Available via license: CC BY-NC-ND 4.0
Content may be subject to copyright.
Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at
https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=cjms20
Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies
ISSN: (Print) (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cjms20
Are golden visas a golden opportunity? Assessing
the economic origins and outcomes of residence
by investment programmes in the EU
Kristin Surak & Yusuke Tsuzuki
To cite this article: Kristin Surak & Yusuke Tsuzuki (2021): Are golden visas a golden opportunity?
Assessing the economic origins and outcomes of residence by investment programmes in the EU,
Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies, DOI: 10.1080/1369183X.2021.1915755
To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/1369183X.2021.1915755
© 2021 The Author(s). Published with
license by Taylor & Francis Group, LLC
Published online: 10 May 2021.
Submit your article to this journal
View related articles
View Crossmark data
Are golden visas a golden opportunity? Assessing the
economic origins and outcomes of residence by investment
programmes in the EU
Kristin Surak
a
and Yusuke Tsuzuki
b
a
Sociology, London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK;
b
Graduate School of Arts and
Sciences, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA, USA
ABSTRACT
Residence by investment (RBI) programmes, or ‘golden visa’
schemes, are now found in half of European Union member states.
Yet no empirical studies have tested the economic drivers or
impacts of these programmes. Filling this lacuna, this article
supplies the first comparative quantitative evaluation of the
economic origins and outcomes of so-called golden visa
programmes in the European Union. Utilising new data, we show
that governments across the political spectrum are more likely to
begin RBI programmes after a decline in economic growth,
especially during an economic crisis, and that the programmes are
generally targeted to address failing areas of the economy.
Furthermore, we show that wealthy investor migrants are better
conceptualised as mobile populations akin to tourists or investors,
rather than as immigrants, and that countries price programmes in
response to both demand-side and supply-side forces. We also find
that the programmes represent a miniscule proportion of foreign
investment in most countries, and that the vast majority of the
investments go into real estate even when other options are
available. However, the impact on real estate markets is trivial, with
the sole exception of Greece. The results suggest that states turn
to golden visa programmes to plug short-term economic gaps but
with negligible national-level economic impact.
ARTICLE HISTORY
Received 21 September 2020
Accepted 5 April 2021
KEYWORDS
Migration; elites; foreign
investment; European Union;
globalisation
Introduction
Over the last decade, residence by investment (RBI) programmes have grown across the
European Union, with currently thirteen countries offering clear options for receiving
residence based on a passive economic investment. These schemes are often touted as
a means for boosting the economy by attracting foreign investment. However, they are
not without controversy. In 2018 and 2019, reports by the European Parliamentary
Research Service and the European Commission questioned their economic benefits,
as has much media coverage (Scherrer and Thirion 2018; European Commission
2019). Others have raised concerns that these ‘golden visa’programmes may price
© 2021 The Author(s). Published with license by Taylor & Francis Group, LLC
CONTACT Kristin Surak k.surak@lse.ac.uk
This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives License
(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/), which permits non-commercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any
medium, provided the original work is properly cited, and is not altered, transformed, or built upon in any way.
JOURNAL OF ETHNIC AND MIGRATION STUDIES
https://doi.org/10.1080/1369183X.2021.1915755
locals out of the housing market. Yet to date, no studies have systematically assessed the
economic origins or outcomes of these programmes.
RBI programmes are one of several migration policy tools available for attracting
economic resources, including also residence permits for entrepreneurs and business
start-up visas. Within this field, investment-based visa programmes can be divided
into ‘active’and ‘passive’variants. Active programmes require the demonstration of
business experience and an on-going involvement with the investment in order to
qualify, and thus aim to harness both economic and human capital. Passive programmes
require merely the expenditure of money (see Sumption and Hooper 2014). That is,
applicants park their funds in the country –typically in real estate, government bonds,
or a company –and have no significant further obligations in maintaining the invest-
ment. It is the passive nature of the qualification, selecting individuals based on economic
capital alone, which has generated much controversy around these programmes, some-
times billed, if inaccurately, as ‘cash-for-passports’(Spiro 2014, 9; Shachar and Hirschl
2014, 244), raising the concern that they put a ‘price tag’on membership (e.g Scherrer
and Thirion 2018, 12).
In practice, the boundary between the entrepreneurial and investor visas can be blurry,
either in the law’s specificity or how it is implemented. Entrepreneur programmes, for
example, may not assess whether applicants have relevant business skills or are regularly
involved in managing the qualifying business, as is the case with Croatia’s‘stay and work
permit.’The result is in an ‘active’scheme with strong ‘passive’characteristics. Similarly,
business investment programmes that do not specify or monitor the degree of investor
involvement at their outset may come to more strictly police human capital contri-
butions. This occurred, for example, when Germany in 2012 revised Section 21 of its
Act on the Residence, Economic Activity, and Integration of Foreigners in the Federal
Territory to require applicants to demonstrate entrepreneurial experience and involve-
ment in the business. As will be discussed below, this article adopts a strict definition
of RBI programmes to focus solely on the more controversial economic-capital-only
options.
Despite substantial media attention, no empirical studies have tested whether countries
turn to these so-called golden visa schemes out of economic need, and no study has offered
a thorough assessment of their economic impact. Filling this lacuna, this article supplies the
first comparative quantitative evaluation of the economic origins and outcomes of RBI pro-
grammes in the European Union. Utilising new data released by governments and gained
through freedom of information requests, it first employs regression analyses to investigate
the relationship between programme inception, economic decline, and the types of quali-
fying investments selected. It next assesses demand curves to understand the factors that
affect pricing. Finally, it evaluates economic impact by assessing RBI revenue as a pro-
portion of FDI inflows, as well as its effect on the real estate sector. The findings indicate
that governments across the political spectrum launch programmes in the wake of econ-
omic downturns –and economic crises in particular –and broadly engineer them to
target sectors in need. Yet states tailor prices to respond to needs beyond revenue-maximi-
zation. The analysis shows that applicants, too, select programmes like tourists and profit-
oriented businesspeople, rather than as immigrants. Contra claims that foreigners are
crowding locals out of the housing market, the effect on real estate is shown to be small
even in countries with the largest programmes. The sole exception is Greece, where the
2K. SURAK AND Y. TSUZUKI
RBI programme now represents a third of real estate transactions. The results suggest that
states are increasingly turning to residence by investment programmes to plug short-term
economic gaps, but with negligible economic impact on the national economy.
Residence by investment programmes
RBI programmes now can be found around the world from Malaysia to the United Arab
Emirates to Panama. However, the most popular over time have been in Canada and the
US, with similar programmes in Australia and New Zealand. These emerged in the late
1980s and early 1990s out of entrepreneurial programmes that were lax in assessing
business involvement, bringing mixed economic outcomes. The US’s EB-5 programme,
for example, floundered for its first decade due to its high price point, rigid system, and
unfavorable tax implications (Wong 2003; see also Rose 1992), while programmes in
Canada and Australia attracted significant investment to rural regions in particular
(DeRosa 1995; Steier 1992; Wong 2003). Canada’s programme –the most popular by
far –quickly became the greatest source of venture capital in four provinces, producing
over 14,000 jobs in less than a decade (DeRosa 1995, 395, 404). In British Columbia
alone, the programme attracted over one billion Canadian dollars in business investment
and created or maintained 25,000 jobs between 1990–1998 (Ley 2003, 430). Yet the Cana-
dian business investor scheme –which included entrepreneurs and investors –was one
of several channels that contributed to a boom in Vancouver real estate, with housing
prices rising more steeply than local incomes (Ley 2010, 126–61). As such, programmes
in the past have generated both economic winners and economic losers.
Despite the spread of RBI programmes in the EU, research evaluating their origins and
economic outcomes is lacking. Existent studies usually treat RBI schemes as one subset of
immigrant investor programmes (IIPs), which includes also citizenship by investment
channels (e.g. Dzankic 2012,2018; Sumption and Hooper 2014; Christians 2017;
Veteto 2014; Scherrer and Thirion 2018; European Commission 2019; Holleran 2019).
