ArticlePDF Available

Multilevel governance and the external strategies of subnational governments in Latin America

Authors:

Abstract

This article examines the external dimensions of domestic conflicts over subnational prerogatives in Latin America – a place where subnational governments cannot leverage their presence in powerful supranational institutions like those of the European Union. In the wake of decentralization, subnational governments across Latin America are adopting a variety of external strategies to defend their newfound prerogatives vis-à-vis national governments. This article conceptualizes three such strategies – targeted at governmental allies at the supranational, national, and subnational scales – and examines how each has been deployed in recent conflicts between national and subnational governments in Colombia, Bolivia, and Ecuador. While domestic conflicts over territorial governance have indeed become externalized in Latin America, external strategies on the part of subnational governments do not appear to have had a decisive impact, in part because their opponents in the national government have been able to similarly identify and solicit the support of their own external allies.
Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at
https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=frfs20
Regional & Federal Studies
ISSN: (Print) (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/frfs20
Multilevel governance and the external strategies
of subnational governments in Latin America
Kent Eaton
To cite this article: Kent Eaton (2021): Multilevel governance and the external strategies
of subnational governments in Latin America, Regional & Federal Studies, DOI:
10.1080/13597566.2021.1875448
To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/13597566.2021.1875448
Published online: 02 Mar 2021.
Submit your article to this journal
View related articles
View Crossmark data
Multilevel governance and the external strategies of
subnational governments in Latin America
Kent Eaton
Crown Faculty Services, UC Santa Cruz, Santa Cruz, CA, USA
ABSTRACT
This article examines the external dimensions of domestic conicts over
subnational prerogatives in Latin America a place where subnational
governments cannot leverage their presence in powerful supranational
institutions like those of the European Union. In the wake of decentralization,
subnational governments across Latin America are adopting a variety of
external strategies to defend their newfound prerogatives vis-à-vis national
governments. This article conceptualizes three such strategies targeted at
governmental allies at the supranational, national, and subnational scales
and examines how each has been deployed in recent conicts between
national and subnational governments in Colombia, Bolivia, and Ecuador.
While domestic conicts over territorial governance have indeed become
externalized in Latin America, external strategies on the part of subnational
governments do not appear to have had a decisive impact, in part because
their opponents in the national government have been able to similarly
identify and solicit the support of their own external allies.
KEYWORDS Multilevel governance; Latin America; subnational governments; decentralization; regional
authority; paradiplomacy
One of the most extensive governance trends of recent decades is the
decision by national governments to endow subnational governments with
additional forms of authority, along with the resources to full their new
roles (Oxhorn, Tulchin, and Selee 2004; Faguet and Poschl 2015; Hooghe
et al. 2016). Decentralization of authority has represented an especially
remarkable pivot in the global south, where colonial legacies and authoritar-
ian regimes have tended to generate highly centralizing patterns of rule
(Smoke, Gomez, and Peterson 2007; Dickovick and Wunsch 2014). Several
decades into this trend, however, we now know that the decision to decen-
tralize is never really the end of the story; instead it typically unleashes new
forms of conict between national and subnational governments as the latter
set out to use, defend and/or enhance their newfound powers while the
© 2021 Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group
CONTACT Kent Eaton keaton@ucsc.edu Crown Faculty Services, UC Santa Cruz, Santa Cruz, CA
95064, USA
REGIONAL AND FEDERAL STUDIES
https://doi.org/10.1080/13597566.2021.1875448
former often seek to claw back resources and prerogatives. As a result, the
distribution of authority between national and subnational governments
(including at both the regional/intermediate and local/municipal scales) has
proved to be quite uid in many cases. As the literature on decentralization
in the global south has demonstrated, this uidity is due in part to the reality
that national governments decide to decentralize largely for short-term and
often for baldly political reasons; rarely are they motivated purely by the nor-
mative desire to deepen democracy, promote economic development, or
enhance citizen security (ONeill 2005; Falleti 2010). When the political
winds shift, when new parties come to power, or when economic crises are
overcome, national governments frequently pursue a range of (overt and
covert) re-centralizing measures to shore up their power (Dickovick and
Eaton 2013).
The purpose of this article is to explore the question of whether and how
subnational governments deploy external strategies in their attempts to
defend themselves, their authority, and their capacity from these encroach-
ments by the national government. By external strategies, I am referring to
behaviours by subnational governments that lead them to breach the
connes of the domestic political arena that are delimited by the borders
of the state to which they belong. Traditionally, conicts between national
and subnational governments over which level gets to do what and with
whose money have been understood as struggles that are fundamentally
domestic, often highly politically sensitive for the centre, and generally
well-protected by international norms of sovereignty. The default assumption
is that nation-states get to decide what if any powers to give their subna-
tional governments, and that if these governments do not enjoy sucient
leverage domestically to demand greater authority from below, there is
little they can do but accept the division of authority on oer from the
centre. As a measure of the sensitivity of territorial governance, it is no
coincidence that, bureaucratically speaking, control over subnational govern-
ments is often merged with internal security matters in Ministries of the
Interior.
To date, scholars have paid signicant attention to how international
forces like economic liberalization, the globalization of capital markets, and
the reduction of trade barriers have all played a role in the adoption of
more decentralized modes of governance (Doner and Hershberg 1999;
Sorens 2004; Goldfrank and Shrank 2009). We also know that specic
global actors like bilateral aid organizations and multilateral nancial insti-
tutions also heavily supported the decision to decentralize across the
global south, despite some disagreement about whether these organizations
mostly followed and endorsed or actually helped cause the decision to
decentralize, which was almost always taken for domestic reasons (Dickovick
2014). But when decentralized institutions are subject to attempts at reversal
2K. EATON
by national governments, is it possible for subnational governments to turn
to external actors as a way to better defend themselves vis-à-vis the centre?
While scholarship on the global north in general and on Europe in particu-
lar has documented the increasingly complex interactions that are taking
place between subnational and supranational levels of politics, thanks to
the literatures on multilevel governance (Hooghe 1996; Hooghe and Marks
2001,2016; Piattoni 2010) and paradiplomacy (Soldatos 1990; Aldecoa and
Keating 1999; Tatham 2016; Tavares 2016), very little is yet known about
the external strategies that subnational governments may be using in the
global south.
1
Regional economic integration has produced a much more
robust set of supranational institutions in Europe than anywhere else,
which means that if subnational governments outside of Europe are also
stepping up their gameinternationally, we should not just look at suprana-
tional institutions for signs of this activity. Instead, the weakness of suprana-
tional institutional channels of the sort we see in the EU may force
subnational governments to get creative about their external activities.
Toward the goal of better understanding the external dimensions of dom-
estic conicts over subnational prerogatives, my approach in this article is to
conceptualize a number of strategies that subnational governments can use
in their defense. This focus on defensive strategies adopted by subnational
governments in the throes of conict with the centre is meant to comp-
lement a literature that has tended to privilege how these governments
have proactively begun to pursue their interests in a more oensive
posture, as in their more aggressive pursuit of direct foreign investment
(Hooghe and Marks 1996; Malesky 2008; Tavares 2016). I focus on Latin
America, perhaps the most dynamic region in the global south in terms of
both decentralization and recentralization. In Latin America, external actors
like the U.S. government, multinational corporations, and transnational
NGOs all shape the authority and capacity of subnational governance in
ways that are both solicited and unsolicited by these governments, but my
concern in this paper is with the former in the sense that I examine explicit
strategies. By strategy, I refer simply to some plan of (external) action
designed and adopted as a solution to a particular problem in this case
the defense of subnational prerogatives. In addition to identifying a
number of such strategies and demonstrating how they have been deployed
in specic conicts, my goal is to begin to illuminate both their potential
payos and possible limitations, along with some sense of the extent to
which external forces are actually shaping internal struggles over territorial
governance in Latin America.
While the article is animated by the goal of deepening awareness of the
range of the external strategies pursued by subnational governments,
together with the seriousness (and high political drama) of some of these
eorts, it also raises questions about the eectiveness of these strategies.
