Content uploaded by Olaf van Vliet
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by Olaf van Vliet on Sep 09, 2021
Content may be subject to copyright.
1
Van Vliet, O., Bakker, V., and Van Doorn, L. (2021) From Social Protection to Social
Investment: European Responses to Globalization, Technological Change, Labour Market
Flexibilization, and Migration. In: G. Fischer and R. Strauss (eds.) Europe’s income, wealth,
consumption, and inequality. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 343-394.
From Social Protection to Social Investment
European Responses to Globalization, Technological Change, Labour Market
Flexibilization, and Migration
1
Olaf van Vliet1,2, Vincent Bakker1 and Lars van Doorn1
1 Leiden University, Department of Economics
2 Leiden University, Institute of Public Administration
Abstract
Globalization, technological change, and migration form three major challenges for European
welfare states in the 21st century. These challenges are regarded as important sources of inequality
on the labour market. Whereas the existing literature has mainly been focused on the sectors and
occupations affected by globalization and technological change, the authors of this chapter argue
that, via job polarization, these phenomena also affect the type of contract that workers have. They
hypothesize that increased competition for low-paying jobs is associated with labour market
flexibilization. Another major trend that they analyse is the free movement of labour. New data
illustrate that labour migration from Central and Eastern European countries to Western European
countries has grown slowly but substantially following recent enlargements of the Union. It has
been considered a challenge for welfare states as it might contribute to feelings of economic
insecurity and might erode solidarity, which forms the basis for the provision of social policy.
Subsequently, the authors analyse how European welfare states have evolved over the past decades.
They show that in spite of budgetary pressure stemming from globalization and migration, most
countries have increased social expenditure. Furthermore, they analyse to what extent the focus has
shifted from classical social protection to social investment policies to enable workers to adapt
themselves to new labour market transformations. They contribute to the existing literature by
covering years after the financial crisis for all EU member states and by demonstrating a novel way
of correcting social expenditures for the number of recipients.
Keywords: globalization, technological change, job polarization, flexibilization, migration, social
investment
1
Financial support from Instituut Gak is gratefully acknowledged.
2
1. Introduction
Welfare states play an important role in the daily life of European citizens. Traditionally,
welfare states provided protection against income loss as a result of unemployment, disability,
and old age. Recently, the enabling function of the welfare state has become more important.
As a result of developments such as globalization and technological change, economies have
become more dynamic and labour markets have become more flexible. Jobs in some sectors
disappear whereas new jobs in other sectors are born. Hence, one of the main challenges for
workers in the 21st century is how to smooth labour market transitions in order to adapt to
increasing flexibility.
Welfare state programmes can play an important role in the transitions between jobs and
sectors which workers are making increasingly more frequently during their careers. This
enabling function requires a new type of welfare state, one that is focused on training and
keeping human capital updated throughout the working life. Such an approach requires so-
called social investments which have been at the core of the European Union (EU) social policy
agenda over the past decade. Yet, welfare states have continuously been under budgetary
pressure over the past decades as a result of globalization affecting labour markets and because
of increased expenditures on pensions and healthcare due to ageing populations. An important
question related to such a transformation of the welfare state is how its redistributive function
is affected and hence what the implications are for income inequality and poverty.
The aim of this chapter is to describe and analyse the challenges that European welfare
states are confronted with in the first decades of the 21st century. First, we focus on the labour
market effects of globalization and technological change. To date, the existing literature has
been mainly focused on the question of what types of work will (dis)appear, for what types of
workers and in which sectors. Although this is an extremely relevant question, in this chapter,
we propose to add another dimension to this debate. We expect that globalization and
technological change also affect the type of contract that workers have. The share of
nonstandard employment has grown over the past years and we hypothesise that globalization
and technological change have contributed to this trend. Furthermore, the results of this trend,
job polarization and labour market flexibilization, will increase inequality between different
groups on the labour market.
Another major trend that we discuss is the role of labour migration. Intra-EU
immigration has grown slowly since Central and Eastern European (CEE) countries have joined
the Union, but it is becoming an increasingly important feature of European labour markets and
in the context of European welfare states. Subsequently, we discuss the implications of these
3
trends and developments for European welfare states. Based on an empirical analysis, we show
how European welfare states have evolved over time, and we examine to what extent social
investment has become more important for them. Here, we update the existing literature with
data for the years during and after the financial crisis, and we extend existing studies by
including all 28 EU member states. Furthermore, we demonstrate a novel way of correcting
social expenditure data for the number of recipients in order to compare the generosity of new
social programmes across countries and over time.
2. Globalization and Technological Change
The economic literature considers globalization and technological change as two pivotal
phenomena transforming European labour markets. However, given the comparable labour
market effects of both forces, there has been a lively debate regarding the question of whether
globalization or technological change is paramount in determining labour market outcomes
(Iversen and Cusack, 2000). This debate is rooted in the methodological challenges associated
with empirically disentangling these two effects from each other since both developments have
taken place in the same period – namely about the past 30 years – and because they yield similar
effects.
Only recently it has been acknowledged that it is not either globalization or
technological change that matters, but that both developments have had an impact on the labour
market. In several studies, David Autor and his co-authors have compared the labour market
effects of Chinese imports with the labour market effects of technological change (Autor et al.,
2013, 2015; Acemoglu et al., 2016). Based on data for the United States, they show that in
sectors exposed to Chinese imports, employment declined because complete production lines
disappeared as a result of these imports. In contrast, technological change lead mainly to
polarization: the production line remained, but routine-intense work was replaced by machines.
A growing number of studies that examined the employment effects of globalization and
technological change across Europe find comparable results (Michaels et al., 2014; Balsvik et
al., 2015; Thewissen and Van Vliet, 2019). In the next couple of paragraphs we elaborate on
both phenomena and show how they have eventually resulted in the polarization of Europe’s
labour market.
4
3. The Initial Prominence of Skills in the Transforming Labour Market
3.1 Globalization
Globalization can be understood as the process of economic, social, and political international
integration. The economic, social, and political dimensions of globalization are closely related
to each other, but, for the analysis of the impact of globalization on European labour markets,
the economic dimension is the most relevant. This dimension entails the reduction or removal
of international barriers as a result of which trade, capital, and migration flows between
countries can increase. As a result, goods and services will be produced in those places in the
world where they can be produced in the most efficient way. This leads to lower prices for
consumers, which will increase welfare for a society as a whole (Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal,
2016).
At the same time, globalization will yield distributive effects within society. Based on a
Ricardo-Viner framework, it can be expected that workers who work in sectors in which exports
increase as a result of the reduction of trade barriers will benefit. In contrast, workers who work
in sectors with increased imports will lose as the imports in fact replace their work (Samuelson,
1971; Sirgy et al., 2007; Walter, 2010). Based on another framework, the Stolper-Samuelson
model (1941), it can be expected that the production factors that are relatively abundant will
gain. Hence, when European countries engage in international trade, this generally means that
products which are produced in labour-intensive manufacturing industries are imported from
low-wage countries, which results in a lower domestic demand for low-skilled workers. At the
same time, exports of knowledge-intensive products increase, which triggers firms to focus on
increasing their productivity and hence on innovation. This results in a higher demand for high-
skilled workers (Bloom et al., 2016). Over the past few decades, the process of globalization
has accelerated rapidly across member countries of the Organisation for Economic Cooperation
and Development (OECD) and across European countries in particular.
3.2 Technological Change
The literature initially assumed that technological change, like globalization, increased the
relative demand for high-skilled workers. Inspired by the work of Tinbergen (1974, 1975),
research explaining the rise in the relative wages of high-skilled workers vis-à-vis low-skilled
workers throughout the 20th century argued that technological change is skill biased (Goldin
and Katz, 2009). This bias is rooted in the assumption that technological improvements
particularly augment the productivity of high-skilled workers resulting in a relative increase in
the demand for high-skilled workers.
5
The wages of high-skilled workers are subsequently determined by the race between
education and technological change (Katz and Murphy, 1992; Katz and Autor, 1999; Goldin
and Katz, 2009; Acemoglu and Autor, 2010). If the growth of the relative supply of high-skilled
workers stagnates, the upsurge in demand caused by technological change results in increased
premiums
2
for high-skilled workers and thus wage inequality. In contrast, an equal increase in
the supply and demand of high-skilled workers relative to low-skilled workers will result in
skill-upgrading in terms of employment but does not affect the skill premium. While research
showed that skill premiums particularly increased in the United Kingdom, this logic holds to a
lesser extent for the other European countries, resulting in a more dispersed wage distribution
(Davis, 1992; Berman et al., 1998; Fitzenbergen and Kohn, 2006; Atkinson, 2007).
4. Explaining Job Polarization: Shifting the Focus from Skill to Routine
While the focus on skills just described has been quite successful in explaining labour market
consequences for a long time, it is not able to offer an appropriate explanation for a rather
recent labour market trend in advanced economies: job polarization (Goos et al., 2014; Gregory
et al., 2016). This process entails an increase in the share of both high-skilled and low-skilled
jobs and a simultaneous decrease in the share of middle-skilled jobs (Acemoglu and Autor,
2010). While the resulting U-shaped labour market was initially documented using data for the
United States (Acemoglu, 1999), this pattern has also been reported for European countries
(Goos et al., 2009, 2014; Michaels et al., 2014; Gregory et al., 2019).
To explain this trend, Autor et al. (2003) introduced the so-called routine-biased
technological change hypothesis. In contrast to the skill-biased technological change
hypothesis’ emphasis on labour productivity, this hypothesis focusses on the nature of tasks.
3
More specifically, it assumes that digital capital (artificial intelligence, computers, and robots)
is especially suited to perform routine-intense tasks characterized as procedural and rule-based
(Acemoglu and Autor, 2010). Subsequently, it can be expected that jobs involving these types
of tasks will be automated and might eventually become extinct. Research has shown that
middle-skilled jobs in particular involve routine-intense tasks (Autor et al., 2006; Autor and
Dorn, 2013; Goos and Manning, 2007; Goos et al., 2014). Examples in this regard are book-
keepers, office clerks, and machine operators. The comparative advantage of digital capital in
2
The wage of high-skilled workers relative to the wage of low-skilled workers.
3
In this regard, a task is defined as a unit of work activity that produces output, both goods and services. Moreover,
workers should be considered as individuals allocating their skills to different tasks depending on their comparative
advantage and labour market prices (Roy 1951; Acemoglu and Autor 2010).
6
performing routine-intense tasks results in a lower demand for labour in these types of jobs, as
a result of which the demand for middle-skilled workers decreases.
Figure 1 shows that the European labour market has indeed polarized: the shares of high-
and low-paying jobs have relatively increased, while the share of middle-paying jobs decreased.
We have grouped the jobs based on Goos et al. (2014), who use two-digit International Standard
Classification of Occupations (ISCO) codes to rank occupations by their mean wage rank based
on the European Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC).
4
For this figure we
use aggregated country-level data. In this regard, we rely on data underlying the European
Commission’s Employment and Social Developments Review provided by the DG
Employment, Social Affairs & Inclusion.
The clear trend of job polarization illustrated in Figure 1 notwithstanding, the intensity
of the process varies substantially per country. The share of middle-paying jobs decreased quite
dramatically in Luxembourg (21%), Ireland (19%), France (18%), Portugal (18%), and the
United Kingdom (17%), whereas Poland experienced a decrease of only 5% in the share of
middle-paying jobs. Moreover, this decrease in Poland was accompanied with a decrease in the
share of low-paying jobs. Note that this variation is in line with the broader critique presented
by some studies in relation to the importance of (labour market) institutions and culture in
explaining labour market transformations (Oesch and Rodríguez Menés, 2011; Fernández-
Macías and Hurley, 2017). The higher wages stemming from legal minimum wages and
collective bargaining might for instance result in a higher share of high-quality and thus high-
paying jobs (Grimshaw et al., 2014). Consequently, job polarization might be less pronounced.
Institutions like employment protection or generous welfare state benefits could potentially
have similar effects.
Another possible explanation for the polarization of the European labour markets is a
shift in Europe’s labour supply. This perspective assumes that employers take the
characteristics of the supply of workers into account when deciding on production techniques
that, in the end, determine the type of available jobs (Murphy and Oesch, 2018). Thus, the
availability of a low number of low-skilled workers might decrease the demand for low-paying
4
As a result, high-paying occupations include corporate managers; physical, mathematical, and engineering
professionals; life science and health professionals; other professionals; managers of small enterprises; physical,
mathematical, and engineering associate professionals; other associate professionals; and life science and health
associate professionals. Middle-paying occupations include stationary plant and related, stationary plant and
related operators; metal, machinery, and related trade work; drivers and mobile plant operators; office clerks;
precision, handicraft, craft printing, and related trade workers; extraction and building trades workers; customer
service clerks; machine operators and assemblers; and other craft and related trade workers. Finally, low-paying
occupations include labourers in mining, construction, manufacturing, and transport; personal and protective
service workers; models, sales persons, and demonstrators; and sales and service elementary occupations.
7
Notes: Educational attainment is coded according to ISCED 1997 for 2002 and ISCED 2011 for 2016. Data years for Romania are 2005 and 2016.
Source: Eurostat Labour Market Database, European Commission DG Employment, Social Affairs & Inclusion (2018) and authors’ calculations.
Figure 1 Job polarization and employment by educational attainment in Europe, 2002-2016
-35
-30
-25
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
Differences between 2002-2016 in percentage points
Low-paying
Middle-paying
High-paying
Less than primary, primary and lower secondary education (levels 0-2)
Upper secondary and post-secondary non-tertiary education (levels 3 and 4)
Tertiary education (levels 5-8)
8
jobs as this incentivises employers to adapt their production process to the availability of a
highly qualified supply of labour. The changes in employment by educational attainment
presented in Figure 1 do not, however, support this argument. Although the number of high-
skilled workers indeed increased, the supply of low-skilled workers increased in Denmark and
Hungary only. While it should be noted that this does not mean that labour supply effects cannot
account for the polarization of European labour markets, there are a least no clear trends that
directly explain job polarization. Moreover, recent literature analysing the disappearance of
middle-skilled jobs supports this finding (Green 2019).
5. Increased Competition at the Lower End of the Labour Market
In the previous paragraphs, we focussed on the effects of globalization and technological
change, the ways in which both forces have shaped the demand for labour, and how this
eventually resulted in job polarization in Europe. Next, we relate the process of job polarization
to the increasing competition for low-skilled jobs. Middle-skilled workers faced with a lower
demand for routine-intense tasks are forced to supply their labour to jobs involving either less
or more complex tasks (Cortes, 2016; Goos, 2018). We argue that without additional education
or training it can be expected that the abilities of middle-skilled workers are better suited to less
complex tasks. Consequently, job polarization will result in increased competition at the lower
end of the labour market.
The employment shares of low-paying jobs for 2002 and 2016 presented in Figure 2
provide tentative support for this expectation.
5
In this figure, we combine the data used for
Figure 1 with individual-level data from the European Union Labour Force Survey (EU-LFS).
This allows us to analyse changes in the share of each education group in low-paying jobs.
Between 2002 and 2016 the share of middle-skilled workers employed in low-paying jobs
increased across Europe. Note, that although a growing number of middle-skilled workers are
on average employed in low-paying jobs (their share increased by 7%), there is a large variation
between the countries. On the one hand, in countries like Portugal (194%), Spain (48%), and
Italy (46%), the share of middle-skilled workers in low-paying jobs increased substantially.
Denmark (−11%) and Sweden (−16%), on the other hand, experienced a decline in the share of
middle-skilled workers in low-paying jobs.
