ArticlePDF Available

Do property rights in waste and by-products matter for promoting reuse, recycling and recovery? Lessons learnt from northwestern Europe

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

Within the context of concurrent global waste and resource crises, there is significant interest in promoting circular economies. One of the identified ways to facilitate greater circularity is through replicable practices of industrial symbiosis, where industries and other organizations exchange waste and by-products resulting in economic, environmental, and social benefits. This paper investigates the role of a particular critical legal mechanism – property rights – in enabling industrial symbiosis by drawing on the experiences of waste and by-product exchanges within three industrial symbiosis case studies located in Kalundborg (Denmark), Peterborough (United Kingdom), and Rotterdam (the Netherlands). In order to determine whether property rights are incentives, facilitative mechanisms, barriers, or opportunities, the Schlager-Ostrom taxonomy is applied. Case findings evidence that different property regimes can have facilitative effects on circularity within industrial symbioses. There is thus no absolute support presumed in favor of one particular property rights regime over others; property regimes are flexible and hence allow for case specificity.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Do property rights in waste and by-products matter for promoting reuse,
recycling and recovery? Lessons learnt from northwestern Europe
Katrien Steenmans
Coventry Law School and Research Associate, Centre for Business in Society, Coventry University, Priory Street, Coventry CV1 5FB, UK
ABSTRACTARTICLE INFO
Article history:
Received 18 November 2020
Received inrevised form 10 February 2021
Accepted 11 February 2021
Available online xxxx
Within the context of concurrent global waste and resource crises, there is signicant interest in promoting circular
economies. One of the identied ways to facilitate greater circularity is through replicable practices of industrial sym-
biosis, where industries and otherorganizations exchange waste and by-products resulting in economic, environmen-
tal, and social benets. This paper investigates the role of a particular critical legal mechanism property rights in
enabling industrial symbiosis by drawing on the experiences of waste and by-product exchanges within three indus-
trial symbiosis case studies located in Kalundborg (Denmark), Peterborough (United Kingdom), and Rotterdam (the
Netherlands). In orderto determine whether propertyrights are incentives, facilitative mechanisms,barriers, or oppor-
tunities,the Schlager-Ostrom taxonomy is applied. Case ndings evidencethat different property regimes can have fa-
cilitative effects on circularity within industrial symbioses. There is thus no absolute support presumedin favor of one
particular property rights regime over others; property regimes are exible and hence allow for case specicity.
Keywords:
Property rights
Industrial symbiosis
Law
Waste
European Union
Circular economy
1. Introduction
Current global resource consumption and waste production are at un-
sustainable levels. Annual global primary resource extraction and use has
exceeded 100 billion tonnes per year since 2017, while simultaneously
more than 2 billion tonnes of municipal solid waste is generated annually
and could increase by 70% by 2050 (Kaza et al. 2018;CircleEconomy
2020). The circular economy concept has emerged as one of the possible re-
source and waste management strategies to mitigate these resource and
waste crises (e.g. Geissdoerfer et al. 2017). Circular economies aim to tran-
sition away from the traditional linear take-make-dispose approach, which
wasteswaste and is resource intensive, towards the prevention of wastes
and loopingof any wastes produced and resources through reuse,
recycling, and otherrecovery for economic, environmental, and social ben-
ets (Kirchherr et al. 2017).
Industrial symbiosis networks, in which wastes and by-products are ex-
changed between different organizations, are identied as a circular econ-
omy implementation (de Abreu and Ceglia 2018;Merli et al. 2018) and
have been explicitly recognized in non-binding European Union(EU) policy
documents as a supportive strategy for achieving similar environmental,
economic, and social benets to circular economies. Industrial symbiosis
networksare, for example, recognized as a strategy for facilitating the circu-
lar economy in the EU's new Circular Economy Action Plan (European
Commission 2020), as well as sustainable consumption and production in
the Roadmap to a Resource Efcient Europe (European Commission
2011), and resource efciency in the European Resource Efciency Plat-
form (European Commission 2012). More recently, and arguably more sig-
nicantly as a result of its legally binding nature, industrial symbiosis is
included in the Waste Framework Directive 2008/98/EC (WFD)
(Directive 2008/98/EC on waste and repealing certain directives, 2008)
as a result of amendments made by Directive 2018/851 (amending Direc-
tive) (Directive 2018/851 amending Directive 2008/98/EC on waste,
2018) to Article 5(3) to allow adoption of certain criteria by Member States
to prioritise replicable practices of industrial symbiosis(emphasis added).
This is in order to contribute to the overarching WFD objective to lay
down measures that prevent or reduce waste generation, impacts of waste
management and generation and impacts of resource use, which are cru-
cial for the transition to a circular economy(Article 1).
A central question is thus: what mechanisms can enable the develop-
ment of industrial symbiosis practices? While several facilitative mecha-
nisms have been explored in the literature, including a platform enabling
information and knowledge exchange (Raabe et al. 2017), an internet-
based market mechanism (Clayton, Muirshead and Reichgelt 2002), and In-
formation and Communications Technology tools (Grant et al. 2010),
scholars have identied the need to further investigate and develop under-
standingof extant industrial symbiosis case studies, as well as the incentives
Current Research in Environmental Sustainability 3 (2021) 100030
E-mail address: katrien.steenmans@coventry.ac.uk.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.crsust.2021.100030
2666-0490/© 2021 TheAuthor(s). Published by Elsevier B.V. Thisis an open access article under theCC BY-NC-ND license(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/
4.0/).
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect
Current Research in Environmental Sustainability
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/crsust
fostering industrial symbiosis (e.g. Domenech et al. 2019;Neves et al.
2020). This paper contributes to this literature by exploring the role of a
specic legal paradigm property rights within selected existing indus-
trial symbiosis networks (see Section 2). This discussion is both timely
due to the increased recognition of industrial symbiosis benets and their
role in achieving circular economies, but also because of ongoing scholarly
discussions on property rights for effective environmental management of
resources (e.g. Hanna et al. 1995;Libecap 2009), which is at the core of in-
dustrial symbiosis and circular economy.
