl Polanyi's study of economic and political change left off. Building upon Polanyi's conception of the double movement, Blyth analyzes the two periods of deep seated institutional change that characterized the twentieth century: the 1930s and the 1970s. Blyth views both sets of changes as part of the same dynamic. In the 1930s labor reacted against the exigencies of the market and demanded state action to mitigate the market's effects by 'embedding liberalism.' In the 1970s, those who benefited least from such 'embedding' institutions, namely business, reacted against these constraints and sought to overturn that institutional order. Blyth demonstrates the critical role economic ideas played in making institutional change possible. Great Transformations rethinks the relationship between uncertainty, ideas, and interests, achieving profound new insights on how, and under what conditions, institutional change takes place.
Article
Platform companies like Uber not only disrupt existing markets but also contest existing regulatory regimes. This raises the question of how, when, and why such companies are regulated. This article develops, tests, and defends a theoretical framework that explains the politics of regulatory response to the rise of platform capitalism. Using discourse network analysis and a case study on the regulation of Uber in New York, it shows that the success or failure of regulations depends on the ability of actors to mobilize broad coalition; that narratives affect the composition of these coalitions; and that platform companies have both unique political strengths and vulnerabilities. This article makes substantive contributions to our understanding of the politics of platform capitalism, and it makes theoretical contributions to the literature studies on coalitional politics, ideational institutionalism, and business power.