5
Note, however, that this figure presents purely descriptive data. Consequently, these findings should be
interpreted with some caution.
9
Notes: Jobs are ranked based on Goos et al. (2014), who use two-digit ISCO codes to rank occupations by their mean wage rank based on EU-SILC. Educational
attainment is coded according to ISCED 1997 for 2002 and ISCED 2011 for 2016. Data years for Romania are 2005 and 2016.
Source: European Commission DG Employment, Social Affairs & Inclusion (2018), and EU-LFS.
Figure 2 Increased competition for low-paying jobs, 2002 and 2016
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
Share of low-paying jobs as % of total jobs
Share of middle skilled holding low-paying jobs
Share of high skilled holding low-paying jobs
Share of low skilled holding low-paying jobs
2002
2016
10
6. Flexibilization of the Labour Market
Up to now, research has mainly analysed the impact of job polarization in relation to the income
distribution (Autor and Dorn, 2013; Goos et al., 2014; Cortes, 2016; Kurer and Gallego, 2019).
The explicit link between job polarization and the type of employment contracts has not been
analysed yet.
6
This is noteworthy given the shift towards flexible employment on most
European labour markets. Moreover, this transition has sparked widely shared concerns
regarding employment protection, social rights, training opportunities, and income inequality
(ILO, 2016, 2019). The European Union also acknowledged the importance of these issues and
addresses them in its Pillar of Social Rights.
We argue that the increasing flexibilization of European labour markets is partly the
result of job polarization and in particular the increased competition for low-skilled jobs. Note
that the number of middle-skilled workers employed in low-paying jobs increased in 16 out of
22 European countries between 2002 and 2016. Moreover, the share of middle-skilled workers
holding low-paying jobs increased on average by 30% in these countries. Although purely
descriptive, this provides empirical support for our argument that middle-skilled workers have
shifted their labour supply to jobs characterized by less complex tasks, thereby increasing
competition for low-skilled jobs.
As is shown in Figure 3, the share of nonstandard employment (NSE) slightly increased
in EU15 countries. In particular, the Netherlands and Luxembourg stand out with an increase
of respectively 10 and 9 percentage points. Both countries are amongst the countries with a
relatively high increase in the share of middle-skilled workers holding low-paying jobs. This
might indicate that the increased competition at the lower end of the labour market not only
resulted in a stagnation of wage growth, but also resulted in competition amongst workers by
type of contract. In contrast, in Denmark and Sweden, which did not experience an increase in
the share of middle-skilled workers in low-paying jobs, the share of NSE remained relatively
stable.
Figure 4, however, shows a slightly different story. Whilst the EU13 countries are
generally characterized by a relatively stable share of middle-skilled workers in low-paying
jobs, the share of NSE increased substantially in 9 out of 13 countries, with Hungary, Latvia,
Lithuania, and Romania as the exceptions. For instance, Poland experienced an increase in NSE
of almost 20 percentage points. Yet the share of middle-skilled workers holding low-skilled
6
A notable exception in this regard is Peugny (2019), who showed that precarious employment (measured as the
proportion of involuntary part-time jobs) mainly affected the lower skilled jobs in the service sector. Nevertheless,
she does not explicitly analyse the link between job polarization and flexibilization.
11
Notes: In most studies NSE includes temporary employment, part-time and on-call work, temporary agency work and other multiparty employment relationships as well
as disguised employment and dependent self-employment (Eurofound 2019). Due to data limitations we have only included part-time work and self-employment.
Source: Eurostat Labour Market Database and authors’ calculations.
Figure 3 Labour market flexibilization in the EU15, 1995-2015
Figure 4 Labour market flexibilization in the EU13, 1995-2015
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
NSE as % of total employment
1995 2005 2015
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
NSE as % of total employment
2000 2005 2015
12
jobs dropped in Poland with 6% in the same period. Although this finding seems to challenge
our expectations, this result might also be caused by differences in the share of middle-skilled
workers between EU13 and EU15 countries. In EU13 countries the average share of middle-
skilled workers in low-paying jobs is 72% compared to 49% in EU15 countries. This difference
might account for a different dynamic at the lower end of the labour market.
Moreover, it is important to emphasise the importance of labour market regulations and
welfare state institutions. For instance, higher minimum wages might result in a higher demand
for high-skilled workers (Grimshaw et al., 2014), strict employment protection and tax and
transfer policies might provide incentives for employers to resort to NSE, education and training
might enable middle-skilled workers to compete for high-skilled jobs, and unions might protect
workers with a standard contract, affecting the incidence of NSE (Keune and Pedaci, 2019).
Our research agenda for the future is to analyse the link between job polarization and labour
market flexiblization as well as the mediating function of these institutions.
7. Labour Migration
7.1 Migration Trends
Over the past few decades, the impact of immigration on European labour markets and welfare
states has become a central topic in both the academic and public debate. In the first place, this
concerns third-country migration, which is to some extent related to geopolitical and economic
developments all over the world. Recently, the war in Syria has resulted in large refugee flows
into Europe. Another major development is the growth in the number of African immigrants
who aim to reach Europe via the Mediterranean Sea. In the European welfare state literature, it
is mainly the effects of labour mobility that have received a lot of attention. Free movement of
labour is an important pillar in the process of European integration as it can reduce labour
market imbalances. That is, workers can move from areas with high unemployment rates to
areas with labour shortages. This is even more relevant for the European Union as diverging
economic situations across countries can be problematic for monetary policymaking.
Furthermore, free movement of labour may lead to a better allocation of labour as there can be
better matches between demand and supply of certain skills. Workers can move to those areas
where they can reach the highest productivity levels.
Traditionally, the mobility of labour across European countries has been relatively low.
Because of differences in language, culture, and welfare state institutions among EU countries,
mobility has been lower than in, for instance, the United States. The rounds of enlargement of
the EU in 2004, 2007, and 2013 with predominantly CEE countries have increased the flows of
13
intra-EU labour migration. Given the differences in labour market conditions between Western
and CEE countries, mainly with regard to employment and wages, it is predominantly mobility
from east to west (Rojas-Romagosa and Bollen, 2018). Despite the attention paid to labour
migration in both the public and academic debate, the coverage of labour migration in
systematic empirical research has remained rather limited. An important reason for this is the
lack of readily available data. In fact, most studies which are theoretically interested in
European labour migration have used data on overall migration due to a lack of better data.
Recently, Fenwick and Van Vliet (2019) constructed an indicator for labour migration
based on the EU Labour Force Survey (EU-LFS) microdata. These data are originally being
used to generate insights into labour market trends such as unemployment rates, but they also
contain information that can be used to construct trends in labour migration. We use these data
in our analysis here. Fenwick and Van Vliet (2019) use information on country of birth and
labour force status to identify labour migrants from CEE countries. They construct the indictor
as a percentage of the labour force. Table 1 shows the volume of labour migration from CEE
countries to Western European countries. Switzerland is included because it is a member of the
Schengen Area, has a comparable economy and welfare state to the EU15, and is traditionally
considered a country of notable immigration.
As shown in Table 1, labour migration from CEE countries to Western European
countries has increased substantially since the enlargements of the European Union. Between
2004 and 2016, the average stock of labour migration has increased from 1% to 3.2% of the
labour force. At the same time, it should be noted that this level is still far below the level of
labour migration from Western European countries to other Western European countries;
namely, on average 7.5% in 2016. Although the stock of CEE labour migration increased in all
Western European countries, there is considerable variation. In Ireland, the stock of CEE
migration has risen the sharpest. In 2016, more than 9% of the Irish labour force consisted of
CEE immigrants. A likely explanation for this development is that Ireland was one of only three
EU countries that did not impose labour market restrictions on immigrants from those countries
that became EU Member States in 2004. Other countries with relatively large proportions of
CEE immigrants are Austria and the United Kingdom. In contrast, in Portugal and France, only
0.3% and 0.7%, respectively, of the labour force consisted of CEE immigrants in 2016.
14
Table 1 Labour migration from Central and Eastern to Western European countries,
2004-2016
2004
2007
2010
2013
2016
Change 2004-2016
Austria
3.4
4.0
4.3
4.8
6.1
2.8
Belgium
0.5
0.7
1.7
2.2
2.6
2.2
Denmark
0.4
0.6
1.1
1.9
2.5
2.2
Finland
0.6
0.4
0.6
0.9
1.4
0.8
France
0.3
0.4
0.6
0.5
0.7
0.4
Germany
0.9
1.0
1.3
1.8
2.9
2.0
Greece
1.2
1.4
1.9
1.8
1.4
0.3
Ireland
3.3
9.7
9.2
9.4
9.4
6.1
Italy
1.2
1.8
3.4
3.9
4.3
3.0
Luxembourg
0.8
2.0
2.5
3.7
4.9
4.1
Netherlands
0.4
0.5
0.8
1.0
1.3
0.9
Portugal
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.4
0.3
0.1
Spain
1.8
3.0
3.6
3.3
3.5
1.8
Sweden
1.3
1.6
2.0
2.6
2.6
1.3
Switzerland
1.5
1.5
1.9
2.2
2.6
1.0
United Kingdom
0.6
2.3
3.3
3.7
5.4
4.8
Mean
1.0
1.9
2.4
2.7
3.2
2.3
Notes: CEE countries: Bulgaria, Croatia, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania,
Malta, Poland, Romania, Slovakia, Slovenia; immigration is expressed as a percentage of the labour
force; for some countries data years are around 2005 (Ireland, 2004; Italy, 2004).
Source: Fenwick and Van Vliet (2019).
7.2 Policy Debate at the EU Level
To foster the mobility of labour, the European Union has adopted a number of policy initiatives
aimed at removing institutional barriers (Eurofound, 2014). For instance, the limited portability
of social rights is a relevant factor for the mobility of workers. In April 2014, the Directive
(2014/50/EU) on minimum requirements for enhancing worker mobility between Member
States by improving the acquisition and preservation of supplementary pension rights was
adopted. In December 2016, the Directive (2016/2341/EU) on the activities and supervision of
institutions for occupational retirement provision was adopted. As a broader policy agenda, the
then President of the European Commission, Jean-Claude Juncker, presented the European
Pillar of Social Rights in 2017. Part of this policy agenda deals with the coordination of social
security systems within the European Union, which is aimed at protecting the social rights of
workers when they move across the borders of EU Member States. As a concrete measure, the
European Commission presented a proposal that extends the portability of unemployment
benefits between Member States from 3 to 6 months. Early in 2019, it became clear that a
15
majority of EU Member States would be in favour of this proposal but that the final decision-
making would be left to the new European Parliament and European Commission, which were
installed later that year.
A more direct type of measure to foster the mobility of labour migration is lifting labour
migration restrictions. In the enlargement rounds since 2004, Western European countries had
the possibility to impose temporary labour migration restrictions. For instance, workers from
those countries which joined the Union in 2004 had direct access to the Irish, Swedish, and
British labour markets, but could work in Austria, Germany, and Switzerland only since 2011
(Fenwick and Van Vliet, 2019). The rationale of these labour migration restrictions is that
Western European countries could temporarily protect their domestic labour market. Given the
differences in wages, Western European countries expected large inflows of workers from CEE
countries and therefore substantial displacement on the labour market, which would harm native
workers.
8. Implications for Welfare States
Globalization, technological change, and migration yield not only employment effects. These
developments may also affect welfare states in a more direct way. In the political economy
literature, the debate on the relationship between economic openness and welfare state
generosity has been centred around the supply and demand side of social protection (Van Vliet
and Wang, 2019). With regard to the supply side of social protection, the efficiency hypothesis
states that policymakers are inclined to cut tax burdens in order to facilitate attractive conditions
for firms due to increasing competitiveness pressures in international markets. The budgetary
pressure resulting from the lower tax revenues contributes to the reduction of the generosity of
welfare state programmes (Garrett and Mitchell, 2001). In contrast, on the demand side, the
compensation hypothesis states that economic globalization may lead to an increased demand
from voters for social policy in order to compensate the increased labour market risks (Rodrik,
1998). Interestingly, a growing body of literature provides empirical support for the microlevel
mechanisms of the compensation hypothesis (Scheve and Slaughter, 2004; Walter, 2017).
Technological change can be expected to affect welfare state generosity via the compensation
mechanism, too. The automation of jobs contributes to feelings of economic insecurity and
hence to a higher demand for social protection (Iversen and Cusack, 2000).
The theoretical effects of migration on the provision of social welfare can also be
classified along the lines of supply and demand. The possible displacement effects could lead
to insecurity with regard to work and income among native workers, and this could result in a
16
higher demand for social protection (Burgoon et al., 2012; Brady and Finnigan, 2014). At the
same time, immigration may also affect the supply side of social policy. Solidarity among
people is lower when they have fewer common linkages such as origin, language, and culture.
Therefore, domestic workers would be less willing to pay taxes and social security contributions
when immigrants are also entitled to social benefits (Alesina et al., 2001; Luttmer, 2001;
Alesina and Glaeser, 2004; Eger, 2010).
Whether the demand-side effect or the supply-side effect dominates is hard to assess on
purely theoretical grounds, and it is therefore more of an empirical question. A large body of
literature with empirical studies on the relationship between globalization and social protection
levels produces rather mixed results. Some studies reported negative effects on social protection
levels (e.g., Busemeyer, 2009a), whereas other studies found evidence for positive associations
(e.g., Hicks and Zorn, 2005) or even mixed effects (e.g., Brady et al., 2005). The mixed results
in the literature partly reflect the variation in the selected countries and years and in the
methodological approaches. A more substantive interpretation of the mixed results is that
globalization affects welfare states via both the supply and demand sides. The resulting
combination of budgetary pressure and an increased demand for social protection yields a
dilemma for policymakers, one that has been called the globalization dilemma (Hays, 2009).
The empirical literature on the effects of immigration on social protection levels is
younger. In an analysis of 18 OECD countries, Soroka et al. (2006) find evidence that suggests
that the negative supply-side effect dominates. However, the results of the empirical study by
Gaston and Rajaguru (2013) are not in line with this negative effect, and their results tend to
suggest a positive association between immigrant and social expenditure. A recent study by
Fenwick (2019) supports these results. Based on data for 16 European countries, she finds a
positive association between immigration and welfare state effort, which is in line with the
explanation that immigration contributes to a higher demand for social protection.
It can be expected that the effects of immigration vary across different welfare state
programmes. The decrease in solidarity as a result of immigration will be smaller in the case of
social insurance programmes, for which immigrants pay social contributions, than in the case
of social security programmes, such as means-tested social assistance benefits, which are
funded from general tax revenues (Boeri, 2010). In their empirical analysis of the cross-country
variation in social expenditure on several welfare state programmes, Soroka et al. (2016) find
that immigration is mainly negatively associated with unemployment benefits and active labour
market policy. Fenwick and Van Vliet (2019) show that the effects of immigration not only
vary across welfare state programmes, but that the effects are also dependent on the type of
17
immigration. They find positive associations between labour migration from CEE countries and
the generosity of several welfare state programmes in Western European countries. These
results are in line with the argument that immigrants may pose labour market risks for native
workers, which increases the demand for social protection. Interestingly, refugees are
negatively associated with the generosity of unemployment benefits and positively associated
with the generosity of social assistance benefits. An explanation for this finding might be that
refugees are considered as ‘less-deserving’ of unemployment benefits but ‘deserving’ of social
assistance benefits.
9. Welfare State Developments
To analyse the development of welfare states across Europe, we use data on public social
expenditures.