The rationale for and contributions of focusing on property rights within
the industrial symbiosis context are three-fold. First, property rights are at
the core of exchanges while thus far being under-explored in industrial
symbiosis literature and its wider eld of industrial ecology; who owns
and is responsible for wastes and other resources determines what can
enter industrial symbiosis systems. The limitedliterature on property rights
has an economic rather than legal focus. Sathre and Grdzelishvili (2006,
387) state that the role of government interests in developing industrial
symbiosis is a question of public versus private responsibility for waste
and pollution, and intrinsically linked to the issue of property rights,but
do not expand on this. Similarly, there is no discussion or elaboration be-
yond identicationof property rights as one of the challenges within indus-
trial ecology by Giurco et al. (2014) and Laybourn (2005).Desrochers
(2012) and Behne (2016) only mention property rights in relation to
them underpinning the economic dimension of industrial ecology. Very
limited prior research thus exists and has adopted a legal approach to prop-
erty rights in industrial symbiosis (and similarly in circular economies more
widely see Steenmans et al. 2020). This paper lls this void by examining
the possible effects of property rights in three case studies of indus trial sym-
biosis networks.
Second, waste is increasingly regarded as a valuable resource, evi-
denced by the amending Directive highlighting that waste is valued as a
resource(Recital 2). The term resourcehas connotations of value, and
is sometimes even dened by reference to it (e.g. Merriam-Webster 2018;
Oxford English Dictionary 2018).How value is perceived may in turn be af-
fected by ownership and attribution, and thereforeproperty rights (Leopold
1968).
Finally, there are many theoretical discussions regarding the signi-
cance of ownership in resource management whether privatization, gov-
ernment intervention, or other institutions are most appropriate (e.g.
Hardin 1968;Welch 1983;Ostrom 1990;France-Hudson 2017;Thomas
2019). These debates and discussions have been applied within numerous
contexts (e.g. Berkes 1987;Lange and Shepheard 2014;Malcolm and
Clarke 2017). Similar discussions are warranted within the context of in-
dustrial symbiosis to consider the most appropriate property right interven-
tions to promote industrial symbiosis practices more widely.
The remainder of the paper is structured in four parts. First,the research
design is described and explained. The second part introduces the case stud-
ies and examines the property regimes present in each of them. These nd-
ings are then discussed in the following section. The nal section concludes
and identies further research.
2. Materials and methods
This section rst sets out the research question, followed by two sec-
tions detailing the data collection and analysis methods. The research de-
sign is summarized in Fig. 1.
2.1. Research question
The research question framingthis paper is: what is the role of property
rights in enabling industrial symbiosis systems in the EU? Within legal re-
search and practice, boundaries are important as they determine what is
and is not covered by the law, and when (Lieber 1838;Thayer 1908;
Cheyne and Purdue 1995;Steenmans 2018). For this reason, the terms
property rightsand industrial symbiosisare described below. What is
meant by enablingand how it is evaluated in this paper is set out in
Section 2.3.3.
Property rights are understood in this paper as a man-made institution
(Macpherson 1978, 1) that describes the nature of rights in resources
(Clarke and Kohler 2005). The frameworkadopted to understand and ana-
lyze property rights is described in Section 2.3.3.
Fig. 1. Research design.
K. Steenmans Current Research in Environmental Sustainability 3 (2021) 100030
2
Industrial symbiosis engages traditionally separate industries and other
organizations in a collective exchange of wastes and by-products resulting
in economic, environmental, and social benets.
1
This denition combines
Chertow's (2007) seminal scholarly denition with denitions included in
the EU's policy documents (European Commission 2011;seealso
European Commission DG Environment News Alert Service, 2012;
European Commission, 2012). In essence, the exchanges within industrial
symbiosis systems comprise the reuse, recycling, or other recovery of
waste and by-product streams, which result in economic, environmental,
and social benets (e.g. Lowe and Evans 1995;Chertow and Lombardi
2005;Hashimoto et al. 2010;Morales et al. 2019). Industrial symbiosis is
thus a particular manifestation of the circular economy, with circular econ-
omies covering materials more widely (beyond waste and by-products) and
at more levels (macro in addition to micro and meso levels) (Kirchherr et al.
2017;de Abreu and Ceglia 2018;Merli et al. 2018).
Key terms within the denition of industrial symbiosis warranting fur-
ther explanation are waste and by-products. Within the EU, waste means
any substance or object which the holder discards or intends or is required
to discardpursuant to Article 3(1) of the WFD. This denition has been the
subject of numerous EU cases (Case C-9/00, 2002; Case C-235/02, 2004;
Case C-304/94, 1997; Case C-444/00, 2003; Case C-457/02, 2004; Joined
Cases C-206/88 and C-207/88, 1990; Joined Cases C-241/12 and
C-242/12, 2013; Joined Cases C-418/97 and C-419/97, 2000)andresulted
in a lack of clear and denitive characteristics, which have in turn been
much discussed in the literature (e.g. Fluck 1994;Cheyne and Purdue
1995;Van Calster 1997;Tromans 2001;Malcolm and Clift 2002;Scotford
2007;Edwards 2013;Steenmans et al. 2017).
2
These issuesare not claried
at national level, with the denition of waste transposed word per word in
the national legislation of the selected case studies (see next section). The
impact is however limited as the denition of waste is generally cast
broadly (Case C-176/05, 2007; Case C-188/07, 2008; Case C-252/05,
2007). Thus, uncertainty in a substance or material being waste means a
cautious lawyer would advise to treat it as waste (Steenmans 2018).
Waste can stop being waste as a result of the end-of-waste criteria set out
in Article 6 of the WFD. The discussion pertaining if and when waste
stops being waste is beyond the scope of this paper as it does not affect
the actual property rights involved though it may affect their perception
when the substance or material is produced or changes hands
(Steenmans and Malcolm 2020).
Instead of the intended product or waste, by-products may be produced
in production processes. Pursuant to Article 5(1) of the WFD (as amended),
by-products must meet the following four conditions: certainty of further
use; use without further processing other than normal industrial practice;
product of integral part of production process; and further use is lawful,
that is the substance of object fullls all relevant product, environmental
and health protection requirements for the specic use and will not lead
to overall adverse environmental or human health impacts(Article 5(1)
(d)). There are uncertainties associated with these conditions e.g. what
qualies as integraland normal(Steenmans 2018)but these are yet
to be discussed in EU case law. Similarly to waste, the by-product criteria
are transposed into the national law of the selected case studies (see next
section).