REGIONAL & FEDERAL STUDIES 3
External forces and trends like liberalization and democratization have unde-
niably pushed the decentralization trend forward, and yet external actors
have so far not proven to be all that useful as allies that subnational govern-
ments can leverage in defense of their prerogatives when these are chal-
lenged by the centre. In part this is because of a two can play that game
dynamic. As will become evident in the case studies that follow, when subna-
tional governments have identied and targeted external partners, their
opponents in the national government have often been able to similarly
identify and solicit the support of their own external allies. One walkaway
point is that domestic conicts over territorial governance, which in an
earlier era seemed almost entirely beyond the purview of actors above and
outside the nation-state, have indeed become externalized and internationa-
lized but not in a way that redounds only to the benet of the subnational
combatants in these conicts.
This article proceeds as follows. In the next section, I conceptualize three
dierent external strategies that subnational governments have used in
their various clashes with the centre, emphasizing as the main criterion the
territorial scale of the external ally solicited: supranational, national, or subna-
tional. All of these strategies are external,extra-domesticand inter-
nationalin the sense that they transcend the national polity, but they
dier in terms of the level of the external government that the subnational
government is targeting. After conceptualizing these strategies as the subna-
tional-supranational,subnational-national, and subnational-subnational
strategies, the next three sections illustrate each one with an example from
adierent country (Colombia, Bolivia, and Ecuador).
Conceptualizing external strategies across multiple scales
Conicts over territorial prerogatives between subnational and national gov-
ernments often take on a David vs. Goliathquality given the structural and
scal advantages of the latter over the former. As the generally weaker party
in these conicts, and following the logic of Edward Gibsons theory of
boundary control (2013), subnational governments may seek to bolster
their position by looking for allies beyond the states territorial limits. External
strategies can also be understood as a way to generate leverage vis-à-vis
national governments in a dynamic that is analogous to the boomerang
eectidentied by Margaret Keck and Kathryn Sikkink (1998). Keck and Sik-
kinks expansive list of actors who belong to the transnational advocacy net-
works that apply the boomerang (e.g. local social movements, foundations,
parts of the executive or parliamentary branches of government) does not,
but should, include subnational ocials who can try to name and shame
national governments with the help of external allies (9). Because national
governments often try to defend or justify their assaults on subnational
4K. EATON
prerogatives by emphasizing the corruption or ineectiveness of subnational
ocials, beleaguered subnational governments can try to ally with external
actors who are deemed legitimate as a way to bolster their own legitimacy.
Visibility is especially important in these conicts because national govern-
ment transgressions against the prerogatives of subnational governments
can go unnoticed by anyone other than the subnational ocials themselves,
especially when these take more covert forms (Dickovick and Eaton 2013).
As a rst cut at conceptualizing the external strategies adopted by subna-
tional governments, which has received scant attention in the existing litera-
ture outside Europe, one simple criterion deserves emphasis, which is the
territorial scale at which they focus their eorts: supranational, national, or
subnational. Taking scale seriously means that, when subnational govern-
ments decide to externalize their conicts with national governments, they
also then have several options in terms of the level of external governmental
institutions they want to target. As developed in the paragraphs below and
summarized in Table 1, external strategies at these three territorial scales
are characterized by dierent combinations of potential risks and possible
pay-os. Risk here is construed narrowly to refer only to how the external
strategy is likely to be perceived by the national government (as the main
antagonist of the subnational government in question), and payorefers
broadly to the benets (material and/or rhetorical) that the subnational gov-
ernment can hope to secure. This exercise is intended as an initial conceptu-
alization that could and should be further rened and extended.
Perhaps the most obvious way for a subnational government to externa-
lize its conict with the national government would be to seek representation
in or recourse from a supranational institution to which the member country
belongs. This subnational-supranationalinterface has received much atten-
tion in the literature on multilevel governance and the European Union,
which has created multiple institutional channels for the expression of subna-
tional interests (Hooghe and Marks 1996,2001; Tatham 2016). No other
regional attempts at economic integration have come close to the European
experience in terms of the number and potential signicance of the insti-
tutional spaces they have created for subnational governments. In the case
of NAFTAs chapter 11, new mechanisms for the resolution of investor-state
disputes have in fact been used to suppress rather than enhance the
stature of subnational governments (Warner and Gerbasi 2004). But even if
Table 1. Comparing external strategies by subnational governments (SNG).
Scale of external ally Possible risk to SNGs Potential payoto SNGs
Supranational Medium Low-High
National High High
Subnational Low Low
REGIONAL & FEDERAL STUDIES 5
the regional institutions that promote economic integration hold little
promise for them, subnational governments in the global south may enjoy
leverage in other supranational institutions, including: (1) regional develop-
ment banks like the Asian Development Bank, (2) regional bodies like the
Organisation of African Unity (OAU), and (3) multilateral institutions like the
United Nations (and its 17 specialized agencies).
The subnational-supranationalstrategy poses medium risks: while the
countrys membership in the supranational institution may provide some
cover for subnational governments that activate this strategy, taking a
conict to a supranational body may be interpreted as a direct challenge
to the national governments role as the sole nexus or point of contact vis-
à-vis these bodies. Reecting the heterogeneity of supranational institutions,
the potential benets derived from this strategy can fall anywhere from the
low to high range: while some of these institutions wield considerable
resources (e.g. the UN Development Program) others are famously loathe
to intervene in domestic conicts (e.g. OAU) and cannot or do not oer
much in the way of material or logistical support.
According to the second strategy, subnational governments seek to lobby
and/or ally with the national government of a foreign power. Under certain,
somewhat extreme, conditions, subnational governments that are embattled
with their respective national governments may seek to establish their own
separate contacts and relationships with national governments in other
countries, typically either neighbouring countries or countries they consider
especially powerful or relevant (i.e. the U.S. or Spain for Latin America).
Directly challenging the norm of foreign non-intervention in internal disputes
over territorial governance, the idea motivating this strategy is to ask foreign
governments to take sides in these disputes and to align with the subnational
government in question. Similar dynamics are what led Panayotis Soldatos
(1990), with the case of Quebec in mind, to conceptualize paradiplomacy
as a relatively new phenomenon.
This second strategy may be infrequent given that it poses a more frontal
challenge to sovereignty than the rst strategy, and should be considered
both high-risk and high-payo. Its riskiness is a function of how likely it is
to provoke extreme reactions from the localnational government, whose
sovereign prerogatives are being threatened much more directly than
when subnational governments try to line up support from supranational
institutions. A stark departure from traditional norms of diplomacy, this strat-
egy may also open up subnational governments to charges that they are
serving the goals of foreign actors and lacking in patriotism; especially
where nationalism is a salient political force, alliances with national govern-
ments abroad can worsen rather than improve the perceived legitimacy of
subnational ocials. But if successful, this strategy could generate signicant
payos in the form of (material and rhetorical) support from a powerful and/
6K. EATON
or neighbouring country. While the odds of this kind of strategy succeeding
are perhaps limited, its activation appears to be more likely (1) in the pres-
ence of ideological anities between the subnational government in ques-
tion and the foreign power, and (2) when foreign access to natural
resources, investment opportunities, and/or strategic exports from the sub-
national region seem to be threatened by the policies of the localnational
government.
Unlike the rst two strategies, the third strategy is external but not vertical
in the sense that it looks to partner horizontally with subnational govern-
ments in other countries rather than with external governmental actors at
higher hierarchical levels. In Europe, Hooghe and Marks (1996 and 2001)
identify a number of functionally-specic networks connecting subnational
governments that have strengthened across the EU, some of which bring
together regions that face common policy problems, and some of which
link together highly successful regions (as in the Four Motors association
created three decades ago between Baden-Württemberg, Catalonia, Lom-
bardy, and Rhône-Alpes). More recently, scholars in Latin America have
begun to study cooperation between subnational governments in neigh-
bouring countries. In Argentina and Chile, for example, Silva and Morán
(2010)nd that Integration Committees between border regions have
brought the two nations closer together, and Colacrai (2010) argues that
Argentine and Chilean subnational governments have collectively deepened
integration in terms of trade, infrastructure, tourism and culture. Schiavón
(2006) likewise shows how Mexican states that are wealthier and geographi-
cally closer to the U.S. have forged ties with U.S. states across the border to
promote and manage integration. All of this research on Latin America to
date sees the subnational-subnationalstrategy as essentially functional to
national objectives in the sense of furthering and accelerating regional inte-
gration. Thus, while these paradiplomatic eorts are far more politically
meaningful than the sister citiesmodality (Tavares 2016), it is important to
emphasize that they still run parallel with, and not orthogonal to, the
eorts of national governments accurately reecting the parain
paradiplomacy.