The amalgamation, however, can obscure more than it reveals for citizenship is a funda-
mentally different status to residence (see Surak, Forthcoming). Within the EU, residence
in a member state brings only the right to temporarily visit other member states (cf. Hol-
leran 2019, 3), but citizenship also secures the right to reside in them as well, even for the
long term. Furthermore, citizenship is inheritable, whereas residence is not, changing cal-
culations of future impact. Crucial for assessing economic implications of the pro-
grammes is the length of time the investment must be held. In RBI programmes, an
investor must maintain their investment in order to retain the visa. If the asset is sold,
the residence permit is not renewed.
1
Citizenship, by contrast, is difficult to revoke.
Malta, Cyprus, Turkey, and Saint Kitts, among others, require their naturalised investors
to retain their qualifying investment, in part or whole, for only five years, after which it
may sold, and –of course –they keep their citizenship. Thus the long-term economic
impact of the economic infusion may be greater for RBI programmes.
The empirical research on IIPs in Europe has focused on policy design and debates
rather than programme operation and outcomes. Existing studies have typologized
policy choices (Sumption and Hooper 2014), examined the possible causes of policy
choices (Dzankic 2018), dissected political debates around the programmes (Parker
2017; Carrera 2014), unpacked marketing (Holleran 2019), discussed the possible
JOURNAL OF ETHNIC AND MIGRATION STUDIES 3
impact on tax competition (Adim 2017; Christians 2017). Investigating programme oper-
ation and demand, Surak (2020b) assessed differences in the scale of programmes and the
demographics of their participants. Yet the existing research leaves open questions about
the economic origins of the programmes in the EU, as well as their economic outcomes.
Are they simply intended to add a revenue stream or do they arise out of and address
economic need? Some have associated the launch of these programmes with economic
declines. Dzankic (2018) proposes that states with medium-sized economies hit by the
Eurocrisis produce RBI programmes, an assertion that resonates with Holleran’s
(2019) qualitative interpretation of the origins of Spain’s RBI scheme. However, a full
appraisal of whether the claim holds across all EU cases requires more empirical evi-
dence: it is necessary to include the timing of programme implementation, as well as
the particular economic needs of the countries, and whether investment options of the
programmes targeted areas that flagged during the crisis.
The question of whether states implement programmes in response to economic need
raises the related query about how governments adjust prices accordingly. Dzankic
(2018, 12, 14) suggests that richer countries place higher prices on their investment
migration programmes, ostensibly because ‘the investment needs to have an impact on
the country’s GDP.’However, the proposition does not take into account the shape of
the demand curve: higher prices do not necessarily mean higher revenue. For
example, the Netherlands stipulates a minimum investment of €1.25 million, but earns
very little from the programme as it has less than five applicants year each year. Bulgaria,
in comparison, requires an investment of only €127,000 but approves on average more
than 100 applicants annually, far outstripping the revenue generated by its economically
larger counterpart (cf. Dzankic 2018, 11).
Finally, do these programmes, designed to attract investment, pay off? Full assess-
ments of the economic outcomes of RBI schemes are scant, even among studies of
longer-standing investment migration programmes outside Europe. Existing research
on investment migration programmes in North America and the Caribbean has
shown that, unsurprisingly, the magnitude of their economic impact depends on the
size of the economy, with larger countries seeing proportionally less benefit than
smaller ones (Xu, El-Ashram, and Gold 2016; see also Migration Advisory Committee
2014). Within countries, urban areas attract more investment, but rural areas may see
more relative benefit (Ley 2010; DeRosa 1995; Friedland and Calderon 2017), and pro-
grammes may contribute to job creation and business formation, but not always at the
promised levels (Ley 2003,2010).
Comparing cases within Europe, a report by European Parliamentary Research Service
suggests that the programmes make a positive contribution to foreign investment, but
may also create macro-economic imbalances (Scherrer and Thirion 2018,36–41).
However, the study bases its conclusion on only two countries –Ireland and Portugal
–out of its sample of eighteen countries that include also business-based RBI pro-
grammes.
2
Furthermore, it considers only the total amount invested over time and
average annual programme receipts as a proportion of GDP. Notably, the aggregate
measures mask substantial annual variation. Their analysis of Ireland is a case in
point, where the average total investment amount hides a jump of 500 percent
between 2015 and 2016. If the calculation had ended in 2015, the average total investment
would be a mere €65 million, or €16.3 million per year, rather than €209 million total and
4K. SURAK AND Y. TSUZUKI
€41.8 million per year. If the analysis extended to 2017, the average would be yet greater:
€79.7 million per year. The limited sample significantly skews the estimated impact of the
contribution to GDP.
Although most RBI schemes offer several investment options, discussions focus
almost entirely on real estate investment, and no empirical studies have examined the
outcomes of other investment channels. Generally, the interest in real estate stems
from the concern that programmes may price locals out of affordable housing (Scherrer
and Thirion 2018; Holleran 2019). To date, only two reports have investigated real estate
market impact, and then only with proxies or limited timeframes. Viesturs, Pukite, and
Nikuradze (2017) examine the Latvian case by looking at the change in property trans-
actions involving foreigners across a time when the government doubled the minimum
requirements for investing in real estate. Using a difference-in-differences approach, they
deduce that the decline in demand for RBI led to a decline in real estate purchases by
foreigners. Scherrer and Thirion (2018,41–3) conclude that RBI programmes may desta-
bilise real estate markets in the EU based on a single data point. They reach this gener-
alisation by examining the variation in property transactions involving all foreign buyers
in Portugal in a single year, finding that in 2016 the number of foreigner buyers increased
by 18 percent over the previous year. Not only does their sample encompass a very
narrow time frame and case selection, but the measure includes sales to all foreigners
of which RBI applicants may be only a small proportion. Thus we still do not know
whether the increase resulted from the RBI programme, or whether it is indicative of
the global trend in foreign real estate investment occurring outside these programmes.
3
Existing research on RBI programmes has opened important questions concerning
whether the schemes are launched to address economic need, as well as the nature
and extent of their economic impact. However, these questions have remained inade-
quately assessed to date due largely to the dearth of empirical evidence. Using new
materials and government sources, we supply the first multi-country data-driven
account of the economic origins and outcomes of the programmes. To investigate
whether and how countries implement RBI programmes in response to economic
need, we test the timing of programme implementation and type of investment
options offered, as well as the extent and type economic decline in the countries. To
assess the economic impact of the programmes, we analyse the factors involved in
pricing. We also contextualise the inflows by examining the investments as a proportion
of foreign direct investment (FDI), and then narrow our analysis to the areas of the
economy seeing the largest inflows, namely real estate. To assess its scale and potential
for destabilising property markets, we examine RBI investment as a proportion of
foreign investment in property.
Research design and methods
This study focuses on RBI programmes that screen participants based only on economic
capital contributions. To eliminate options that may also include human capital com-
ponents, it adopts a strict definition of RBI that includes only programmes that have
at least one clearly passive investment option. Qualifying investments come in six
types: (1) investment in a company, (2) investment in an investment fund or structure,
(3) investment in government bonds, (4) deposits in a bank, (5) investment in real estate,
JOURNAL OF ETHNIC AND MIGRATION STUDIES 5
and (6) financial contributions to the public good. Financial contributions to a govern-
ment may also be a minor component, but in no EU case is it a stand-alone option.
Because it may be ambiguous whether business investments are fully active or passive
as addressed above, this article considers only programmes where company investment
is not the sole option for qualification. In these cases, at least one additional channel that
is passive by definition, such as real estate or government bond purchases, must be
available.
The analysis employs new data from government reports and freedom of information
requests, in addition to information from parliamentary debates. Latvia and Portugal
have regularly produced publicly available government statistics on their programmes.