7
The main public social policy areas considered are: old age; survivors;
incapacity-related benefits; health; family; active labour market programmes; unemployment;
housing; and ‘other’ social policy areas. Data are taken from the most recent version of the
OECD (2019a) Social Expenditure Database (SOCX) and OECD (2019b) Labour Market
Statistics. To guarantee consistency over time, increase the cross-country comparability of the
data, and maximise the number of observations, some adjustments have been made. First, we
have complemented the data with data from the OECD (2019c) Education Statistics for
spending on pre-primary education, which have been included in SOCX since the introduction
of ISCED 1997 (generally around 1998) only.
8
Second, some of the CEE member states of the
EU are not members of the OECD (Bulgaria, Cyprus, Croatia, Malta, and Romania) or have
been a member for a relatively short amount of time (Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Slovenia); as
a result, statistics for these countries are not available from the OECD or for a relatively short
7
We do not focus on mandatory and voluntary private expenditures. Data on private social spending are deemed
to be of lesser quality than public spending data (Adema and Fron, 2019). In addition, private social expenditures
are almost exclusively confined to old-age, sickness, and health programmes (such as sickness benefits paid by
employers to employees as mandated by law, mandatory pension contributions to private pension funds, and
employment-related health plans), whereas the focus here is predominantly on new types of social policies.
Moreover, voluntary private expenditures cannot be disaggregated to the same level of detail as public
expenditures.
8
Expenditures on pre-primary education are included under SOCX category 5-2-1: in-kind spending for families
on early childhood education and care. For years for which public expenditures on pre-primary education were not
available from the same OECD database, data were estimated. This mainly refers to years before 1997. For the
estimation, we used backward extrapolation based on the developments of public educational expenditure data
from the UNESCO Institute for Statistics (UIS) or expenditures on educational institutions available from another
OECD database. For almost all countries theses series are very strongly correlated to the public educational
expenditure data available from the OECD (generally, r ≥ 0.99). Furthermore, the corrections for differences in
the compulsory age of entry into primary school implemented in SOCX (outlined in Annex I.1.4 of the SOCX
2019 Manual, see Adema and Fron, 2019) have been excluded because we are interested in total spending.
18
time span only. In these cases, we have complemented the data with similar data from Eurostat.
9
An obvious limitation of social expenditure data is that developments do not only reflect
deliberate policy changes, but that expenditures are also driven by cyclical and demographic
trends such as unemployment and ageing of populations (Van Vliet, 2010; Jensen, 2011). Yet
expenditure data offer a bird’s-eye perspective which provides insight into long-term trends for
a large number of countries. Furthermore, we also provide a descriptive analysis in which
expenditures are corrected for the number of beneficiaries.
Table 2 shows developments in public social expenditure across 15 Western European
countries, 13 CEE countries, and 4 non-EU countries for the period 1985–2015. On average,
EU15 countries spent 25% of their gross domestic product (GDP) on welfare state programmes
in 2015. This proportion is substantially lower in EU13 countries, where on average 18% of
GDP was spent on social policies in 2015. The highest level of social expenditures can be
observed in France, where in 2015 almost one-third of GDP was spent on welfare state
programmes. With 14.6% of GDP, Romania was the country with the lowest social
expenditures in 2015. In the United States, the proportion of GDP spent on social policy is
comparable to the social expenditure level in the EU13.
10
Against the background of globalization, technological change, and ageing of
populations, the developments in social expenditure over time are particularly interesting. In
the EU15, the EU13, and in the group of non-EU countries, the share of GDP devoted to social
policy has on average increased over the past few decades. In the last couple of years, the high
expenditures are probably partly caused by the high unemployment rates during the financial
crisis. Yet also before 2010, the levels of social expenditures had been increased on average.
Interestingly, there is substantial variation in the developments across countries. Over time,
social expenditures have been increased in most of the countries. Within the EU15, only in
9
For European countries, SOCX data since around 1990 are based on data from the European System of integrated
Social Protection Statistics (ESSPROS) provided by Eurostat. The definitions of social expenditures used by
SOCX and ESSPROS are similar, but there are differences in coverage and categorization. ESSPROS data were
converted to the SOCX format using Annex I.1.1 of the SOCX, 2019 Manual (Adema and Fron, 2019), which
describes how to regroup ESSPROS items into SOCX using the example of Sweden in 2015. The latest edition of
the ESSPROS manual (Eurostat, 2016) was used to identify schemes that classify as mandatory private or
voluntary private for Bulgaria, Cyprus, Malta, and Romania. Data from the Croatian Bureau of Statistics (2019)
was used for Croatia. As with SOCX data, OECD data on labour market programmes for European countries are
also based on data from Eurostat. The only category for which substantial differences may exist concerns the first,
‘public employment services (PES) and administration’ (termed ‘labour market services’ by Eurostat) (OECD,
2018a). Statistics on education are usually obtained through the joint collection of education data by the UIS, the
OECD, and Eurostat, referred to as UOE data. SOCX data on health expenditures are based on the OECD Health
Statistics. For the five European countries not covered by SOCX, health expenditures are taken from ESSPROS.
10
This can partly be explained by the fact that private social expenditures, which account for roughly 40% of
overall social expenditure – one of the highest among OECD countries – are not included.
19
Table 2 Public social expenditure (% GDP), 1985-2015
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
2015
Change
1985-2015
Austria
23.2
23.2
26.4
25.9
26.1
27.7
27.7
4.4
Belgium
26.2
24.7
24.9
23.7
25.4
28.4
28.7
2.6
Denmark
19.9
22.3
25.3
24.0
25.4
28.9
28.9
9.0
Finland
21.7
23.3
28.9
22.6
23.9
27.2
30.1
8.4
France
25.9
24.9
29.1
27.7
28.8
31.1
31.9
6.0
Germany
20.0
19.1
25.3
25.5
26.4
26.1
25.0
5.1
Greece
15.4
15.7
16.6
17.8
19.9
24.9
25.3
9.9
Ireland
20.9
17.2
17.9
13.0
15.6
24.2
15.2
-5.7
Italy
21.0
21.4
22.6
24.1
27.0
28.4
Luxembourg
18.9
18.3
19.9
18.7
22.8
23.1
22.1
3.2
Netherlands
23.8
24.0
22.4
18.7
20.1
17.6
17.6
-6.2
Portugal
10.5
12.3
16.1
18.5
22.3
24.5
24.1
13.6
Spain
17.3
19.4
21.0
19.4
20.6
25.1
24.7
7.3
Sweden
26.8
27.1
30.4
26.8
27.4
26.1
26.2
-0.6
United Kingdom
18.1
14.9
16.7
15.9
18.0
21.8
21.0
2.9
Mean EU15
20.6
20.5
22.8
21.4
23.1
25.6
25.1
4.5
Standard deviation
4.5
4.2
4.8
4.3
3.7
3.2
4.6
0.1
Coefficient of variation
0.22
0.21
0.21
0.20
0.16
0.13
0.18
-0.04
Bulgaria
14.8
16.8
17.6
Croatia
20.3
20.7
Cyprus
15.3
18.6
19.6
Czech Republic
16.6
18.0
18.1
19.8
19.5
Estonia
13.0
13.0
18.2
15.8
Hungary
20.2
22.0
23.1
20.8
Latvia
13.6
12.9
19.7
15.9
Lithuania
15.0
13.7
19.4
15.9
Malta
15.7
17.6
15.5
Poland
21.1
22.2
20.5
21.0
20.7
20.3
Romania
13.5
13.7
17.7
14.6
Slovak Republic
18.7
17.6
15.8
17.9
17.7
Slovenia
21.9
21.5
23.4
22.7
Mean EU13
17.0
16.5
19.5
18.2
Standard deviation
3.4
3.4
2.0
2.6
Coefficient of variation
0.20
0.20
0.10
0.14
Non-EU
Iceland
13.3
14.8
14.5
15.8
16.4
15.1
Norway
17.2
21.6
22.5
20.4
20.7
22.0
24.8
7.6
Switzerland
13.5
12.2
14.2
14.0
15.7
15.3
16.1
2.6
United States
13.1
13.5
15.4
14.3
15.7
19.3
18.8
5.7
Notes: Total expenditures in current prices (millions of national currency) have been divided by GDP in
current prices (millions of national currency) to obtain spending as a percentage of GDP; for some
countries, data years are around 1985 (Denmark, 1986; Portugal, 1986), 1990 (Poland, 1991), 1995
(Belgium, 1994), 2000 (Estonia, 2003; Latvia, 2003; Lithuania, 2003; Romania, 2003; Slovenia,
20
2003), 2005 (Bulgaria, 2008; Cyprus, 2006; Malta, 2006), 2010 (Croatia, 2012) or 2015 (Croatia,
2014; Poland, 2014).
Source: OECD Social Expenditure Database; Eurostat ESSPROS Database, OECD Labour Database;
European Commission DG Employment, Social Affairs & Inclusion Labour Market Policy Database;
OECD Education and Training Database; Eurostat Education and Training Database; UIS Education
Database; OECD National Accounts Database; authors' calculations.
Ireland, the Netherlands, and Sweden were social expenditures lower in 2015 than in 1985, with
the sharpest decline in the Netherlands. The largest increase can be observed in Portugal where
social expenditures have been increased from 10.5% of GDP in 1985 to 24.1% in 2015. Also
within the EU13, social expenditures increased in most of the countries. Only in Malta, Poland,
and the Slovak Republic have social expenditures declined as a percentage of GDP over time.
In all four non-EU countries, social expenditures were increased.
Taken together, these trends indicate that in spite of budgetary pressure stemming from
globalization and migration, social expenditures have not been decreased. In fact, most
countries have increased the share of GDP spent on social policy. In the context of the debate
about the impact of globalization, migration, and technological change, these findings lend
support for the argument that economic insecurity stemming from structural labour market
transformations has been compensated with higher public spending on welfare state
programmes (Rodrik, 1998; Iversen and Cusack, 2000; Burgoon et al., 2012). Moreover, the
development that countries have spent larger shares of their GDP on social policy is probably
related to the increase in prosperity over the past decades (Meltzer and Richard, 1983), a catch-
up effect. Interestingly, this increase in prosperity can be partly attributed to the same structural
transformations.
Another notable pattern demonstrated by Table 2 is the trend of convergence. Between
1985 and 2010, the dispersion in social expenditures declined, indicated by the declines in the
standard deviation and coefficient of variation. This indicates that, within the EU15, social
expenditure levels converged. In earlier studies, in which this trend of convergence has been
documented as well, it has been shown that this trend of convergence is stronger within the
EU15 than in a broader group of OECD countries (Starke et al., 2008; Caminada et al., 2010;
Van Vliet, 2010). For this reason, it has been argued in these studies that this EU-specific trend
can be attributed, on the one hand, to European economic integration, which has progressed
further than international economic integration in general. On the other hand, this EU-specific
trend has been attributed to EU social policy initiatives, such as the European Employment
Strategy and the Lisbon Strategy. Interestingly, an opposite trend can be observed from 2010
21
onwards. This trend of divergence seems to be related to the incidence of the financial crisis.
The economic consequences of the crisis, for instance, in terms of unemployment and fiscal
balance, varied across countries. For this reason, but also because of different political
constellations, (social) policy responses to the crisis varied as well across countries (Starke et
al., 2014; Raess and Pontusson, 2015). This has resulted in diverging social expenditures. A
similar pattern can be observed in the EU13, where the dispersion in social expenditures has
also increased since 2010. Moreover, the gap between the mean of the EU15 and the EU13 has
not been narrowed over time. Earlier studies have shown that Western and Eastern European
countries had not converged in terms of welfare state spending (Draxler and Van Vliet, 2010).
Our data suggest that approximately a decade after the EU enlargements of 2004 and 2007,
such a trend of convergence has still not occurred.
10. Social Investment
In response to the various challenges and developments just described, an academic discourse
on the sustainability of the welfare state and future of social policy has developed since the
1990s. Several of these studies describe the rise of a so-called new welfare state, which ‘puts
the emphasis less on income replacement and more on the promotion of labour market
participation through activation and investment in human capital’ (Bonoli and Natali, 2012: 9).
In comparison to the traditional, post-war welfare state, this entails a reorientation of social
policies towards programmes aimed at activation and human capital development. The main
objective thereof is increasing the carrying capacity of the welfare state by fostering labour
market participation and preparing individuals for the new social risks of the service-based
(knowledge) economy (Esping-Andersen, 2002; Armingeon and Bonoli, 2006; Bonoli, 2013;
Hemerijck, 2013). Increased participation among women plays a central role within this. While
this increases the carrying capacity it simultaneously entails new social risks with regard to
combining work and family. Instead of a safety net, the new welfare state provides a trampoline
(Jenson and Saint-Martin, 2003) that involves policies aimed at preparing individuals, families,
and societies to respond to such new social risks (Morel et al., 2012).
New social risks can be defined as ‘the risks that people now face in the course of their
lives as a result of the economic and social changes associated with the transition to a post-
industrial society’ (Taylor-Gooby, 2004: 2). These new risks include reconciling work and
family life, single parenthood, having a frail relative, possessing low or obsolete skills, and
insufficient social insurance coverage (Bonoli, 2006). In contrast, old social risks include
unemployment, old age, ill health, sickness and disability, and the financial burden of raising
22
children (Vandenbroucke and Vlemincx, 2011). From the perspective of the new welfare state,
new social risks should be addressed by new welfare state programmes such as (child)care,
family-friendly working-time arrangements, and education.
A second dimension of the new welfare state concerns an investment dimension, which
is reflected in most of the new welfare state programmes (Vandenbroucke and Vlemincx, 2011).
Whilst old social policies predominantly concern compensating benefits that protect individuals
against old social risks associated with the loss of income, new social policies concern
capacitating benefits that are aimed at preventing such risks from materializing as well as
addressing new social risks (Häusermann, 2012; Hemerijck, 2013). Instead of passive benefits,
the new welfare state allocates public resources to investments in human capital. Most of the
new social policies are provided through services, which constitutes the third dimension
(Vandenbroucke and Vlemincx, 2011). In line with this dimension, welfare states should
become more service-oriented by prioritizing spending on in-kind benefits over spending on
cash transfers.
A specific type of new welfare state that reflects these dimensions is the social
investment state. This term was first coined by Antony Giddens (1998), who advocated a ‘Third
Way’ that synthesises ‘neoliberalism’ and the post-war welfare state through a shift from
protecting people against labour market risks to integrating them into the labour market and
creating a society of ‘responsible risk takers’. In order to achieve this, welfare expenditures
ought to be concentrated on investments in human capital, and governments should emphasise
life-long education: ‘the guideline is investment in human capital wherever possible, rather than
in the direct provision of economic maintenance. In place of the welfare state we should put the
social investment state’ (Giddens, 1998: 177, emphasis added).
Current and future challenges caused by globalization, technological change, the growth
of the services sector, and demographic changes, such as job polarization, flexibilization, and
the emergence of new social risks, and the implications for social policy associated with these
challenges have also been acknowledged and documented in EU policies (European
Commission, 2017). This has, for instance, resulted in the adoption of the European Pillar of
Social Rights in 2017 and social investment explicitly being put on the European policy agenda.
