ChapterPDF Available

Growth Models Under Austerity

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

Fiscal policy is an integral part of a country's growth model. An export-led strategy requires a reduction of fiscal deficits in order to promote cost competitiveness, while a demand-led strategy requires fiscal flexibility to manage domestic demand. This chapter shows that governments in fact subordinate their fiscal policy to the macroeconomic regime of their country: governments in export-led economies are 2-3 times more likely to pursue fiscal austerity than those in demand-led regimes. We also find that the rigid fiscal policies that many countries pursue are not in line with voter attitudes and individual level macroeconomic beliefs. Contrary to the economic ideas that provide the intellectual foundation of fiscal austerity, voters believe that these policies are detrimental to economic growth, but there is great variation in the beliefs of left and right voters. These ideological differences translate into distinct fiscal policies under left and right governments in balanced growth regimes, but not in unbalanced regimes. These results point to a mismatch between government policy, especially in export-led economies, and voter views on fiscal policy. This mismatch potentially contributes to the political disillusionment of voters and hence the rise of populist parties.
Content may be subject to copyright.
1
Growth Models Under Austerity
Evelyne Hübscher & Thomas Sattler
Chapter 15 in: Lucio Baccaro, Mark Blyth and Jonas Pontusson (eds.). 2022. Diminishing
Returns: The New Politics of Growth and Stagnation. Oxford University Press.
Abstract
Fiscal policy is an integral part of a country’s growth model. This chapter shows how
governments subordinate their fiscal policy to the macroeconomic regime of their country:
governments in export-led economies are 2-3 times more likely to pursue fiscal austerity than
those in demand-led regimes. These rigid fiscal policies in many countries are not in line with
voter attitudes and individual-level macroeconomic beliefs. Contrary to the economic ideas
that provide the intellectual foundation of fiscal austerity, voters believe that these policies
are detrimental to economic growth, but there is great variation between left and right voters.
These ideological differences translate into distinct fiscal policies under left and right
governments in balanced growth regimes, but not in unbalanced regimes. These results point
to a mismatch between government policy, especially in export-led economies, and voter
attitudes. This mismatch potentially contributes to the disillusionment of voters that has been
observed in many countries.
Keywords: fiscal policy; austerity; growth model; party politics; voters; partisanship; public
opinion
1. Introduction
Fiscal policy is an integral part of a country’s growth model (Baccaro and Pontusson 2016;
Blyth and Matthijs 2017). An export-led strategy, for instance, requires that governments
limit fiscal deficits i.e. by implementing fiscal austerity in order to promote cost
competitiveness and, hence, to enhance export opportunities for domestic firms. In contrast,
governments in demand-led regimes should be less concerned about fiscal deficits because
they need fiscal flexibility to manage domestic demand.
This chapter shows that, consistent with the implications of the growth-models perspective,
governments subordinate their fiscal policy to the macroeconomic regime of their country.
We find that the decision to pursue fiscal austerity varies significantly across countries. This
variation is in line with a country’s growth model. The amount of fiscal austerity
implemented in export-oriented economies before the Great Recession is about 2–3 times
greater than the amount of austerity in demand-led economies. Differences in austerity are
2
more strongly related to growth regimes than to other economic or political variables,
including fiscal deficits, government partisanship or political constraints.
Our analysis also contrasts this systemic, regime-based view with the popular approach in
political economy to explain economic policies from a voter-driven, bottom-up perspective.
Contrary to this view, we find that growth models dominate voter preferences: governments
tend to favor the fiscal policies that reinforce their country’s growth regime even if these
policies stand in conflict with the preferences of voters. Specifically, voters are quite critical
of austerity, but this skepticism does not prevent governments in export-led countries from
systematically implementing spending cuts. In addition, government responsiveness is lowest
in growth models that are closest to a specific `ideal type’: While on average left voters are
much less supportive of austerity than right voters, these diverging preferences only translate
into distinct policies under left and right governments in balanced growth regimes, but not in
unbalanced regimes, i.e. heavily export- or demand-led, regimes.
Together, these results suggest that a country’s overarching macroeconomic strategy is
critical to understand fiscal and macroeconomic policymaking. It better explains variations in
fiscal austerity than voter preferences, and it limits the ability or willingness of party
governments to respond to the fiscal preferences of their supporters in regimes that mirror
ideal growth models. This points to a mismatch between government policy, especially in
export-led economies, and voter attitudes. This mismatch is likely to contribute to political
disillusionment of voters and possibly contributes to political perturbations, such as the rise
of populist parties (Hopkin 2020; Hopkin and Blyth 2019) especially in those countries
where austerity is implemented without the postulated positive effects on growth.
2. Fiscal policy and growth regimes
2.1 Popular perspectives on austerity
A common perspective in comparative and international political economy puts popular
preferences at the center of the analysis of economic policymaking (e.g., (Beramendi et al.
2015; Lake 2009). In this bottom-up view, voters demand or oppose economic policies,
which incentivizes governments to pursue or avoid these policies. Change in economic policy
3
then can occur either through a swing in voter preferences; or through a change in
government partisanship when new government parties represent societal groups with
interests and beliefs that are different from the supporter of previous government parties.
Voters can prevent economic policies by threating to punish government parties in the next
election or by vetoing policy change at various stages of the policymaking process
(Hallerberg and Basinger 1998; Henisz 2004; Immergut 1992).
Applied to fiscal policy, the above model implies that variation in the pursuit of austerity
primarily arises from variation in voter attitudes towards fiscal cuts, change in government
partisanship, or differences in political constraints, such as veto players. But evidence that
this is the case is limited, for two reasons. First, voter preferences cannot explain variation in
fiscal policies across countries with different growth regimes. For a long time, and potentially
in line with the voter-driven perspective, the political economy literature suggested that
voters dislike fiscal deficits and, hence, support deficit-reducing policies (Alesina et al. 2011;
Alesina et al. 1998; Brender and Drazen 2008). More recent findings, however, raise doubts
about the enthusiasm of voters towards austerity. Although voters may be critical of deficits
and debt (Brender and Drazen 2008), they are even more critical of austerity when they are
confronted with concrete propositions to cut spending in specific areas, such as pensions,
unemployment insurance or education (Bojar et al. 2018; Bremer and Bürgisser 2018;
Hübscher et al. 2020). This opposition is remarkably stable across countries (Hübscher et al.
2020) and over time (Hübscher et al. 2015).
1
Second, fiscal policies should diverge more strongly across party governments than they
actually do if voter preferences were a key driver of these policies. We know from previous
research that voters hold different attitudes towards austerity depending on their ideological
orientation: left voters are significantly more likely to reject austerity than right voters
(Hübscher et al. 2020). But despite this large ideological variation, government partisanship
only has a limited effect on austerity policies: left and right governments are about equally
likely to implement austerity packages (Hübscher 2016, 2018; Hübscher and Sattler 2017).
2
1
Of course, exceptions in peculiar circumstances are possible. For instance, many Eastern
European citizens accepted austerity in order to avoid currency devaluations, which would
have increased their foreign currency denominated debt (Walter 2015).
2
There is a tendency towards more austerity by right governments, but this result depends on
model specification and is not robust. There is also evidence that austerity packages by left
4
Others find that left governments are more likely to cut welfare spending, which is in
contradiction to the voter-driven perspective (Armingeon et al. 2016).
2.2 Fiscal austerity through a growth-models lens
Given these limitations of the voter-driven approach, growth models offer a fresh political
perspective on the determinants of fiscal policy and overall macroeconomic policy. Fiscal
policy, i.e. fiscal expansion or restraint, plays a crucial role for a country’s macroeconomic
regime. Public investment and consumption directly contribute a significant share towards a
country’s domestic demand. Public expenditures also indirectly affect demand via their effect
on citizens’ consumption behavior, e.g. by increasing or decreasing wages in the public
sector or by providing more or less generous social assistance programs. In countries that
pursue a consumption- and demand-led model, fiscal flexibility, therefore, is an important
instrument to stimulate domestic demand and hence growth.