The terms wasteand by-productare used interchangeably with re-
sourcesthroughout this paper. This approach resonates with the view
adopted by interview participants.
2.2. Data collection
The research adopts a mixed-methods approach combining empirical
research with desk-based and doctrinal research. This approach is applied
for three reasons: triangulation, facilitation, and complementarity
(Hammersley 1996;Bryman 2008).
A multi-case study method is used toexplore the particularity and com-
plexity of property rights within real-life industrial symbiosis contexts (Yin
2009). The three selected case studies provide useful insights into the role
of property rights in waste: despite historically being criticized for not
being able to contribute to scientic development, it is possible to general-
ize based on one case study with the value of examples often undervalued
(Flyvbjerg 2006).
The selected industrial symbiosis case studies are in: Kalundborg
(Denmark), Peterborough (United Kingdom (UK)), and Rotterdam (the
Netherlands). The case study selection criteria were: location, exemplary
outcome, access, and language.
First, the cases selected are all within the EU,
3
which provides some uni-
formity in the regulatory and policy frameworks via the harmonizing effect
of EU law. For example, the denition of waste is exactly the same in the
Waste Ordinance (Bekendtgørelse af lov nr 1309 af 18.12.2012 om affald
some aendret, 2012) in Denmark; the Environmental Protection Act (Wet
milieubeheer, 1979)intheNetherlands;andtheEnvironmental Protection
Act 1990 in England as in the WFD. In relation to by-product, the term is
not used in the Danish Waste Ordinance, but the concept is still present as
materials meeting the by-product criteria are not classed as waste. In the
Netherlands and UK, by-products are dened by reference to the WFD in
the Dutch Environmental Protection Act and Waste (England and Wales)
Regulations 2011 respectively. The identical denitions do not indicate
that the governance of waste and by-products is identical across the case stud-
ies,butitprovidesattheveryleastacommonbaseline.Propertyrightsare
not harmonized at EU level due to different legal systems (see below),
though Article 36(1) of the WFD dictates that waste cannot be abandoned
(i.e. owners cannot unilaterally cede their ownership).
Second, the cases were selected using replication logic instead of repre-
sentation, which requires every chosen case to demonstrate the occurrence
of exemplary outcomes (Yin 2009). This is dened as those meeting
Chertow's 32 heuristic, as this starts recognizing complex relationships
rather than linear one-way exchanges (Chertow 2007). The heuristic re-
quires a minimum of three different entities, of which none are engaged pri-
marily in a recycling-oriented relationship, exchanging at least two
different resources. Moreover, the case studies are more than eco-
industrial parks as the entities include consumers.
Third, access was based on availability of resources on the case studies
and access to possible interview participants.
Finally, cases were selected in countries where the researcher had the
requisite language skills to read policy and regulatory documents.
Case study data was collected through interviews and desk-based re-
search. Desk-based research reviewed extant literature, and EU and na-
tional laws mainly to understand the case studies, and to triangulate and
validate data. Semi-structured interviews were conducted between 2015
and 2017. The open-ended questions on property rights included: Are you
aware of the property rights in the industrial symbiosis? What is the role
of property rights? Follow-up questions were asked (depending on preced-
ing responses), including: In your opinion, would it be possible to rethink
property rights by extending responsibility to the manufacturer so that
they have to take goods backinstead of selling them? Are communal prop-
erty rights something that you think can be further explored? These ques-
tions were thus focused on understanding the perception of property
rights by practitioners and experts, to compare and contrast withthe actual
assigned property rights in law (see Section 2.3.3). Interviews were audio
recorded, and then transcribed for analysis.
Sixteen interviews (eight in Kalundborg, ve in Peterborough, and
three in Rotterdam) were conducted with representatives from industries
and other organizations exchanging wastes or by-products in the industrial
1
For a detailed discussion on how thisdenition has been amended see Steenmans (2018).
2
The EU case law and literature on the denition of waste are reviewed in detail in
Steenmans (2018).
3
The UK triggered the process to leave the EU on 29 March 2017 with the process allowed
to take upto two years. At the timeof researchingthis paper, theUK was still a MemberState of
the EU. Currently, the UK remains subject to EU law,includingthe WFD, until at least 31 De-
cember 2020 as a result of the transition period.
K. Steenmans Current Research in Environmental Sustainability 3 (2021) 100030
3
symbiosis (hereafter referred to as symbionts) and third parties (i.e. stake-
holders, including municipalities and research organizations, that have a
role in the initiation and sustainment of industrial symbiosis, but are not
symbionts themselves). When the same information was being repeated
by interview participants, this indicated that sufcient interviews had
been conducted. As far as possible, participants were selected of similar ca-
pacity and levels across the three case studies.
2.3. Data analysis
Data from desk-based research and interviews were coded, with addi-
tional doctrinal research methods adopted for laws. This data was triangu-
lated before being evaluated and compared. These analysis methods are
detailed below.
2.3.1. Coding
Coding is used in qualitative inquiry to organize, sort, and analyze data
(Charmaz 2006). A code is a word or short phrase that assigns a summative,
salient, essence-capturing, and/or evocative attribute for a portion of
data(Saldaña 2012, 3). An inductive approach was used to develop the
codes through identifying repeated themes and terms through two cycles:
rst to identify initial codes, and then to check and conrm these codes.
2.3.2. Doctrinal law
Even though the doctrinal research method is used, this paper cannot be
categorized as a piece of doctrinal research as case studies and interviews are
also employed. Doctrinal research focuses almost entirely on law's own lan-
guage of statutes and case law to make sense of the legal world(Morris and
Murphy 2011, 31); it comprises identifying, analyzing, and synthesizing the
content of law, including the identication and exposition of ambiguities and
inconsistencies (Posner 1981;Hutchinson 2013). This process was mainly
applied to EU and national waste laws relating to denitions of waste and
by-products to understand the legal implications of the terms, and to check
whether they considered or addressed anything relevant to property rights.