The Europe 2020 Strategy for smart, sustainable, and inclusive growth intends to lift at least 20
million people out of poverty and increase employment of the population aged 20–64 to 75%
(European Commission, 2010). To help attain this target, the European Commission launched
the Social Investment Package in 2013. In an era of economic crises and austerity, this package
constituted a series of policy measures designed to address the growing risk of poverty and
23
social exclusion. It provides a policy framework for redirecting national policies ‘towards social
investment throughout life, with a view to ensuring the adequacy and sustainability of budgets
for social policies’ by ‘investing in social policies, services and cash benefits which both
activate and enable’ (European Commission, 2013: 4, 10).
Despite the positive effects ascribed to social investment in both the academic literature
and EU policy documents, it has received substantial criticism. Realizing social inclusion
through work may, for instance, not be feasible for vulnerable groups in society (Cantillon and
Van Lancker, 2013). Given disappointing developments in poverty rates in relation to the
Europe 2020 target, some scholars have questioned whether this focus on activation and
employment has been at the expense of policies aimed at mitigating poverty and inequality
(Cantillon, 2011; Vandenbroucke and Vlemincx, 2011; Van Kersbergen and Hemerijck, 2012).
Empirical studies find limited support for such claims. Although shifts in expenditures from old
to new welfare state programmes might be related to stagnating or increasing poverty rates in
some European countries (Van Vliet and Wang, 2015), expansion of these new policies has not
been at the expense of minimum income protection benefits (Noël, 2018). This phenomenon
could potentially be explained by Matthew effects, whereby social benefits and services accrue
to the middle and high-income classes.
Such Matthew effects have been identified for public childcare subsidies for children
under 3 in Flanders (Ghysels and Van Lancker, 2011) and, to a somewhat lesser extent, for
children under 6 in other European countries (Van Lancker and Ghysels, 2014).
11
They can
predominantly be explained by supply-side issues such as limited availability and affordability,
which means that a higher degree of government involvement and more spending could address
their incidence (Van Lancker and Ghysels, 2016; Pavolini and Van Lancker, 2018). Bonoli and
Liechti (2018) have also identified Matthew effects in relation to some active labour market
policies (ALMPs). While these programmes generally focus on disadvantaged groups such as
the low-skilled and migrants, they sometimes suffer from negative access bias by requiring
preexisting skills.
11. Operationalising Social Investment
Given the new perspective on social policy and its relation to the economy that social
investment entails, it has to a large extent been formulated in terms of the reallocation of
expenditures on passive, compensating transfers to expenditures on activating and capacitating
11
Van Lancker and Ghysels (2014) do not find support for the assumption that expenditures on new policies
(childcare and parental leave) crowd out spending on traditional policies (child benefits).
24
policies. While studies contrasting new capacitating social policies to old compensating social
policies are abundant (Vandenbroucke and Vlemincx, 2011; Häusermann, 2012; Nikolai, 2012;
Hemerijck, 2013; Kuitto, 2013; Ronchi, 2018), a univocal conceptualization of the policies that
comprise social investment is absent in the literature. Nevertheless, broader definitions have
been provided by some scholars. Social investment has, for example, been summarized as a
future-oriented approach that aims to prepare, support, and equip individuals in a way that
increases their chances to participate in the knowledge-based economy and reduces their future
risks of income loss and poverty by creating, mobilizing, and preserving skills and human
capital (Garritzmann et al., 2017: 36–39). Likewise, Hemerijck (2017) identifies three
complementary functions of social investments over the life course: easing the ‘flow’ of labour
market and life-course transitions, raising the quality of the ‘stock’ of human capital, and
operating as stabilization ‘buffer’ by offering a safety net. These functions can, in turn, be linked
to a broad range of policies that reflect these functions to different extents (De Deken, 2017).
Policies that have figured centrally in studies on social investment, both descriptive and
empirical, are ALMPs and early childhood education and care (ECEC; henceforth childcare).
While descriptive studies have linked a broad range of activating and capacitating welfare state
programmes to different stages of the life course (Kvist, 2013; Kuitto, 2016), empirical studies
have tended to concentrate on ALMPs and childcare only (Bonoli, 2013; Hemerijck et al., 2016;
Noël, 2018). Others scholars have focused on aggregated groups of social policies. Some have,
for example, distinguished traditional social protection from social investment by
distinguishing between cash benefits and in-kind benefits (Ahn and Kim, 2015; Ronchi, 2018),
whereas others have distinguished between groups of old and new social policies
(Vandenbroucke and Vlemincx, 2011; Van Vliet and Wang, 2015). Nevertheless, some
empirical studies based on a disaggregated spending approach have considered additional new
social policies, such as education, maternity and parental leave, and residential care and home-
help services (Nelson and Stephens, 2012; Taylor-Gooby et al., 2015; Bakker and Van Vliet,
2019; Kim and Ahn, 2019).
We closely follow Bakker and Van Vliet (2019) in classifying welfare programmes as
social investments. Public expenditures on the following categories constitute total spending on
new social policies: residential care and home-help services for the elderly; residential care,
home-help services, and rehabilitation services for the sick, disabled, and incapacitated;
maternity and parental leave; early childhood education and care; home help and
accommodation services for families with children; active labour market policies; and primary
to tertiary education.
25
It has been debated whether spending on maternity and parental leave can be classified
as investment-oriented given that this programme also reflects a compensatory function and is
provided through cash benefits (Bonoli, 2013; De Deken, 2017). For that reason, Kuitto (2016),
for example, groups this programme under compensating rather than social investment
spending. The availability of maternity and parental leave increases the chance that people
utilise the leave period and return to their pre-childbirth job once it ends (Klerman and
Leibowitz, 1997), thereby stimulating continued labour market participation.
12
Moreover, it has
been found that maternal care throughout children’s first year of life can have a positive impact
on their development (Berger et al., 2005; Baker and Milligan, 2010). Despite being provided
as a cash benefit, these programmes do therefore reflect aspects of activation and human capital
enhancement. Moreover, they address the new social risk of combining work and care, which
has led several scholars to consider them as social investments or new social policies
(Vandenbroucke and Vlemincx, 2011; Hemerijck, 2013; Taylor-Gooby et al., 2015).
Based on the aforementioned studies, we group traditional welfare state programmes
that address traditional social risks by protecting against the loss of income, such as pensions,
sickness benefits, unemployment benefits, and minimum income benefits, under old social
policies.
13
This covers all cash pension benefits for people of old age, all cash benefits for
survivors, all cash incapacity-related benefits, cash family allowances, all cash unemployment
benefits, and all other cash benefits aimed at income maintenance.
11.1 Spending on Social Investment
Table 3 shows the development of public social expenditure on social investment-oriented new
social policies and old social policies across all EU Member States and four non-EU countries
for the period 1995–2015. In addition, it shows the ratio of spending on new social policies as
a share of total spending on both old and new policies. We have chosen to display data since
1995 because social investment has arisen throughout the 1990s and data for some of the
spending categories are only available since then. In contrast to Table 2 the sum of new and old
12
Several studies lend support for this claim and find positive employment effects associated with the provision
of leave arrangements (Ruhm [1998] for European countries, Berger and Waldfogel [2004] for the United States,
Baker and Milligan [2008] for Canada). Nevertheless, Lalive and Zweimüller (2009) found that a generous
extension of parental leave from 1 to 2 years in Austria resulted in lower and delayed returns to work. If leave
arrangements are too generous or long they might thus result in lower employment as a result of decreasing labour
market attachment (see Akgunduz and Plantenga [2013] for a meta-analysis).
13
While unemployment benefits are generally considered compensatory by providing an income transfer to smooth
consumption in case job loss occurs, they could also be seen as a job search allowance or tool to preserve or invest
in skills that increase the prospects of finding a job. This latter view has mainly been reflected in the Varieties of
Capitalism literature (e.g., Estevez-Abe et al., 2001).
26
social policies excludes the categories ‘other benefits in kind’, funeral expenses for survivors,
all housing benefits, and in-kind social assistance benefits, but additionally includes public
expenditures on primary, secondary, and tertiary education.
On average, EU15 countries spent nearly 8% of GDP on new social policies in 2015,
whereas they spent 21% of GDP on old social policies. Spending on new social policies hence
comprises slightly more than 25% of total spending on old and new social policies. While social
spending on both new and old social policies has on average increased between 2005 and 2015,
the ratio of spending on new social policies to the sum of spending on new and old social
policies has slightly decreased since 2005. EU13 countries spend considerably less on both new
and old social policies. In 2015, they spent nearly 6% of GDP on new social policies and 16%
of GDP on old social policies. While the average share of spending on new social policies in
2015 is comparable to 2005, spending on old social policies has increased relative to GDP. As
a result, the ratio of spending on new social policies to spending on the sum of new and old
social policies has fallen from approximately 29% to 27% of GDP. Although EU13 countries
allocate less resources to social policies, the share of spending on new social policies is rather
comparable to that of EU15 countries in 2015.
Nordic welfare states stand out as most generous spenders on new social policies relative
to total spending on new and old social policies. This is to a large extent due to their strong
orientation to the provision of social policy through services. In these countries, as well as in
the Netherlands and Switzerland, spending on new social policies comprise 30% or more of
total spending on new and old social policies. It is worth noting that the Baltic States and Malta
realize nearly similar levels of relative spending on new social policies. In addition, the
variability of relative spending levels on new social policies is much smaller in the new EU
Member States than in the EU15, indicated by the lower standard deviations and coefficients
of variation. In addition to the high levels of spending on new social policies in some of the
countries just mentioned, this relatively high variability amongst EU15 countries is also
attributable to the fact that the Mediterranean welfare states concentrate a substantially lower
amount (less than 20%) of their social expenditures on new social policies. Moreover, these
ratios have fallen in all of the Mediterranean welfare states over time. A potential explanation
for this could be that these countries were hit relatively hard by the economic crises since 2008.
On the one hand, this might have increased expenditures on old social policies, such as
unemployment benefits. On the other hand, austerity measures might have involved cuts in
expenditures on new social policies.
27
Table 3 Spending on new and old social policies, 1995-2015
New social policies
(% GDP)
Old social policies
(% GDP)
New / (New + Old) social
expenditure ratio
1995
2005
2015
1995
2005
2015
1995
2005
2015
Change
1995-2015
Austria
7.4
6.7
7.3
23.9
23.6
24.7
24.0
22.1
22.9
-1.1
Belgium
6.5
7.2
8.1
22.7
22.8
25.5
22.8
24.0
24.1
1.3
Denmark
13.9
14.2
14.6
16.8
17.2
19.8
45.2
45.2
42.5
-2.6
Finland
11.1
9.3
11.3
22.9
18.8
22.8
32.7
33.1
33.1
0.3
France
8.9
7.5
7.8
24.3
24.7
27.7
26.8
23.4
21.9
-4.8
Germany
6.4
6.4
6.4
22.0
22.9
21.4
22.6
21.8
23.0
0.4
Greece
3.1
4.2
3.9
15.2
19.3
24.5
16.8
18.0
13.9
-3.0
Ireland
6.8
5.7
4.9
14.1
13.2
12.9
32.7
30.3
27.4
-5.3
Italy
4.9
5.1
5.0
20.4
22.5
26.0
19.5
18.6
16.0
-3.5
Luxembourg
5.0
6.2
6.2
18.4
19.5
18.4
21.5
24.0
25.3
3.8
Netherlands
7.0
8.0
8.1
19.4
16.5
13.9
26.5
32.7
37.0
10.5
Portugal
5.1
5.8
5.6
15.1
20.8
22.6
25.2
22.0
19.9
-5.3
Spain
5.2
5.7
5.6
19.4
17.9
22.4
21.1
24.1
19.9
-1.2
Sweden
14.0
13.0
13.7
20.7
19.0
16.5
41.6
40.7
45.2
3.6
United Kingdom
4.2
6.1
6.4
13.0
14.4
17.4
25.7
29.8
27.0
1.3
Mean EU15
7.3
7.4
7.7
19.2
19.5
21.1
27.0
27.3
26.6
-0.4
Standard deviation
3.3
2.8
3.2
3.7
3.4
4.5
8.0
7.9
9.2
1.2
Coefficient of
variation
0.45
0.38
0.41
0.19
0.17
0.21
0.29
0.29
0.34
0.05
Bulgaria
5.3
5.0
12.6
15.2
29.5
24.9
Croatia
5.8
16.4
18.1
23.7
Cyprus
6.5
6.5
10.9
13.4
18.0
32.2
26.5
Czech Republic
5.4
5.1
5.2
14.3
15.7
17.1
27.4
24.4
23.1
-4.3
Estonia
5.8
6.5
13.7
11.4
14.6
33.8
32.6
Hungary
5.8
6.7
6.5
17.4
18.3
16.6
25.1
26.8
28.1
3.0
Latvia
5.8
6.8
13.1
10.9
13.0
34.8
34.2
Lithuania
5.8
5.5
11.8
11.6
13.3
33.4
29.3
Malta
6.5
6.0
12.1
13.9
13.4
31.6
31.1
Poland
5.8
6.4
6.2
20.3
19.2
18.2
22.5
24.9
25.5
3.0
Romania
4.6
3.5
11.4
11.7
13.3
28.4
20.9
Slovak Republic
5.9
5.1
5.9
16.5
13.9
15.7
26.2
26.7
27.3
1.1
Slovenia
6.7
5.9
20.3
19.7
20.6
25.4
22.4
Mean EU13
5.9
5.8
14.7
14.5
15.9
29.3
26.9
Standard deviation
0.7
0.9
3.4
3.1
2.4
3.7
4.1
Coefficient of
variation
0.12
0.15
0.23
0.21
0.15
0.13
0.15
Non-EU
Iceland
8.3
10.5
9.0
11.4
10.4
10.4
44.4
50.1
46.5
2.1
Norway
13.3
11.0
11.4
15.5
15.0
18.0
46.1
42.4
38.8
-7.3
Switzerland
6.3
7.0
6.8
12.3
13.2
13.3
33.8
34.5
33.7
-0.1
United States
4.7
5.1
4.9
13.9
14.4
17.3
25.5
26.6
22.2
-3.3
28
Notes Total expenditures in current prices (millions of national currency) have been divided by GDP in
current prices (millions of national currency) to obtain spending as a percentage of GDP; expenditures
on new social policies exclude tertiary education in Luxembourg in 1995 and 2005; for some
countries, data years for new social spending are around 1995 (Austria, 1997; Belgium, 1998;
Sweden, 1997; United Kingdom, 1997; Hungary, 1999; Poland, 1997; Iceland, 1998), 2005 (Bulgaria,
2008; Cyprus, 2006; Malta, 2006), or 2015 (Denmark, 2014; Croatia, 2014; Estonia, 2013; Poland,
2014); for some countries, data years for old social spending are around 1995 (Cyprus, 2000; Estonia,
1999; Hungary, 1999; Latvia, 1997; Lithuania, 1996; Romania, 2000; Slovenia, 1996), 2005
(Bulgaria, 2008; Croatia, 2008) or 2015 (Poland, 2014).
Source: OECD Social Expenditure Database; Eurostat ESSPROS Database; OECD Labour Database;
European Commission DG Employment, Social Affairs & Inclusion Labour Market Policy Database;
OECD Education and Training Database; Eurostat Education and Training Database; UIS Education
Database; OECD National Accounts Database; authors' calculations.
12. A Disaggregated Spending Approach to Social Investment
Although overall expenditure data provide insights into long-term trends, they do not enable
one to identify the spending priorities of welfare states in terms of specific welfare state
programmes. We therefore also use disaggregated expenditure data to examine long-term trends
in specific programmes. We concentrate on the programmes that have figured most centrally in
the literature on social investment and that are likely to offer the strongest responses to the
challenges outlined earlier: social investment-oriented ALMPs, childcare, and education.