But what are the prospects for cooperation between subnational govern-
ments in separate countries in collaborative relationships that do not further,
complement or deepen the policy objectives of their respective national gov-
ernments, but instead conict with or undermine those objectives? For
instance, when the policy autonomy of a subnational government is threa-
tened by the national government what help might subnational govern-
ments in other countries provide? There are good reasons to doubt that
subnational governments outside the country could be of much assistance
by virtue of their subnational identities (and coers). Other possible external
allies examined in this article, including the U.S. government or multilateral
REGIONAL & FEDERAL STUDIES 7
institutions, would appear to have far more to oer in the way of resources,
leverage, and capacity. Nevertheless, alliances between subnational govern-
ments that are embattled with national governments for the same reason, or
that seek to defend greater autonomy from those governments for similar
purposes, may still serve a number of limited objectives. Precisely because
a subnational unit in a given country may be quite special, distinctive, or
unusual relative to other units in that same country, and therefore somewhat
isolated domestically, partnering with subnational units deemed to be similar
in other countries can oer a possible way to overcome their isolation. Not-
withstanding these benets, the subnational-subnationalstrategy generates
limited payos, and likely poses limited risks as well: national governments
generally do not perceive that their sovereignty could be threatened by sub-
national governments abroad.
Before illustrating each of the three external strategies in the sections that
follow, a few further reections about and possible extensions of this simple
conceptual schema are in order. First, while it makes sense to emphasize the
dierent risks and benets that subnational ocials associate with these
strategies, it is important to note that they should be thought of as potentially
combinable rather than mutually exclusive. Faced with the nearly existential
threats that are described below, subnational ocials may seek to activate
allies at more than one scale, making multiple overtures and seeing what
sticksin a dynamic akin to venue shopping.
2
Second, each of these strategies
could be bilateral or multilateral in scope, and at either end of the relation-
ship. In other words, a subnational unit can strategize alone or in concert
with other units in that same country, and it/they can either target one exter-
nal governmental actor or multiple external governmental actors at the scale
of their choosing. The choice between bilateral and multilateral approaches,
along with the degree to which the three strategies are combinable, will
depend largely on context.
Third, while my conceptual schema emphasizes governmental actors at
multiple scales, it should be possible to broaden this framework to include
non-governmental allies at each scale as well (in the form of transnational
NGOs, civil society groups that are organized at the national level, and sub-
national civil-society partners in other countries). External NGOs that are
issue-specic rarely articulate the strengthening of subnational governments
as one of their core goals (unlike such development agencies as USAID or
NORAD), but they often do identify these governments as partners who
can help them achieve their own core goals, including for example the
environmental stewardship that indigenous municipalities might be seen
as guaranteeing, or the human rights protections that might be strengthened
by local government criminal justice reforms. For the great majority of subna-
tional units in Latin America, which often incorporate vast and sparsely popu-
lated rural areas, external NGOs have played especially key roles in bringing
8K. EATON
much needed capacity to subnational bureaucracies, both by training the
employees of subnational agencies and by directly supplying skills like pro-
gramme design and evaluation, service provision, and data analysis. From
the perspective of subnational governments, building relationships with
external NGOs may be seen as less overtly threatening to the centre than
the three governmental strategies emphasized here, even if many national
governments have recently moved to more heavily regulate these NGOs (Car-
others and Brechenmacher 2014).
The subnational-supranational strategy: A mayors suspension
in Colombia
When in the aftermath of decentralization national governments in Latin
America have developed concerns about how subnational ocials are
using their new authority, they can seek to recentralize the scal resources
at their disposal or limit their capacity to act administratively in ways that chal-
lenge national policy preferences. But they can also set their sights on the
third, political dimension of decentralization, which refers to the direct elec-
tion of subnational ocials who in the past were appointed and removed
by the centre. While political decentralization has proven to be quite
stickyin the sense that national governments have not been able to directly
reverse or suspend subnational electoral processes (in contrast to scal and
administrative recentralization), they have been able to target the individuals
who participate in these elections and to suspend from oce those who win.
Where the electoral apparatus that runs subnational elections is not indepen-
dent from the national executive branch, individual candidates may be pro-
scribed from running for oce for essentially political reasons rather than
for failing to meet legal requirements. If that doesnt work, where judicial
systems are likewise politically compliant, the national government can
then try to use the judiciary to remove elected mayors and governors from
oce. For example, prosecutors in Bolivia sought to suspend and/or arrest
all four of the governors who led the lowland autonomy movement
described in the next section (succeeding in three cases).
3
The national strat-
egy at play here is to target subnational ocials as individuals rather than the
subnational institutions they control.
Domestic judicial institutions play a critical role in adjudicating the jurisdic-
tional disputes that inevitably arise under multilevel governance (witness the
pivotal role played over time by the U.S. Supreme Court vis-à-vis federalism),
but they can only decisively referee these national-subnational disputes if
they enjoy sucient independence from national executive and legislative
branches. Without a modicum of judicial independence, subnational
elected ocials in Latin America are unlikely to nd recourse in domestic judi-
cial institutions to protect their formal governing prerogatives when they are
REGIONAL & FEDERAL STUDIES 9
embroiled in signicant policy conicts with the centre. Even in federal cases,
where provincial governors may have their own (possibly compliant) judicial
institutions, disputes with the national government over the formal division
of authorities will necessarily be ruled upon by higher-level judicial powers.
Against the backdrop of this forbidding domestic landscape, and embattled
in political and policy disputes that have taken the form of judicial and legal
persecution, subnational elected ocials may try to protect themselves by
pursuing recourse from supranational institutions. While the judicial nature
of the assault suggests the appropriateness of a judicial response, the
national bias in domestic judicial institutions increases the appeal of external
judicial venues.
By far the most prominent example of a subnational-supranationaljudi-
cial strategy in Latin America comes from Colombia and the case of Bogotá
mayor Gustavo Petro (201215). In a country that sat out the region-wide
left turn that took place after 2000, and where the left has indeed never gov-
erned nationally, the election of a former guerrilla leader to Colombias
second most important political oce represented a political earthquake,
especially given the municipal bent of the decentralizing reforms that were
introduced beginning in the 1980s (Falleti 2010; Restrepo 2015). Petros
various attempts to reverse neoliberalism, which he proposed to do by reg-
ulating urban sprawl, promoting the densication of the city, and re-asserting
public authority vis-à-vis transport and housing markets, put him on a col-
lision course with a number of vested economic interests who enjoyed a
great deal of inuence vis-à-vis national institutions (Eaton 2020). Most fate-
fully, Petro sought to un-do the privatization of trash collection and to create
a wholly municipally-owned trash company, arguing that oligopolistic prac-
tices had created one of the most lucrative businesses in the city along
with a notoriously low quality/high cost service. Due both to poor planning
on the part of Petros administration and a campaign of sabotage by the
national government, which embargoed in Colombian ports the dump
trucks Petro attempted to import from the U.S., uncollected trash began to
pile up in the streets of Bogotá.
4
On 9 December 2013, approximately half way into his term as mayor and
in the midst of the trash crisis, Petro was suspended from oce by Inspector
General and conservative jurist Alejandro Ordoñez, who further stipulated
that the mayor would be unable to run for any other oce for a period of
15 years. Ordoñez justied the suspension on the grounds that Petro had
broken laws requiring competition in public service provision, in addition
to using unauthorized trucks to collect trash. That night, as thousands of
Bogotanos mobilized in Petros defense in the citys main plaza, the mayor
denounced the undemocratic nature of the drive to suspend him and
called for the beginning of a democratic and peaceful revolution in Colombia.