2.3.3. Evaluation of property rights
Evaluation looks at what does and does not work, and why and how
(Pawson and Tiley 1997;Pawson 2013). A two-step evaluation process
was adopted to: (1) identifythe existing property rights regimes; and (2) as-
sess their effects. For the rst step, a taxonomy was used to facilitate under-
standing by clarifying what property regimes are present based on the
presence of certain property rights.
Traditionally, property rights regimes have been described as private,
communal, state, or no property (e.g. Waldron 1988;Bromley 1989;
Clarke and Kohler 2005). This characterization is not without its limits as
it arguably renders invisible many new forms of property(Heller 2000,
417), but it can provide a useful analytical tool as long as it is acknowledged
that the boundaries fray at the edges(Heller 2000, 418) and that these
ideal types are almost never found in practice. In most cases there are over-
lapping sets of rights, underneaththe general classications(Barry and
Meinzen-Dick 2014, 298). The Schlager and Ostrom (1992) taxonomy
adopted and applied in this paper can help understand these overlaps.
Schlager and Ostrom subscribe to the notion that property is a bundle
of rightsmetaphor (e.g. Demsetz 1967;Penner 1996;Johnson 2007;
Ellickson 2011). This taxonomy is relevant to this research as it was devel-
oped in relation to research on common-poolresource systems, as which in-
dustrial symbiosis networks have been described (Steenmans 2018).
Common-pool resource systems comprise natural or man-made resource
systems and a ow of resource units or benets form these systems
(Ostrom 2002, 39; see also Ostrom 1990).
Schlager and Ostrom, drawing on Commons (1924) and Ciriacy-
Wantryp and Bishop (1975),identifyve separate bundles:
1. Access: the right to enter a dened property;
2. Withdrawal: the right to obtain resource units or products of a
resource system;
3. Management: the right to regulate internal usepatterns and transform
the resource by making improvements;
4. Exclusion: the right to determine who will have an access right, and
how that right may be transferred; and
5. Alienation: the rightto sell or lease either or both of the management
and evolution rights.
These rights do not need to be simultaneously present. Schlager and
Ostrom arrange these bundles across ve classes of user as shown in
Table 1: full owner, proprietor, authorized claimant, authorized user, and
authorized entrant.
Private property has been described as that sole and despotic dominion
which one man claims and exercises over the external things of the world,
in total exclusion of the right of any other individual in the universe
((Blackstone II, 1765-1769) 2). There is therefore a legal entity that is the
full owner of the private property holding all ve bundles. According to
Locke (1980), one way private property can come about is by man mixing
labor with the elements of the natural world so it becomes that person's
property (called Locke's labor theory).
4
State property is similar to private
property in that the state (or other public body) is the full owner and
holds all ve bundles. But, in practice the state will often permit individuals
and groups to access the property, such as public parks (Barry andMeinzen-
Dick, 2014). Communal property iswhere each member of the community
has the rightto (1) access the property, and (2) not be excluded from it. All
members of the community are therefore proprietors. No property (also
known as res nullius) is where everyone can access the resource but no
one has an enforceable right to this access against others or the state so
everyone can enter and withdraw, but no one is an authorized entrant or
other class of user.
A limit of applying the Schlager-Ostrom taxonomy is that the bundle
of rights approach is not widely accepted in civil law (Orsi 2014). There
are, however, numerous examples where Schlager-Ostrom's taxonomy of
rights are applied in civil law systems without acknowledgement of the
possible ingrained conict (e.g. Bouriaud and Smithüsen 2005;Stebek
2011;Baur and Binder 2013). This can be justied using Mattei's
(2000, 13) argument that [t]he bundle metaphor can easily be adapted
It will be enough to clarify that different [rights] might be missing in
different legal systems.
Once the property rights are identied, the next step is to evaluate
their enablingeffects. This is informed by what is and is not possible
under those property regimes, which determines whether they are in-
centives, barriers, or opportunities in the context of the case studies.
In this paper, incentives are dened as mechanisms that actively moti-
vate an exchange to take place; facilitative mechanisms enable ex-
changes but do not have causal impacts; barriers stop or limit an
exchange; and opportunities are where there is potential for property re-
gimes to become an incentive. The relevant impact(s) of property rights
inthecasestudieswasdeterminedbythenatureoftherightstogether
with what was conveyed during interviews.
2.3.4. Comparing case studies
In reviewing property rights and national laws, the different jurisdic-
tions of the case studies must be acknowledged the UK has a common
Table 1
Schlager-Ostrom taxonomy. Adopted from Schlager and Ostrom (1992).
Authorized
entrant
Authorized
user
Authorized
claimant
Proprietor Full
owner
Access X X X X X
Withdrawal X X X X
Management X X X
Exclusion X X
Alienation X
4
There has been much discussion of Locke's labor theory in the literature.See for example
Waldron (1984),Judge (2002),andWiderquist (2010).
K. Steenmans Current Research in Environmental Sustainability 3 (2021) 100030
4
law system, while Denmark and the Netherlands have Scandinavian and
Napoleonic civil law systems respectively. The similarities and differences
between these systems ar e not examined in this paper, as this is unne cessary
according to mainstream comparative methods in legal research (Siems
2014). Despite differences, there are many commonalities between the
two systems (e.g. human rights, the rule of law, and a positive and rational
law) and often differences are misleading or exaggerated. Legal rules often
apply in similar ways, particularly as the case studies are limited to Western
legal systems (Siems 2014). However, it is necessary in relation to compar-
ing their property systems.
Civil and common law property systems are coherent within them-
selves but difcult to reconcile(van Erp 2006a). Some of the key differ-
ences identied are in their approaches to ownership and title; in civil
law there is a strict separation of property from obligations while in
common law many of the lesser estates look something like very
long-term relational contracts(Chang and Smith 2016, 139); common
law systems arguably have a larger and more open-ended set of property
rights; and common law still differentiates between land, personal prop-
erty, and trust law, whereas general principle s and rules exist in civil law
for all forms of property (van Erp 2006b;Chang and Smith 2016). De-
spite apparent differences between the details of civil and common
law property regimes, there is increased recognition that the leading
principles underlying policies, fundamental concepts, and basic rules
are quite similar, and that they may therefore be compared to a certain
degree in comparative studies (Mattei 2000;van Erp 2006a, 2006b;
Dalhuisen 2013).