Table 4 presents public expenditures on ALMPs as a percentage of GDP for the same
32 countries over the period 1985–2015. The table shows that EU15 countries spend a
substantially higher percentage of GDP on ALMPs than EU13 countries do. In 2015, EU15
countries on average spent 0.76% of GDP on ALMPs, whereas the average for the EU13 was
0.3%. Despite a somewhat volatile trend over time, with sharp increases in the second half of
the 1990s and following the economic crisis, average spending levels have slightly increased in
the EU15 over time. At the same time the variation in spending has decreased, which is mainly
the result of substantial decreases among some of the more generous spenders such as Belgium,
the Netherlands, and Sweden. Spending on ALMPs has hence converged to a higher level over
time.
Even though expenditures on ALMPs constitute a substantially lower per cent of GDP
in EU13 countries, spending has slightly increased over time in the majority of countries. The
variation has, however, increased. This suggest that while some countries are modestly
increasing their spending (e.g., the Czech Republic and Hungary), others have experienced
substantial decreases, particularly in recent years (e.g., Latvia, Poland, and Slovenia). These
statistics should, however, be interpreted with some caution, because expenditure-based
29
Table 4 Public expenditure on active labour market policies (ALMPs) (% GDP),
1985-2015
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
2015
Change
1985-2015
Austria
0.28
0.31
0.37
0.50
0.60
0.81
0.73
0.46
Belgium
1.16
0.80
0.92
0.83
0.65
0.72
0.71
-0.45
Denmark
1.02
1.05
1.70
1.84
1.53
2.02
2.04
1.02
Finland
0.72
0.83
1.38
0.86
0.87
1.00
0.99
0.28
France
0.59
0.71
1.17
1.17
0.90
1.13
1.00
0.41
Germany
0.56
0.77
1.16
1.25
1.12
0.90
0.63
0.07
Greece
0.15
0.18
0.38
0.23
0.07
0.23
0.22
0.07
Ireland
1.02
1.03
1.30
0.78
0.61
0.90
0.56
-0.46
Italy
0.22
0.26
0.55
0.53
0.42
0.50
Luxembourg
0.39
0.19
0.13
0.19
0.50
0.55
0.66
0.27
Netherlands
1.16
1.12
1.20
1.31
1.17
1.10
0.76
-0.41
Portugal
0.16
0.46
0.48
0.61
0.65
0.67
0.55
0.39
Spain
0.32
0.76
0.42
0.77
0.76
0.92
0.59
0.28
Sweden
1.95
1.54
2.08
1.63
1.10
1.10
1.25
-0.70
United Kingdom
0.44
0.38
0.26
0.21
0.38
0.38
0.19
-0.26
Mean EU15
0.71
0.69
0.88
0.85
0.76
0.86
0.76
0.05
Standard deviation
0.50
0.40
0.60
0.50
0.36
0.43
0.45
-0.05
Coefficient of variation
0.71
0.58
0.68
0.59
0.48
0.50
0.59
-0.12
Bulgaria
0.46
0.11
0.15
Croatia
0.21
0.42
Cyprus
0.08
0.28
0.15
Czech Republic
0.16
0.12
0.18
0.23
0.32
0.43
Estonia
0.07
0.07
0.22
0.21
Hungary
0.58
0.40
0.38
0.32
0.63
0.88
Latvia
0.12
0.21
0.56
0.14
Lithuania
0.19
0.22
0.30
0.31
Malta
0.14
0.17
0.25
Poland
0.37
0.25
0.42
0.68
0.46
Romania
0.15
0.11
0.12
Slovak Republic
0.22
0.73
0.31
0.33
0.32
0.19
Slovenia
0.26
0.29
0.50
0.24
Mean EU13
0.24
0.34
0.30
Standard deviation
0.13
0.19
0.21
Coefficient of variation
0.51
0.57
0.68
Non-EU
Iceland
0.03
0.09
0.06
0.08
0.06
0.05
Norway
0.58
0.88
1.22
0.60
0.72
0.62
0.52
-0.06
Switzerland
0.17
0.20
0.43
0.51
0.67
0.60
0.58
0.41
United States
0.27
0.21
0.17
0.15
0.12
0.13
0.09
-0.17
Notes: Total expenditures in current prices (millions of national currency) have been divided by GDP in
current prices (millions of national currency) to obtain spending as a percentage of GDP; for some
30
countries, data years are around 1985 (Denmark, 1986; Portugal, 1986), 1990 (Czech Republic, 1991;
Hungary, 1992; Slovak Republic, 1991), 2000 (Estonia, 2003; Latvia, 2003; Lithuania, 2003;
Slovenia, 2003), 2005 (Cyprus, 2006; Malta, 2006; Romania, 2006) or 2010 (Croatia, 2012).
Source: OECD Labour Database; European Commission DG Employment, Social Affairs & Inclusion Labour
Market Policy Database; OECD Social Expenditure Database; OECD National Accounts Database;
authors' calculations.
indicators are fraught with limitations. They are, for example, unable to capture institutional
characteristics of welfare programmes. In addition, variation in expenditures across or within
countries may not only reflect policy preferences, but may also stem from different
demographic compositions and economic trends such as ageing populations and unemployment
(Jensen, 2011). If the main analytical interest actually lies in policy changes, expenditures have
to be corrected for such trends. For that reason we also present ‘effort’ on specific programmes,
which constitutes expenditures corrected for the number of recipients relative to GDP per capita
in order to allow for comparison across countries and over time (cf. Vandenbroucke and
Vlemincx, 2011; Ronchi, 2016; Bakker and Van Vliet, 2019).
Most of the existing studies have used the unemployment rate or number of unemployed
as proxies to correct spending on ALMPs for the number of recipients (e.g., Van Vliet and
Koster, 2011; Kuitto, 2016). The use of unemployment rates is, however, problematic as they
are expressed as a share of the labour force. Labour force participation rates differ greatly across
countries, to a large extent due to different rates of female participation. Moreover, since
unemployment, inactivity, and employment together constitute the entire labour force, changes
in other social policies such as early retirement, higher education or part-time work might affect
the unemployment rate and thereby generate artificial changes in effort on ALMPs. Besides,
not all ALMPs are designed to facilitate labour market participation by the unemployed.
Programmes focused on sheltered employment or the provision of wage subsidies often provide
alternatives to work for people who would otherwise not participate on the labour market, for
instance due to reduced work capacity (Clasen et al., 2016). To provide a more accurate image
of the generosity of ALMPs across countries, we correct spending on specific programmes for
the number of participants in the respective programmes. These data are available from the
‘Labour Market Programmes: Expenditure and Participants’ dataset from the OECD
Employment Database and the Labour Market Policy Database of the European Commission’s
DG for Employment, Social Affairs, & Inclusion. Even though data on participant stocks are
31
available since 1998 for most European countries, they have rarely been used in scholarly
work.
14
In Table 5 we present the development of public expenditure on two groups of ALMPs
(cf. Bengtsson et al., 2017). Not all ALMPs similarly reflect social investment aspects. Bonoli
(2010, 2012) distinguishes four groups of ALMPs based on the extent to which they reflect
human capital investment and a ‘pro-market employment orientation’. Two of them, upskilling
and employment assistance, are considered social investment-oriented ALMPs. Upskilling
entails human capital investment and ‘facilitates labour market re-entry on the one hand, and
impacts positively on productivity on the other’ (Bonoli, 2012: 184). Employment assistance is
aimed at removing obstacles to labour market participation and thereby constitutes ‘a source of
savings for the public purse, but it also reduces the duration of unemployment and hence its
scarring effect on the beneficiary’ (Bonoli, 2012: 183).
The former can be operationalized through expenditures on programmes included under
the category ‘training’ in internationally comparative labour market programmes data. The
latter category comprises the spending categories public employment services (PES) and
administration, employment incentives (including job rotation schemes), sheltered and
supported employment and rehabilitation, and start-up incentives. There are no participant data
for PES and administration, however, because the expenditures included in this category relate
to participants in all the other programmes. Spending on this category is therefore not included
in expenditures on employment assistance in Table 5.
Table 5 provides a much more nuanced picture than Table 4. While expenditures on
ALMPs have risen in general, they have, on average, fallen per participant in training and
employment assistance in EU15 countries. More interestingly, expenditures per participant in
EU13 countries have increased to such an extent that these countries on average spent more
relative to GDP per capita in 2015 than EU15 countries did. Within both country groups there
are, however, substantial differences between countries. While combining expenditure data
with participant stocks might lead to better insights (Clasen et al., 2016), the data show a
surprisingly volatile pattern for some countries. This raises some questions that require further
investigation in order to determine whether this concerns an issue of data quality or whether
countries have really altered the generosity of their programmes to such extents. In addition, it
should be stressed that changes in this indicator can be caused by multiple sources, including
the level of expenditures, the number of participants, and the overall state of the economy.
14
Cronert (2019) constitutes the sole exception.
32
Table 5 Public expenditures on social investment-oriented active labour market
policies (ALMPs) per participant (% GDP per capita), 2000-2015
Training
Employment assistance
2000
2007
2015
Change
2000-2015
2000
2007
2015
Change
2000-2015
Austria
26.7
30.5
35.5
8.9
13.7
13.5
17.7
4.0
Belgium
24.4
17.3
12.6
-11.8
16.1
22.3
18.5
2.4
Denmark
71.0
37.1
59.2
-11.9
49.1
42.7
43.8
-5.3
Finland
37.9
41.4
37.7
-0.3
36.3
32.8
42.0
5.7
France
44.0
33.3
45.9
1.9
18.7
16.9
11.5
-7.2
Germany
54.5
27.8
16.8
-37.7
56.1
31.1
32.7
-23.5
Greece
13.1
41.0
15.3
2.2
8.9
39.5
22.4
13.5
Ireland
33.4
35.2
26.6
-6.7
16.6
14.8
12.7
-3.9
Italy
16.3
10.0
13.2
-3.1
14.8
16.1
19.2
4.4
Luxembourg
27.2
23.5
22.6
-4.6
8.7
11.5
11.4
2.7
Netherlands
13.4
12.9
8.6
-4.7
39.1
48.6
32.5
-6.6
Portugal
62.8
42.7
21.6
-41.2
18.1
13.5
Spain
26.4
19.1
17.1
-9.4
8.4
4.8
8.1
-0.4
Sweden
76.2
67.7
41.8
-34.4
42.4
40.3
35.0
-7.3
United Kingdom
32.4
41.1
30.6
32.3
Mean EU15
37.3
32.0
26.7
-10.6
25.7
25.7
22.9
-2.7
Standard deviation
20.3
14.6
15.0
-5.3
16.2
13.3
12.0
-4.2
Coefficient of variation
0.54
0.46
0.56
0.02
0.63
0.52
0.52
-0.11
Bulgaria
32.9
35.6
22.1
15.6
45.5
23.3
Croatia
55.4
37.0
Cyprus
23.6
7.1
22.4
22.4
Czech Republic
23.1
9.9
23.8
0.7
16.3
20.7
38.6
22.2
Estonia
34.7
39.6
6.1
19.2
Hungary
30.6
42.7
42.9
12.4
15.2
24.0
Latvia
42.8
42.0
46.3
3.5
39.2
18.5
Lithuania
37.6
35.6
49.9
12.3
34.5
27.3
Malta
7.2
12.5
29.6
17.3
Poland
37.8
75.9
25.1
22.6
Romania
39.0
14.2
2.0
-37.0
18.0
18.4
12.3
-5.8
Slovak Republic
40.4
25.0
13.3
17.7
Slovenia
8.6
14.8
33.6
25.0
21.3
17.1
Mean EU13
28.0
34.6
21.8
24.6
Standard deviation
13.3
20.7
9.3
9.9
Coefficient of variation
0.47
0.60
0.43
0.40
Non-EU
Norway
47.4
32.8
35.3
-12.1
40.0
39.1
38.3
-1.6
Switzerland
57.6
46.5
43.9
-13.7
58.6
46.2
29.2
-29.3
Notes: Total expenditures in current prices (national currency) have been divided by the number of
participants and this number was subsequently divided by GDP per capita (national currency) to
obtain spending per participant relative to GDP per capita; participant stock data are not available for
Iceland and the Unites States; for some countries, data years on training are around 2000 (Ireland,
33
1999; Luxembourg, 2001; Spain, 2003; Sweden, 2003; Czech Republic, 2002; Hungary, 2003; Latvia,
2003; Lithuania, 2003; Romania, 2003; Slovenia, 2003) or 2015 (Italy, 2014);for some countries, data
years on employment assistance are around 2000 (Ireland, 1999; Spain, 2003; Czech Republic, 2003;
Romania, 2003), 2007 (Malta, 2006) or 2015 (Italy, 2014; Slovenia, 2014).
Source: OECD Employment Database; European Commission DG Employment, Social Affairs & Inclusion
Labour Market Policy Database; OECD National Accounts Database; authors' calculations.
Figure 5 Strictness of sanction rules, 1985-2012
Notes: Original values have been multiplied by 100 to facilitate interpretation; data for the Netherlands are
available since 1997 only; data are not available for Luxembourg, Central and Eastern European welfare
states, Iceland and the United States.
Source: Knotz and Nelson (2019) and authors’ calculations.
Given the strong focus of the European social investment agenda on getting people out of
poverty by moving them into work, Vandenbroucke and Vleminckx (2011) argue that the
‘active welfare state’ might actually be a more accurate term than ‘social investment state’.
While the social investment state has gradually been developing since the 1990s, a more abrupt
activation turn also occurred in the 1990s (Clasen, 2000; Raffass, 2017). Data on activation
strategies in terms of benefit conditionality have only recently become available (Knotz and
34
Nelson, 2019). Figure 5 presents the strictness of sanction rules for 14 European and 2 non-
European countries in 1985 and 2012. It shows that sanction rules have gotten substantially
tougher since 1985. According to Knotz (2018, 2019) this trend towards greater coercion in
labour market policies can be explained through the adaption of rules and provisions in response
to the emergence of new social risks, on the one hand, and the increased need for social
protection in combination with limited resources during economic crises (such as those around
2000 and 2008), on the other. The only countries in which sanctions rules have been slightly
relaxed over time are Denmark, France, and the Netherlands.
13. Education
Together with ALMPs, policies focused on early childhood have figured most prominently in
the literature on social investment. These policies cannot only be expected to increase labour
market participation by enabling parents to reconcile work and family (see Akgunduz and
Plantenga [2018] for a meta-analysis), but to stimulate cognitive development of children as
well (Burger, 2010). In addition to education during early childhood, initial education and post-
initial education during working life can both be expected to have a positive effect on the quality
of a county’s labour force. The modernization of education systems and expansion of lifelong
learning programmes has been identified by the European Commission (2017) as one of the
most important mechanisms to address the challenges that go hand in hand with globalization,
technological change, and the growth of the services sector. The right to ‘quality and inclusive
education, training and life-long learning in order to maintain and acquire skills that enable
[one] to participate fully in society and manage successfully transitions in the labour market’ is
even mentioned as very first in the European Pillar of Social Rights. Participation in education
at a later age has become particularly relevant given that some jobs will become obsolete and
the (routine-based) skills that go with them outdated. Workers are therefore confronted with the
need to continuously adapt their skills or acquire new ones.
In Table 6 we show the development of public expenditure on education since 1995.
15
Educational expenditures can be distinguished into expenditures on core and peripheral
educational goods and services, on the one hand, and expenditures on educational institutions
and outside educational institutions, on the other. Public expenditures on education cover all of
15
Internationally comparative data on education spending by level are usually only available since the introduction
of ISCED 1997. For that reason, the data we present with regard to education do not extend as far back in the past
as data on social expenditure.