Public spending policies also have fundamental consequences for international
competitiveness of domestic firms and their export opportunities. Public deficits induce
inward capital flows when international investors buy government bonds. These inflows push
countries towards a current account deficit (Chinn and Prasad 2003; Jones 2015, 2016) and,
hence, are detrimental to exports. Public sector employment and wages also feature
prominently in real-economy models of trade imbalances. Trade surpluses are easier to
achieve in systems with wage coordination, in which the sheltered sector, such as the public
sector, accepts to limit wage growth in line with the interests of the exposed, trading sector
(Johnston 2016; Johnston et al. 2014; Manger and Sattler 2020). In countries that pursue an
export-led model, fiscal restraint, therefore, is the preferred fiscal strategy.
These diverging fiscal strategies have their ideational origins in different economic literatures
that postulate distinct mechanisms linking fiscal policy to economic growth. A large
macroeconomics literature highlights the positive impact of fiscal policy on growth via so-
called ‘fiscal multipliers’. Vice versa, research in this tradition points to the adverse effect of
fiscal austerity on growth (Chowdhury and Islam 2012; Guajardo et al. 2014), especially
during recessions (Jordà and Taylor 2016). In line with these insights, recent research shows
governments are somewhat smaller, but these differences are small compared to differences
in attitudes between left and right voters.
5
that fiscal multipliers and hence the detrimental impact of austerity on European economies
were much larger during the past crisis than the ECB assumed (Gόrnicka et al. 2018).
Researchers in this tradition, therefore, have called for a more active fiscal policy in order to
stimulate growth (Blanchard 2019; Blanchard and Summers 2017).
The intellectual counter position to the fiscal flexibility view does not explicitly consider the
link between fiscal policy and international competitiveness and exports. But it also points to
a supply side argument that connects low deficits and fiscal restraint to economic growth via
‘expansionary fiscal contractions’. As Blyth (2013) describes in detail (see also, Dellepiane-
Avellaneda 2014), an influential view advocates that fiscal austerity in fact does not inhibit
growth, but can even induce economic expansion (Alesina et al. 2019; Giavazzi and Pagano
1990).
3
To the extent that fiscal consolidations have negative effects, these are traced to an
inadequate strategy to consolidate: in particular, tax-based consolidations are seen as
detrimental to growth, while growth is unaffected by spending-based consolidations.
From a growth-models perspective, fiscal and macroeconomic policies should be much less
variant over time than the voter-driven perspective suggests. Specifically, fiscal austerity can
be expected to change less with government ideology and voter attitudes and should
primarily vary across countries that pursue distinct macroeconomic strategies. Largely, the
main macroeconomic policies should be ‘locked in’, either institutionally, ideationally or
politically. Institutionally, debt brakes, for instance, can ensure that governments of export-
led countries do not deviate from the prescribed low-deficit policies. Ideationally, the public
discourse can help to secure wider political support for the preferred policy by disseminating
the economic arguments that motivate the country’s growth model (Barnes and Hicks 2018;
Ferrara et al. 2021). Politically, the influence of the dominant social bloc pushes political
parties and governments towards the policy that is in line with the growth model (see esp.
chapters 1 and 15 in this volume, and Haffert and Mertens 2019). To the extent that policies
vary over time, policy adjustments mostly follow the need of the particular growth regimes
and vary less according to political ideology.
4
3
In the language of the previous view, this means that the ‘fiscal multiplier’ is small or even
reverse.
4
Accordingly, macroeconomic outcomes that are central to growth models, notably current
accounts, are highly persistent and vary mostly across countries. This cross-country variation
in current accounts and trade balances is much more significant than the within-country
variation over time (Manger and Sattler 2020).
6
This does not necessarily mean that ideology and government partisanship do not play any
role at all. Instead, partisanship may matter most in countries with more balanced growth
regimes, i.e. in which both domestic and external demand equally contribute to economic
growth, but it should matter less in countries with more unbalanced growth regimes. In
export-led regimes, the dominant social interests are aligned in favor of fiscal austerity,
which pushes both left and right governments in that direction. In demand-led regimes, social
interests demand fiscal flexibility and oppose austerity, which again should be taken into
account by both left and right governments. In mixed regimes, however, governments have
greater political room to pursue distinct fiscal policies that vary according to their ideological
viewpoints and the attitudes of their supporters.
3. What do voters want? Beliefs about austerity and growth
Following the discussion in the previous section, we begin our empirical analysis with an
analysis of voters (cf., Häusermann and Kriesi 2015). Specifically, we study the beliefs that
they hold about the link between fiscal policy and economic growth. This allows us to
explore to what extent these beliefs are consistent with the ideational narratives that
accompanied fiscal consolidation measures taken by governments over the past decades. It
also allows us to see how voter attitudes vary, both across countries and across subgroups of
voters. We will then compare these attitudes with the actual behavior of governments, which
we will analyze in the next section.
We conducted surveys in two countries Germany and the United Kingdom – because they
represent polar extremes in terms of their growth model (see chapters 9 and 10 in this volume
and section 4 of this chapter). The survey took the form of a vignette-based online
experiment (Mutz 2011), which allows us to examine how respondents evaluate the
governments’ fiscal strategy and its impact on economic growth. All respondents read about
a situation in which their country experiences a situation of low growth and high fiscal
deficit.
We then present two different scenarios how the government intends to address this situation.
In both scenarios, the government aims at reducing the deficit and increasing growth albeit
7
through fundamentally different mechanisms. Each mechanism corresponds to one of the
different economic theories discussed in the previous section. In the first scenario, the
government follows a Keynesian approach that highlights ‘fiscal multipliers’: it proposes to
increase public spending in order to stimulate growth, which should then lead to a lower
fiscal deficit. In the second scenario, the government follows a non-Keynesian approach that
highlights the possibility of ‘expansionary fiscal contractions’: it proposes to cut public
spending in order to reduce the deficit, which should then stimulate economic growth. The
control group read about a scenario, in which the government does not change fiscal policy.
Respondents are randomly exposed to one out of these three scenarios and the difference in
their responses towards the scenarios represent the political effect of one policy solution
compared to another.
5
Table 1 shows the exact wording of each scenario.
Table 1: Design of Experiment
Introduction (shown to all respondents)
The UK [German] economy has experienced slow economic growth for several years. At the same time, the UK
[Germany] has experienced a sizeable deficit in the public budget for several years. The UK’s prime minister
[German Chancellor] then announces in a televised speech how to deal with the situation.
Group 1 (Control)
Group 2 (Austerity)
Group 3 (Expansion)
The prime minister says that
despite this situation, the
government will keep the current
level of public spending on
government programmes, such as
public infrastructure, healthcare,
schools and public pensions,
unchanged.
The prime minister says that the
government will cut public
spending on government
programmes, such as public
infrastructure, healthcare, schools
and public pensions, in order to
reduce the public deficit. The
prime minister says that the
resulting reduction of the public
deficit will also stimulate economic
growth.
The prime minister says that that
the government will increase
public spending on government
programmes, such as public
infrastructure, healthcare, schools
and public pensions, in order to
stimulate economic growth. The
prime minister says that the
resulting increase in economic
growth will also reduce the public
deficit.
After having been exposed to one of the above scenarios, the respondents answered a set of
questions that are used as outcome variables in our analysis. More specifically, respondents
were asked 1) to what extent they approve of the government’s policy strategy, and 2) how,
according to them, the decision will affect economic growth.