3. Results: case studies
The case studies are set out below, with the focus limited to two ex-
changes within the industrial symbiosis networks in order to focus the
discussion.
3.1. Kalundborg industrial symbiosis
The seminal example of industrial symbiosis is located in Kalundborg
with at least 13 key symbionts exchanging 28 resources, presented in
Fig. 2.
5
The exchanges in the Kalundborg industrial symbiosis including
the water from Lake Tissø and steam sold by Ørsted to Equinor are con-
trolled by commercially negotiated contracts, most often between two
parties (Ehrenfeld and Gertler 1997;Jacobsen 2002;Jacobsen and
Anderberg 2004;Doménech and Davies 2011;andconrmed by interview
participants). The contracts include clauses on the prices for the resource
exchanges for a set period, payment terms, and mechanisms for future
changes (such as escape clauses and requirements for upgrading) (Gertler
1995;Jacobsen 2002;Chertow, 2004). They evidence that symbionts can
sell their wastes and by-products, and are able to exclude and alienate
them from others. These resources are thuscurrently predominantly treated
as private property with the relevant symbionts as full owners in Schlager-
Ostrom terms. Contracts and private property rights provide the certainty
and security that many companies require to minimize their risk in indus-
trial symbiosis.
The treatment and perception of property rights in gypsum are bothpri-
vate, but the treatment of steam as private property differs from the usual
perception of steam. Steam has been described as the ultimate externality
because it usually leaves the premises in the form of an atmospheric emis-
sion (Steenmans et al. 2017, 10). It is most often treated as res nullius, com-
parable to greenhouse gas emissions thatare produced by all symbionts but
over which no one claims full ownership. Either can currently be justied
legally. The steam is produced by and belongs to Ørsted, but usually its
form (and perceived lack of value) prevent entities from claiming full
Fig. 2. Kalundborg industrial symbiosis. Based on Kalundborg Symbiosis (2018).
5
This is the minimum number, as arguably furthersymbiotic exchanges exist. Forexample,
there is an H&M in Kalundbor g where households can return clothing waste for reuse, recov-
ery or recycling as part of their H&M garment collecting initiative (H&M 2018).
K. Steenmans Current Research in Environmental Sustainability 3 (2021) 100030
5
ownership. Even if steam was determined tobe res nullius, then the captur-
ing of it by Ørsted would be sufcient to apply Locke's labor theory as
collecting is sufcient to constitute labor and then still become private
property (Locke 1980).
The perception of private property rights facilitates symbiotic ex-
changes through enabling the commodication of wastes and by-
products; both wastes and by-products are perceived and treated as trad-
able economic goods of (monetary) value. This was evidenced during the
interviews with, for example, one interview participant stating that the ex-
changes are perceived as quite a good business deal,and another partic-
ipant that companies see waste as a good that can be sold or you can
[save] money by buying another company's waste.
There is one exception to the above discussion on private property ex-
changes; the water supplied by Lake Tissø is state property to which other
legal entities (including individuals) are given access (e.g. shing and sail-
ing) and withdrawal rights (e.g. for industrial symbiosis purposes). As state
property is a particular form of private property, the previous arguments
still apply. Some argue that water should instead be res nullius or commu-
nal property (as commodication of water is considered inappropriate)
(Clarke and Malcolm 2016, 121; see also: Malcolm and Clarke 2017), but
it would then still become private property as a result of Kalundborg Utility
mixing their labor with the water (Locke 1980).
3.2. Peterborough industrial symbiosis
A meeting in April 2015 between Peterborough Reuse Limited, Oppor-
tunity Peterborough (a not-for-prot company wholly owned by Peterbor-
ough City Council), and Masteroast Coffee Company Limited (a roasting
and packing facility) resulted in the initiation of a symbiotic system in Pe-
terborough, UK, repurposing coffee sacks and unwanted clothing into
bags. Currently, Masteroast provides Peterborough Reuse with more than
1400 hessian and jute sacks every week. The sacks are rst cleaned and
processed before being sent to offenders and ex-offenders to cut into
shape. The materials are then turned into retail items (including reusable
bags) and log sacks for tree planting, the forest industry, and riverbank re-
inforcement against ooding by a group of local and predominantly long-
term unemployed, recent migrant, or stay-at-home women recruited and
trained by Peterborough Reuse and the UK Department of Work and Pen-
sions (Masteroast 2016). The retail bags are lined with excess fabric,
which is bought from local charity shops and in some instances received
as donations from households. This system is represented in Fig. 3.
As in Kalundborg, the hessian bag exchanges are mainly governed by con-
tracts, and symbionts have the complete bundle of Schlager-Ostrom rights
that mean they are private property. There are, however, instances where
the property rights are less clear-cut. Some excess fabric used by Peterbor-
ough Reuse for lining its retail bags were provided by individuals that
intended to discard the fabrics (i.e. waste according to the WFD), but had
not yet physically discarded them. In essence, they are the full owner in
Schlager-Ostrom terms, but do not exercise their power to exclude or alienate
others and only want to exercise their rights as authorized claimants. Accord-
ing to an interview participant, the actual full owners instead perceive the ex-
cess fabrics as communal property that the local community can access.
The divergence between legal reality and the perception of property rights
in excess fabrics is comparable to a scenario where neighbors place furniture
outside their house with the intention for it to be taken by another household.
But, English case law demonstrates that there are limits to this. For example,
individuals have faced or been threatened with prosecution in recovering
food waste from bins outside food stores (The Guardian 2014;BBC 2011),
even though recovering food for consumption from state-owned bins in public
spaces is considered acceptable despite also legally being private property of
the state (Steenmans and Malcolm 2020). Furthermore, in the English case
of Williams and Others v Phillips and Roberts and Others v Phillips (1957) dust-
menemployedbyawastemanagementcorporationwereconvictedofsteal-
ing goods from dustbins collected in the course of their duties, selling the
goods to dealers, and sharing the proceeds. Lord Goddard CJ (Williams and
Others v Phillips and Roberts and Others v Phillips, 1957,8)said:
If I put refuse in my dustbin outside my house, I am not abandoning it in
the sense that I am leaving it for anybody to take it away. I am putting it
out so that it may be collected and taken away by the local authority,
and until it has been taken away by the local authority it is my property.