In response to the suspension of Petro from oce, one departmental tribunal
10 K. EATON
(Tribunal Administrative de Cundinamarca) issued a ruling that sought to
reinstate the mayor, only to be reversed by the more powerful Council of
State, which upheld the suspension (Gómez 2014).
Anticipating the inability of Colombias domestic judicial institutions to
protect him from what was essentially a policy disagreement, Petro appealed
to the Organisation of American States Inter-American Court of Human
Rights (ICHR) and asked for an injunction (medidas cautelarias) to prevent
his suspension. That Petros request was quickly granted by the ICHR and
that he was ultimately reinstated in his position as mayor could at rst
glance be taken as evidence of the utility of this subnational-supranational
strategy. The story, however, is more complicated, and in ways that raise
doubts about how much this strategy really contributed to the outcome.
First, it is important to note that Colombian President Juan Manuel Santos,
one of the chief opponents of the mayors policy vision for Bogotá, refused
to reinstate Petro after the ICHR ruling, ordered his departure from the mayor-
alty, and appointed a close political ally (Rafael Pardo) to nish out Petros
term (Reyes 2014). Eventually, President Santos agreed to reinstate Petro
only four months later, in April 2014, days after Petro announced that he
would support Santoss reelection bid in order to prevent the victory of
anti-peace candidate Oscar Zuluaga in the second round of the 2014 presi-
dential election. In other words, the price Bogotásrst leftist mayor had to
pay for the privilege of nishing his elected mandate was to support the
countrys right-of-centre president, a deeply political and highly contingent
quid pro quo that likely has more to do with the outcome than the inter-
national court ruling itself. Nevertheless, the ICHR ruling may have played a
role in a subsequent decision by Colombias Council of State in November
2017, which annulled Ordoñezs ruling, restored Petros political rights, and
claried that administrative sanctions should never be sucient to remove
an individuals political rights.
5
The subnational-national strategy: East vs. West in Bolivia
The most important recent example of the subnational-nationalstrategy can
be seen in the 20062008 conict that unfolded between the national gov-
ernment and the governors of the four eastern departments in Bolivias
lowland region (or medialuna), who sought to coordinate with the U.S. gov-
ernment their resistance to the administration of President Evo Morales
(20062019). Powerful gas and agricultural interests in these departments,
which make up nearly two-thirds of the national territory and account for
most of Bolivias export revenue, strongly opposed the rise to national
power of the Movement toward Socialism (MAS), which culminated in the his-
toric 2005 election of the countrysrst ever indigenous president Evo
Morales (Humphreys and Bebbington 2010). As support for neoliberal
REGIONAL & FEDERAL STUDIES 11
economic policies collapsed at the national level, regional elites in the more
export-oriented economies of the lowland departments continued to favour
pro-market approaches, setting the stage for a dramatic ideological show-
down between east and west over development models (Eaton 2017).
Whereas Morales sought to delegitimize departmental authorities, promoting
a new constitution that would deny the possibility of departmental auton-
omy in favour of municipal and indigenous autonomies, his opponents in
the eastern departments sought to protect their newfound authority and
revenue (derived from the rst ever gubernatorial elections in 2005 and a
generous tax sharing scheme for departments that had been introduced
only the year before Moraless victory).
In the attempt to broaden their movement for regional autonomy and
overcome skepticism that they were essentially motivated by the desire to
defend their privileged economic position, eastern elites successfully
deployed a discursive strategy whereby they claimed that lowland (camba)
territorial interests and identities were under attack (Gustafson 2006; Eaton
2007,2011). But these elites also tried to supplement this inherently domestic
strategy with an external strategy that linked them closely to the U.S. govern-
ment in a number of institutional guises, including the U.S. Agency for Inter-
national Development, the National Democratic Institute and the
International Republican Institute (formally non-governmental partisan enti-
ties that mostly nance party-building and democracy promotion eorts in
the global south), and ultimately the U.S. embassy itself. In step with Bolivias
ideological polarization, this collaboration between the U.S. and Bolivias
eastern region became more pronounced after the October 2003 toppling
of President Gonzalo Sánchez de Losada, the architect of Boliviasinclusive
neoliberalismwho was invited to set up his government in one of these
departments (Santa Cruz) when he fell from power in La Paz. In 2004, the
U.S. government shifted its programming away from support for municipal
governments, which had been the focus of Sánchez de Losadas decentraliz-
ing reforms in the 1990s (Faguet 2013), toward support for (especially
lowland) departmental governments. Specically, USAIDsOce of Transition
Initiatives spent $13 million on 100 grants to department governments and
moderate civil society groups (Burron 2012), focusing on building the
capacity of the prefect-led department governmentswhich were led by
directly-elected governors after 2005 (Wol2011).
This subnational-nationalstrategy came to a head in the chaotic fall of
2008, when Bolivia approached the brink of a civil war between highland sup-
porters of the MAS-led national government and lowland supporters of the
movement for regional autonomy (or secession, in the hopes of some of
these supporters). In the context of work stoppages, hunger strikes, and wide-
spread protests against cuts in revenue transfers for the east, Santa Cruz Gov-
ernor Rubén Costas solicited a series of meetings with U.S. Ambassador Philip
12 K. EATON
Goldberg (Fabricant 2011). Immediately after the last of these meetings,
Costas ordered an ocial take overof national institutions in Santa Cruz
(including the state-owned television station and tax collecting agency),
the timing of which led many to suspect that the ambassador had signalled
his approval of such an action.
6
President Morales then accused Goldberg of
inciting division and separatism in support of what he termed a golpe cívico-
prefectual (i.e. a civic coup by the departmental prefects) and expelled him
from the country on 9 September 2008. The U.S. responded by expelling Boli-
vian Ambassador Gustavo Guzmán and by decertifying Bolivias drug control
eorts, which terminated preferential access for Bolivian exports to the U.S.
market through the Andean Trade Promotion and Drug Certication Act.
Bolivia and the U.S. would only re-establish top-level diplomatic ties after
the end of the MAS government in 2019.
The Bolivian conict thus illustrates some of the key features of the sub-
national-nationalstrategy, including the role of ideological shifts as an ante-
cedent condition that simultaneously led to the rupture between the two
national governments (i.e. Bolivia and the U.S.) and the closer anity
between subnational governments and the foreign power (i.e. the medialuna
departments and the U.S.). The case also speaks to the high stakes of this
strategy, which led to a prolonged fracture in diplomatic ties and produced
real economic costs for the Bolivian economy, including the four lowland
departments, where many U.S.-bound Bolivian exports originate. Finally,
the Bolivian conict clearly reveals the two can play that gamedynamic.
As eastern governors sought to coordinate their eorts with the U.S. ambas-
sador in the most dire phase of the conict, President Morales then solicited
the intervention of Union of South American Nations (UNASUR), a brand-new
association of Latin American states with a decidedly progressive orientation
created at the high mark of the regions left turn. UNASUR forcefully indicated
its support for the national government and embraced Moraless attempt to
treat the departmental protests as a threat to Bolivias institutional order and
territorial integrity.
The subnational-subnational strategy: Neoliberal networks in
Ecuador
As a salient example of the subnational-subnationalstrategy, this section
focuses on eorts by pro-market actors in the Ecuadorian city of Guayaquil
to strengthen their defense of subnational autonomy by building networks
with ideologically like-minded groups in the subnational jurisdictions of
other Latin American countries. Resented by other Ecuadorian municipalities
for its signicant scal and structural advantages, Guayaquil sought to
connect with subnational units in other countries that were similarly trying
to defend economic models that clashed with the centralizing ambitions of
REGIONAL & FEDERAL STUDIES 13
their own national governments. Unlike the two strategies discussed above,
this external strategy took a specic organizational form in the 2006 creation
in Guayaquil of the International Confederation for Liberty and Regional
Autonomy (Confederación Internacional por la Libertad y la Autonomía
Regional or CONFILAR). Although this case reveals the low risk/low payo
nature of this third external strategy, it also suggests that external horizontal
alliances between similarly embattled subnational governments can provide
much-needed solidarity and moral support, as well as a broader platform
both for ideational exchanges and for the diusion of more practical infor-
mation about strategies and tactics.