Since 2018, Greece has issued government reports. Spain produced one report covering
September 2013 to December 2014 and has thereafter issued brief summaries, and the
UK has released basic, publicly available statistics about its programme since 2008.
Freedom of information requests for demographic and economic information were
answered in whole –or more often in part –by Bulgaria, Estonia, Hungary, Ireland, Lux-
embourg, the Netherlands, and the United Kingdom. Cyprus, Italy, and Malta ignored
repeated requests for information and therefore are excluded from analyses dependent
on participation numbers. Although the United Kingdom (UK) is no longer a member
of the EU, it is included in the analysis during the period of its membership. The pro-
gramme in Hungary, which was terminated in 2016, is included for the duration of its
existence (see Figure 1). Since 1998, Malta has had six different RBI programmes,
three of which are still active. Where relevant, we operationalise the minimum invest-
ment amount for Malta using the least costly option.
1993
1994
1995
1996
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
UK
Malta1
Malta2
Malta3
Malta4
Malta5
Malta6
Bulgaria
Latvia
Irel and
Hungary
Cyprus
Portugal
Spain
Netherlands
Gree ce
Luxembourg
Estonia
CzechRepublic
Italy
Figure 1. Timeline of RBI programmes.
Malta 1: Permanent Residence Scheme; Malta 2: High Net Worth Individual Visa for EU/EAA/Switzerland; Malta 3: High Net
Worth Individual Visa for non-EU/EAA/Switzerland; Malta 4: Global Residence Programme; Malta 5: The Residence Pro-
gramme; Malta 6: Malta Residency and Visa Programme.
6K. SURAK AND Y. TSUZUKI
RBI programmes in the EU
Half of all EU member states possess RBI programmes, yet these vary greatly in size. Our
analysis does not test for why individuals select one country over another, which can
depend on historical links, marketing, and the commissions that intermediaries earn
for promoting programmes (see Surak 2020b). Notable, however, is that demand is chan-
nelled into a narrow selection. Only 3 out of 14 countries that have had programmes –
Latvia, Portugal, and Greece –account for over half of all golden visas issued. Together
with Spain, the UK, and Hungary, these 6 countries have generated over 95 percent of
golden visa cases and 95 percent of its revenue (see Figure 2). The UK and Portugal
together account for more than half of the revenue brought into the EU through the pro-
grammes over time.
Notably, too, minimum qualifying investment amounts for RBI programmes vary
substantially, ranging from €60,000 in Latvia to over €2 million in the UK (Map 1).
Most, however, fall between €250,000 and €500,000. Among the investment types,
company investment is the most popular, with 12 out of 14 countries offering this
channel. Investment funds follow with 9 countries and real estate with 8 countries.
Further qualifying options include government bonds (7 countries), bank deposits (6
countries), and contributions to the public good (3 countries). Additionally, contri-
butions to government coffers are a minor component of the Latvian programme, as
well as the three Maltese schemes in operation.
1,891
7,563
4,991
7,509
717
6,932
3,165
6,046
1,156
4,625
6,313
4,244
918
935
49
384
<17
<19
0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% 100%
Total investment
(millions EUR)
Main applications
Greece (2014-2019) Portugal (2013-2019) Latvia (2010-2019)
Spain (2014-2 019) Hungary (2014-2016) United Kingdom (2010-2019)
Ireland
(
2012-2019
)
Bul
g
aria
(
2014-2017
)
Other
Figure 2. Total main applications and investments approved over time by country issuing visa.
Sources: Bulgaria: Investment Bulgaria, Estonia: Police and Border Guard Board, Greece: Enterprise Greece, Hungary:
Immigration and Asylum Office, Ireland: Department of Justice and Equality, Latvia: Office of Citizenship and Migration
Affairs, Luxembourg: Ministry of Foreign and European Affairs, Netherlands: Immigration and Naturalization Service,
Portugal: Immigration and Borders Service, Spain: Ministry of Labor and Migration, UK: Home Office.
Note: Exact investment figures are available for only Portugal and Latvia. In all other cases, total investment is estimated
by multiplying the number of applicants by the minimum investment amount. The ‘other’category includes Estonia, Lux-
embourg, and Netherlands, which have less than 20 applicants among them.
JOURNAL OF ETHNIC AND MIGRATION STUDIES 7
Economic origins and outcomes
Carrying out a detailed evaluation of economic origins and outcomes presents several
challenges. Governments are reluctant to respond to freedom of information requests
and publicly available detailed reports are uncommon. Only Latvia and Portugal
provide annual figures on investors selecting particular investment channels, while
Greece has done the same for the real estate option only. Of the remaining countries,
Map 1. RBI programmes in EU member states to 2020.
0
500
1,000
1,500
2,000
2,500
3,000
3,500
4,000
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
Millions EUR
Other
Bulgaria
Ireland
United Ki ngdom
Hungar y
Spain
Latvia
Portugal
Greece
Figure 3. Revenue by country.
Sources: Bulgaria: Investment Bulgaria, Estonia: Police and Border Guard Board, Greece: Enterprise Greece, Hungary:
Immigration and Asylum Office, Ireland: Department of Justice and Equality, Latvia: Office of Citizenship and Migration
Affairs, Luxembourg: Ministry of Foreign and European Affairs, Netherlands: Immigration and Naturalization Service, Por-
tugal: Immigration and Borders Service, Spain: Ministry of Labor and Migration, UK: Home Office.
8K. SURAK AND Y. TSUZUKI
only Ireland and Spain have issued cumulative totals for specific periods. To a degree, the
dearth of basic information on all programmes is manageable when assessing their econ-
omic impact: Portugal, Spain, Latvia, and Greece account for around 70 percent of all
approved applications and nearly 60 percent of all revenue generated (Figure 3).
4
Since 2014, the programmes have brought in close to €3 billion annually to the EU.
Though the UK sees only a few hundred applications per year, its high minimum invest-
ment amount and long history make it the largest-grossing programme, attracting over
€5.5 billion since 2010. Overall, the trend has been upwards, with the exception of a
decline in 2015 among several leading countries. The causes, however, are case-
specific. The UK doubled its minimum investment amount from £1 million to £2
million in 2015, leading to a rush before the new prices took effect and a decline there-
after. In Latvia, a new coalition government with a nationalist, anti-Russian agenda took
power in 2014. It dramatically slowed the processing of applications, long dominated by
Russians, and doubled the minimum investment amount in real estate options, leading to
a significant decline. In 2015, Portugal became mired in a corruption scandal involving
its RBI programme. The programme was frozen and audited, producing a temporary halt
and large backlog before recovering and levelling off.
Programme origins: economic need
Do countries start programmes to address economic need? To test which factors motiv-
ate countries to adopt RBI programmes, we analyse data from 2005 to 2019 across 28
countries in the EU and conduct a regression using country-year as the unit of analysis.
First, we examine whether or not programmes are established in response to an economic
downturn by using a dummy variable for the start of the programme as the dependent
variable.
5
For the main independent variable, we test GDP growth over one-year, two-
year, and three-year time spans. If the start of a programme correlates with a lower
level of GDP growth, it is likely that governments begin RBI programmes in response
to economic need. We also look for the effect of the Eurocrisis as a more systemic and
severe event that we operationalise as occurring from 2010 to 2012 and by including a
dummy variable if the dependent variable contains values from 2010–2012. We expect
this dummy variable to be significant if governments behave differently due to the econ-
omic crisis. We include an interaction term with GDP growth to see if governments were
particularly sensitive to drops in GDP during the crisis. The number of countries with
pre-existing residence programmes is included as a control variable to address the possi-
bility of contagion effects: governments may introduce programmes because others
already have them. To test whether changes in a government’s political orientation,
such as the rise of right-wing parties, have an effect, we include the relative strengths
of right wing, centre, and left wing parties in government, taken from the Comparative
Political Data Set (CPDS).
6
Year- and country-fixed effects are included to control for
other factors.