6
This allows us to examine to
5
The fielding phase of the survey has been administered by respondi. For each country we
have a total of roughly 1.200 respondents (stratified by age cohorts and gender). The survey
has been in the field between August 2 and August 9, 2019.
6
The exact wording of the questions is the following: “To what extent do you approve the
Prime Minister’s announcement?”, answer categories varied between 1 (strongly disapprove)
to 5 (strongly approve); “How do you think this decision will affect the growth of the British
[German] economy?”, with answer categories varying between “negatively”, “neither/nor”,
and “positively”.
8
what extent respondent’s assessment of fiscal policy is consistent with the economic ideas
discussed above.
Figure 1: Approval of policy (approval varies between 1 and 5, with higher values
indicating higher levels of approval)
Figure 1 shows the mean values of all three treatment groups for the approval of each policy
option with 95% confidence intervals. It becomes immediately clear that a decrease in
spending is the least preferred option in both countries.
7
A decrease in spending is also
significantly less popular than the status quo with popular disagreement being stronger in
Germany than in the UK. In both countries, an increase in spending is the most popular
policy option. In the UK this policy option enjoys significantly more approval than the status
quo, which is not the case in Germany. This finding could be interpreted as evidence that
on average – voters in Germany may be more critical of spending increases than voters in the
UK, which is in line with our expectations for an export-led economy. However, these
differences are small compared to the general disagreement with fiscal cuts in both countries.
7
Assessing the impact of our policy treatments on a third outcome variable (whether
respondents would vote for the prime minister after a given treatment) reveals the same
results, the proportion of respondents who would vote for the incumbent is as low as 10% for
Germany and roughly 25% for the UK.
0
.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
5
Approval of Govt. Decision
No Change Decrease Spending
Increase Spending
Germany
0
.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
5
Approval of Govt. Decision
No Change Decrease Spending
Increase Spending
UK
9
Figure 2: Expected impact of policy on economic growth
We also examine voters’ beliefs about the relationship between the different types of fiscal
policies and economic growth. Figure 2 shows how respondents expect the economic
performance of their country to change as a result of different fiscal policies. We find that an
overwhelming majority of respondents believe that an increase in public spending will have a
positive effect on economic growth. Specifically, the ratio of respondents who expect an
increase in spending to have a positive effect ranges from 50% (in Germany) to 60% (in the
UK). In contrast, only a relatively small faction of respondents (10%-20%) think that
austerity measures will have a positive effect on the economy. If voter preferences were in
line with the dominant growth model, we should find that German voters, on average, expect
austerity to have a positive effect on economic growth and an increase in spending to be
negatively associated with economic growth.
Finally, we examine how these evaluations differ with respondents’ political ideology,
notably their self-placement on the left-right axis. Figure 3 shows that in both countries the
predicted level of approval for spending increases is high across the whole ideological
spectrum, with the UK showing a slightly higher level of support for spending increases
(across the ideological spectrum). Furthermore, support for increases in spending at the very
left of the ideological spectrum is only slightly different from the level of support at the very
right. In contrast, approval of austerity varies greatly in the UK with the left being highly
0
.1
.2
.3
.4
.5
.6
.7
Positive Impact on Econ. Growth
No Change Decrease Spending
Increase Spending
Germany
0
.1
.2
.3
.4
.5
.6
.7
Positive Impact on Econ. Growth
No Change Decrease Spending
Increase Spending
UK
10
critical of austerity and the right showing a significantly higher level of approval. While the
overall pattern in Germany is similar (in particular for approval of increases in spending), the
level of support for austerity is approximately the same as in the UK at the left of the political
spectrum, but does not increase as much as it does in the UK when moving towards the right
of the political spectrum. In fact, the level of approval of austerity at the left is only slightly
different from the level of approval at the conservative end as indicated by the 95%
confidence intervals.
Figure 3: Predicted effect of spending increases (gray) and spending cuts (black) on
policy approval as left-right position of voters changes (with 95% confidence interval).
We again perform the same analysis for the expected impact on economic growth in Figure
A3. More left voters expect that spending has a positive effect on economic growth than right
voters. In the UK, there is a shared belief across the ideological spectrum that an increase in
spending will have a positive effect on economic growth, while there is a clear divide across
the ideological spectrum when it comes to respondents’ evaluation of the impact austerity.
While the left expects that cuts have a negative impact on growth, voters on the right expect a
more positive effect of austerity on growth.
The evidence on voter attitudes in this section suggests that voters are rather skeptical about
the ideational narrative that has shaped the latest series of fiscal consolidation episodes. The
beliefs of a majority of voters are not consistent with the economic arguments coined by
11
economists and exponents from international organizations, which were overwhelmingly in
favor of austerity policies (until the most recent past). While there is variation in the level of
opposition towards austerity across the political spectrum, a majority of respondents find the
Keynesian arguments about the connection between fiscal policy and economic growth more
convincing. Furthermore, opposition to austerity is similar in countries following a demand-
led as well as an export-led growth model.
4. What do governments do? Patterns of growth regimes and austerity
The previous section found that voters, on average, are quite critical of the idea that austerity
will be good for economic performance. At the same time, there is a strong difference
between left and right voters. In this section, we examine to what extent these diverging
views translate into different fiscal policies under different party governments. Or whether
fiscal austerity is in fact much more tied to systemic factors, in particular the growth regime
of a particular country.
Our analysis uses data from the IMF on fiscal consolidation events in 16 OECD countries
between 1978 and 2007 (Devries et al. 2011). This dataset includes all political
announcements of fiscal measures that aim at reducing the public deficit as reported in
government documents and policy reports. The indicator reflects by how much these
measures were supposed to improve the fiscal balance (as % of the GDP). As opposed to
commonly used fiscal policy measures that are grounded in actual spending, this indicator
does not reflect variation of macro-economic indicators, such as the level of unemployment
and economic growth. The indicator used, therefore, allows us to directly uncover political
dynamics in fiscal consolidation and has become the standard indicator of fiscal
consolidations in recent research (Alesina et al. 2015; Armingeon et al. 2016; Guajardo et al.
2014; Hübscher 2016).
To identify differences in growth regimes, we use an indicator by Baccaro and Neimanns
(2021) that captures the contributions of exports and internal demand to aggregate growth of
a country. Although we also look at export and demand contributions separately, we
generally use the difference between export and demand contributions to growth because
both dimensions are theoretically relevant for our purpose. A value around zero means that
12
export and internal demand contributes about equally to growth, i.e. the growth model is
balanced. Negative (positive) values mean that internal demand (exports) contribute
disproportionately to growth, i.e. the growth model is more unbalanced. This indicator is
available from 2000 onwards. Since we want to examine cross-country differences, we use
the mean of the indicator for each country between 2000 and 2007.
Figure 4: Austerity and growth contributions per country (until 2007)
Figure 4 shows how austerity (left graph) and growth contributions (right graph) are
distributed across countries. The figure reveals a number of insightful patterns that are
consistent with the growth model perspective. First, the overall size of consolidation
implemented in these countries varies significantly. It ranges from a total of 23% of GDP in
Italy to just about 3% in France. If we only look at spending-based (as opposed to tax-based)
consolidations, the Netherlands with fiscal cutbacks of more than 13% of its GDP is the
biggest consolidator. France implemented the smallest spending cuts with a total of about 1%
of its GDP. In other words, the cross-country variation in fiscal austerity is considerable. As
we will show below, this variation can only partially be explained with core macro-economic
fundamentals, such as the state of public finances.