Guayaquil is the capital of a coastal region (Guayas) long considered the
most economically powerful in Ecuador, thanks to the agro-exports that
have owed through its port since colonial times and that fuelled the rise
of commercial banks with deep and extensive inuence over the national
government based in Quito (Burbano de Lara 2009). In the last two
decades, the success of Guayaquils consistently pro-market and liberal orien-
tation provided a sharp contrast both with the instability and turmoil that
plagued the national government in the decade between 1997 and 2007,
and with the anti-neoliberal and state-centered orientation of Rafael
Correas subsequent decade as president between 2007 and 2017. In these
two decades, Guayaquil took advantage of Ecuadors distinctive approach
to decentralization, which encouraged subnational governments to apply
for the transfer of authorities from below rather than to unilaterally and sym-
metrically implement transfers in a more top-down fashion (Van Cott 2008;
Faust and Harbers 2012). To defend the Guayaquil modelrst from chaos
(19972007) and then from socialism(200717), Mayor Jaime Nebot
(20002019) emphasized the importance of autonomy by fully utilizing the
citys formal authority and by acting informally to promote what he called
autonomia al andar, which could be roughly translated as autonomy as
you go(Silva 2016). The mayor and the local businesses that formed his
core constituency also looked abroad, nancing high-prole visits to Guaya-
quil in 2005 on the part of two prominent (and foreign) subnational leaders:
Jordi Pujol, the Catalan leader who championed autonomy during his long
presidency of Catalonia, and Rubén Costas, a leading advocate of autonomy
for Santa Cruz in Bolivia who would become its rst ever elected governor.
7
Building on these overtures, CONFILAR formalized an emerging network
between likeminded neoliberals who came to associate the defense of
liberal approaches with the defense of regional autonomy in countries
whose national governments had come under the control of twenty-rst
century socialists. Not entirely unlike the Four Motorsdynamic in Europe,
CONFILAR brought together local government ocials and private sector
leaders from three of the richest and most successful regions in Bolivia
(Santa Cruz), Ecuador (Guayaquil), and Venezuela (Zulia), characterized both
14 K. EATON
by the productivity of their export activities and by their natural resource
wealth (e.g. hydrocarbons). Including advocates of free enterprise from Gua-
temala and Peru as well, CONFILAR hoped that its workshops, courses, and
media outreach could trumpet regional successes with pro-market strategies
and focus criticism on the centralizing tendencies of the statist projects that
threatened to eliminate neoliberalism not just at the national level but at the
subnational level as well. CONFILAR held its second major conference in
Santa Cruz in 2007, and was greatly energized by the momentum of the
movement for autonomy in lowland Bolivia, which would culminate in the
2008 wildcat referenda on departmental autonomy promoted by Carlos
Dabdoub as president of the Pro-Santa Cruz Committee (who also served
as CONFILARsrst president).
8
Over a decade later, however, one is struck by how quickly the enthusiasm
generated by CONFILAR evaporated, by how little organizational residue it
seemed to leave, and, more generally, by the limitations of this horizontal
strategy. First, the non-hierarchical horizontality of this low riskstrategy
did not protect the network from denunciations by each countrys respective
president (Rafael Correa, Evo Morales and Hugo Chávez), who labelled the
aliated groups as separatists and who incorrectly claimed they were being
funded by foreign powers (i.e. the U.S.). This represents a particular twist on
the two can play that gamedynamic; in response to horizontal networking
among subnational governments, presidential opponents sought to externa-
lize the conict further in the attempt to discredit the emerging network.
9
Second, when comparing the three regions that formed the core of CONFILAR
(Guayaquil, Santa Cruz, and Zulia), what emerges is that the only one that was
able to defend the more liberal approach they all wanted to preserve for their
regions was Santa Cruz. This outcome had much to do with the domestic alli-
ance that Santa Cruz was able to form with other like-minded regions within
Bolivia in the east, which its counterparts in Guayaquil and Zulia were unable
to achieve (Eaton 2017). Third, the subnational-subnationalstrategy is
subject to electoral shifts and the possible subnational victories of parties
whose alignment with the national government means that they will be far
less interested in defending subnational prerogatives vis-à-vis the centre.
For example, the state of Zulia was won by a pro-Chávez candidate in Vene-
zuelas regional elections in 2012, putting an end to a 12-year period of
control by governors (e.g. Manuel Rosales and Pablo Pérez Alvarez) who
were opposed to Chávez and who had sought to defend regional autonomy
in coordination with their peers in Guayaquil and Santa Cruz.
Conclusion
The shift to multilevel governance is taking place across the globe and yet its
eects may play out very dierently depending on cross-national and cross-
REGIONAL & FEDERAL STUDIES 15
regional dierences in the underlying strength of institutions, and in the
degree to which formal institutions actually constrain political action. In
Latin America, which is generally characterized by a far weaker institutional
landscape than Europe, the design of new institutional rules that we call mul-
tilevel governancehas generated almost constant conict over the content
of these rules and quite high levels of institutional volatility as reected
in the recentralising eorts that began not long after the ink was dry on
decentralizing legislation itself. Institutional design in the context of weak
institutions is a recipe for the kinds of raw political conicts between national
and subnational governments that are described in this article. In less institu-
tionalized settings, one could conclude that conict between the political
actors who are either constituted or transformed by the shift to multilevel
governance is one of the most import eects of this shift in sharp contrast
to the mostly cooperative behaviours that have been emphasized in applying
the multilevel governance framework to the European Union.
As conicts over the division of authority between national and subnational
governments continue to rage in Latin America, they have become increasingly
internationalized and thus more dicult to understand as purely domestic
struggles. In this article I have privileged the bottom upeorts of subnational
governments to secure the help of actors outside their respective states, which
they have sought to do by pursuing external strategies at three dierent scales.
What the dierences between these strategies suggest is that subnational
ocials from across the ideological spectrum are looking to a variety of external
actors for help in their conicts with the centre, and for a variety of reasons.
Facing a hostile national landscape in a country where the left has never won
oce, Bogotá mayor Gustavo Petro activated a subnational-supranational
strategy in the attempt to prevent his suspension from oce over policy dis-
agreements with the national government. While the suspension likely failed
for other reasons, the order to reinstate the mayor from the Inter-American
Court of Human Rights brought international attention to his plight and may
have encouraged an important domestic ruling in his favour down the line. In
Bolivia, it was the U.S. government and its obvious unease over the rise to
power of President Evo Morales that encouraged opposition governors on
the right of the spectrum to adopt a subnational-nationalstrategy, leading ulti-
mately to the expulsion of the U.S. ambassador at a moment when the country
was poised on the verge of civil war. In Ecuador, the domestic isolation of the
countrys most powerful city led its popular but nationally-embattled mayor
to build organizational ties with similarly isolated subnational units and pro-
market local authorities in other countries, a subnational-subnationalstrategy
that unfolded along horizontal rather than vertical lines.
While the externalization of domestic conicts over territorial governance
is undeniable, its impacts on actual outcomes should not be overstated and
deserve further consideration in future research. External actors of the sort
16 K. EATON
discussed in this paper can bring not just scal and organizational resources
but also visibility, leverage, and even legitimacy to subnational governments
in their struggles with the centre, but they can also be mobilized by the
centre itself as national ocials learn to play the same game. Given the sig-
nicant advantages they typically enjoy relative to both local and provincial
governments, national governments may ideally prefer to keep external
actors out of their conicts with these governments, particularly at the
outset. As Gibson (2013) has reminded us, it is the weaker actor who wants
to externalize its conict with a stronger actor. But once the border is brea-
ched by the increasingly bold and aggressive external strategies of subna-
tional governments, then national governments may well follow suit by
lining up their own external allies. The help provided by external allies may
appear to be especially critical for subnational governments because of the
structural disadvantages they usually face in these domestic conicts, but
the increasing heterogeneity of the international environment (populated
by a proliferating number of multilateral and transnational actors) means
that both sides in these conicts are likely able to nd sympathetic external
allies. In Bolivia, for example, when conservative governors in the eastern low-
lands sought the support of the U.S. in their eorts to defend departmental
prerogatives from a centralizing and leftist national project, the national gov-
ernment was able to respond by leveraging the intervention of a supportive
(and left-leaning) new international body (UNASUR). In Ecuador, pro-market
voices in Guayaquil built networks with likeminded subnational actors in
Bolivia and Venezuela in the attempt to defend regional autonomy, eorts
which presidents in all three countries then sought to delegitimize as
directed and funded by the U.S. government.