In the next step, we explore whether the specific investment options are chosen to
combat declines in targeted sectors of the economy. RBI programmes can stimulate
the economy in three key ways. First, the sale of government bonds allows states to
ease their debt burden by incentivizing the purchase of such loans. Second, investment
into businesses (including through investment funds) can create jobs and thereby
JOURNAL OF ETHNIC AND MIGRATION STUDIES 9
lower the unemployment rate. Third, real estate investment can boost the domestic prop-
erty market. Assessing these options involves three regressions, each taking the start of
the specific investment option (business, bonds, real estate) as the dependent variable.
To operationalise the economic need that each option might respond to, the main inde-
pendent variables are the housing market price index (real estate), debt-to-GDP ratio
(government bonds), and unemployment rate (business investment), for their respective
regressions. The control variables included are the annual GDP growth rate, the long-
term interest rate,
7
and the number of countries with an RBI programme. The growth
rate is designed to control for general economic activity, as opposed to the economic
indicators more closely related to the investment options. Based on the results in the
first step, a one-year GDP growth is used. The interest rate tests for the possibility that
governments use the RBI programme to borrow cheaply at the expense of distorting
the financial market. We again control for political orientation, as well as year- and
country- fixed effects.
Although the dependent variables are binary, we use a linear regression in all cases
since countries which do not have an RBI programme would be dropped in probit-
type regressions. To account for the time needed to establish a programme, we used
values lagged by one year. In addition, we control for year- and country-specific
effects. The results are shown in Tables 1 and 2.
The first regression shows that RBI programmes are indeed implemented after a
period of slowed economic growth. The effect is strongest for the three-year averages,
and the interaction for the two-year average regression is negative and significant.
Thus governments are more likely to implement programmes if they have experienced
a sustained economic downturn, and more likely to do so if the downturn occurred
during the Eurocrisis. For the option-level data, we find that the real estate and business
investment options have a significant relationship with their respective economic indi-
cators. However, the start of bond option does not correlate significantly
with the unemployment rate. Thus, the real estate and business investment options
appear to be designed to address areas of economic need, while the government bond
Table 1. Main regression results for programme start.
[1] 1 year [2] 2 years [3] 3 years [4] 1 year [5] 2 years [6] 3 years
Average GDP growth −0.559**
[.271]
−0.803**
[0.334]
−0.924**
[0.413]
−0.564*
[0.329]
−0.449
[0.347]
−0.498
[0.356]
Crisis 0.019
[0.065]
0.003
[0.048]
0.005
[0.026]
0.020
[0.061]
0.023
[0.051]
0.024
[0.032]
Crisis * GDP growth 0.030
[0.811]
−1.85*
[1.05]
−1.98
[1.42]
Housing index
Debt-to-GDP
Unemployment rate
Right-wing −0.001
[0.001]
−0.001
[0.001]
−0.001
[0.001]
−0.001
[0.001]
−0.001
[0.001]
−0.001
[0.001]
Left-wing −0.001
[0.002]
−0.001
[0.002]
−0.001
[0.001]
−0.001
[0.001]
−0.001
[0.001]
0.001
[0.001]
No. of existing programmes 0.004
[0.003]
−0.004
[0.006]
−0.003
[0.006]
0.004
[0.003]
−0.002
[0.006]
0.002
[0.005]
N 270 243 216 270 243 216
R
2
0.4034 0.4188 0.4624 0.4034 0.4315 0.4733
(year- and country-fixed effects, *p< .10, **p< .05, ***p< .001, one-tailed).
10 K. SURAK AND Y. TSUZUKI
option does not. Notably, the number of programmes already in existence does not have
a significant effect on starting an RBI programme, indicating that there is no contagion
effect. The political variables are also insignificant, which is consistent with the findings
of scholars who disaggregate the impact of political orientation on migration policy (de
Haas and Natter 2015). Not only do both left-wing and right-wing governments
implement RBI programmes, but also opposition parties, once in power, do not end
the use of such programmes. Notably, however, our findings show that a decline in
GDP growth is correlated not with greater restrictiveness, but its opposite: governments
under declining economic conditions are more likely to launch such programmes,
suggesting that they are treated more akin to economic tools rather than immigration-
related ones (cf. de Haas and Natter 2015, 18, 20). Robustness checks show that the
results hold even when each country is left out of the regression one at a time, and
thus reflect a general trend.
Programme pricing: a demand-side approach
If states implement programmes in response to economic need, do they adjust prices
accordingly? More specifically, what factors influence the pricing of investment
amounts? Dzankic (2018) asserts that richer countries place higher prices on RBI
options because the investment needs to impact GDP, which is larger in such cases.
However, as discussed above, the economic logic supporting this ‘supply-side’approach
is not clear, since higher prices do not always generate higher revenue if the decrease in
demand offsets the increase in price. The alternative ‘demand-side’explanation is that
governments choose the profit-maximising point on the demand curve: they select a
price that generates the most revenue, and thus the minimum investment amount is
determined by the demand curve of the applicants. As a result, more attractive countries
will have a higher minimum investment amount.
Table 2. Main regression results for investment option start.
[7] Start
(Real estate)
[8] Start
(Bond)
[9] Start
(Business)
Average GDP growth −0.385
[0.450]
0.087
[0.173]
−0.058
[0.451]
Crisis
Crisis * GDP growth
Housing index −0.002**
[0.001]
Debt-to-GDP 0.002
[0.001]
Unemployment rate 0.010*
[0.006]
Right-wing −0.000
[0.001]
−0.001
[0.001]
0.000
[0.001]
Left-wing −0.000
[0.001]
−0.001
[0.001]
0.001
[0.001]
No. of existing programmes 0.009
[0.006]
−0.001
[0.002]
0.003
[0.005]
N 318 314 299
R
2
0.4886 0.1961 0.4232
(year- and country-fixed effects, *p< .10, **p< .05, ***p< .001, one-tailed).
Sources: Eurostat: housing index, debt-to-GDP ratio, unemployment rate; World Bank: annual GDP growth; OECD and the
ECB Statistical Data Warehouse: long-term interest rate
JOURNAL OF ETHNIC AND MIGRATION STUDIES 11
To understand how governments price programmes, we need to first determine the
factors influence the decision. Here, we consider three hypotheses. First, investors –
like others seeking residence options –may behave as though they are making an immi-
gration decision and select a country based on factors that make it livable in the long run,
such as education, pollution, and crime rates. Second, investors may have a more short-
term orientation, leading them to behave like tourists. Qualitative research on wealthy
migrants has found that many maintain multiple bases and do not principally reside
in countries where they have acquired residence. They instead live as ‘flexible citizens’
(Ong 1999) who travel frequently between residences and business locations (see also
Surak 2020a). Thus, a country’s attractiveness is more likely to be correlated with its
attractiveness as a tourist destination with, for example, desirable resort areas more
important than average level of health care or pollution. Third, a country may be
more attractive because it provides better investment opportunities and a higher rate
of return.
To test these three hypotheses, we run a regression with data from all EU countries
with RBI programmes from 2008 to 2019, taking the number of applicants as the
main dependent variable (Table 3). For the first hypothesis, we use as the explanatory
variable several quality of life variables from the Eurostat database. The variables were
chosen based on the completeness of the data over our time period, as well as whether
they are ‘public goods’in the sense that even a wealthy investor with ample money
cannot obtain them individually.
8
For the second, we use the annual number of tourists
that arrive in each country. For the third, we use the year-on-year GDP growth rate as
well as the housing rate because –as will be seen in the next section –the vast majority
of investment goes into real estate. All of the variables are lagged by one year to avoid the
simultaneity problem, namely the problem that the independent variables may be deter-
mined by the number of applicants in the same year. As control variables, we include the
number of RBI programmes already in existence, as well as the minimum investment
amount. The number of existing resident programmes represents the number of choices
the applicant has, or in other words, the degree of competition in the market.
9
Thus, we
Table 3. Main regression results for investor behaviour.