Second, and crucial for our purpose, the pattern of fiscal consolidations seems to be largely
consistent with the growth models view. Among the countries with particularly low levels of
austerity are the United States, the UK and Australia, in which, according to the graph on the
right in Figure 3, internal demand contributes much more to growth than exports. In contrast,
0 5 10 15 20 25
Total fiscal consolidation (% of GDP)
France
Australia
United Kingdom
United States
Denmark
Portugal
Canada
Finland
Austria
Ireland
Spain
Germany
Sweden
Belgium
Netherlands
Italy
Spending-based consolidation
Tax-based consolidation
-.03 -.02 -.01 0 .01 .02
Growth Contributions: External - Internal
United States
Australia
Spain
United Kingdom
Finland
Canada
Portugal
France
Italy
Denmark
Sweden
Austria
Netherlands
Ireland
Germany
Belgium
13
countries, where export contribute most to economic growth, like Germany, Belgium and the
Netherlands, dominate the top of the austerity ranking. The differences in fiscal policy
between these two groups are sizeable. The total amount of consolidation by the export-led
group is about 2-3 times the size of the amount by the demand-led group. A more systematic
analysis of the bivariate relationship between growth contributions and austerity confirms this
preliminary conclusion (see Appendix A.2). There is a clear correlation between growth
contributions and total austerity. Most of this correlation is due to the relationship between
export contributions and austerity, but the pattern between demand contributions and
austerity also goes in the expected direction.
The question now arises to what extent these differences are related to varying
macroeconomic fundamentals, especially fiscal deficits, and political circumstances, in
particular government ideology, across countries. When zooming in on how austerity events
are spread over time while also plotting information on a country’s deficit (see Appendix
A.3), we find that austerity is only partially related to fiscal deficits. For instance, the US and
the UK refrained from implementing austerity even during periods of prolonged and at
times substantive deficits. This pattern becomes more pronounced from the mid-1990s
leading up to the `Great Recession’.
8
Germany, and other more export-oriented countries,
such as the Netherlands, and Belgium, battled fiscal deficits much more pro-actively by
implementing austerity measures or managed to run surpluses for a number of consecutive
years, which rendered austerity unnecessary.
8
This coincides with the period that Baccaro and Pontusson (2016) define as turning point,
from 1993 up to the Great Recession.
14
Table 2: Determinants of fiscal austerity
Baseline / OLS
Full / OLS
Full / Multilevel
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
GrowthContr(i)
5.105***
5.682*
(1.955)
(2.962)
Abs(GrowthContr)(i)
-5.676
-5.539
(5.141)
(6.270)
Ideology(i,t)
0.021
0.049***
0.029*
0.124***
0.037**
0.126***
(0.015)
(0.018)
(0.016)
(0.037)
(0.018)
(0.043)
Abs(GrowthContr)(i)*Ideology(i,t)
-7.155***
-7.132**
(2.039)
(2.948)
Constraints(i,t)
0.203
-0.915*
0.102
0.379
-0.126
0.189
(0.224)
(0.477)
(0.230)
(0.244)
(0.291)
(0.284)
Deficit(i,t-1)
-0.069***
-0.083***
-0.068***
-0.067***
-0.075***
-0.073***
(0.010)
(0.011)
(0.010)
(0.010)
(0.008)
(0.008)
Growth(i,t-1)
-0.037***
-0.028*
-0.037***
-0.035**
-0.033**
-0.032**
(0.014)
(0.015)
(0.014)
(0.014)
(0.014)
(0.014)
Constant
0.311***
0.326***
0.397***
0.325***
0.391***
(0.026)
(0.028)
(0.077)
(0.040)
(0.084)
Fixed / Random effects
--
FE
--
--
RE
RE
Sd(Cons)
--
--
--
--
0.11
0.09
Sd(Ideo)
--
--
--
--
--
0.04
Corr(Cons, Ideo)
--
--
--
--
--
-0.09
p
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
R2
0.20
0.41
0.21
0.22
--
--
N
477
477
477
477
477
477
Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.
15
To further investigate the role of the broader macro-economic and political environments in
these countries, we also estimate a series of annual time-series cross-section models with
fiscal austerity as the outcome variable. This allows us to examine the relationship between
growth regimes and austerity, net of the variation that arises due to systematically different
macroeconomic and political circumstances. Following our theoretical discussion, we include
the fiscal balance and economic growth as macroeconomic explanatory variables. In order to
assess political determinants of fiscal consolidation, we consider government ideology and
institutional constraints.
9
This strategy allows us to isolate the country-specific differences
that are not related to variation in macro-economic or political circumstances.
As expected, the results for the first baseline model in Table 2 show that fiscal deficits have a
considerable impact on the propensity of a government to implement austerity. Specifically, a
one-unit increase in the fiscal balance (1% of GDP) leads to a decrease in consolidation
activities of ca. 0.07% of GDP. Political and institutional factors do not have a significant
impact on fiscal consolidation. While the sign on the coefficient on government partisanship
goes into the expected direction (more conservative governments implement bigger
consolidation packages), the coefficients are not robustly statistically significant.
Although the economic variables, especially the fiscal balance, have an important influence
on fiscal consolidations, the baseline model with country-fixed effects show that a large part
of the variation is country-specific and unrelated to fundamental macro-economic indicators.
The explained variance in the specifications that include country dummies is more than twice
as big than the explained variance in the specifications without. This confirms our
expectation that countries vary in their fiscal strategy in a way that the standard economic and
political variables do not capture.
9
The variables measuring fiscal deficits and growth are taken from the Comparative
Institutional Dataset by Armingeon et al.. Government ideology is operationalized as the
government parties’ position on the ideological left-right axis from the Comparative
Manifestos Dataset (Volkens et al. 2013) weighted by its vote share. Lower values on the
ideology variable signify a more leftist government. In order to control for institutional
constraints we use Henisz’s (2004) index of political constraints, which measures to what
extent a government is constrained to implement its agenda. A higher level of political
constraints implies that the government is meeting a veto point, i.e. in the form of a different
majority in the upper chamber.
16
We, therefore, re-examine to what extent the growth regime of a country can explain the
cross-country variation after having factored out the impact of macroeconomic fundamentals.
In the model in column (3), we simply add the growth model variable, which has a
statistically significant impact on austerity. The model in column (5) accounts for the multi-
level nature of our data (Gelman and Hill 2007). It accounts for the fact that growth models
are (almost) time-invariant, whereas the control variables, like macroeconomic fundamentals,
vary over time. We use a “partial pooling” approach, which fixes the coefficients on the time-
varying variables, but allows the intercept to vary with the growth strategy. The intercepts
then represent the typical austerity level in a country per year when the control variables are
at their means.
10
Figure 5: Estimated relationship between growth contributions and austerity (based on
model (5) in Table 1)
Figure 5 shows how these country-specific austerity levels that we estimated from model (5)
are related to the countries’ growth strategies. The empirical relationship is clear: the more
important external demand is for growth, the more austerity a country implements (up to a
maximum of 0.5% of GDP per year). Vice versa, the more important internal demand is for
10
This interpretation requires that we center the control variables at their means.
USA
GBR
AUT BEL
DNK
FRA
DEU
ITA
NLD
SWE
CAN
FIN
IRL
PRT
ESP
AUS
y = 0.33 + 5.68*x
(0.02) (1.66)
R2 = 0.46
0
.1
.2
.3
.4
.5
.6
Austerity per year (% of GDP)
-.025 -.0125 0 .0125 .025
External - internal demand contribution to growth
17
growth, the less austerity a country implements (with a minimum of slightly more than 0.1%
of GDP per year).
11
Finally, we re-examine the role of partisanship through the growth models perspective. As
discussed in section 2, partisanship should only matter in countries with more balanced
growth models and not in those with unbalanced ones. This requires a revised empirical
specification, which we present in columns (4) and (6) of Table 2. In these specifications, we
interact the partisanship variable with the absolute value of the difference between external
and internal demand contributions. The latter variable reflects to what extent exports or
internal demand contribute disproportionately to growth: if the variable is zero, then the
growth contributions of exports and internal demand are equal, i.e. the model is balanced; if it
is positive, then the growth contribution of either exports or internal demand dominate, i.e.
the model is unbalanced.