35
these categories (OECD, 2018b).
16
Data until 2011 are according to ISCED 1997, whereas data
for 2012–2016 are according to ISCED 2011.
17
To guarantee comparability over time, spending
data after 2011 exclude expenditures on ISCED 2011 level 01 (early childhood educational
development). This constitutes a new category of early childhood education related to
educational content for children in the age range of 0–2. This category did not exist under
ISCED 1997, which only covered pre-primary education (designed for children from the age of
3 to the start of primary education; ISCED 1997 level 0; ISCED 2011 level 02).
18
On average, expenditures on education as a per cent of GDP have increased in EU15
countries over time, although a drop can be observed after 2010 as a result of which the overall
increase is rather small. As with social expenditures a trend of convergence can be observed
until 2010, whereas a trend of divergence can be observed throughout more recent years. Again,
Mediterranean countries are the lowest spenders on education among the EU15 whilst the
Nordic countries stand out as the most generous spenders by allocating approximately 7% of
their GDP to education. When excluding these countries, EU13 and the other EU15 countries
display similar levels of education expenditure around 5% of GDP.
Despite moderate increases throughout the first decade of the 21st century, spending
levels in EU13 countries in 2015 are comparable to those in 2000. Nevertheless, both the
standard deviation and coefficient of variation have decreased over time. This convergence is
mainly the result of the catch-up among some of the rather low spenders like Bulgaria, Croatia,
the Czech Republic, and the Slovak Republic. With 3.1% of GDP, Romania was also the
country with the lowest educational expenditures in 2015.
As with expenditure on ALMPs, we also provide spending figures per recipient. Instead
of focusing on total education expenditure, we concentrate on expenditures for and of
educational institutions (e.g., Busemeyer, 2009b). Specifically, we use expenditure on
educational institutions per full-time equivalent (FTE) pupil or student as a share to GDP per
capita, which provides an assessment of the investments made in each student, taking into
16
In addition to spending on teaching staff, school buildings, schoolbooks, and teaching materials this also
includes, for example, spending on research and development; school meals; transport to schools; housing on
campus; and public-to-private transfers such as loans for tuition and student living costs and subsidies for student
living costs, reduced transport fares, private spending on school materials, and private tutoring.
17
The presented figures for Latvia (1995–2015) and Lithuania (2000–2015) are also according to ISCED 2011.
Data according to this classification were provided retrospectively by the OECD, whereas data according to ISCED
1997 are not available from the OECD database used for the other OECD countries.
18
Currently, ISCED 01 programmes are in place in approximately half of the countries considered: Austria,
Belgium (Flanders), Denmark, Finland, Germany, Greece, Italy, Spain, Sweden, the United Kingdom, Croatia,
Cyprus, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Romania, Slovenia, Iceland, and Norway. For a country-by-country
overview, see European Commission, Education, Audiovisual and Culture Executive Agency (EACEA) and
Eurydice (2019).
36
Table 6 Public expenditure on education (% GDP), 1995-2015
1995
2000
2005
2010
2015
Change 1995-2015
Austria
6.1
5.6
5.2
5.7(b)
5.4
-0.7
Belgium
5.0
5.8
6.4
6.5
Denmark
7.7
8.1
8.1
8.6(b)
8.8
1.0
Finland
6.5
5.7
6.0
6.5(b)
6.7
0.2
France
5.8
5.5
5.5
5.7
5.5
-0.3
Germany
4.5
4.3
4.4
4.9
4.6
0.1
Greece
2.9
3.3
4.0
3.6
3.6
0.7
Ireland
4.7
4.1
4.5
6.0
3.8
-0.9
Italy
4.3
4.4
4.2
4.3
4.1
-0.3
Luxembourg
3.6
4.3
3.9
0.3
Netherlands
4.8
4.6
4.8
5.5
5.3
0.6
Portugal
4.9
5.2
5.1
5.4
4.9
0.0
Spain
4.4
4.2
4.1
4.9(b)
4.2
-0.2
Sweden
7.1
6.8
6.5
6.5(b)
6.9
-0.1
United Kingdom
3.9
3.8
4.6
5.5
5.4
1.4
Mean EU15
5.1
5.0
5.2
5.6
5.3
0.2
Standard deviation
1.4
1.3
1.1
1.2
1.4
0.1
Coefficient of variation
0.27
0.25
0.22
0.21
0.27
0.00
Bulgaria
3.4
3.9
4.3
4.1
3.9
0.5
Croatia
3.7
4.0
4.3
4.4
Cyprus
4.6
5.4
7.0
7.9
6.2
1.5
Czech Republic
4.0
3.7
3.9
4.1
5.8
1.7
Estonia
5.8
5.5
4.8
5.5
4.8
-1.0
Hungary
4.5
4.9
5.3
4.8
4.5
0.0
Latvia
6.0
6.2
4.8
5.1
5.3
-0.7
Lithuania
5.1
5.6
4.9
5.3
4.2
-0.9
Malta
4.5
6.6
6.7
5.1
Poland
5.3
4.8
5.4
5.1
4.8
-0.5
Romania
2.9
3.5
3.5
3.1
Slovak Republic
3.9
3.7
3.9
4.6
Slovenia
5.8
5.7
5.5
4.6
Mean EU13
4.7
4.9
5.1
4.7
Standard deviation
1.0
1.1
1.2
0.8
Coefficient of variation
0.22
0.22
0.24
0.17
Non-EU
Iceland
6.4
7.4
7.0
6.9
Norway
7.4
6.5
6.9
6.7(b)
6.9
-0.4
Switzerland
5.0
4.8
5.2
4.9
5.1
0.1
United States
5.1
4.7
4.9
5.3
4.8
5.0
Notes: Total expenditures in current prices (millions of national currency) have been divided by GDP in
current prices (millions of national currency) to obtain spending as a percentage of GDP for most
countries; for Bulgaria, Croatia, Cyprus, Malta and Romania percentages were directly copied from
Eurostat; the presented figures for Estonia (1995, 2000), Lithuania (1995) and Slovenia (2001) are
37
estimates based on the development of percentages directly available from Eurostat.
To guarantee comparability over time spending on ISCED 2011 level 01 is excluded, because this
category was not included in ISCED 1997; for Denmark and Lithuania, expenditures on ISCED 2011
level 01 cannot be distinguished from expenditures on level 02 and are hence included; the presented
figure for Croatia (2015) concerns expenditures on public educational institutions, because public
expenditures on education are not available after 2011.
For some countries there is a break in the time series between 2011 and 2012 following the
introduction of ISCED 2011 as a result of which spending on pre-primary education before and after
2011 cannot be compared (Austria, Denmark, Finland, Spain, Sweden, and Norway).
For most countries data according to ISCED 1997 are available since 1997 only (Austria, Denmark,
Finland, France, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United
Kingdom); for some countries, data years are around 2000 (Croatia, 2002; Slovenia, 2001), 2010
(Greece, 2012; Luxembourg, 2012) or 2015 (Denmark, 2014; Croatia, 2014; Estonia, 2013; Slovak
Republic, 2014).
Source: OECD Education Database; Eurostat Education and Training Database; OECD National Accounts
Database; authors' calculations.
account the relative wealth of countries (OECD, 2019d). As is customary in the literature, we
distinguish between spending on pre-primary, primary, secondary (comprising lower
secondary, upper secondary and post-secondary non-tertiary education), and tertiary education
(e.g., Garritzmann and Seng, 2016).
19
For OECD countries these percentages are generally directly available for 2012–2016
for pre-primary education and 2005–2015 for primary and secondary education as well as
tertiary education. Eurostat provides similar percentages for: primary and lower secondary;
upper secondary, and post-secondary non-tertiary education; and tertiary education. Coverage
for some countries extents back into the 1990s.
20
The OECD data were preferred over Eurostat
data. The latter were only used for country-years not covered by the OECD data. For some
country years, notably spending per FTE pupil enrolled in pre-primary education in 1995 and
2005, figures were calculated. This was done by dividing total expenditure on educational
institutions at the respective level by the corresponding FTE enrolment. Next, expenditure per
pupil or student was divided by GDP per capita.
21
19
Note that spending on pre-primary education is not exactly the same as spending on childcare. In the SOCX
data, childcare (ECEC) additionally includes spending on child (day)care and other pre-school services. Spending
on pre-primary education, however, constitutes the lion’s share of total spending on ECEC.
20
To obtain expenditures per FTE student in primary and secondary education, the two percentages were weighted
by the relative shares of students enrolled in the two groups.
21
Note that expenditure and enrolment data often do not refer to the same period. The former usually refer to the
calendar year (except for the United Kingdom and United States), whereas the latter generally refer to the calendar
(pre-primary education only) or school year (usually September yeart-1 to August yeart). The OECD implements
several adjustments on a country-by-country basis to ensure that student numbers coincide with the financial year
(OECD, 2018b). Enrolment rates adjusted to the financial year are, however, only available since 2002 from the
OECD and 2012 from Eurostat. These adjustment have therefore not been implemented in the calculations for the
1995 figures (and 2005 for Bulgaria, Croatia, Cyprus, Latvia, Lithuania, and Romania). Any biases associated
with this are likely to be small as these calculations predominantly pertain to expenditure on pre-primary education,
38
Table 7 shows that, on average, expenditures per pupil on pre-primary and primary and
secondary educational institutions have increased in EU15 countries, whereas expenditures on
tertiary educational institutions per student have somewhat decreased. In EU13 countries,
expenditures per primary and secondary pupil have increased as well, but expenditures for
pupils in pre-primary educational institutions and students in tertiary educational institutions
decreased. Furthermore, it is worth noting that EU15 and EU13 countries on average invest
rather similar shares of GDP per capita in their pupils and students. Nonetheless, spending on
pupils in pre-primary education has traditionally been somewhat higher in the new EU Member
States. There is, however, a lot of variation within these two groups of countries as well as
within countries over time.
14. Conclusion
In this chapter, we presented the trends of globalization, technological change, and migration
as three key challenges for European labour markets and welfare states in the 21st century. In
particular globalization and technological change have been regarded as important sources of
inequality between different groups in the labour market as these developments have been
mainly beneficial for the employment opportunities and incomes of highly skilled workers. The
more recent literature mainly considers the automation of routine-intense tasks as an important
explanation for current labour market developments and in particular for the trend of job
polarization. Whereas the existing literature has been mainly focused on the question of what
types of work will (dis)appear, for what types of workers, and in which sectors, we argue that
globalization and technological change, via job polarization, also affect the type of contract
under which workers operate. The figures presented here show that the share of middle-skilled
workers in low-paying jobs has increased in many European countries. At the same time, in
many of these countries, the share of nonstandard employment has increased over time. Hence,
we hypothesise that the increased competition for low-paying jobs is associated with the rise of
nonstandard employment or, in other words, with labour market flexibilization. Interestingly,
this hypothesis seems to have implications for both the policy agenda and the research agenda
of the coming decade. For academic research, the implication would be that there is an
additional outcome variable in the analyses of globalization and technological change. In
addition, job polarization and the rise of nonstandard employment may also have implications
for market income distribution, which would be an interesting direction for future research.
Moreover, the public policy debate regarding the consequences of globalization and
which generally uses headcounts instead of FTEs (OECD, 2018d).
39
Table 7 Expenditures on educational institutions per full-time equivalent (FTE) pupil or student by level (% GDP per capita)
Pre-primary education
Primary and secondary education
Tertiary education
1995
2005
2015
Change
1995-2015
1995
2005
2015
Change
1995-2015
1995
2005
2015
Change
1995-2015
Austria
19.0
18.7(b)
18.8
-0.1
31.0
27.2
27.8
-3.3
40.5
44.4
35.0
-5.5
Belgium
11.1
14.1
17.4
6.3
21.8
22.7
26.1
4.3
36.5
36.7
37.9
1.5
Denmark
22.1
15.3(b)
23.9
1.8
27.2
26.1
26.7
-0.5
44.5
43.5
32.5
-12.0
Finland
33.5
13.9(b)
25.2
-8.2
25.3
20.7
23.8
-1.5
53.0
38.5
41.7
-11.3
France
15.1
16.2
19.2
4.1
24.4
23.9
24.3
-0.1
31.6
36.6
39.7
8.1
Germany
17.1
17.9
20.4
3.3
25.1
22.1
22.5
-2.6
41.6
40.9
35.4
-6.2
Greece
–
–
19.6
11.9
20.9
23.1
11.2
20.0
24.7
15.3
-4.7
Ireland
12.4
13.3
12.7
0.4
15.0
15.8
12.6
-2.4
25.5
25.9
19.2
-6.3
Italy
11.7
16.3
17.1
5.4
22.3
23.6
24.6
2.3
23.4
24.2
30.8
7.4
Luxembourg
–
15.8
17.1
15.3
20.6
19.9
4.6
47.6
Netherlands
13.3
15.8
16.7
3.4
18.6
20.6
21.9
3.2
50.2
40.9
38.5
-11.7
Portugal
6.0
15.2
24.1
18.1
18.8
24.7
28.9
10.1
40.6
42.3
39.9
-0.7
Spain
17.0
18.4(b)
18.9
2.0
21.8
22.7
23.5
1.7
32.8
35.5
36.2
3.4
Sweden
13.7
13.9(b)
29.5
15.8
25.2
22.5
22.9
-2.3
63.3
45.6
50.7
-12.6
United Kingdom
24.3
18.0
21.8
-2.5
16.2
24.6
26.9
10.7
36.3
44.1
64.1
27.8
Mean EU15
16.6
15.9
20.2
3.5
21.3
22.6
23.7
2.4
38.6
37.4
37.6
-0.9
Standard deviation
7.0
1.8
4.2
-2.8
5.3
2.7
3.9
-1.4
11.9
7.5
11.7
-0.2
Coefficient of variation
0.42
0.11
0.21
-0.21
0.25
0.12
0.16
-0.08
0.31
0.20
0.31
0.00
Bulgaria
27.6
25.6
25.0
-2.6
17.5
19.1
17.8
0.3
48.3
43.3
37.2
-11.1
Croatia
26.4
30.1
20.1
21.3
38.8
21.3
Cyprus
11.0
15.8
16.9
5.9
25.8
31.8
39.6
13.9
59.9
41.6
41.1
-18.8
Czech Republic
17.2
15.1
14.8
-2.4
19.6
18.4
21.1
1.5
36.0
29.9
32.5
-3.5
Estonia
10.8
22.4
22.5
22.9
23.3
44.2
Hungary
19.9
24.7
26.1
6.3
20.8
23.1
22.7
1.9
56.6
32.4
33.5
-23.1
Latvia
34.5
22.3
19.0
-15.5
24.6
24.1
22.4
-2.2
39.5
27.0
29.7
-9.8
Lithuania
37.6
22.6
19.1
-18.4
20.8
17.0
18.5
-2.3
49.1
31.3
33.7
-15.4
Malta
15.2
21.3
26.5
26.0
42.0
50.5
51.5
9.5
40
Poland
17.6
27.9
23.4
5.8
17.5
22.4
25.3
7.8
35.3
41.1
36.4
1.1
Romania
19.2
12.4
15.5
13.8
30.2
30.7
Slovak Republic
15.8
17.3
19.6
3.8
13.1
16.7
22.8
9.7
42.2
35.2
53.6
11.4
Slovenia
47.1
24.9
29.5
26.7
35.8
32.4
Mean EU13
22.3
21.1
22.1
23.2
35.4
36.8
Standard deviation
9.1
4.9
5.0
6.1
7.5
8.9
Coefficient of variation
0.41
0.23
0.23
0.26
0.21
0.24
Non-EU
Iceland
16.1
18.4
25.2
9.1
20.3
23.8
22.9
2.5
30.6
25.7
25.9
-4.7
Norway
10.9(b)
27.7
26.8
27.5
38.6
32.4
40.2
1.6
Switzerland
8.2
8.8
9.7
1.4
21.0
21.1
29.0
8.0
49.6
40.7
42.7
-6.9
United States
21.4
19.4
19.4
-2.0
21.3
22.7
22.5
1.2
56.2
54.8
53.6
-2.6
Notes: Expenditure concerns expenditure of and for public and private educational institutions from public, private and international sources; pre-primary education refers
to ISCED 2011 level 01 (ISCED 1997 level 0) exclusively; primary and secondary education includes post-secondary non-tertiary education.