No. of applications
Tourism 241.0***
[68.64]
Education −15.65
[18.15]
Pollution 6.45
[15.00]
Crime −9.45
[13.00]
GDP growth 1581.0
[1218]
Housing index −28.07
[9.70]
No. of RBI programmes 87.06
[63.53]
Minimum investment amount −0.001***
[0.000]
N73
R
2
0.4106
(year-fixed effects, *p< .10, **p< .05, ***p< .001, one-tailed).
12 K. SURAK AND Y. TSUZUKI
would expect the coefficient for existing programmes to be negative. The minimum invest-
ment amount is designed to account for the slope of the demand curve and thus is expected
to be negative. The regression also includes fixed year-effects.
10
The results suggest that RBI participants behave like tourists when choosing countries:
the more tourists there are in a country, the more applicants it is likely to receive. The
long-term quality of life variables, such as education, crime, and pollution, are not sig-
nificant. In addition, the coefficient for housing prices is significantly negative, which
suggests that people prefer countries where real estate is cheaper. As such, RBI
program participants act more like tourists or investors and less like immigrants when
choosing among the offerings. As for the control variables, the minimum investment
price has a negative correlation, showing that on average the slope of the demand
curve is negative and lower prices lead to more applications. The effect of the number
of RBI programmes is insignificant, which aligns with the results found in the previous
section: there is no contagion effect. In sum, we see that minimum investment prices are
higher where the demand curve is more favourable due to attractive living conditions.
Again, the results hold even when we leave out any one country from the regression.
Knowing what shapes a demand curve, we can now evaluate what determines the
minimum investment amount for each country by comparing two hypotheses. The
‘demand-side’hypothesis posits that governments react passively to market demand
and set a minimum price that maximises the total revenue. Thus, proxies for attractive-
ness should have a positive impact on investment price. The ‘supply-side’argument
asserts that the price depends on needs internal to the country. In the first regression
analysis, we found that countries begin programmes in response to economic crises.
As such, we can expect that as the economy improves, the priority of these programmes
would decline. If the political costs involved in maintaining a controversial programme
outweigh the benefits of additional revenue, countries may raise their price to decrease
the number of applicants, as occurred in the case of Latvia discussed above.
To test these hypotheses, we run a regression, but this time the dependent variable is
the minimum investment amount for each country from 2008 to 2019. The independent
variables are similar to the regression above. For the demand side, we include the signifi-
cant quality of life variables from the above regression. For the supply side, we revisit the
economic considerations from the first regression analysis, and include all key economic
variables, lagged by one year. Since the regression result in Table 3 shows that economic
indicators are not significantly correlated with applications, any significant effect in this
new regression must come from the supply side. Other control variables included are the
number of existing RBI programmes and year-fixed effects.
Although the regressions in Tables 3 and 4are similar in terms of variables, they are
different in their interpretation. In Table 3, where the main variable is the number of
applications, the focus is on what variables affect applicant choice and how. In Table
4, the focus is on what governments judge is important when adjusting their prices: dom-
estic need or investor demand. The results are summarised in Table 4.
The regressions support the demand-side hypothesis: a country’s attractiveness as
measured by the number of tourists and education is significantly correlated with the
minimum investment amount. This shows that applicants tend to choose countries
with higher livability, and that governments of those countries charge more in response.
There is some asymmetry in that applicants evaluate countries as tourists and profit-
JOURNAL OF ETHNIC AND MIGRATION STUDIES 13
oriented businesspeople, while governments price according to the country’s overall
attractiveness. At the same time, the supply-side hypothesis receives some support as
well: GDP growth and unemployment rate are negatively correlated with investment
price. From an economic perspective, maximizing revenue is best outcome, but the
number of new residents may have other effects on the domestic economy. For
example, a country with higher unemployment rate may want more investor residents
since the qualifying investment may create new jobs. On the other hand, low GDP
growth may correlate with increased political pressure to keep rich investors from
buying houses. The results of the paired regressions show that applicants behave most
similarly to tourists and investors when selecting options, and that governments
respond to both supply-side and demand-side forces when setting prices.
Programme outcomes: economic impact
What are the effects of these programmes on the overall economy? In assessing this ques-
tion, it is important to note several issues that can dilute a programme’s overall economic
benefit. Real estate may be sold above market value to investors seeking to fulfil
minimum investment requirements. Businesses may not grow or be sustainable. Admin-
istrative oversight may facilitate the exaggeration of job creation or neglect to register
business collapse (e.g. Ley 2003). To assess whether such practices undermine the econ-
omic benefits of the programmes requires a detailed analysis of how each operates on the
ground, which lies beyond the scope of this article. Instead it relies on the available infor-
mation on the number of main applicants, amount of investment, and type of invest-
ment, and extrapolates based on the number of applicants and the minimum
investment amount where data are not available.
Qualifying investments enter the economy from external sources and thus they
resemble foreign direct investment (FDI), though officially they do not come under
this category.
11
Other studies have used Foreign Portfolio Investment (FPI) to situate
Table 4. Main regression results for demand curve determinants.
Minimum investment amount
Tourism 222939***
[30512]
Education 45319***
[4727]
Pollution 10905***
[3850]
Crime 3111
[5645]
GDP growth −1599602***
[476469]
Housing index 3112
[2328]
Unemployment rate −53301***
[6881]
Debt-to-GDP ratio 448
[986.5]
No. of RBI programmes −2277
[11913]
N76
R
2
0.8561
(year-fixed effects, *p< .10, **p< .05, ***p< .001, one-tailed).
14 K. SURAK AND Y. TSUZUKI
the magnitude of these flows (Scherrer and Thirion 2018). However, FDI is a better com-
parison because the assets are relatively illiquid for the investor: if the investor sells the
investment, then she loses the visa. The upshot is a longer-term orientation more charac-
teristic of FDI than FPI.
12
Figure 4 reveals substantial variance among countries where
data are available, ranging from RBI receipts representing 15 percent of FDI in Portugal,
to less than 1 percent in Ireland.
We also see that the scale of the programme does not necessarily correlate with the
proportion of FDI. Spain, for example, has the second highest number of annual appli-
cants, but the programme constitutes only 3 percent of FDI inflows. By contrast, the pro-
grammes in Latvia and Portugal –countries with smaller economies overall –attract
investment that is equivalent to a substantial proportion of FDI. Even in countries
that are heavily reliant on FDI, such as Ireland, programme revenue is miniscule in com-
parison to other sources of foreign investment. Notably, RBI programmes are not subject
to EU rules concerning state aid, which can pose challenges when states compete for FDI.
As such, it has been hypothesised that the programmes offer an alternative means to
compete for foreign investment (Lindeboom and Meunier, Forthcoming). However,
our analysis shows that most countries are not actively exploiting programmes in this
manner. Importantly, even large programmes in small economies, such as the one in
Latvia, contribute less than 1 percent to GDP. Thus contra Scherrer and Thirion
(2018,39–41), concerns that the programmes may destabilise economies and produce
macroeconomic risks are unwarranted.
How do the injections affect specific sectors? Existing work claims that RBI pro-
grammes can have a negative impact on the real estate market by driving out locals
(Scherrer and Thirion 2018; Holleran 2019). Unfortunately, the sole empirical assess-
ment to date takes into account only partial data from two countries and does not
isolate the impact of RBI investment from general foreign investment in real estate
0.32% 0.98%
2.60%
7.23%
14.40%
12.19%
14.02%
3.17%
1.78% 1.48% 2.50% 2.43%
0.04% 0.03% 0.05% 0.11% 0.36% 0.30%
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
14%
16%
Ireland(2012-2019)
Bulgaria(2014-2017)
Spain(2014-2019)
Greece(
2014-2019)
Portugal(2013-2019)
Latvia(2013-2019)
RBI/FDI FDI/GDP RBI/GDP
Figure 4. Investment as a Proportion of Foreign Direct Investment and GDP.