While the three cases examined in this article cast some doubt on the
eectiveness of the range of external strategies available to subnational gov-
ernments, and on the decisiveness of the support that external actors can
oer, much more research is needed to know whether these strategies
might be more successful elsewhere in the global south even elsewhere
in Latin America. The empirical examples and country cases drawn upon in
this article are exclusively unitary and exclusively Andean. External strategies
may face rosier prospects in federal cases. The weakness of constitutional pro-
tections for subnational governments that is characteristic of unitary cases
may simultaneously increase the appeal of external strategies for those gov-
ernments, while making it easier for the national government to repress those
same strategies. Perhaps more importantly, a number of political realities in
the Andes, including post-conict dynamics, the erosion of liberal democratic
norms, and generally feckless legislatures have all greatly empowered presi-
dents in their conicts with subnational governments, enabling them to
ignore formal institutional constraints and out the rule of law. More institu-
tionalized settings may well oer subnational governments greater
REGIONAL & FEDERAL STUDIES 17
safeguards if and when they decide to go internationalin their conicts with
national governments.
Notes
1. The conicts examined in this paper occupy the conceptual space between
protodiplomacy, which scholars use to refer to diplomatic eorts by subna-
tional governments that are seeking independence, and paradiplomacy
which scholars use to refer to diplomatic eorts by subnational governments
that do not necessarily challenge their respective national governments but
instead work parallelto traditional diplomacy (Tavares 2016).
2. I am grateful to Simon Toubeau for this insight.
3. As another example, many of the regional presidents in Peru who oppose large-
scale mining projects have been arrested on corruption charges. See Los pre-
sidentes regionales que ahora están presos,El comercio, June 13, 2016. Vene-
zuela is the country that has most aggressively sought to preemptively bar
opposition candidates from running for subnational oce. For example, in
2008 the National Electoral Court banned 272 candidates from running for sub-
national oces, including Leopoldo López the popular mayor of Chacao who
was prohibited from running for Metropolitan Mayor of Caracas.
4. Interview with Susana Muhamad, Petros Secretary of the Environment, Septem-
ber 14, 2017, Bogotá.
5. Consejo de Estado tumba fallo que sacó a Gustavo Petro de la Alcaldía de
Bogotá,El Espectador, November 15, 2017.
6. Interviews with Andrés Gallardo, President of the Municipal Council of Santa
Cruz, February 27, 2104, Santa Cruz; and Eliane Capobianco, Director of Auton-
omous Development in the Department of Santa Cruz, February 24, 2014, Santa
Cruz.
7. Interview with Juan José Illingworth, former National Deputy, June 10, 2008,
Guayaquil.
8. Interview with Benjamin Rosales, former Governor of Guayas, January 14, 2014,
Guayaquil.
9. In response, the Guayaquil-based business group that nanced CONFILARsrst
conference (Corporación Guayas) published an op-ed piece refuting these
charges. See Los separatistasde Guayaquil,El Diario, May 15, 2008.
Acknowledgements
For constructive comments on an earlier version of this article, I would like to thank
Nicholas Charron, Jean-Paul Faguet, Amuitz Garmendia Madariaga, Agustina
Giraudy, Imke Harbers, Liesbet Hooghe, Charlie Jeery, Hanna Kleider, Sandra Leon,
Gary Marks, Emanuele Massetti, Sara Niedzwiecki, Simona Piattoni, Lorenzo Piccolo,
Arjan Schakel, Sarah Shair-Roseneld, Prerna Singh, Michael Tätham, Simon
Toubeau and Christina Zuber.
Disclosure statement
No potential conict of interest was reported by the author(s).
18 K. EATON
References
Aldecoa, F., and M. Keating, eds. 1999.Paradiplomacy in Action: The Foreign Relations of
Subnational Governments. London: Frank Cass.
Burbano de Lara, F. 2009.Las luchas autonómicas de Guayaquil y Santa Cruz.In Los
condicionantes de la crisis en América Latina, edited by E. Arceo and E. Basualdo,
275320. Buenos Aires: CLACSO.
Burron, N. 2012.Unpacking U.S. Democracy Promotion in Bolivia: From Soft Tactics to
Regime Change.Latin American Perspectives 39 (1): 115132.
Carothers, T., and S. Brechenmacher. 2014.Closing Space: Democracy and Human
Rights Support Under Fire. Washington, DC: Carnegie Endowment for Peace.
Colacrai, M. 2010.El tejido de relaciones bilaterales desde el ámbito subnacional.In
La Política Internacional Subnacional en América Latina, edited by L. Maira, 305328.
Buenos Aires: Libros del Zorzal.
Dickovick, T. 2014.Foreign Aid and Decentralisation: Limitations on Impact in Autonomy
and Responsiveness.Public Administration and Development 34 (3): 194206.
Dickovick, T., and K. Eaton. 2013.Latin Americas Resurgent Center: National
Government Strategies after Decentralisation.Journal of Development Studies 49
(11): 14531466.
Dickovick, T., and J. Wunsch, eds. 2014.Decentralization in Africa: The Paradox of State
Strength. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.
Doner, R., and E. Hershberg. 1999.Flexible Production and Political Decentralization:
Elective Anities in the Pursuit of Competitiveness.Studies in Comparative
International Development 34 (1): 4582.
Eaton, K. 2007.Backlash in Bolivia: Regional Autonomy as a Reaction against
Indigenous Mobilization.Politics and Society 35 (1): 71102.
Eaton, K. 2011.Conservative Autonomy Movements: Territorial Dimensions of
Ideological Conict in Bolivia and Ecuador.Comparative Politics 43 (3): 291310.
Eaton, K. 2017.Territory and Ideology in Latin America: Policy Conicts Between National
and Subnational Governments. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Eaton, K. 2020.Bogotás Left Turn: Counter-Neoliberalization in Colombia.
International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 44 (1): 117.
Fabricant, N. 2011.A Realigned Bolivian Right: New Democratic Destabilizations.
NACLA Report on the Americas 44 (1): 3031.
Faguet, J. P. 2013.Decentralization and Popular Democracy: Governance from Below in
Bolivia. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Faguet, J. P., and C. Poschl. 2015.Is Decentralization Good for Development?
Perspectives from Academics and Policy Makers. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Falleti, T. 2010.Decentralization and Subnational Politics in Latin America. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
Faust, J., and I. Harbers. 2012.On the Local Politics of Administrative Decentralization:
Applying for Policy Responsibilities in Ecuador.Publius 42 (1): 5277.
Gibson, E. 2013.Boundary Control: Subnational Authoritarianism in Federal
Democracies. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Goldfrank, B., and A. Shrank. 2009.Municipal Neoliberalism and Municipal Socialism:
Urban Political Economy in Latin America.International Journal of Urban and
Regional Research 33 (2): 443462.
Gómez, S. 2014.Los dos caminos del Presidente frente a medidas cautelares al
Alcalde.El Tiempo. March 18. https://www.eltiempo.com/archivo/documento/
CMS-13682915.
REGIONAL & FEDERAL STUDIES 19
Gustafson, B. 2006.Spectacles of Autonomy and Crisis.Journal of Latin American
Anthropology 11 (2): 351379.
Hooghe, L., ed. 1996.Cohesion Policy and European Integration: Building Multi-Level
Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hooghe, L., and G. Marks. 1996.Europe with the Regions? Regional Representation in
the European Union.Publius 26 (1): 7391.
Hooghe, L., and G. Marks. 2001.Multi-Level Governance and European Integration.
New York: Rowman & Littleeld.