Figure 6: Effect of ideology across different growth models (with 95% confidence
intervals)
To simplify the interpretation of the interaction, we compute the marginal effects of
government ideology based on model (4) in Table 2 and plot them in Figure 6.
12
The blue
11
Finland deviates from this pattern due to extensive austerity measures in 1993/1994 in the
wake of the EMS crisis and the resulting economic crisis. Apart from this peculiar episode,
Finland did not implement any austerity
-.1
0
.1
.2
Effect of government ideology on austerity
0 .005 .01 .015 .02 .025
Balanced vs. unbalanced growth contributions
Marginal effect
Distribution
0
20
40
60
Frequency
18
line represents how the impact of ideology on austerity changes when the growth model
becomes more unbalanced. The grey bars represent how countries are distributed along the
scale of the moderating variable. As we can infer from the figure, ideology has a very strong
and statistically significant impact in balanced growth models. In the most balanced model, a
change from a typical center left government to a typical center right government increases
the expected austerity level per year by 0.32% of GDP.
13
This effect decreases and becomes
statistically insignificant when the growth model becomes more unbalanced.
14
When we tie these findings back to our analysis of voter preferences in the previous section,
we can conclude that the voter-driven perspective seems to work better in balanced models,
but not at the unbalanced “extremes” on the continuum of available growth strategies. In the
balanced models, party governments implement distinct fiscal policies in line with the
diverging demands from their leftist or rightist voter base. In the unbalanced models,
dominated by a demand-led or an export-led economy, this link between voter preferences
and government ideology is broken.
5. Reconciling micro and macroor why do governments ignore voters?
The results from the previous two sections raise the question why governments in important
cases seemingly ignore voters and implement policies that are at odds with the attitudes of a
majority of voters and the government party’s own constituencies. Ultimately, nonobservance
of voters can be politically risky and create political dissatisfaction and instabilities. This
problem is particularly prevalent in export-led countries where the discrepancy between anti-
austerity attitudes of the majority of voters and pro-austerity policies by governments is most
severe. Voter preferences and government policies are less in disarray in demand-led
12
The government ideology variable varies from -5 to +5, with higher number indicating
more right governments.
13
We define a typical center left (right) government as one that is one standard deviation, i.e.
1.67 points, below (above) the mean.
14
In additional analyses, we disentangled the moderating effects of export-led from the effect
of demand-led models. In line with our expectation, we find that in demand-led models, the
partisanship effect works mostly through the behavior of right governments: right
governments increasingly pursue austerity, while left governments continue to avoid
austerity, when a heavily demand-led model becomes more balanced. In contrast, the
partisanship effect mostly works through the behavior of left governments in export-led
models: left governments become less austere, while right governments continue to pursue
austerity, when a heavily export-led model becomes more balanced.
19
economies since governments in these countries tend to pursue austerity less often. But the
question why right governments are unresponsive to the preference of right voters for
spending cuts also prevails in these regimes.
Our answer highlights the trade-off that government parties face between the costs from
alienating a large share of voters (potentially including the median voter) and the costs from
alienating the dominant social bloc. When parties in government face competing demands
from organized interests and the wider electorate, they need to decide whose demands they
will prioritize in their policy decisions based on their assessment of these costs (Barta 2018).
The social bloc represents a key political stakeholder that it is well organized and that
governments cannot simply ignore. The power of this bloc is grounded in its financial
strength and its ability to influence the public discourse and public opinion, which again can
have an impact on a wider share of voters (see chapter 1 and the chapters in part 2 of this
volume). The power of voters arises from the threat that they will resort to other political
parties if they are dissatisfied with the policy of the government party.
For a long time, parties seemed to perceive the costs of alienating voters as the lesser of two
evils. In fact, the convergence of the main political parties on a similar economic agenda in
many political systems itself helped to contain these costs because it limited the options that
were available for alienated voters. Most mainstream parties eventually began to prioritize
the interests of the dominant social block and to converge on pro-market policies throughout
the post-war period, which led to an overall decline in political competition (Baccaro and
Howell 2017; Lynch 2019; Przeworski 2019). A prominent example of this process is the
development of ‘Third Way’ politics, an attempt of the left to overcome their traditional
alliances in order to reform the economy while embracing neoliberal ideas (Bremer and
McDaniel 2020). This development prepared the ground for the austerity narrative that
emphasized the importance of balanced budgets, the importance of a lean state, and the
abandonment of counter-cyclical public spending.
This mainstream party convergence initiated a process of dealignment between voters and
established parties, but this development was slow-moving and not seen as a problem that
parties need to address urgently. In particular the growing distance between political parties
and their constituents, or the cartelization of political parties (Katz and Mair 1995, 2009),
resulted in an alienation of voters from their parties and a further push of parties towards
20
organized interests and the state. As a consequence, a slow but steady decline in votes and an
increase in swing voters rendered the supporter base of mainstream parties less stable over
the years.
15
Both trends can be interpreted as a latent withdrawal of voter support from the
dominant political-economic model by parts of the electorate. Nonetheless, political parties
actively pursued this mutual process of dealignment in order to uphold the macro-economic
policies prescribed by the growth model. For a long time, this development was not perceived
as problematic because in most countries the established parties shared government
responsibility and were the only ones who had a realistic chance to participate in government,
which limited political competition from other parties.
Only the financial crisis and the following Great Recession generated new political dynamics
that put this political-economic equilibrium to a test. The Great Recession disrupted the
complacent policy community and also served as a trigger for disenchanted citizens to
mobilize against their government and for new parties to be established. The majority of
these newly established parties and movements took a decidedly anti-austerity and/or anti-
establishment stance and managed to stir up the party landscape in a number of countries.
16
Other parties, which already existed for a longer time, gained more prominence again in the
wake of the financial crisis and were able to present themselves as viable alternatives to
mainstream parties.
17
6. Conclusions
We draw three main conclusions from this analysis. First, austerity policies vary greatly
across countries and in line with a country’s growth model. Countries that pursue export-led
models are much more likely to implement austerity than those that are more demand-led,
even if we account for macroeconomic and political circumstances. Second, fiscal policies
15
Average turnout at general elections in Western democracies declined from roughly 82.5%
in 1980 to just about slightly more than 70% in 2016 (see Hübscher et al. 2019). This figure
includes countries in which turnout hardly changed, such as Belgium, to countries, in which
turnout declined dramatically. I.e. Austria experienced a decline in turnout from 92% in 1979
to 75.6% in 2019. In Germany, turnout dropped from roughly 90% in 1980 to 70.8% in 2009
and increased to slightly over 76% in 2016. The recovery in turnout was largely due to
citizens who were politically inactive and voted AfD in 2016.
16
Among the more prominent parties/movements founded after the financial crisis are
Podemos, Syriza, M5S, and la France Insoumise.
17
Examples of parties in this category are Die Linke or Lega.
21
vary along ideological preferences of government parties only in balanced, but not in
unbalanced growth models. Together, these results suggest that governments subordinate
fiscal policy to the greater macroeconomic strategy, which is specific to their country and
which is unrelated to objective macroeconomic factors. Moreover, this fiscal strategy seems
to be part of a broader political consensus among political elites that cuts across political
parties on the left and the right in many countries.