Sources: Bulgaria: Investment Bulgaria, Greece: Enterprise Greece, Ireland: Department of Justice and Equality, Latvia:
Office of Citizenship and Migration Affairs, Portugal: Immigration and Borders Service, Spain: Ministry of Labor and
Migration, Eurostat: FDI, World Bank: GDP.
JOURNAL OF ETHNIC AND MIGRATION STUDIES 15
(Scherrer and Thirion 2018,42–3). In the following analysis, we use more complete data
to test these arguments by examining the four largest programmes in Greece, Latvia, Por-
tugal, and Spain, which account for over 70 percent of total approvals in the EU. If there
is a deleterious affect on local real estate, it is likely to be found in these cases.
First, we find that the focus on the real estate sector is warranted. Only Portugal, Spain,
and Latvia have released information about the number of investors selecting each type
of investment, but these countries account for nearly 60 percent of approved appli-
cations. In Portugal and Spain, over 90 percent of investors select real estate, as do
over 85 percent in Latvia (Figure 5). Greece has released figures only for applicants select-
ing real estate. Bureaucrats involved with the programme have confirmed that these rep-
resent the vast majority of cases. Thus we see that an overwhelming proportion of the
investment goes into the real estate market. Accordingly, if there is a strong effect on
the economy, positive or negative, it would appear in the real estate sector. The
Latvian numbers are particularly striking since the minimum amount for qualifying
through business investment is around one-quarter of the minimum real estate invest-
ment. Although countries may hope the programmes address other economic sectors,
investors overwhelmingly choose real estate options when available.
How significant are RBI programmes to a country’s property sector? If we look at total
foreign investment in residential property in Portugal, we find 8 percent of homes were
sold to non-residents in 2018, which amounts to 13 percent of the residential property
sector (Table 5). However, RBI investments constituted just 22 percent of total foreign
investment in real estate and about 3 percent of the total real estate market. A similar
situation can be found in Spain. From 2013 to 2017, there were 3,350 golden visas
issued, with 94 percent secured through investment in real estate, amounting to a total
investment of €2.3 billion in property.
13
During the same period, foreign nationals
8056 5744 3140
698
402 354
124 87 211
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
Latvia (2013-2019) Portugal (2015-2019) Spain (2013-2017)
Real estate Companies Funds / Banks Other
Figure 5. Number of investors by investment type.
Sources: Latvia: Office of Citizenship and Migration Affairs, Portugal: Immigration and Borders Service, Spain: Ministry of
Labor and Migration.
16 K. SURAK AND Y. TSUZUKI
comprised 13 percent to 15 percent of the total market in real estate, or nearly 219,000
transactions.
14
Thus only 1.5 percent of the foreign investment in property came
through the RBI programme, which represented less than one percent of the country’s
real estate market.
In Latvia, investment through RBI programmes has had a larger, though still not sub-
stantial, impact on the real estate market. In 2014, the government raised the minimum
investment amount for its real estate option from €142,000 in urban areas and €71,000 in
rural areas to €250,000 nationwide. Drawing on data in Viesturs, Pukite, and Nikuradze
(2017), we can see that this caused a large decrease in applications, as numbers dropped
from 5600 in 2014–1400 in 2015. At the same time, the proportion of foreigners in real
estate transactions fell from 15 percent to 10 percent. Thus RBI applicants accounted for
roughly 6.7 percent (2014) and 1.7 percent (2015) of total transactions. Furthermore, the
impact was concentrated in two regions. Riga, the capital of Latvia and the most urba-
nised area, saw transactions halve from around 2000 to 1000. Saulkrasti, a resort district,
experienced an even more drastic drop in the percentage of real estate transactions invol-
ving foreigners, from about 70 percent to 10-20 percent. The concentration of invest-
ments in this resort area conforms to the findings in Table 4 that investors behave as
tourists.
The Greek programme presents a markedly different story in comparison to the other
cases. Since implementation in 2014, it has become one of the most popular in Europe.
With a minimum investment amount of €250,000 in real estate, the programme attracted
at least €470 million into the property in 2018 alone.
15
To put this in perspective, the total
real estate market the same year was more than €1.3 billion, of which €655 million came
from foreign investors.
16
Thus, we can reasonably estimate that investment from the RBI
programme accounts for about 36 percent of the real estate sector, and 72 percent of
foreign investment into the sector. As such, the programme has come to constitute a sub-
stantial proportion of the total property market. The findings warrant further investi-
gation of whether the property market is showing signs of destabilisation and where
specifically locals have been priced out of housing.
Our findings show that the programmes do not appear to be ‘pressuring’the real estate
sector based on this measure alone (cf. Scherrer and Thirion 2018, 36). If only Greece
raises concerns, what accounts for the anxiety about such programmes? Only speculation
Table 5. Significance of RBI investment within the real estate market.
Country
Proportion of foreign
transactions within the real
estate market
Proportion of RBI
transactions within foreign
transactions
Proportion of RBI transactions
within total real estate
transactions
Portugal (2018) 13% 22.4% 2.9%
Spain (2013–2017) 13-15% 1.5% 0.2%
Greece (2018) 50% 71.8% 35.9%
Latvia (2014–2015) 10-15% 16%-44% 1.7%-6.7%
Note: Italicised numbers represent estimates.
Sources: Portugal: https://www.idealista.pt/en/news/property-sale-portugal/2019/10/14/437-which-foreigners-buy-most-
properties-portugal;https://www.registradores.org/actualidad/portal-estadistico-registral/estadisticas-de-propiedad.
Spain: Ministry of Labor and Migration; https://d500.epimg.net/descargables/2018/05/05/9bae4bd00e517653407aa03d8fd
99176.png.
Greece: Enterprise Greece; https://www.greece-is.com/news/foreign-investors-spending-greek-real-estate/.
Latvia: Viesturs, Pukite, and Nikuradze (2017).
JOURNAL OF ETHNIC AND MIGRATION STUDIES 17
is possible, but notably the nationality composition of RBI programmes sets them apart
from dominant sources of foreign investment in property. In Portugal, the golden visa
programme attracts applicants predominantly from China (55 percent), Brazil (10
percent), and Turkey (5 percent). However, the top countries accounting for foreign
real estate investment –a far larger proportion of the property market –are in
Europe: France (28 percent), Great Britain (15 percent), Switzerland (8 percent), and
Germany (6 percent).
17
Similarly, in Spain, the main players are predominantly Euro-
pean, with the United Kingdom, France, Germany, Belgium, and Sweden claiming the
top five spots for a total of 44 percent of the foreign transactions in the market.
18
Spain’s RBI programme attracts predominantly Chinese (37 percent), Russians (27
percent), and other non-EU nationals.
19
Notably too studies have presented their ana-
lyses in ways that overstate the impact of RBI investments in real estate while underplay-
ing changes in local and EU real estate purchases (e.g. Scherrer and Thirion 2018,42–3).
As such, it is possible that the purchase of property by more distant, even racially distinct,
‘others’raises greater fear among nationals that the country is being bought up by puta-
tively threatening foreigners (see also Rogers, Wong, and Nelson 2017).
Conclusion
The twentieth century saw a remarkable shift from screening new immigrants based on
racial origins to screening based on human capital contributions (Joppke 2005; FitzGer-
ald and Cook-Martín 2014). The spread of RBI programmes in the twenty-first century
adds a new dimension: screening new residents by economic capital contributions only.
The results of this investigation suggest an upper limit on Ellerman’s(2019)finding that
western countries now devalue the economic offerings of foreigners when selecting new
members. In contrast to the policies aimed at workers that she examines, here we see that
countries are indeed supplying pathways to long-term residence and citizenship for those
making economic contributions –as long as they are very sizeable. Notably, the injec-
tions are one-offand the new residents are not expected to continue to contribute to
economic growth in the same way that migrant workers might; they must simply main-
tain the original investment. The trend suggests a short-term calculation on the part of
states, seeking to plug economic gaps, as our analysis finds, rather than a longer-term
orientation of crafting a middle-class national identity (cf. Elrick and Winter 2018; Eller-
man 2019). If social capital (Portes 1998), human capital (Stark, Helmenstein, and Fürnk-
ranz-Prskawetz 1998; Ellerman 2019), and ethnic capital (Mateos and Durand 2012;Kim
2018) have captured the attention of social scientists analysing migration, the develop-
ments tracked here suggest that a renewed focus on economic capital may be warranted.
