ChapterPDF Available

Dependency theory

Authors:
1
Forthcoming in L.-P. Rochon and S. Rossi (eds), Encyclopedia of Post-Keynesian
Economics. Edward Elgar
Dependency theory
David M. Fields
According to Rostow (1960), all societies can be placed on a linear continuum, that is, a
stages of economic growth path, from undeveloped to developed. The assumption is that
capitalism is a historically progressive system, which is transmitted from the privileged
economically advanced countries to the rest of the world by a continual process of
destruction and replacement of primitive social structures (Palma, 1978). This
modernization theory is a ‘blame the victim approach to problems affecting the ‘Third
World. It ignores external influences, like colonialism (and neo-colonialism).
Dependency theory, on the other hand, highlights the extent to which global dialectical
forces of motion and contradiction generate vast disparities of wealth and power. The world
economy is reproduced as a world-system (Wallerstein, 1979) of unequal exchange
(Emmanuel, 1972; Amin, 1974, 1976). If economic growth is not reached, it is not because
within the Third World there exists obstacles as a result of innate poverty arising from
some form of ‘backwardness but owing to the net outflow of vital resources.
2
Baran and Sweezy (1960), in Monopoly Capital, assess the degree to which monopoly, as
measured by the market concentration ratio of large capitalist firms (corporations), in
economically advanced countries, ensues a fundamental division between advanced
countries and impoverished ones. The result is that weaker countries suffer the retardation
of the requisite forces to spawn autonomous and dynamic processes of self-governance of
the conditions that engender independent social/political/economic coordination, planning
and control. This constitutes a “hierarchical [world] system with one or more leading
metropolises, completely dependent colonies [even if not name, certainly in practice] at the
bottom, and many degrees of superordinate and subordination in between (Baran and
Sweezy, 1966, pp. 1789).
Nevertheless, economic growth in the Third World, while controlling for socioeconomic
income differentials, is viable (Cardoso and Faletto, 1970) if there is an “embedded
autonomy” (Evans, 1995) to engage in Keynesian aggregate demand management. This is
measured by the extent to which a country does not suffer the inability to borrow in its own
currency.
The essence of ‘monetary sovereignty’ is the cartalist (or chartalist) (Goodhart, 1998)
conception that emphasizes State power to fully establish a national currency. From this
perspective, underdevelopment’, or ‘dependency, is the powerlessness of a country in
setting its own unit of account, which forces it to peg its currency to a reference currency of
an economically advanced country. This results in a dearth of flexibility to use monetary
policy and fiscal policy for domestic economic needs. Since the central bank is forced to
3
maintain a certain level of reserves of the foreign reference currency such that the price of
the domestic currency, in terms of the reference currency, does not change, this produces a
negative money-multiplier that sets in motion an inherent deflationary bias, which, if not
counteracted by capital inflows to spur aggregate demand, can lead to abrupt contraction of
the monetary base, stinting any supposed progress towards economic supremacy (see
Vernengo, 2006; Fields and Vernengo, 2012; Vernengo and Fields, 2016).
In this sense, if any form of government spending is to be engaged, an ‘underdeveloped
country has to issue bonds that are not denominated in its own currency. This is a balance-
of-payments constraint (Thirwall, 2011). It amounts to the attraction of external
commercial loans with the faith of the country’s financial markets by foreign investors used
as collateral. If confidence is lost in the strength of the countrys financial markets, leading
to a spread over bonds like US Treasury securities, if the foreign reference currency is the
US dollar, interest rates on domestic foreign-currency-denominated bonds are likely to rise.
Government spending would become very costly, removing the domestic capacity to spur
public investment as an effective countercyclical policy in the face of economic stagnation.
If development fails to occur, it is not because of “the survival of archaic institutions, or
some inability to contract some “modern man” (Inkles, 1969) syndrome. On the contrary, it
is generated by the same capitalist development that led to the domination by economically
advanced countries, that is, “the development of capitalism itself (Frank, 1969, p. 23). It is
an operation of what Myrdal (1957) referred to as international backwash effect that
produces falling terms of trade for economically weaker countries (Prebisch, 1950). Since
4
the imbalance of international trade defines the mechanisms by which capital is drained
from former colonized countries, there is no way for a Third World economy to ‘catch up
in Rostowian fashion (Amin, 1976, p. 383).
SEE ALSO:
Aggregate demand; Balance-of-payments constrained growth; Capitalism; Monopoly
Capital; Monopoly power.
REFERENCES
Amin, S. (1974), Accumulation and development: a theoretical model”, Review of African
Political Economy, 1 (1), 926.
Amin, S. (1976), Unequal Development, Brighton, UK: Harvester.
Baran, P. and P. Sweezy (1966), Monopoly Capital: An Essay on the American Economic
and Social Order, New York: Monthly Review Press.
Cardoso, F.H. and E. Faletto (1970), Dependência e desenvolvimento na América Latina,
Rio de Janeiro: Zahar.
5
Emmanuel, A. (1972), Unequal Exchange: An Essay on the Imperialism of Trade, New
York: Monthly Review Press.
Evans, P. (1995), Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation, Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Fields, D. and M. Vernengo (2012), “Hegemonic currencies during the crisis: the dollar
versus the euro in a Cartalist perspective”, Review of International Political Economy, 20
(4), 74059.
Frank, A.G. (1969), The development of underdevelopment”, Monthly Review, 18 (4), 17
31.