The mismatch between government policy and voters’ fiscal policy views that our analysis
uncovers has important political implications. In the short and medium term, governments
may be able to sell austerity to their electorates by highlighting the potential positive effects
of deficit reduction (Barnes and Hicks 2018). The political discourse plays an important role:
voters are more likely to support austerity if they are consistently exposed to arguments
highlighting the benefits of these policies (Ferrara et al. 2021). In the long term, however,
these policies need to have the alleged, desired effect and generate economic growth in order
to secure political support from voters. If this is not the case, like in Italy, for example, it is
likely that political backlash follows. Germany, the country whose economic success heavily
relies on export, also experiences significant changes of its political landscape. The combined
vote share the two mainstream center-left and center-right have lost between 1990 and 2016
amounts to roughly 23% (SPD: -13% / CDU: -10%). A significant share of people previously
voting for either of these parties now support challenger parties, such as Die Linke, the Green
Party or the AfD, all of which call for changes (though different in nature) of the dominant
macro-economic policies.
There is an increasing amount of evidence that this is in fact the case in a broad range of
countries. In Britain, for instance, the rising popularity of UKIP has been linked to the
austerity policies of the past decade (Fetzer 2019). More broadly, austerity has detrimental
effects on party systems and increases political polarization when mainstream parties
converge on a policy of fiscal restraint (Hübscher et al. 2019). The transformation of party
systems and the rise of populism in many countries, therefore, can be directly traced to the
spread of neoliberal economic policies and the adverse economic effects of macroeconomic
regimes on many voters (Hopkin 2020; Hopkin and Blyth 2019). With the spread of austerity
to consumption-led and mixed economies during and after the Great Recession, public
discontent with economic policymaking is likely to rise further. These ongoing developments
22
are likely to complicate the formation of stable government coalitions needed to produce
sustainable policy outputs.
23
7. Bibliography
Alesina, A., Carloni, D., and Lecce, G. (2011) 'The Electoral Consequences of Large Fiscal
Adjustments', NBER Working Paper No. 17655: 1-19.
Alesina, A., Favero, C., and Giavazzi, F. (2015) 'The Output Effect of Fiscal Consolidation
Plans', Journal of International Economics 56: S19-S42.
Alesina, A., Favero, C., and Giavazzi, F. (2019) Austerity: When It Works and When It
Doesn’t: Princeton University Press.
Alesina, A., Perotti, R., and Tavares, J. (1998) 'The Political Economy of Fiscal
Adjustments', Brookings Papers of Economic Activity 1998(1): 197-248.
Armingeon, K., Guthmann, K., and Weisstanner, D. (2016) 'Choosing the Path of Austerity:
How Parties and Policy Coalitions Influence Welfare State Retrenchment in Periods
of Fiscal Consolidation', West European Politics 39(4): 628-47.
Baccaro, L., and Howell, C. (2017) Trajectories of Neoliberal Transformations: European
Industrial Relations since the 1970s: Cambridge University Press.
Baccaro, L., and Neimann, E. (2021) 'Determinants of Wage (Dis-)Satisfaction: Trade
Exposure, Export-Led Growth, and the Irrelevance of Bargaining Structure',
Manuscript, MPIfG
Baccaro, L., and Pontusson, J. (2016) 'Rethinking Comparative Political Economy', Politics
& Society 44(2): 175-207.
Barnes, L., and Hicks, T. (2018) 'Making Austerity Popular: The Media and Mass Attitudes
Towards Fiscal Policy', American Journal of Political Science 62(2): 340-54.
Barta, Z. (2018) In the Red: The Politics of Public Debt Accumulation in Developed
Countries: MIT Press.
Beramendi, P., Häusermann, S., Kitschelt, H., and Kriesi, H., eds (2015) The Politics of
Advanced Capitalism: Cambridge University Press.
Blanchard, O. (2019) 'Public Debt and Low Interest Rates', Presidential Lecture to the
American Economic Association, January
Blanchard, O., and Summers, L. (2017) 'Rethinking Stablization Policy: Back to the Future',
PIIE Working Paper, October
Blyth, M. (2013) Austerity: The History of a Dangerous Idea: Oxford University Press.
Blyth, M., and Matthijs, M. (2017) 'Black Swans, Lame Ducks, and the Mystery of Ipe's
Missing Macroeconomy', Review of International Political Economy 24(2): 203-31.
Bojar, A., Björn, B., Kriesi, H., and Wang, C. (2018) 'The Effect of Austerity Packages on
Government Popularity During the Great Recession', British Journal of Political
Science (Online First).
Bremer, B., and Bürgisser, R. (2018) 'Are Voters Austerians? Evidence from Survey
Experiments on Budgetary Trade-Offs and Priorities', Paper presented at the Annual
Meeting of the Conference for Europeanists (CES), Chicago, April 5-8
Bremer, B., and McDaniel, S. (2020) 'The Ideational Foundations of Social Democratic
Austerity in the Context of the Great Recession', Socio-Economic Review 18(2): 439–
46.
Brender, A., and Drazen, A. (2008) 'How Do Budget Deficits and Economic Growth Affect
Reelection Prospects? Evidence from a Large Panel of Countries', American
Economic Review 98(5): 2203-20.
Chinn, M. D., and Prasad, E. S. (2003) 'Medium-Term Determinants of Current Accounts in
Industrial and Developing Countries: An Empirical Exploration', Journal of
International Economics 59(1): 47–76.
24
Chowdhury, A., and Islam, I. (2012) 'The Debate on Expansionary Fiscal Consolidation:
How Robust Is the Evidence?', The Economic and Labour Relations Review 23(3):
13-38.
Dellepiane-Avellaneda, S. (2014) 'The Political Power of Economic Ideas: The Case of
‘Expansionary Fiscal Contractions’', British Journal of Political Science 17(3): 391-
418.
Devries, P., Guajardo, J., Leigh, D., and Pescatori, A. (2011) 'A New Action-Based Dataset
of Fiscal Consolidation', IMF Working Paper 11/128 (June).
Ferrara, F. M., Haas, J., Peterson, A., and Sattler, T. (2021) 'Exports Vs. Investment: How
Political Discourse Shapes Support for External Imbalances', Socio-Economic Review
(Online First).
Fetzer, T. (2019) 'Did Austerity Cause Brexit?', American Economic Review 109(11): 3849-
86.
Gelman, A., and Hill, J. (2007) Data Analysis Using Regression and Multileve/Hierarchical
Models: Cambridge University Press.
Giavazzi, F., and Pagano, M. (1990) 'Can Severe Fiscal Contractions Be Expansionary? Tales
of Two Small European Countries', In Nber Macroeconomics Annual, O. Blanchard
and S. Fischer (ed.), Boston: MIT Press.
Guajardo, J., Leigh, D., and Pescatori, A. (2014) 'Expansionary Austerity: New International
Evidence', Journal of the European Economic Association 12(4): 949-68.
Gόrnicka, L., Kamps, C., Köster, G., and Leiner-Killinger, N. (2018) 'Learning About Fiscal
Multipliers During the European Sovereign Debt Crisis: Evidence from a Quasi-
Natural Experiment', ECB Working Paper 2154.
Haffert, L., and Mertens, D. (2019) 'Between Distribution and Allocation: Growth Models,
Sectoral Coalitions and the Politics of Taxation Revisited ', Socio-Economic Review
(Online First).
Hallerberg, M., and Basinger, S. (1998) 'Internationalization and Changes in Tax Policy in
Oecd Countries -- the Importance of Domestic Veto Players', Comparative Political
Studies 31(3): 321-52.
Häusermann, S., and Kriesi, H. (2015) 'What Do Voters Want? Dimensions and
Configurations in Individual-Level Preferences and Party Choice ', In The Politics of
Advanced Capitalism, P. Beramendi, S. Häusermann, H. Kitschelt and H. Kriesi:
Cambridge University Press.