Thus in England, where waste is left does not matter whether curbside
or in dustbin as the transfer of property does not occur until collected by
the intended entity. These examples demonstrate that there is no legal un-
certainty in relation to property rights, but that context, intention, and so-
cial norms affect the perception of property rights.
The perception of communal property rights in this case has been facil-
itative of industrial symbiosis, though not incentivized, as the motivation
was mainly social (the training of women) and environmental (prevent
wastedhessian and jute sacks) (interview participants).
3.3. Rotterdam harbor industrial symbiosis
Previous research has focused on industrial symbiosis in the Rotterdam
port (e.g.B aas 1998, 2000;Baas and Boons 2004;Baas and Korevaar 2011).
Fig. 3. Peterborough industrial symbiosis. Based on interview data and Peterborough Reuse (2017).
K. Steenmans Current Research in Environmental Sustainability 3 (2021) 100030
6
First, there was the INdustrial EcoSystem (INES) Project, which was ex-
tended and re-labeled the INES Mainport Project (19992002). Between
2003 and 2010 the INES project was included in the R3: Sustainable enter-
prises project, together with the Sustainable Rijnmond and Energy 2010
programs, under which it faltered and was hardly known (Baas and
Korevaar 2011). Since 2007, the focus has been on the Rotterdam climate
Initiative (2018), which is a new development rather than a direct replace-
ment of INES asno evidence indicates that the Initiative was aware of INES.
The Rotterdam Climate Initiative is the umbrella framework under which
the Port of Rotterdam Authority, Deltalinqs, DCMR Environmental Protec-
tion Agency Rijnmond, and the City of Rotterdam collaborate to deliver a
sustainable world port city (Rotterdam Climate Initiative, 2018a).
A number of smaller projects have developed independently that focus
on circular approaches within the Rotterdam port these are not a result of
the Initiative but fall within its scope. These are presented in Fig. 4. This
paper focuses on the Recycled Park Project and Verdraaidgoed.
The Recycled Park Project, launched by WHIM Architecture and the
RecycledIsland Foundation, aims to catch plastic waste larger plastic frag-
ments rather than microplastics in the New Meuse River in Rotterdam be-
fore it enters the North Sea. The plastic waste is then usedto build a oating
island on which there is a park for the Rotterdamcommunity touse. Three
litter traps have been developed and placed, and a 140m
2
prototype
recycled park is open to the public. The goal is to place eight plastic litter
traps in the river and expand the island to 190m
2
(Recycled Park 2018).
The islands have been durably built to counteract the plastic breaking
down in the water and contributing to the problem of microplastics
(Herranz 2018).
Recycled Park is an authorized user of the plastic litter in Schlager-
Ostrom terms, as they (together with everyone else in the world) can access
and withdraw littered plastics from the river. They are not authorized
claimants as they cannot manage the littered plastics in the New Meuse
River they had to apply for the necessary permits to place the traps into
the river. The littered plastics are thus perceived as res nullius. Through
the labor of collecting and transforming plastic waste into an island,
RecycledPark becomes the authorized claimant as they manage the island.
Recycled Park could become a proprietor or full owner, but the aim is for
the island to be communal, so that everyone has the privilege to enter the
island and right not to be excluded or alienated.
These perceived property rights differ from the legal reality. Theplastic
litter has been unlawfully abandoned and littered, pursuant to the Dutch
Environmental Protection Act(Wet milieubeheer, 1979) and the Rotterdam
Waste Regulation (Afvalstoffenverordening Rotterdam, 2009).
6
Their most
recent previous legal owner therefore technically still owns the plastic litter
in the river. Given that in practice there is often no method of identifying
them, the plastic waste is instead perceived as res nullius. The absence of
property rights is a driver of industrial symbiosis in the case of the Recycled
Park; if littered plastics were treated asprivate property, they would not be
retrieved from the river before entering the sea from where retrieval is
more expensive (Jambeck et al. 2015).
More typical of the industrial symbiosis is the example of
VerdraaidGoed, as part of which reusable bags are made from residual ma-
terials such as old ags, promotion banners, and shop window canvas
drapes similar to the Peterborough example (VerdraaidGoed 2018). House-
holds have been full owners and used their alienation right to transfer man-
agement to VerdraaidGoed. Private property in such examples therefore
enables the symbiotic exchanges (as in Kalundborg and Peterborough).
These are often motivated by environmental reasons rather than economic,
as there is not always monetary value attached to these exchanges.
Fig. 4. Rotterdam industrial symbiosis. The dotted lines indicate that theproject is still being developed ranging from the conceptual to piloting stages. Developedbased on
interview data and Rotterdam Climate Initiative (2018b).
6
Chapter 10(25) of the Dutch Environmental Protection Act states that regulations may be
made to preventlittering, whichare enacted in Rotterdamby the Rotterdam WasteRegulation
with paragraph 4 setting out the unlawfulness of littering for Rotterdam.
K. Steenmans Current Research in Environmental Sustainability 3 (2021) 100030
7
4. Discussion
The case study ndings on property rightsare collated in Table 2.Across
all case studies, property regimes had received little or no explicit thought
by interview participants and extant literature prior to this study, despite
being inherent in industrial symbiosis exchanges.
There is no one-size-ts-all approach to property rights across the case
studies to facilitate symbiotic exchanges; property regimes are exible
and hence allow for case specicity. Where the exchanges occur between
businesses, the exchanges are generally private, with one notable exception
of steam in Kalundborg as a result of the nature and form of the resource.
Two of the exchanges involving consumers (i.e. unwanted clothingin Peter-
borough and plastic litter in Rotterdam) seem to allow different property
rights (communal and res nullius respectively) based on the perceived real-
ity. It was the desire to enact environmental and social benets, specically
preventing waste ending up in landll or the sea, and providing skills and
work for specic social groups, that motivated the exchanges. These expe-
riences contrast with the Kalundborg industrial symbiosis where exchanges
were mainly motivated by economic factors (Jacobsen 2002; Sterr and Ott
2004; interview participants) and where waste is viewed as a commodity.