Goodhart, C.A.E. (1998), “The two concepts of money”, European Journal of Political
Economy, 14 (3), 40732.
Inkles, A. (1969), “Making men modern: on the causes and consequences of individual
change in six developing countries”, American Journal of Sociology, 75 (1), 20824.
Myrdal, G. (1957), Economic Theory and Underdeveloped Countries, London: Duckworth.
6
Palma, G. (1978), Dependency: a formal theory of underdevelopment or a methodology
for the analysis of concrete situations of underdevelopment?”, World Development, 6 (7),
881924.
Prebisch, R. (1950), El desarrollo económico de la América Latina y sus principales
problemas”, Revista de Economía Argentina, 48 (37980), 21166.
Rostow, W.W. (1960), The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto,
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Thirwall, A.P. (2011), “Balance of payments constrained growth models: history and
overview”, PSL Quarterly Review, 64 (259), 30751
Vernengo, M. (2006), “Technology, finance, and dependency: Latin American radical
political economy in retrospect”, Review of Radical Political Economics, 38 (4), 55168.
Vernengo, M. and D. Fields (2016), “DisORIENT: money, technological development and
the rise of the West, Review of Radical Political Economics, 48 (4), 5628.
Wallerstein, I. (1979), The Capitalist World-Economy, Volume 2, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
An extensive and important literature has shown that the Rise of the West occurred considerably later than often thought, only in the 19th century, and that the main advantages of the West prior to that period were essentially military. However, this revisionist literature fails to incorporate the insights of radical political economics, both regarding money and the role of demand in technological progress, in ways that distort their conclusions. This paper suggests that both revisionists and radical political economists would benefit from each other’s insights.
Article
Full-text available
Thiriwall’s 1979 balance of payments constrained growth model predicts that a country’s long-run growth of GDP can be approximated by the ratio of the growth of real exports to the income elasticity of demand for imports assuming negligible effects from real exchange rate movements.1 This chapter surveys developments of the model since then allowing for capital flows, interest payments on debt, terms of trade movements and disaggregation of the model by commodities and trading partners. Various tests of the model are discussed, and extensive lists of papers that have examined the model are presented.
Article
Full-text available
This paper suggests that the dollar is not threatened as the hegemonic international currency, and that most analysts are incapable of understanding the resilience of the dollar, not only because they ignore the theories of monetary hegemonic stability or what, more recently, has been termed the geography of money; but also as a result of an incomplete understanding of what a monetary hegemon does. The hegemon is not required to maintain credible macroeconomic policies (i.e., fiscally contractionary policies to maintain the value of the currency), but rather to provide an asset free of the risk of default. It is argued that the current crisis in Europe illustrates why the euro is not a real contender for hegemony in the near future.
Article
Full-text available
The surge in academic work on globalization has made several of the topics dear to authors of the dependency school relevant once again. Therefore a reconsideration of dependency theory seems to be appropriate. There are at least two approaches to dependency. This paper analyzes critically their similarities, differences and limitations, in particular regarding the role of technology, and international finance in the explanation of center and periphery interactions. The evolutions of the ideas on dependency in Latin America are evaluated. The reduced relevance of strict definitions of the technological division of labor, and the theoretical problems caused by the effective industrialization of several countries in the periphery, the debt crisis, and the failure of the neoliberal agenda are also discussed. In the era of globalization and great transformations in the international economy the 'new' dependency seems to be financial in nature.
Article
These comments are not by a China specialist but come from someone who has been concerned with world capitalist development and the development of underdevelopment within it. In the comments that follow, therefore, the evaluation of the content of Lippit's argument about China will largely be left to the China specialists; while here we will concentrate on the construction of the argument about the development of underdevelopment. To begin with, we may question whether the title Mr. Lippit chooses for his essay is even appropriate for the argument he constructs. Mr. Lippit does well in examining the theses that are "more obscurantist than explanatory" (as he terms one of them, though the same term applies equally to the others), and he does more than well to reject them on grounds of their lack of scientific foundation. In their universal versions (and also their applications to other case studies) the Rostowian stage theory beginning with "traditional" society, the Parsonian (pseudo-Weberian) theory of pattern variables including family structure and culture, the Leibensteinian low- and Schultzian high-level equilibrium trap theory, and the Nurskian-Myrdalian vicious circles have all long since shown to be a-, indeed anti-, historical and therein akeady scientifically unacceptable as vehicles for the explanation of any social process and development (and non- or under
Article
In this article Samir Amin sets out the core of his model of the global accumulation of capital. In it he defines two distinct patterns: one applying to development at the centre, the other to dependent development in the periphery. Central development is characterised by the dominance of economic activity to satisfy mass consumer needs and the consequent demand for production goods. The power of the masses is enlisted in a ‘social contract’ which allows the establishment of a limited economic viability, at a national level. However, the internationalisation of productive capital increasingly threatens that stability. The peripheral systems are dominated by production of luxury goods and exports and the consequent lack of importance of internal mass markets. This leads to growing inequality, technological dependence, political weakness among the oppressed — in sum, marginalization. Restructuring of these economies requires a break with the international economy, and self‐centred development which establishes the dominance of production for mass needs, though there are particular difficulties for individual countries attempting such a break and ultimately a solution can be found only if such changes take place internationally. Policies for the difficult period of transition must first and foremost focus on the need to build the political consciousness necessary to complete tills process.