In Greece (until 2012) and Luxembourg (until 2008) expenditures on pre-primary education are included under primary education; underlined figures include
expenditures on and pupils enrolled in pre-primary education.
Figures in italics were calculated by dividing expenditures in current prices (national currency) by the number of students enrolled in the respective level and
subsequently relating this number to GDP per capita; the presented figures for Malta (2005) and Romania (2005) seem to overestimate expenditures, because they
may include educational expenditures not allocated to a specific level.
For most countries expenditures on pre-primary educational institutions are not available for 1995 so that data for 1994 has been used instead (Austria, Belgium,
Denmark, Finland, France, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, United Kingdom, Czech Republic); for some countries, data years for expenditure on pre-
primary education are around 1995 (Bulgaria, 1999; Cyprus, 1999; Hungary, 1997; Latvia, 1998; Lithuania, 1998; Poland, 1999; Slovak Republic, 1999; Iceland,
1998; Switzerland, 1999), 2005 (Luxembourg, 2008; Croatia, 2007; Malta, 2008; Switzerland, 2008) or 2015 (Denmark, 2014; Ireland, 2014; Croatia, 2014;
Switzerland 2012).
For some countries, data years for expenditure on primary and secondary education are around 1995 (Luxembourg, 1996; Bulgaria, 1999; Cyprus, 1999; Hungary,
1996; Latvia, 1998; Lithuania, 1998; Poland, 1999; Slovak Republic, 1998; Iceland, 1998; Switzerland, 1999), 2005 (Luxembourg, 2008; Croatia, 2007;
Switzerland, 2008) or 2015 (Denmark, 2014; Croatia, 2014; Switzerland 2012).
For some countries, data years for expenditure on tertiary education are around 1995 (Ireland, 1999; Italy, 1997; Bulgaria, 1999; Czech Republic, 1997; Hungary,
1997; Latvia, 1996; Poland, 1999; Slovak Republic, 1998; Iceland, 1998; Norway, 1999; Switzerland, 1999), 2005 (Croatia, 2007; Switzerland, 2008) or 2015
(Denmark, 2014; Croatia, 2014; Switzerland 2012).
For some countries there is a break in the time series between 2011 and 2012 following the introduction of ISCED 2011 as a result of which spending on pre-
primary education before and after 2011 cannot be compared (Austria, Denmark, Finland, Spain, Sweden, and Norway).
Source: OECD Education Database; Eurostat Education and Training Database; OECD National Accounts Database; authors' calculations.
41
technological change should not only be focused on the growth of certain sectors and the decline
of other sectors, but it should also be focused on the trends in nonstandard employment and
hence on the type of contract.
With regard to migration, the free movement of labour has been considered an important
issue for European labour markets and welfare states. We have shown that, since 2004, the
intra-EU labour migration from CEE countries to Western European countries has increased
substantially. Free movement of labour is economically important for the European Union as it
can reduce labour market imbalances, which is especially important for the functioning of the
Eurozone. At the same time, it has been considered a challenge for welfare states as it might
contribute to feelings of economic insecurity and erode solidarity, which forms the basis for the
provision of social policy.
Subsequently, we have analysed developments in the provision of welfare state
programmes across European countries. Interestingly, it turns out that, despite the budgetary
pressure stemming from various sources, social spending has been increased in most European
countries. However, in the 21st century, the main question will not be whether governments
have increased or decreased their welfare state expenditures. Instead, the question will be
whether and how the focus has been shifted from classical social protection to social investment
in order to enable workers to adapt themselves to new labour market transformations. In the
past decade, such welfare state reforms have been at the core of the EU agenda on social policy.
Yet this policy agenda is not uncontroversial, as some fear that a shift of resources from social
protection to social investment would reduce the redistributing capacity of welfare states and
hence contribute to an increase of income inequality and poverty.
To analyse the developments in welfare state effort, we present a new way of correcting
social expenditures for the actual number of benefit recipients. So far, our data show that in
many countries the shift from old to new social policies has been rather limited at best. Here, it
might play a role that a substantial number of our data years overlap with the financial crisis.
Breunig and Busemeyer (2012) have for instance argued that investment spending is harder hit
by austerity measures than spending on traditional insurance-based programmes due to different
institutional and political constraints. If policymakers are confronted by budgetary constraints,
postponing or cutting public investments involves lower political costs than adjusting spending
on traditional programmes. This is also reflected in public survey data, which shows that
support for social investment policies drops when expenditures on it come into conflict with
fiscal or budgetary trade-offs (Busemeyer and Garritzman, 2017; Busemeyer and Neimanns,
2017). This brings us to the more general question of how, given political and economic
42
constraints, a transformation from traditional social policy to social investment policies could
be realized. On the one hand, increasing numbers of policymakers and academics seem to be
convinced that investments in human capital, training, and active labour market policy would
be (part of) an adequate response to the labour market challenges of globalization, technological
change, and flexibilization. On the other hand, it seems to be challenging, at least in the short
run, to get support from voters and hence from political parties to shift resources from
traditional income protection programmes to new social investment programmes.
43
References
Acemoglu, D. (1999). Changes in Unemployment and Wage Inequality: An Alternative Theory
and Some Evidence. American Economic Review, 89(5): 1259-1278.
Acemoglu, D., and Autor, D. (2010). Skills, Tasks and Technologies: Implications for
Employment and Earnings. NBER Working Paper No. 16082. Cambridge: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Acemoglu, D., Autor, D., Dorn, D., Hanson, G. and Price, B. (2016). Import competition and
the great US employment sag of the 2000s. Journal of Labor Economics, 34(S1): S141-
S198.
Adema W. and Fron, P. (2019). The OECD SOCX Manual – 2019 Edition. A guide to the
OECD Social Expenditure Database. Paris. OECD.
Ahn, S.-H. and Kim, S.-W. (2015). Social investment, social service and the economic
performance of welfare states. International Journal of Social Welfare, 24(1): 109-119.
Akgunduz, Y.E. and Plantenga, J. (2013). Labour market effects of parental leave in Europe.
Cambridge Journal of Economics, 37(4): 845-862.
Akgunduz, Y.E. and Plantenga, J. (2018). Child Care Prices and Maternal Employment: A
Meta-analysis. Journal of Economic Surveys, 32(1): 118-133.
Alesina, A. and Glaeser, E.L. (2004). Fighting poverty in the US and Europe: A world of
difference. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Alesina, A., Glaeser, E.L., and Sacerdote, B. (2001). Why Doesn’t the United States Have a
European-Style Welfare State? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 187-277.
Armingeon, K. and Bonoli, G. (eds.) (2006). The Politics of Post-Industrial Welfare States:
Adapting post-war social policies to new social risks. London: Routledge.
Atkinson, A.B. (2007). The distribution of earnings in OECD countries. International Labour
Review, 146(1): 41-60.
Autor, D. and Dorn, D. (2013). The Growth of Low-skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of
the US Labor Market. American Economic Review, 103(5): 1553-1597.
Autor, D., Dorn, D. and Hanson, G. (2013). The China syndrome: Local labor market effects
of import competition in the United States. American Economic Review, 103(6): 2121-
2168.
Autor, D., Dorn, D. and Hanson, G. (2015). Untangling trade and technology: Evidence from
local labor markets. Economic Journal, 125(584): 621-646.
Autor, D., Katz, L.F. and Kearney, M.S. (2006). The Polarization of the US Labor Market.
American Economic Review, 96(2): 189-94.
Autor, D., Levy, F. and Murnane, R.J. (2003). The Skill Content of Recent Technological
Change: An Empirical Exploration. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4): 1279-1333.
Baker, M. and Milligan, K. (2008). How does Job-Protected Maternity Leave Affect Mothers’
Employment? Journal of Labor Economics, 26(4): 655-691.
Baker, M. and Milligan, K. (2010). Evidence from Maternity Leave Expansions on the Impact
of Maternal Care on Early Child Development. Journal of Human Resources, 45(1): 1-
32.
44
Bakker, V. and Van Vliet, O. (2019). Social Investment, Employment Outcomes and Policy
and Institutional Complementarities: A Comparative Analysis across 26 OECD
Countries. Department of Economics Research Memorandum 2019.01. Leiden: Leiden
University Press.
Balsvik, R., Jensen, S. and Salvanes, K. (2015). Made in China, sold in Norway: Local labor
market effects of an import shock. Journal of Public Economics, 127: 137-144.
Bengtsson, M., De la Porte, C. and Jacobsson, K. (2017). Labour Market Policy under
Conditions of Permanent Austerity: Any Sign of Social Investment? Social Policy &
Administration, 51(2): 367-388.
Berger, L.M. and Waldfogel, J. (2004). Maternal leave and the employment of new mothers in
the United States. Journal of Population Economics, 17(2): 331-349.
Berger, L.M., Hill, J. and Waldfogel, J. (2005). Maternity Leave, Early Maternal Employment
and Child Health and Development in the US. Economic Journal, 115(501): 29-47.
Berman, E., Bound, J. and Machin, S. (1998). Implications of Skill-Biased Technological
Change: International Evidence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(4): 1245-1279.
Bloom, N., Draca, M. and Van Reenen, J. (2016). Trade induced technical change? The impact
of Chinese imports on diffusion, innovation, and productivity. Review of Economic
Studies, 83(1): 87-117.
Boeri, T. (2010). Immigration to the Land of Redistribution. Economica, 77(308): 651-687.
Bonoli, G. (2006). New social risks and the politics of post-industrial social policies, pp. 3-26
in: K. Armingeon, and G. Bonoli (eds.), The Politics of Post-Industrial Welfare States:
Adapting post-war social policies to new social risks. London: Routledge.
Bonoli, G. (2010). The Political Economy of Active Labor-Market Policy. Politics & Society,
38(4): 435-457.
Bonoli, G. (2012). Active labour market policy and social investment: a changing relationship,
pp. 181-204 in: N. Morel, B. Palier and J. Palme (eds.), Towards a Social Investment
Welfare State? Ideas, Policies and Challenges. (pp. 181-204). Bristol: Policy Press.
Bonoli, G. (2013). The Origins of Active Social Policy: Labour Market and Childcare Policies
in a Comparative Perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bonoli, G. and Liechti, F. (2018). Good intentions and Matthew effects: access biases in
participation in active labour market policies. Journal of European Public Policy, 25(6): 894-
911.
Bonoli, G. and Natali, D. (eds.) (2012). The Politics of the New Welfare State. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Brady, D., and Finnigan, R. (2014). Does immigration undermine public support for social
policy? American Sociological Review, 79(1): 17-42.
Brady, D., Beckfield, J. and Seeleib-Kaiser, M. (2005). Economic globalization and the welfare
state in affluent democracies, 1975-2001. American Sociological Review, 70(6): 921-948.
Breunig, C. and Busemeyer, M.R. (2012). Fiscal austerity and the trade-off between public
investment and social spending. Journal of European Public Policy, 19(6): 921-938.
45
Burger, K. (2010). How does early childhood care and education affect cognitive development?
An international review of the effects of early interventions for children from different
social backgrounds. Early childhood research quarterly, 25(2): 140-165.
Burgoon, B., Koster, F. and Van Egmond, M. (2012). Support for redistribution and the paradox
of immigration. Journal of European Social Policy, 22(3): 288-304.
Busemeyer, M.R. (2009a). From myth to reality: Globalisation and public spending in OECD
countries revisited. European Journal of Political Research, 48(4): 455-482.
Busemeyer, M.R. (2009b). Social democrats and the new partisan politics of public investment
in education. Journal of European Public Policy, 16(1): 107-126.
Busemeyer, M.R. and Garritzmann, J.L. (2017). Public opinion on policy and budgetary trade-
offs in European welfare states: evidence from a new comparative survey. Journal of
European Public Policy, 24(6): 871-889.
Busemeyer, M.R. and Neimanns, E. (2017). Conflictive preferences towards social investments
and transfers in mature welfare states: The cases of unemployment benefits and childcare
provision. Journal of European Social Policy, 27(3): 229-246.
Caminada, K., Goudswaard, K. and Van Vliet, O. (2010). Patterns of Welfare State Indicators
in the EU: Is There Convergence? Journal of Common Market Studies, 48(3): 529-556.
Cantillon, B. (2011). The paradox of the social investment state: growth, employment and
poverty in the Lisbon era. Journal of European Social Policy, 21(5): 432-449.
Cantillon, B. and Van Lancker, W. (2013). Three Shortcomings of the Social Investment
Perspective. Social Policy and Society, 12(4): 553-564.
Clasen, J. (2000). Motives, means and opportunities: Reforming unemployment compensation
in the 1990s. West European Politics, 23(2): 89-112.
Clasen, J., Clegg, D. and Goerne, A. (2016). Comparative Social Policy Analysis and Active
Labour Market Policy: Putting Quality before Quantity. Journal of Social Policy, 45(1):
21-38.
Cortes, G. (2016). Where Have the Middle-Wage Workers Gone? A Study of Polarization
Using Panel Data. Journal of Labor Economics, 34(1): 63-105.
Croatian Bureau of Statistics (2019). Social Protection in the Republic of Croatia, 2017. Zagreb:
Croatian Bureau of Statistics.
Cronert, A. (2019). Unemployment reduction or labor force expansion? How partisanship
matters for the design of active labor market policy in Europe. Socio-Economic Review,
17(4): 921-946.
Davis, S. (1992). Cross-Country Patterns of Change in Relative Wages. In: O.J. Blanchard and
S. Fischer (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual, (Vol. 7) (pp. 239-292). Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
De Deken, J. (2017). Conceptualizing and Measuring Social Investment. In: A. Hemerijck (ed.),
The Uses of Social Investment (pp. 185-194). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Draxler, J. and Van Vliet, O. (2010). European Social Model: No Convergence From the East.
Journal of European Integration, 32(1): 115-135.
Eger, M.A. (2010). Even in Sweden: The Effects of Immigration on Support for Welfare State
Spending. European Sociological Review, 26(2): 203-217.
46
Esping-Andersen, G. (ed.) 2002. Why We Need a New Welfare State. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Estevez-Abe, M., Iversen, T. and Soskice, D. (2001). Social Protection and the Formation of
Skills: A Reinterpretation of the Welfare State. In: P.A. Hall and D. Soskice (eds.), The
Varieties of Capitalism; The institutional foundations of comparative advantage (pp. 145-
183). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Eurofound (2014). Labour mobility in the EU: Recent trends and policies. Dublin: Eurofound.
Eurofound (2019). Labour market segmentation: Piloting new empirical policy analysis.