Hooghe, L., and G. Marks. 2016.Community, Scale, and Regional Governance: A
Postfunctionalist Theory of Governance, Volume 2. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hooghe, L., G. Marks, A. Schakel, S. Chapman Osterkatz, S. Niedzwiecki, and S. Shair-
Roseneld. 2016.Measuring Regional Authority: A Postfunctionalist Theory of
Governance, Volume 1. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Humphreys, D., and A. Bebbington. 2010.Anatomy of a Regional Conict: Tarija and
Resource Grievances in Moraless Bolivia.Latin American Perspectives 37 (4): 140
160.
Keck, M., and K. Sikkink. 1998.Activists beyond Borders: Advocacy Networks in
International Politics. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Malesky, E. 2008.Straight Ahead on Red: How Foreign Direct Investment Empowers
Subnational Leaders.Journal of Politics 70 (1): 97119.
ONeill, K. 2005.Decentralizing the State: Elections, Parties, and Local Power in the Andes.
New York: Cambridge University Press.
Oxhorn, P., J. Tulchin, and A. Selee, eds. 2004.Decentralization, Democratic Governance
and Civil Society in Comparative Perspective: Africa, Asia and Latin America. Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins University Press.
Piattoni, S. 2010.The Theory of Multi-Level Governance: Conceptual, Empirical, and
Normative Challenges. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Restrepo, D. 2015.Procesos de descentralización en Bolivia y Colombia. Bogotá:
Universidad Nacional de Colombia.
Reyes, E. 2014.Santos se ve obligado a reintegrar a Pedro a la alcaldía de Bogotá.El
país, April 23. https://elpais.com/internacional/2014/04/23/actualidad/
1398276193_198520.html.
Schiavón, J. 2006.La proyección internacional de las entidades federativas: México ante
el mundo. México: Instituto Matías Romero.
Silva, V. 2016.Constructing a State in the Face of Regional Power: The Case of
Guayaquil.Latin American Perspectives 43 (1): 93108.
Silva, V., and C. Morán. 2010.Relaciones subnaciones: El caso de Chile y Argentina.In
La Política Internacional Subnacional en América Latina, edited by L. Maira, 259304.
Buenos Aires: Libros del Zorzal.
Smoke, P., E. D. Gomez, and G. Peterson, eds. 2007.Decentralization in Asia and Latin
America: A Comparative Interdisciplinary Perspective. New York: Edward Elgar.
Soldatos, P. 1990.An Explanatory Framework for the Study of Federated States as
Foreign Policy Actors.In Federalism and International Relations: The Role of
Subnational Units, edited by H. Michelmann and P. Soldatos, 3453. Oxford:
Clarendon Press.
Sorens, J. 2004.Globalization, Autonomy, and the Politics of Secession.Electoral
Studies 23 (4): 727752.
Tatham, M. 2016.With, Without, Or Against the State: How European Regions Play the
Brussels Game. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
20 K. EATON
Tavares, R. 2016.Paradiplomacy: Cities and States as Global Players. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Van Cott, D. 2008.Radical Democracy in the Andes. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Warner, M., and J. Gerbasi. 2004.Rescaling and Reforming the State under NAFTA:
Implications for Subnational Authority.International Journal of Urban and
Regional Research 28 (4): 853873.
Wol,J.2011.Towards Post-Liberal Democracy in Latin America?: A Conceptual
Framework Applied to Bolivia.Journal of Latin American Studies 45 (1): 3149.
REGIONAL & FEDERAL STUDIES 21
... The first example is the Regional Authority Index (RAI), an instrument to measure levels of decentralization, which reveals the contributions of expanding the MLG tradition to the Global South. The second example is the work by Eaton (2021), which reveals the advantages of incorporating supranational actors and institutions into the study of SNR processes. These works move beyond the almost exclusive focus on the Global North in MLG and the lack of inclusion of subnational-supranational relations in SNR. ...
... We argue that these blind spots, which for the most part comprise independent variables and scope conditions that have been largely studied by one tradition but not by the other, constitute a springboard for scholars of territorial politics to build on each other's work, and in turn, expand knowledge cumulation. The following section zooms in two examples that illustrate the path towards moving beyond the original research program to achieve knowledge accumulation: the RAI and Eaton (2021). The last section proposes to merge SNR and MLG into a single research program on territorial politics. ...
... By contrast, SNR, as its name denotes, is largely focused on processes that unfold below the national state. Consequently, and with notably few exceptions (Bates 1997;Eaton 2021), 8 the effects of supranational institutions on subnational institutions/ actors and vice versa have been surprisingly absent in this tradition. As a result, an involuntary division of labour has emerged between MLG research, where supranational actors and institutions figure prominently in theories and analyses, versus SNR studies where international actors and institutions are almost absent. ...
Article
The Subnational Research (SNR) and Multilevel Governance (MLG) research programs have tackled some of the crucial questions in comparative politics. Despite their shared principle that actors and institutions located at one territorial level are shaped by and shape other levels of government, each tradition has developed its own set of concepts and theories without fully acknowledging the other. We believe that this has been detrimental for knowledge accumulation. We argue that more knowledge accumulation in the study of territorial politics is possible if (1) scholars engage with each tradition, and (2) they are attentive to differences, or blind spots, in each traditions’ theories, concepts, and scope conditions. Drawing on two examples, the Regional Authority Index (RAI) and Kent Eaton’s work (2021) we show the benefits of transcending the boundaries of each tradition. We conclude by proposing a unified framework for the study of territorial politics that incorporates both SNR and MLG.
... The first example is the Regional Authority Index (RAI), an instrument to measure levels of decentralization, which reveals the contributions of expanding the MLG tradition to the Global South. The second example is the work by Eaton (2021), which reveals the advantages of incorporating supranational actors and institutions into the study of SNR processes. These works move beyond the almost exclusive focus on the Global North in MLG and the lack of inclusion of subnational-supranational relations in SNR. ...
... We argue that these blind spots, which for the most part comprise independent variables and scope conditions that have been largely studied by one tradition but not by the other, constitute a springboard for scholars of territorial politics to build on each other's work, and in turn, expand knowledge cumulation. The following section zooms in two examples that illustrate the path towards moving beyond the original research program to achieve knowledge accumulation: the RAI and Eaton (2021). The last section proposes to merge SNR and MLG into a single research program on territorial politics. ...
... By contrast, SNR, as its name denotes, is largely focused on processes that unfold below the national state. Consequently, and with notably few exceptions (Bates 1997;Eaton 2021), 8 the effects of supranational institutions on subnational institutions/ actors and vice versa have been surprisingly absent in this tradition. As a result, an involuntary division of labour has emerged between MLG research, where supranational actors and institutions figure prominently in theories and analyses, versus SNR studies where international actors and institutions are almost absent. ...
... The following section shifts from the empirical to the conceptual by exploring the promise and limitations of MLG as a framework outside of Europe, an issue that is illuminated in different ways by several articles in this special issue (Eaton 2022;Giraudy and Niedzwiecki 2022, Piccoli 2022, and Shair-Rosenfield 2022. We argue that MLG's promise in the global south is considerable because it helps us to understand how actors from multiple territorial levels interact in a non-formal and non-hierarchical manner, and because it explicitly emphasizes the key roles played by supranational actors and forces. ...
... Too often, rather than accept the need to negotiate with the substate regions that were empowered by decentralization, national governments sought instead to simply take away their newfound authority. Recentralization as a form of institutional instability is important in the articles by both Eaton (2022) and Shair-Rosenfield (2022). For the former, it has encouraged subnational officials to 'go global' in the attempt to defend their prerogatives, and for the latter it helps explain why commitments to self-rule on the part of national governments are often seen as non-credible unless they are accompanied by forms of shared rule as well. ...
Article
Full-text available
This article introduces the special issue on the rise of substate regional governments within and beyond Europe. Drawing on the Regioznal Authority Index (RAI) and the Measure of International Authority (MIA), we trace the increase in authority ‘above and below’ the state and argue that it is important to study the differential impacts – as well as the interconnectedness – of the main sub-dimensions of regional (i.e. self-rule and shared rule) and international authority (i.e. delegation and pooling). Turning from the empirical to the conceptual, we also critically examine Multilevel Governance (MLG) as a framework that can be applied to the global south. While MLG helps to illuminate the often non-formal and non-hierarchical nature of territorial politics and the key role of supranational actors in the global south, other factors may limit its applicability including capacity deficits, institutional instability, and conflictual dynamics between levels of government.