Perhaps unsurprisingly, some interview participants in the Peterbor-
ough and Rotterdam case studies stated that private property rights can
be a barrier because they dictate what and how property can be considered
and legally transferred e.g. [private property rights are] I suspect, one of
the main barriers actually for people to move on(Peterborough interview
participant). In Rotterdam, plastic litter would not be retrieved from the
river if it was perceived as private property, whereas perceived res nullius
property rights were identied as potentially helping create conditions
for industry to progresstowards circular economies (Rotterdam interview
participant). A similar argument can be made in Kalundborg; if property
rights were not perceived as private, the economic incentive would not be
present to initiate the exchange. In general, the perceived property rights
were therefore facilitative mechanisms across the case studies, as they nei-
ther directly incentivize nor motivate the exchanges to occur, but also did
not prevent them, with the actual property rights in some cases presenting
a possible barrier.
Overall, the case studies thus simultaneously demonstrate that existing
property regimes can be facilitative, but that their potential as outright in-
centives is not yet maximized. They still remain very much in the back-
ground of any discussion. To realize their incentivizing capabilities,
changes in the law can and arguably should be implemented to make
waste producers andholders aware of how waste can andshould be sustain-
ably managed to achieve circular economy and resource efciency goals.
A possible legislative mechanism is identied in Article 8 of the WFD:
Extended Producer Responsibility (EPR) (though the link with property
rights is not made explicit in this provision). EPR shifts responsibility for
waste management from the entities traditionally responsible consumers
and authorities to the producers of products. EPR can exist in different
forms: physical responsibility where the producer is responsible for the
physical end-of-life management of its products (i.e. product take-back pro-
grams); economic responsibility where the producer covers all or part of the
nancial costs for end-of-life management of its products; liability where
the producer bears responsibility for environmental damages by the prod-
uct; and informative responsibility where the producer provides informa-
tion on the product and its environmental effects across the life-cycle
stages (Lindhqvist 2000; see also Steenmans 2019 for an overview of EPR
within the EU WFD).
Property rights can be used to implement EPR measures, though further
investigation is needed, which is beyond the scope of this study. Private
property rights are commonly suggested as a mechanism for facilitating
physical responsibility; producers may lease products, so that they retain
ownership and the product is returned to them at the end of its life cycle
(e.g. Clift 1997). The possible contribution of otherpropertyrights to phys-
ical responsibility, and the possible relationships between property rights
and the other types of responsibility generally are not yet explored. Per-
haps, producers could remain authorized claimants of products so that
Table 2
Comparison of property rights in case studies.
Resource Resource type
a
Exchange Perceived
v
actual
reality
Schlager-ostrom taxonomy Property regime Impact
Waste By-product Business-to-business Consumer-to-business Authorized
entrant
Authorized
user
Authorized
claimant
Proprietor Full
owner
Communal Private Res
nullius
State Incentive Facilitative
mechanism
Barrier Opportunity
Kalundborg
Gypsum ✓✓ Perceived ✓✓✓✓✓ ✓
Actual ✓✓✓✓✓ ✓
Steam ✓✓ Perceived ✓✓✓✓✓ ✓
Actual ✓✓✓ ✓ ✓
Peterborough
Hessian
bags
✓✓ Perceived ✓✓✓✓✓ ✓
Actual ✓✓✓✓✓ ✓
Unwanted
clothing
✓✓Perceived ✓✓✓ ✓
Actual ✓✓✓✓✓ ✓
Rotterdam
Plastic
litter
✓✓Perceived ✓✓✓ ✓ ✓
Actual ✓✓✓✓✓ ✓
Recycled
textile
waste
✓✓Perceived ✓✓✓✓✓ ✓
Actual ✓✓✓✓✓ ✓
a
Based on interview participants' perspectives and application of the WFD denition.
K. Steenmans Current Research in Environmental Sustainability 3 (2021) 100030
8
they can manage them to ensure resource- and cost-effectiveness. Further
research in this area should also cover property rights in relation to extend-
ing EPR to producer ownership schemes (e.g. UCL ISR and Systemiq 2019)
and recasting EPR as pre-market producer responsibility in order to limit
market access to durable, reparable, and reusable products (Maitre-Ekern
2021).
The potential of property rights in incentivizing industrial symbiosis is
also recognized in practice; one interview participant noted the potential
positiveimpact of private property rights and resultant economic incentives
if one of the forms of extended producer responsibility is applied:
If [companies] just lease the product instead of selling it But, most
people are not there yet because you need to see the value for that
you need to see where is your incentive, and for manufacturers it is
mainly economic.
Communal property regimes can also be adopted to encourage more in-
dustrial symbiosis networks either open access for everyone or limited to
adened group of entities and individuals.A community could have shared
responsibility for the management of pooled waste and by-products, while
also having the opportunity and privilege to consume it. Environmentally
responsible entities within the community could then interfere with others'
waste and by-products to ensure that they are managed properly. Commu-
nal property could, however, equally result in others using or managing
wastes and by-products in an environmentally detrimental fashion,
whether intentionally or negligently. Laws can and should be enacted to
avoid such outcomes these should be explored in further research. Simi-
larly, res nullius property requires support by laws to ensure resources are
managed effectively.
5. Conclusions
Industrial symbiosis has been identied as a conducive strategy for pro-
moting and achieving a number of EU resource efciency and circular econ-
omy policy goals (see Section 1), as well as international aims, such as the
United Nations Sustainable Development Goals (Schroeder et al. 2019;
Cecchin et al. 2020). There have therefore beencalls for widespread imple-
mentation of industrial symbioses, but further research is needed on how
this can be facilitated. This paper has contributed to this research gap by ex-
amining the role of property rights in enabling industrial symbiosis.
Property rights in waste and by-products need careful thought and con-
sideration in different contexts, as they can affect how waste is conceived
and treated. Yet, property rights are currently not consciously engaged
with or used to incentivize development of industrial symbiosis practices.
Four possible property regimes were presented (private, state, commu-
nal, and res nullius) and there is evidence that all four can have positive en-
abling effects on industrial symbiosis.Private property regimes canresult in
the commodication of waste and see it treated as an economic good of
value as in Kalundborg and Peterborough, but simultaneously a monetary
incentive is not always necessary to achieve a private exchange for environ-
mental purposes as in Rotterdam. Only the perception of a resnullius prop-
erty regime was encountered in practice in Rotterdam. It resulted in certain
stakeholders taking initiative to turn waste into something of value. Simi-
larly, there was also only the perception of communal property rights that
again enabled certain stakeholders to turn waste into a product perceived
to have value. Finally, there was evidence of state property (Lake Tissø in
Kalundborg and municipal solid waste in Peterborough), but these were
not the main focus and require further examination.