Dublin: Eurofound.
European Commission (2010). Europe 2020. A European strategy for smart, sustainable and
inclusive growth. Brussels: European Commission.
European Commission (2013). Towards Social Investment for Growth and Cohesion -
Including Implementing the European Social Fund 2014-2020. Brussels: European
Commission.
European Commission (2017). Reflection Paper on the Social Dimension of Europe. Brussels:
European Commission.
European Commission (2018). Employment and Social Development in Europe – Annual
Review 2018. Brussels: European Commission.
European Commission, EACEA and Eurydice. (2019) Key Data on Early Childhood Education
and Care in Europe – 2019 Edition. Luxembourg.
Eurostat (2016). European system of integrated social protection statistics - ESSPROS manual
and user guidelines 2016 edition. Luxembourg: Authors.
Eurostat. (2016). European system of integrated social protection statistics—ESSPROS manual
and user guidelines 2016 edition. Luxembourg; Eurostat.
Fajgelbaum, P. and Khandelwal, A. (2016). Measuring the unequal gains from trade. Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 131(3): 1113-1180.
Fenwick, C. (2019). The political economy of immigration and welfare state effort: evidence
from Europe. European Political Science Review, 11(3): 357-375.
Fenwick, C. and Van Vliet, O. (2019). Immigration and EU welfare states: does the type of
migration matter? Mimeo. Leiden: Leiden University Press.
Fernández-Macías, E., and Hurley, J. (2016). Routine-biased technical change and job
polarization in Europe. Socio-Economic Review, 15(3): 563-585.
Fitzenberger, B. and Kohn, K. (2006). Skill Wage Premia, Employment, and Cohort Effects:
Are Workers in Germany All of the Same Type? IZA Discussion Paper No. 2185. Bonn:
Institute for the Study of Labor.
Garrett, G. and Mitchell, D. (2001). Globalization, government spending and taxation in the
OECD. European Journal of Political Research, 39(2): 145-177.
Garritzmann, J., Häusermann, S., Palier, B. and Zollinger, C. (2017). The World Politics of
Social Investment. LIEPP Working Paper No. 64. Paris: Sciences Po.
Garritzmann, J.L. and Seng, K. (2016). Party politics and education spending: Challenging
some common wisdom. Journal of European Public Policy, 23(4): 510-530.
47
Gaston, N. and Rajaguru, G. (2013). International migration and the welfare state revisited.
European Journal of Political Economy 29(1): 90-101.
Ghysels, J. and Van Lancker, W. (2011). The unequal benefits of activation: An analysis of the
social distribution of family policy among families with young children. Journal of European
Public Policy, 21(5): 472-485.
Giddens, A. (1998). The Third Way: The Renewal of Social Democracy, Cambridge, MA:
Polity Press.
Goldin, C. and Katz, L.F. (2009). The Race between Education and Technology. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press.
Goos, M. (2018). The impact of technological progress on labour markets: Policy challenges.
Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 34(3): 362-375.
Goos, M. and Manning, A. (2007). Lousy and Lovely Jobs: The Rising Polarization of Work
in Britain. Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(1): 118-133.
Goos, M., Manning, A. and Salomons, A. (2009). Job polarization in Europe. American
Economic Review, 99(2): 58-63.
Goos, M., Manning, A. and Salomons, A. (2014). Explaining job polarization: Routine-biased
technological change and offshoring. American Economic Review, 104(8): 2509-2526.
Green, A (2019). What is happening to middle skill workers. OECD Social, Employment and
Migration Working Papers NO. 230. Paris: OECD Publishing.
Gregory, T., Salomons, A. and Zierahn, U. (2018). Racing With or Against the Machine?
Evidence from Europe. ZEW Discussion Paper No. 16-053. Mannheim: Leibniz Centre
for European Economic Research.
Grimshaw, D., Bosch, G., and Rubery, J. (2014). Minimum wages and collective bargaining:
what types of pay bargaining can foster positive pay equity outcomes? British Journal of
Industrial Relations, 52(3): 470-498.
Häusermann, S. (2012). The Politics of Old and New Social Policies, pp. 111-132 in: G. Bonoli
and D. Natali (eds.), The Politics of the New Welfare State. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Hays, J.C. (2009). Globalization and the New Politics of Embedded Liberalism. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Hemerijck, A. (2013). Changing Welfare States. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hemerijck, A. (2017). Social Investment and Its Critics. In: A. Hemerijck (ed.), The Uses of
Social Investment (pp. 3-42). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hemerijck, A., Burgoon, B., Die Pietro, A. and Vydra, S. (2016). Assessing Social Investment
Synergies. Luxembourg: European Commissnio DG for Employment, Social Affairs and
Inclusion.
Hicks, A. and Zorn, C. (2005). Economic Globalization, the Macro Economy, and Reversals of
Welfare: Expansion in Affluent Democracies, 1978-94. International Organization, 59(3):
631-662.
ILO (2016). Non-standard employment around the world: Understanding challenges, shaping
prospects. Geneva: ILO.
48
ILO (2019). Work for a brighter future. Geneva: ILO.
Iversen, T. and Cusack, T.R. (2000). The Causes of Welfare State Expansion:
Deindustrialization or Globalization? World Politics, 52(3): 313-349.
Jensen, C. (2011). Less Bad than its Reputation: Social Spending as a Proxy for Welfare Effort
in Cross-national Studies. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and
Practice, 13(3): 327-340.
Jenson, J. and Saint-Martin, D. (2003). New Routes to Social Cohesion? Citizenship and the
Social Investment State. Canadian Journal of Sociology, 28(1): 77-99.
Katz, L. and Murphy, K. (1992). Changes in Relative Wages, 1963-1987: Supply and Demand
Factors. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(1): 35-78.
Katz, L.F. and Autor, D. (1999). Changes in the Wage Structure and Earnings Inequality. In:
O. Ashenfelter and D. Card (eds.), The Handbook of Labor Economics (pp. 1463-1555).
Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Keune, M. and Pedaci, M. (2019). Trade union strategies against precarious work: Common
trends and sectoral divergence in the EU. European Journal of Industrial Relations. doi:
https://doi.org/10.1177/0959680119827182.
Kim, S.-W. and Ahn, S.-H. (2019). Social investment effects of public education, health care,
and welfare service expenditures on economic growth. Asian Social Work and Policy
Review. Doi: https://doi.org/10.1111/aswp.12190.
Klerman, J. and Leibowitz, A. (1997). Labor supply effects of state maternity leave legislation.
In Blau, F. and Ehrenberg, R. (eds.), Gender and Family Issues in the Workplace (pp. 68-
85). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Knotz, C. (2018). A rising workfare state? Unemployment benefit conditionality in 21 OECD
countries, 1980-2012. Journal of International and Comparative Social Policy, 34(2): 91-
108.
Knotz, C. (2019). Why Countries ‘Get Tough on the Work-Shy’: The Role of Adverse
Economic Conditions. Journal of Social Policy, 48(3): 615-634.
Knotz, C. and Nelson, M. (2019). The Comparative Unemployment Benefit Conditions and
Sanctions Dataset. Department of Political Science, Lund University.
Kuitto, K. (2016). From social security to social investment? Compensating and social
investment welfare policies in a life-course perspective. Journal of European Social
Policy, 26(5): 442-459.
Kurer, T. and Gallego, A. (2019). Distributional consequences of technological change:
Worker-level evidence. Research & Politics, 6(1): 45-51.
Kvist, J. (2013). The Post-crisis European Social Model: Developing or Dismantling Social
Investments? Journal of International and Comparative Social Policy, 29(1): 91-107.
Lalive, R. and Zweimüller, J. (2009). How Does Parental Leave Affect Fertility and Return to
Work? Evidence from Two Natural Experiments. Quarterly Journal of Economics,
124(3): 1363-1402.
Luttmer, E.F.P. (2001). Group Loyalty and the Taste for Redistribution. Journal of Political
Economy, 109(3): 500-528.
49
Meltzer, A.H. and Richard, S.F. (1983). Tests of a Rational Theory of the Size of Government.
Public Choice, 41(3): 403-418.
Michaels, G., Natraj, A., Van Reenen, J. (2014). Has ICT polarized skill demand? Evidence
from eleven countries over 25 years. Review of Economics and Statistics, 96(1): 60-77.
Morel, N., Palier, B. and Palme, J. (eds.) (2012). Towards a Social Investment Welfare State?
Ideas, Policies and Challenges. Bristol: Policy Press.
Murphy, E.C. and Oesch, D. (2018). Is employment polarisation inevitable? Occupational
change in Ireland and Switzerland, 1970-2010. Work, employment and society, 32(6):
1099-1117.
Nelson, M. and Stephens, J.D. (2012). Do social investment policies produce more and better
jobs? In: N. Morel, B. Palier and J. Palme (eds.), Towards a Social Investment Welfare
State? Ideas, Policies and Challenges (pp. 205-234). Bristol: Policy Press.
Nikolai, R. (2012). Towards social investment? Patterns of public policy in the OECD world.
In: N. Morel, B. Palier and J. Palme (eds.), Towards a Social Investment Welfare State?
Ideas, Policies and Challenges pp. (91-115). Bristol: Policy Press.
Noël, A. (2018). Is social investment inimical to the poor? Socio-Economic Review. doi:
https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwy038.
OECD (2018a). Notes on the scope and comparability of data on labour market programmes.
Paris: OECD.
OECD (2019a). Social Expenditure Database. Paris: OECD.
OECD (2019b). Labour Database. Paris: OECD.
OECD (2019c). Education and Training Database. Paris: OECD.
OECD (2019d). Education at a Glance 2019. Paris: OECD.
OECD. (2018b). OECD Handbook for Internationally Comparative Education Statistics 2018:
Concepts, Standards, Definitions and Classifications. Paris: OECD.
Oesch, D., and Rodríguez Menés, J. (2011). Upgrading or polarization? Occupational change
in Britain, Germany, Spain and Switzerland, 1990-2008. Socio-Economic Review, 9(3):
503-531.
Pavolini, E. and Van Lancker, W. (2018). The Matthew effect in childcare use: a matter of
policies or preferences? Journal of European Public Policy, 25(6): 878-893.
Peugny, C. (2019). The decline in middle-skilled employment in 12 European countries: New
evidence for job polarisation. Research & Politics, 6(1): 405-423.
Raess, D. and Pontusson, J. (2015). The politics of fiscal policy during economic downturns,
1981-2010. European Journal of Political Research, 54(1): 1-22.
Raffass, T. (2017). Demanding Activation. Journal of Social Policy, 46(2): 349-365.
Rodrik, D. (1998). Why do more open economies have bigger governments? Journal of Political
Economy, 106(5): 997-1002.
Rojas-Romagosa, H. and Bollen, J. (2018). Estimating migration changes from the EU’s free
movement of people principle. CBP Discussion Paper No. 385. The Hague: CPB
Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis.
50
Ronchi, S. (2016). The Social Investment Welfare Expenditure data set (SIWE). GK SOCLIFE
Working Paper No. 17. Cologne University.
Ronchi, S. (2018). Which Roads (if any) to Social Investment? The Recalibration of EU
Welfare States at the Crisis Crossroads (2000-2014). Journal of Social Policy, 47(3): 459-
478.
Roy, A.D. (1951). Some Thoughts on the Distribution of Earnings. Oxford Economic Papers,
3(2): 135-146.
Ruhm, C.J. (1998). The Economic Consequences of Parental Leave Mandates: Lessons from
Europe. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(1): 285-317.
Samuelson, P. (1971). Ohlin was Right. Swedish Journal of Economics, 73(4): 365-384.
Scheve, K., and Slaughter, M.J. (2004). Economic insecurity and the globalization of
production. American Journal of Political Science, 48(4): 662-674.
Sirgy, M.J., Lee, D.-J., Miller, C., Littlefield, J.E. and Atay, E.G. (2007). The impact of imports
and exports on a country’s quality of life. Social Indicators Research, 83(2): 245-281.
Soroka, S., Johnston, R. and Banting, K. (2006). Immigration and Redistribution in a Global
Era, pp. 261-288 in: S. Bowles, P. Bardhan, and M. Wallerstein (eds.), Globalization and
Egalitarian Redistribution. Princeton: Princeton University Press and Russell Sage
Foundation.
Soroka, S., Johnston, R., Kevins, A., Banting, K., and Kymlicka, W. (2016). Migration and
welfare state spending. European Political Science Review, 8(2): 173-194.
Starke, P., Klaasch, A. and Van Hooren, F. (2014). Political Parties and Social Policy Responses
to Global Economic Crises: Constrained Partisanship in Mature Welfare States. Journal
of Social Policy, 43(2): 225-246.
Starke, P., Obinger, H. and Castles, F.G. (2008). Convergence towards where: In what ways, if
any, are welfare states becoming more similar? Journal of European Public Policy, 15(7):
975-1000.
Stolper, W. and Samuelson, P. (1941). Protection and real wages. Review of Economic Studies
9(1): 58-73.
Taylor-Gooby, P. (ed.) (2004). New Risks, New Welfare: The Transformation of the European
Welfare State. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Taylor-Gooby, P., Gumy, J.M. and Otto, A. (2015). Can ‘New Welfare’ Address Poverty
through More and Better Jobs? Journal of Social Policy, 44(1): 83-104.
Thewissen, S. and Van Vliet, O. (2019). Competing with the Dragon: Employment effects of
Chinese trade competition in 17 sectors across 18 OECD countries. Political Science
Research and Methods, 7(2): 215-232.
Tinbergen, J. (1974). Substitution of Graduate by Other Labour. Kyklos, 27(2): 217-226.
Tinbergen, J. (1975). Income differences: Recent research. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Van Kersbergen, K. and Hemerijck, A. (2012). Two Decades of Change in Europe: The
Emergence of the Social Investment State. Journal of Social Policy, 41(3): 475-492.
Van Lancker, W. and Ghysels, J. (2014). Who Benefits from Investment Policies? The Case of
Family Activation in European Countries. In: B. Cantillon and F. Vandenbroucke (eds.),
51
Reconciling Work and Poverty Reduction: How Successful are European Welfare States?
(pp. 212-237) Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Van Lancker, W. and Ghysels, J. (2016). Explaining patterns of inequality in childcare service
use across 31 developed economies: A welfare state perspective. International Journal of
Comparative Sociology, 57(5): 310-337.
Van Vliet, O. (2010). Divergence within Convergence: Europeanization of Social and Labour
Market Policies. Journal of European Integration, 32(3): 269-290.
Van Vliet, O. and Koster, F. (2011). Europeanization and the political economy of active labour
market policies. European Union Politics, 12(2): 217-239.
Van Vliet, O. and Wang, C. (2015). Social Investment and Poverty Reduction: A Comparative
Analysis across Fifteen European Countries. Journal of Social Policy, 44(3): 611-638.
Van Vliet, O. and Wang, J. (2019). The Political Economy of Social Assistance and Minimum
Income Benefits: A Comparative Analysis across 26 OECD Countries. Comparative
European Politics, 17(1): 49-71.
Vandenbroucke, F. and Vleminckx, K. (2011). Disappointing poverty trends: Is the social
investment state to blame? Journal of European Social Policy, 21(5): 450-471.
Walter, S. (2010). Globalization and the Welfare State: Testing the Microfoundations of the
Compensation Hypothesis. International Studies Quarterly, 54(2): 403-426.
Walter, S. (2017). Globalization and the demand-side of politics: How globalization shapes
labor market risk perceptions and policy preferences. Political Science Research
Methods, 5(1): 55-80.