We find that states continue to harness mobility policies in service of economic objec-
tives, now in a more starkly transactional manner, and –as we show –no matter what
the political orientation of the government may be.
If RBI programmes are becoming an increasingly popular policy option, not all
countries see the same uptake. Demand in Europe is concentrated in a handful of pro-
grammes: just four countries represent 75 percent of all investor residents. The pro-
grammes now bring nearly €3.5 billion to the Union annually, yet the economic
benefits are uneven. Indeed, only in two countries, Latvia and Portugal, are the economic
injections large enough to represent a significant proportion of FDI. However in no
18 K. SURAK AND Y. TSUZUKI
country do they represent a substantial proportion of GDP, suggesting that concerns
about macroeconomic destabilisation are unwarranted.
Our analysis reveals that economic decline leads to a greater likelihood that countries
will start programmes, and that if the economic decline occurred during the Eurocrisis,
the likelihood is yet greater –an argument proposed but not demonstrated by the litera-
ture (e.g. Parker 2017; Holleran 2019; Dzankic 2018; Veteto 2014). The choice of invest-
ment options, too, is largely responsive to economic need when governments implement
real estate and business investment options, though not government bond options. Fur-
thermore, the spread of programmes itself does not lead to more programmes: there is no
contagion effect. As such, driving the onset of RBI programmes is more than mere client
politics or neo-liberal ideology (cf. Mavelli 2018); economic need is a significant factor
behind them. However, investors may stymie government intentions to use programmes
to boost several areas of the economy, for they overwhelmingly invest in real estate if
given the option.
Furthermore, our analysis suggests that wealthy investor migrants may be better con-
ceptualised as mobile, profit-oriented populations akin to tourists and businesspeople,
rather than as long term-oriented immigrants. The results lend support to qualitative
work that identifies such mobile populations as ‘flexible citizens’(Ong 1999), who use
investment to multiply their options and secure additional bases, rather than to pack
up and immigrate or invest in a growing economy (see also Ley 2010; Surak 2020a).
We also find that countries with strong tourism sectors can charge more for their pro-
grammes as well. Yet they are not merely profit maximisers, choosing a price that will
attract the most applicants; they respond to internal issues too, changing price in accord-
ance with economic growth and employment rates.
A number of analysts have raised warning flags that investor migrants may price locals
out of real estate (Scherrer and Thirion 2018; Holleran 2019). Our analysis shows the
concern is unwarranted: the proportion of RBI real estate transactions in the national
market is miniscule in nearly all cases. Notably, these programmes attract more
distant and often ‘browner’others than the fellow Europeans who constitute the greatest
proportion of foreign real estate buyers and raise less media hype, suggesting that xeno-
phobia may lie behind the concern. Greece is the sole, but significant, exception where
the scale of the programme could indeed destabilise the property market. As real
estate investment tends to be concentrated in specific locales (Friedland and Calderon
2017; Viesturs, Pukite, and Nikuradze 2017), regional and city-level data are necessary
to further identify whether more limited destabilisation is occurring in particular areas.
What has been the impact of Covid-19 on these programmes? The sudden hardening
of borders across the world has sent many wealthy people looking for ways to hedge their
risks by securing mobility options and a Plan B (Surak 2020b,2020c). To date, as we
show, national-level healthcare statistics have been insignificant, but Covid-19 may
encourage wealthy investors to select countries that have handled the pandemic well
or that offer state-of-the-art healthcare. Covid-19 may also bring a shift away from a
short-term ‘tourist-like’calculation to a medium-term calculation preferring a place
for longer-stint stays.
Regarding supply, Covid-19 is likely to increase the attractiveness of RBI programmes
as a way to draw in foreign investment. Our study found that countries are more prone to
start programmes after a period of slowed economic growth, particularly after a systemic
JOURNAL OF ETHNIC AND MIGRATION STUDIES 19
recession. If the economic downturn spurred by the pandemic continues, it is likely that
new countries will start their own programmes, replicating the pattern we found, and
that countries with RBI offerings already in place will attempt to develop them further
to address deepening economic need. Even if the schemes to date have been small,
they still offer a means to attract additional resources at little cost. With real estate the
most popular qualifying option, the investment boost is likely to be concentrated in
the property and construction sector, which itself is transforming as the pandemic
reconfigures work patterns and the desirability of urban living. Even if the European
Commission continues to call for ending the programmes, countries are more likely to
adapt their RBI offerings –perhaps by shifting them closer to, or even transforming
them into, entrepreneurial options –rather than do away with them entirely.
Notes
1. Bulgaria, which offers permanent residence, is the exception. Cyprus also grants permanent
residence, but requires investors to maintain the real estate purchased for qualification. The
bank deposit can be withdrawn after three years.
2. The report’sdefinition of RBI programmes is more expansive than our own and includes
cases where human capital contributions are assessed. See the research design and
methods section below.
3. The report also strains to make a similar case with respect to citizenship by investment pro-
grammes. The authors flag a 43 percent increase in real estate sales in Cyprus between 2015
and 2016, with nearly a quarter coming from foreigners –a 34 percent increase over the pre-
vious year. The explanation, however, ignores the much larger jump in real estate purchases
by locals in the comparable time span, which rose by 46 percent. The full picture indicates
that it is not that foreigners are increasingly dominating the market, but that the market as a
whole is becoming more attractive to foreigners and locals alike.
4. The Figure does not include Malta, Cyprus, or Italy, which have not issued reports and did
not respond to repeated requests for data. Service providers involved with developing the
Italian programme confirm that only a handful of people have applied. The lack of data
on Cyprus and Malta, however, leaves a potentially significant gap. Both countries host
popular citizenship by investment schemes, and their RBI programmes possess structures
similar to popular real estate-based programmes in the Mediterranean. Thus, it is likely
that the number of approvals in Malta and Cyprus contribute more to the EU’s total RBI
admissions, though they are unlikely to be among the top choices
5. We operationalized this by setting the value to ‘1’for every year a new programme starts. In
all of the robustness checks, the significance and magnitude of the coefficients were similar
and did not change our conclusions.
6. In the regressions, we drop centre parties to avoid collinearity. To check robustness, we run
regressions using the other two definitions and find that the results are consistent.
7. Estonia does not have comparable data since it only rarely issues government bonds, and
therefore 0 was substituted for all values
8. Because of their visa status, investors cannot make use of most important welfare state pro-
visions such as public pensions, unemployment payments, or public housing benefits,
should these wealthy individuals even seek them out. Furthermore, all the programmes
require participants to possess private health insurance.
9. We include Hungary as an option and count Malta as only one programme as investors are
unlikely to select more than one residence programme in a single country.
10. Fixed country effects are left out of the regression since tourism and quality of life likely
include time-invariant, country-specific elements, such as the Colosseum, Côte d’Azur, or
the London School of Economics.
20 K. SURAK AND Y. TSUZUKI
11. The exception are cases –possible only in Bulgaria and Luxembourg –where local banks can
finance the qualifying investment by loaning a portion of the funds to the investor, effec-
tively printing the money within the country.
12. FDI data are taken from the World Bank. We use the minimum investment amount to cal-
culate overall investment where only the total number of accepted investors is available.
13. Data from Extranjeros Residentes en España Reports from the Ministry of Labor and
Migration.
14. Data from Estadísticas de la Propiedad, Registrar of Spain. To match the period for the
Golden Visa figures, we start from the fourth ‘trimestral’in 2013.
15. Data from Enterprise Greece.
16. https://www.greece-is.com/news/foreign-investors-spending-greek-real-estate/.