Henisz, W. J. (2004) 'Political Institutions and Policy Volatility', Economics \& Politics
16(1): 1-27.
Hopkin, J. (2020) Anti-System Politics: The Crisis of Market Capitalism in Rich
Democracies: Oxford University Press.
Hopkin, J., and Blyth, M. (2019) 'The Global Economics of European Populism: Growth
Regimes and Party System Change in Europe', Government and Opposition 5(2): 193-
225.
Hübscher, E. (2016) 'The Politics of Fiscal Consolidation Revisited', Journal of Public Policy
36(4): 573-601.
——— (2018) The Clientelistic Turn in Welfare State Policy-Making: Party Politics in
Times of Austerity: ECPR Press.
Hübscher, E., Kemmerling, A., and Sattler, T. (2015) 'Austerity for the Win? The Effect of
Fiscal Consolidation on Political Support for the Government', Paper presented at the
Annual Meeting of the European Political Science Association, Vienna, June 25-27
Hübscher, E., and Sattler, T. (2017) 'Fiscal Consolidation under Electoral Risk', European
Journal of Political Research 56(1): 151-68.
25
Hübscher, E., Sattler, T., and Wagner, M. (2019) 'Does Austerity Cause Polarization?', Paper
presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association,
Washington D.C., August 29-September 1
——— (2020) 'Voter Responses to Fiscal Austerity', British Journal of Political Science
(Online First).
Immergut, E. M. (1992) Health Politics: Interests and Institutions in Western Europe:
Cambridge University Press.
Johnston, A. (2016) From Convergence to Crisis: Labor Markets and the Instability of the
Euro: Cornell University Press.
Johnston, A., Hancké, B., and Pant, S. (2014) 'Comparative Institutional Advantage in the
European Sovereign Debt Crisis', Comparative Political Studies 47(13): 1771-800.
Jones, E. (2015) 'Getting the Story Right: How You Should Choose between Different
Interpretations of the European Crisis (and Why You Should Care)', Journal of
European Integration 37(7): 817-32.
——— (2016) 'Macroeconomic Imbalances and Sovereign Debt Markets', In Europe,
Canada and the Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement, K. Hübner: Taylor
& Francis.
Jordà, O., and Taylor, A. M. (2016) 'The Time for Austerity: Estimating the Average
Treatment Effect of Fiscal Policy', The Economic Journal 126(590): 219-55.
Katz, R. S., and Mair, P. (1995) 'Changing Models of Party Organization and Party
Democracy: The Emergence of the Cartel Party', Party Politics 1(1): 5-28.
——— (2009) 'The Cartel Party Thesis: A Restatement', Perspectives on Politics 7(4): 753-
66.
Lake, D. (2009) 'Open Economy Politics: A Critical Review', Review of international
Organizations 4(3): 219-44.
Lynch, J. (2019) 'Populism, Partisan Convergence, and Mobilization in Western Europe',
Polity 51(4).
Manger, M. S., and Sattler, T. (2020) 'The Origins of Persistent Current Account Imbalances
in the Post-Bretton Woods Era', Comparative Political Studies 53(3-4): 631-64.
Mutz, D. (2011) Population-Based Survey Experiments: Princeton University Press.
Przeworski, A. (2019) Crises of Democracy: Cambridge University Press.
Volkens, A., Lehmann, P., Merz, N., Regel, S., and Werner, A. (2013) 'The Manifesto Data
Collection. Manifesto Project (Mrg/Cmp/Marpor)', \urlhttps://manifesto-
project.wzb.eu/ (July).
Walter, S. (2015) 'Crisis Politics in Europe: Why Austerity Is Easier to Implement in Some
Countries Than in Others ', Comparative Political Studies 49(7): 841-73.
Article
Full-text available
We introduce a novel approach to operationalizing growth models. Drawing on the most recent release of OECD Input–Output Tables, we compute the import-adjusted growth contributions of consumption, investment, government expenditures, and exports for sixty-six countries in the years 1995–2007 and 2009–2018, covering not only advanced Western economies but also Central and Eastern European, South-East Asian, and Latin American countries. We find that most are export-led or domestic demand-led and other forms of growth are rare. Our results differ from other classifications in that they reveal important geographical variation as well as temporal change. In a subsequent step, we illustrate the utility of the methodology by investigating the link between real exchange rate devaluation and export-led growth, a contentious issue in the existing literature. For pre-crisis advanced Western economies, we find an association between the two variables, which is statistically significant only when our new indicator is used.
Article
The growth models approach (GMA) has become increasingly prominent in Comparative Political Economy over the last years. While it has originally been developed for advanced economies, there is a growing number of applications for developing countries. This raises the question of how readily transferable the GMA concepts are to the peripheral capitalist experience. This paper explores the analytical building blocks for an extension of the GMA to developing economies from post-Keynesian-structuralist perspective. It argues that in a developing country context supply-side considerations will be more important and build on structuralist theory to understand the ‘real’ constraints in the developing countries' growth process. It uses Minskyan theory to understand how currency hierarchy creates financial causes for international economic stratification. As a consequence, the role of the state is more crucial than in advanced economies, but at the same time states are more vulnerable. This paper concludes by reflecting on the key concepts of GMA, finance-led, export-led and state-led growth in the light of developing economies and identifying neoliberal as well developmentalist versions of these.
Article
Full-text available
In recent decades, governments in many Western democracies have shown a remarkable consensus in pursuing fiscal austerity measures during periods of strained public finances. In this paper, we show that these decisions have consequences for political polarization. Our macro-level analysis of 166 elections since 1980 finds that austerity measures increase both electoral abstention and votes for non-mainstream parties, thereby boosting party system polarization. A detailed analysis of selected austerity episodes also shows that new, small and radical parties benefit most from austerity policies. Finally, survey experiments with a total of 8,800 respondents in Germany, Portugal, Spain and the United Kingdom indicate that the effects of austerity on polarization are particularly pronounced when the mainstream right and left parties both stand for fiscal restraint. Austerity is a substantial cause of political polarization and hence political instability in industrialized democracies.
Article
Full-text available
We present a new methodology for operationalizing growth models based on import-adjusted demand components. Applying the methodology to the latest release of OECD Input-Output Tables, we calculate the growth contributions of consumption, investment, government expenditures, and exports for sixty-six countries in the periods 1995 to 2007 and 2009 to 2018 and identify the respective growth models. We find that most countries are export-led or domestic demand-led and that other forms of growth are rare. Our results corroborate previous classifications in comparative political economy but also differ from them in significant respects. Importantly, our classification improves on previous ones by covering not just the advanced capitalist economies but also Central and Eastern European and South-East Asian and Latin American countries. In a further step, we illustrate how the new indicators can be used to analyze the “drivers” of different types of growth. This examination reveals that there is a clear trade-off between consumption- and export-led growth in advanced Western economies in the period 1995 to 2007 and a dependence of export-led growth in these countries on real exchange rate devaluation in the same period, while export complexity is not a significant predictor of export-led growth.
Preprint
Full-text available
Political opposition to fiscal adjustments has varied significantly across countries. Our analysis links this variation to differences in the congruence of voter attitudes towards fiscal trade-offs across political blocs in different countries. These differences in attitudes, in turn, coincide with the implications of the distinct macroeconomic growth strategies that these countries pursue. Based on original survey data, we show that in Germany, supporters of different parties not only share similar views on the appropriate size of fiscal adjustment, but also on how to distribute these cuts across various spending items. In Spain, there is fundamental disagreement on the amount of austerity, but voters largely agree on the composition of fiscal adjustments. In the UK, there is disagreement between voters of diverging political blocs on both accounts. Variation in public attitudes, therefore, gives rise to very diverse political dynamics surrounding fiscal adjustments in different countries.