... As highlighted in the previous section, to the best of my knowledge, there is no existing theory on multilevel regime decoupling, and building a complete theoretical account of a global phenomenon exceeds the scope of a single paper, likely requiring a joint disciplinary effort. Nonetheless, my approach to the topic is primed by regime change studies (Ansell and Samuels 2014;Boix 2003;Miller 2021;Przeworski 1991), discussions on democratic institutional design (Lijphart 1999;Linz 1990;Power and Gasiorowski 1997;Tsebelis et al. 2023), the scholarship on federalism (Erk and Swenden 2010; Gibson 2004; Montero and Samuels 2004;Ziblatt 2006), and research on multilevel governance (Benz, Broschek, and Lederer 2021;Eaton 2022;Giraudy and Niedzwiecki 2021;Pazos-Vidal 2019). To use a Bayesian heuristic: coming into the analysis, my priors had been shaped by the cumulative knowledge of these academic agendas. ...
Article
Full-text available
Regimes do not change consistently across territorial levels. There has been progress in understanding national democratic erosions and subnational regimes, but barring a few exceptions, these research strands have not engaged in a thorough dialogue. To bridge this gap, I contend that when democracy advances in one territorial level, but erodes in another, we observe multilevel regime decoupling (MRD). Using global data from the Varieties of Democracy project, I examine the 1990–2022 period, showing that the proportion of decoupled cases increased from 20% in the 1990s, to 43% in the first decade of the twenty-first century. Preliminary regression analyses and a descriptive exploration of Italy, South Africa, India, and the United States indicate the non-deterministic influence of structural factors and the potentially pivotal role of courts in facilitating decoupled change. Considering these findings, renewed data collection efforts and an actor-centred approach are needed to strengthen our understanding of the varieties of (de)coupled regime change that have become common over the last decade. Given that regimes across territorial levels increasingly move in separate directions, future assessments of autocratization and democratic change need to embed territorial considerations in their analysis to remain informative about citizens’ real-world experiences on the ground.
... Subnational levels gained presence in the policy sphere over the last decades, when countries in the Global South and North transferred and/or started sharing responsibility with the intermediate and local levels in many policy fields (Di Virgilio 2021;Brenner 2004;Eaton 2021), including education and early childhood. This process entailed a devolution of the political authority towards subnational political units (Giraudy and Niedzwiecki 2021); that is, the actors, institutions, and processes that operate within countries (Snyder 2001). ...
Article
Full-text available
With early childhood inhabiting a firm position on policy agendas, an emerging global consensus acknowledges the need for research into early childhood education and care (ECEC) systems. However, standardised approaches to comparison dominate the field. These studies tend to be grounded in methodological nationalism, assuming nation states as the natural and necessary unit to study social phenomena. I argue the national unit is not sufficient to understand ECEC systems and that we need to consider subnational levels (district and local). Subnational approaches enable the reconstruction of the different actors and institutions at play in all levels of ECEC systems. This movement beyond methodological nationalism requires a shift towards integrated approaches and territorialised policy analysis. I illustrate my argument drawing on qualitative data from two subnational studies in Argentina. I discuss the conceptual and methodological implications for international comparison and comparative research in the early childhood field.
... Much of the more innovative research analyzing regions and cities embeds them in multilevel, multi-actor analyses (Eaton 2021;Heikkinen et al. 2020;Toubeau and Vampa 2021). A good illustration of this is the work by Resnick (2021). ...
Article
Full-text available
Tras acceder al gobierno nacional después de treinta años, el Partido Nacional afrontó por primera vez una elección departamental separada en el tiempo. Nuestro interrogante es primordialmente descriptivo: analizar integralmente los resultados y a su vez compararlos con los períodos anteriores. Este proceso también nos permite comenzar a aproximarnos a la cuestión sobre la existencia de un potencial efecto de arrastre de la elección presidencial por sobre la departamental. En este artículo esta cuestión es abordada mediante una descripción integral de los resultados departamentales 2020, por medio de algunos de los índices e indicadores más utilizados en la disciplina. Al tiempo, se destacan los principales hitos del ciclo.
Article
Full-text available
In developing an extensive network of trade agreements, the European Union has pushed for liberalization commitments that impinge on the competencies of subnational jurisdictions. This raises new challenges in federal systems as the emerging multilevel character of trade politics means subnational authorities could increasingly demand a say in the negotiation or ratification of these trade agreements. To address the tension between subnational regulatory autonomy and collective problem-solving in trade negotiations, Europe needs to avoid suboptimal trade outcomes where actions of contestation by subnational jurisdictions on the grounds of regulatory encroachment can undermine or veto collective agreement. Using the cases of Belgium and Germany, this article illustrates how the growing subnational contestation around trade agreements requires greater coordination and consensus to avoid domestic gridlock in their ratification. The article suggests normative ideas for the EU to address the overlapping authority challenges across multilevel governance. As the values of trade have changed, these normative measures should include the framing of trade narratives, addressing asymmetries of influence, enhancing subnational engagement, and mitigating the distributive costs of liberalization. These avenues for trade policymaking are to be ultimately advantageous for the EU's pursuit of greater integration.
Article
For decades now, scholars have questioned the influence that international trade has had on labour regimes across the globe. This article seeks to contribute to this body of literature by assessing the relationship between trade openness and labour flexibility across countries while controlling for institutional complementarities and industrial relations values included in the varieties of capitalism (VoC) literature. In parallel, the article’s empirical core assesses the relationship between labour flexibility and trade openness within OECD and Latin American countries. As the empirical sections will highlight, the paper’s examination of the cited bivariate relationship points to a policy convergence toward labour flexibility among OECD countries that were originally considered by the VoC framework. Conversely, in Latin America, the cited relationship exhibits diverging trajectories in policy outcomes, suggesting an influential impact of the ‘pink tide’ that swept across the region at the turn of the century.
Article
Full-text available
For the political left, decentralization has increased both the appeal and the importance of governing the city, and yet sharp constraints limit the left's transformative potential when it controls that level of government alone. Bogotá is an important case in point under the recent mayoral administration of Gustavo Petro (2012–15), a demobilized guerrilla leader who sought to implement a series of urban policy reforms that together represent one of the most substantively radical and intellectually coherent attempts to challenge neoliberalism in all of Latin America. Focusing on the four policy arenas through which Petro hoped to transform the city (environment, housing, transport, and trash collection), the article documents the veto power of the firms whose privileges he threatened, as well as the tools through which they derailed reform. In contrast to the failure of his political economy agenda, Petro was indeed able to enact a number of progressive social policy reforms precisely because they did not threaten the profitability of the city's entrenched growth machine.
Chapter
Federalism and International Relations is the first comparative study of an increasingly important phenomenon: the international role and activities of component units of major liberal democratic federal States. The first part of the book identifies common concepts and themes and explores the reasons for the proliferation of paradiplomatic activities by these non-traditional actors on the international scene. The subsequent chapters focus on the international role of subnational units in individual countries: Austria, Australia, Canada, the Federal Republic of Germany, Switzerland, and the USA; the authors also consider the case of Belgium, not formally a federation, but operating to all intents and purposes like one. They examine in detail the nature and history of foreign-policy federalism of these units and the scope and variety of their international activities. They also explore such topics as the constitutional and institutional contexts in which paradiplomatic activity by component units takes place and the factors which motivate these international activities in each federal State. Finally they assess the implications of the paradiplomatic activities for the conduct of foreign policy in each federation.
Book
This book, first published in 2005, explores the location and dynamics of power within the state, focusing on a recent wave of decentralizing reforms that have swept across both developed and developing countries in recent years. Variation in the timing of reform across countries only vaguely relates to the genesis of an international consensus pushed by big lenders and development banks or the reemergence of democracy in decentralizing countries. The book develops a theory linking decentralization's adoption to the electoral concerns of political parties: decentralization represents a desirable strategy for parties whose support at subnational levels appears more secure than their prospects in national elections. It examines this argument against experiences in Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru and Venezuela and speculates on how recent political changes may affect decentralization's shape and extent in coming years.