17. https://www.idealista.pt/en/news/property-sale-portugal/2019/10/14/437-which-
foreigners-buy-most-properties-portugal.
18. Data from Estadísticas de la Propiedad, Registrar of Spain. To match the period for the
Golden Visa figures, we start from the fourth ‘trimestral’in 2013
19. Similar information for Greece and Latvia is unavailable.
Disclosure statement
No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).
References
Adim, L. 2017.“Between Benefit and Abuse: Immigrant Investment Programs.”Saint Louis
University Law Journal 62 (1): 121–136.
Carrera, S. 2014.“How Much Does EU Citizenship Cost?”CEPS Paper in Liberty and Security in
Europe, No. 64.
Christians, A. 2017.“Buying In: Residence and Citizenship by Investment.”St. Louis University
Law Journal 62: 51–71.
de Haas, H., and K. Natter. 2015.“The determinants of migration policies. Does the political orien-
tation of governments matter?”International Migration Institute IMI Working Paper Series,
117.
DeRosa, J. 1995.“The Immigrant Investor Program: Cleaning Up Canada’s Act.”Case Western
Reserve Journal of International Law 27: 359–405.
Dzankic, J. 2012.“The Pros and Cons of Ius Pecuniae: Investor Citizenship in Comparative
Perspective.’2012/14. EUI Working Papers. Robert Schuman Centre for Advanced Studies,
EUDO Citizenship Observatory.
Dzankic, J. 2018.“Immigrant Investor Programmes in the European Union (EU).”Journal of
Contemporary European Studies 26 (1): 64–80.
Ellerman, A. 2019.“Human Capital Citizenship and the Changing Logic of Immigrant
Admissions.”Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies. doi:10.1080/1369183X.2018.1561062
Elrick, J., and E. Winter. 2018.“Managing the National Status Group: Immigration Policy in
Germany.”International Migration 56 (4): 19–32.
European Commission. 2019.“Report from the Commission to the European Parliament, the
Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of Regions:
Investor Citizenship and Residence Schemes in the European Union.”{SWD2019)5 final}.
Brussels.
FitzGerald, D., and D. Cook-Martín. 2014.Culling the Masses: The Democratic Origins of Racist
Immigration Policy in the Americas. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Friedland, G., and J. Calderon. 2017.EB-5 Project Database: Supplement with Trends and
Observations. New York: NYU Stern Center for Real Estate Finance Research.
Holleran, M. 2019.“Buying Up the Semi-Periphery: Spain’s Economy of ‘Golden Visas’.”Ethnos:
Journal of Anthropology, doi:10.1080/00141844.2019.1687548.
JOURNAL OF ETHNIC AND MIGRATION STUDIES 21
Joppke, C. 2005.Selecting by Origin: Ethnic Migration in the Liberal State. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Kim, J. 2018.“Ethnic Capital, Migration, and Citizenship: A Bourdieusian Perspective.”Ethnic and
Racial Studies, doi:10.1080/01419870.2019.1535131.
Ley, D. 2003.“Seeking Homo Economicus: The Canadian State and the Strange Story of the
Business Immigration Program.”Annals of the Association of American Geographers 93 (2):
426–441.
Ley, D. 2010.Millionaire Migrants: Trans-Pacific Life Lines. Chichester: Wiley-Blackwell.
Lindeboom, J., and S. Meunier. Forthcoming.“In the Face of the Euro Crisis: Foreign Direct
Investment and Investor Programmes in the European Union.”In Citizenship and Residence
Sales: Rethinking the Boundaries of Belonging, edited by D. Kochenov and K. Surak.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mateos, P., and J. Durand. 2012.“Residence v. Ancestry in Acquisition of Spanish Citizenship: A
Netography Approach.”Migraciones Internacionales 6 (4): 9–46.
Mavelli, L. 2018.“Citizenship for Sale and the Neoliberal Political Economy of Belonging.”
International Studies Quarterly 62 (3): 482–493.
Migration Advisory Committee. 2014.Tier 1 (Investor) Route: Investment Thresholds and
Economic Benefits. London: The Migration Advisory Committee. https://www.gov.uk/
government/publications/the-investment-limits-and-economic-benefits-of-the-tier-1-investor-
route-feb-2014.
Ong, A. 1999.Flexible Citizenship: The Cultural Logics of Transnationality. Durham: Duke
University Press.
Parker, O. 2017.“Commercializing Citizenship in Crisis EU: The Case of Immigrant Investor
Programmes.”Journal of Common Market Studies 55 (2): 332–348.
Portes, A. 1998.“Social Capital: Its Origins and Application in Modern Sociology.”Annual Review
of Sociology 24: 1–24.
Rogers, D., A. Wong, and J. Nelson. 2017.“Public Perceptions of Foreign and Chinese Real Estate
Investment: Intercultural Relations in Global Sydney.”Australian Geographer 48 (4): 437–455.
Rose, R. 1992.“Fixing the Wheel: A Critical Analysis of the Immigrant Investor Visa.”San Diego
Law Review 29: 615–642.
Scherrer, A., and E. Thirion. 2018.Citizenship by Investment (CBI) and Residency by Investment
(RBI) Schemes in the EU: State of Play, Issues and Impacts. Brussels: European Parliament,
European Parliamentary Research Service, PE 627.128.
Shachar, A., and R. Hirschl. 2014.“On Citizenship, States, and Markets.”Journal of Political
Philosophy 22 (2): 231–257.
Spiro, P. 2014.“Cash-for-Passports and the End of Citizenship.”In Debating Transformations of
National Citizenship, edited by R. Bauböck, 17–20. Cham: Springer Open.
Stark, O., C. Helmenstein, and A. Fürnkranz-Prskawetz. 1998.“Human Capital Depletion, Human
Capital Forma, and Migration: A Blessing or a ‘Curse’.”Economics Letters 60 (3): 363–367.
Steier, L. 1992.“Confounding Market Hierarchy in Venture Capital Governance: The Canadian
Immigrant Investor Program.”Journal of Management Studies 35 (4): 511–535.
Sumption, M., and K. Hooper. 2014.Selling Visas and Citizenship: Policy Questions from the Global
Boom in Investor Immigration. Washington, DC: Migration Policy Institute.
Surak, K. 2020a.“Millionaire Mobility and the Sale of Citizenship.”Journal of Ethnic and
Migration Studies 47 (1): 166–189.
Surak, K. 2020b.“Who Wants to Buy a Visa? Comparing the Uptake of Residence by Investment
Programs in the European Union.”Journal of Contemporary European Studies. doi:10.1080/
14782804.2020.1839742.
Surak, K. 2020c.“How COVID-19 Will Transform the Market in Investment Migration.”
Globalcit. June 3, 2020. https://globalcit.eu/how-covid-19-will-transform-the-market-in-
investment-migration/.
Surak, Kristin. Forthcoming.“Marketizing Sovereign Prerogatives: How to Sell Citizenship.”
European Journal of Sociology.
22 K. SURAK AND Y. TSUZUKI
Veteto, J. 2014.“The Alienability of Allegiance: An International Survey of Economic Citizenship
Laws.”The International Lawyer 48 (1): 79–103.
Viesturs, J., I. Pukite, and I. Nikuradze. 2017.“Limiting the Program of Temporary Residence
Permits for Foreigners Based on Real Property Investment in Latvia.”Baltic Journal of Real
Estate Economics and Construction Management 5: 248–258.
Wong, L. 2003.“Chinese Business Migration to Australia, Canada, and the United States: State
Policy and the Global Immigration Marketplace.”Asian and Pacific Migration Journal 12 (3):
301–336.
Xu, Xin, Ahmed El-Ashram, and Judith Gold. 2016.“Too Much of a Good Thing? Prudent
Management of Inflows under Economic Citizenship Programs.”Working Paper WP/15/93.
International Monetary Fund.
JOURNAL OF ETHNIC AND MIGRATION STUDIES 23