Article
Full-text available
An extensive literature in comparative political economy has examined the determinants of wage militancy and moderation at the country level. So far, however, there has been no attempt to analyse the determinants of wage satisfaction and dissatisfaction at the individual level. Based on two waves of the International Social Survey Programme, this article seeks to fill this void. It examines to what extent trade exposure affects individual attitudes towards wages, and whether bargaining institutions facilitate the internalisation of competitiveness requirements, as suggested by the vast literature on neocorporatism. Surprisingly, no relationship is found between the structure of wage bargaining (more or less coordinated or centralised) and wage dissatisfaction at the individual level. Instead, wage dissatisfaction decreases strongly when workers are individually exposed to trade and countries rely heavily on export-led growth. The findings point to the need to rethink the determinants of wage moderation. Supplemental data for this article can be accessed online at: https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2021.2024010 .
Article
Full-text available
The economic imbalances that characterize the world economy have unequally distributed costs and benefits. That raises the question of how countries could run long-term external surpluses and deficits without significant opposition against the policies that generate them. We show that political discourse helps to secure public support for these policies and the resulting economic outcomes. First, a content analysis of 32 000 newspaper articles finds that the dominant interpretations of current account balances in Australia and Germany concur with very distinct perspectives: external surpluses are seen as evidence of competitiveness in Germany, while external deficits are interpreted as evidence of attractiveness for investments in Australia. Second, survey experiments in both countries suggest that exposure to these diverging interpretations has a causal effect on citizens’ support for their country’s economic strategy. Political discourse, thus, is crucial to provide the societal foundation of national growth strategies.
Article
Full-text available
During the Great Recession, governments across the continent implemented austerity policies. A large literature claims that such policies are surprisingly popular and have few electoral costs. This article revisits this question by studying the popularity of governments during the economic crisis. The authors assemble a pooled time-series data set for monthly support for ruling parties from fifteen European countries and treat austerity packages as intervention variables to the underlying popularity series. Using time-series analysis, this permits the careful tracking of the impact of austerity packages over time. The main empirical contributions are twofold. First, the study shows that, on average, austerity packages hurt incumbent parties in opinion polls. Secondly, it demonstrates that the magnitude of this electoral punishment is contingent on the economic and political context: in instances of rising unemployment, the involvement of external creditors and high protest intensity, the cumulative impact of austerity on government popularity becomes considerable.
Article
Full-text available
Why do some countries run persistent current account surpluses? Why do others run deficits, often over decades, leading to enduring global imbalances? Such persistent imbalances are the root cause of many financial crises and a major source of international economic conflict. We propose that differences in wage-bargaining institutions explain a large share of imbalances through their effect on the trade balance. In countries with coordinated wage bargaining, wage growth in export industries can be restrained to ensure competitiveness, leading to persistent trade surpluses. We estimate the contribution of these institutions to trade balances in Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) member countries since 1977 and find ample support for our hypothesis. Contrary to much of the literature, the choice of fixed or floating exchange rate regimes has only a small effect on trade or current account balances. In other words, internal adjustment in surplus countries via wage-bargaining institutions trumps external adjustment by deficit countries.
Article
Full-text available
The ‘austerity settlement’ has come to define the post-crisis European political economy. Since 2010, parties from across Europe’s political mainstream have implemented austerity and despite the apparent conflict with the interests of their traditional constituents, even social democratic parties have acquiesced to this settlement. However, within the existing literature ‘social democratic austerity’ is currently under-theorized as it is assumed to involve a rather straightforward adaptation of social democrats to neo- and/or ordoliberal ideas. Utilizing rich and original evidence from over 60 elite interviews with key social democratic stakeholders in France, Germany and the UK, this article contests this view. It demonstrates instead that a distinct set of ideas based on New Keynesianism, supply-side economics, and the social investment paradigm provide the ideational foundations for social democratic austerity post-crisis. Understanding this, it is argued, is critical in order to fully appreciate how and why austerity has become dominant in post-crisis Europe.
Article
Comparative political economists typically analyze taxation as a matter of distribution. This article, by contrast, develops an allocational explanation of tax policy choices: as taxes channel resources into some economic activities and restrain others, they become subject to the allocational concerns of different sectors of the economy. We argue that sectoral coalitions straddling the class divide substantially influence the development of tax systems, and that the power of these coalitions is associated with differences in growth models. Employing a mixed methods approach, we first demonstrate a systematic association between growth models and consumption taxation across advanced capitalist countries. Afterward, we study the German value-added tax increase in 2005 to illustrate the political dynamics behind this result. In this debate, an export sector coalition prevailed over a domestic sector coalition that strongly opposed the reform. We conclude by discussing the wider implications for the study of taxation and comparative capitalism.
Book
Recent elections in the advanced Western democracies have undermined the basic foundations of political systems that had previously beaten back all challenges—from both the Left and the Right. The election of Donald Trump to the US presidency, only months after the United Kingdom voted to leave the European Union, signaled a dramatic shift in the politics of the rich democracies. This book traces the evolution of this shift and argues that it is a long-term result of abandoning the postwar model of egalitarian capitalism in the 1970s. That shift entailed weakening the democratic process in favor of an opaque, technocratic form of governance that allows voters little opportunity to influence policy. With the financial crisis of the late 2000s, these arrangements became unsustainable, as incumbent politicians were unable to provide solutions to economic hardship. Electorates demanded change, and it had to come from outside the system. Using a comparative approach, the text explains why different kinds of anti-system politics emerge in different countries and how political and economic factors impact the degree of electoral instability that emerges. Finally, it discusses the implications of these changes, arguing that the only way for mainstream political forces to survive is for them to embrace a more activist role for government in protecting societies from economic turbulence.
Article
This paper documents a significant association between the exposure of an individual or area to the UK government’s austerity-induced welfare reforms begun in 2010, and the following: the subsequent rise in support for the UK Independence Party, an important correlate of Leave support in the 2016 UK referendum on European Union membership; broader individual-level measures of political dissatisfaction; and direct measures of support for Leave. Leveraging data from all UK electoral contests since 2000, along with detailed, individual-level panel data, the findings suggest that the EU referendum could have resulted in a Remain victory had it not been for austerity. (JEL D72, F15, F60, H53, I38)
Article
This lecture focuses on the costs of public debt when safe interest rates are low. I develop four main arguments. First, I show that the current US situation, in which safe interest rates are expected to remain below growth rates for a long time, is more the historical norm than the exception. If the future is like the past, this implies that debt rollovers, that is the issuance of debt without a later increase in taxes, may well be feasible. Put bluntly, public debt may have no fiscal cost. Second, even in the absence of fiscal costs, public debt reduces capital accumulation, and may therefore have welfare costs. I show that welfare costs may be smaller than typically assumed. The reason is that the safe rate is the risk-adjusted rate of return to capital. If it is lower than the growth rate, it indicates that the risk-adjusted rate of return to capital is in fact low. The average risky rate however also plays a role. I show how both the average risky rate and the average safe rate determine welfare outcomes. Third, I look at the evidence on the average risky rate, i.e., the average marginal product of capital. While the measured rate of earnings has been and is still quite high, the evidence from asset markets suggests that the marginal product of capital may be lower, with the difference reflecting either mismeasurement of capital or rents. This matters for debt: the lower the marginal product, the lower the welfare cost of debt. Fourth, I discuss a number of arguments against high public debt, and in particular the existence of multiple equilibria where investors believe debt to be risky and, by requiring a risk premium, increase the fiscal burden and make debt effectively more risky. This is a very relevant argument, but it does not have straightforward implications for the appropriate level of debt. My purpose in the lecture is not to argue for more public debt, especially in the current political environment. It is to have a richer discussion of the costs of debt and of fiscal policy than is currently the case.