There is currently no evidence to suggest that any of the three alterna-
tive property regimes is more conducive to promoting industrial symbiosis.
It is therefore recommended that any contemporary selection of property
rights is context dependent. The current EU context appears more favorable
to private property regimes as they are central to the existing capitalist
economy (e.g. Screpanti 1999), whereas communal property regimes
would require a more fundamental shift in thinking about waste as a collec-
tive responsibility. Whichever property regime is intended to produce
incentivizing effects wouldneed further implementation of legal structures,
as currently their potential is not being harnessed.
Questions remain on, for example, the responsibilities and duties the
state should have in relation to wastes and by-products; whether communal
ownership should be limited to a dened community (limited access) or in-
clude everyone in the world (open access); the legal and regulatory frame-
works required to support and complement property regimes to ensure the
desired resource management; and the impacts of the WFD's end-of-waste
denition. In particular, further research is needed to explore the effects
of all property regimes to elucidate their suitability as property regimes
for incentivizing and facilitating replicability of industrial symbiosis and
circularity. Such research needs to be complemented by investigations of
law and policy tools that are dependent on the existence of a particular
property regime and require or nudge waste producers or holders to man-
age waste in a particular manner by assigning particular duties. Examples
of such mechanisms include product take-back programs, EPR, and other
types of producer ownership schemes (e.g. UCL ISR and Systemiq 2019).
Declaration of Competing Interest
The authors declare that they have no known competing nancial inter-
ests or personal relationships that could have appeared to inuence the
work reported in this paper.
Acknowledgements
Thank you to Dr. Ine Steenmans, Dr. Phillip Taylor, and Lore Steenmans
for their comments and suggestions.
References
de Abreu, M.C.S., Ceglia, D., 2018. On the implementation of a circular economy: the role of
institutional capacity-building through industrial symbiosis. Resour. Conserv. Recycl.
138, 99109. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2018.07.001.
Afvalstoffenverordening Rotterdam, 2009. 2009 van 1 januari.
Baas, L., 1998. Cleaner production and industrial ecosystems, a Dutch experience. J. Clean.
Prod. 6 (34), 189197. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0959-6526(98)00015-8.
Baas, L., 2000. Developing an industrial ecosystem in Rotterdam: Learning by what? J. Ind.
Ecol. 4 (2), 46. https://doi.org/10.1162/108819800569753.
Baas, L., Boons, F.A.,2004. An industrialecology project in practice: exploring the boundaries
of decision-making levels in regional industrial systems. J. Clean. Prod. 12 (810),
10731085. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2004.02.005.
Baas, L., Korevaar, G., 2011. Eco-industrial parks in the Netherlands: The Rotterdam Harbor
and industry complex. In: Harmsen, J., Powell, J.B. (Eds.), Sustainable Development in
the Process Industries: Cases and Impact. Wiley, Hoboken.
Barry, D., Meinzen-Dick, R., 2014. The invisible map: Community tenure rights. In: Hecht,
S.B., Morrison, K.D., Padoch, C. (Eds.), The Social Lives of Forests: Past, Present, and Fu-
ture of Woodland Resurgence. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Baur, I., Binder, C.R., 2013. Adapting to socioeconomic developments by changing rules in
the governance of common property pastures in the Swiss Alps. Ecol. Soc. 18 (4),
6075. https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-05689-180460.
BBC, 2011. Who, what, why: Is taking rubbish illegal? www.bbc.co.uk/news/magazine-
13037808 Accessed May 2018
Behne, B.A., 2016. Industrial ecology analysis of the potential for an Eastern Nebraska Indus-
trial Symbiosis Network (ENISN): A comparative study. Masters thesis. University of Ne-
braska, Lincoln, Nebraska, USA.
Bekendtgørelse af lov nr 1309 af 18.12.2012 om affald some aendret
Affaldsbekendtgoerelsen.
Berkes, F., 1987. The common property resource problem and the sheries of Barbados and
Jamaica. Environ. Manag. 11 (2), 225235. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01867201.
Blackstone II, W., 1765-1769. Commentaries on the Laws of England. Clarendon Press,
Oxford.
Bouriaud, L., Smithüsen, F., 2005.Allocation of property rights on forests through ownership
reform and forest policies in Central and eastern European countries. Swiss Forestry J.
156 (8), 297305. https://doi.org/10.3188/szf.2005.0297.
Bromley, D.W., 1989. Property relations and economic development: the other land reform.
World Dev. 17, 867877. https://doi.org/10.1016/0305-750X(89)90008-9.
Bryman, A., 2008. Social Research Methods. 3rd edition. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Case C-176/05, 2007. KVZ retec GmbH and Republik Österreich ECR I-1721.
Case C-188/07, 2008. Commune de Mesquerv Total France SA, Total International Ltd ECR I-
04501.
Case C-235/02, 2004. Saetti and Frediani ECR I-1005.
Case C-252/05, 2007. Thames Water Utilities Ltd v South East London Division, Bromley
MagistratesCourt ECR I-3903.
Case C-304/94, 1997. Euro Tombesi and Others ECR I-3561.
Case C-444/00, 2003. Mayer Parry Recycling Ltd and Environmental Agency, Secretary of
State for the Environment, Transport and the Regions ECR I-6163.
K. Steenmans Current Research in Environmental Sustainability 3 (2021) 100030
9
Case C-457/02, 2004. Niselli ECR I-10875.
Case C-9/00, 2002. Palin Granit and Vehmassalon kansanterveystyön kuntayhtymän hallitus
ECR I-3533.
Cecchin, A., Salomone, R., Deutz, P., Raggi, A., Cutaia, L., 2020. Relating industrial symbiosis
and circular economy to the sustainable development debate. In: Salomone, R., Cecchin,
A., Deutz, P., Raggi, A., Cutaia, L. (Eds.), Industrial Symbiosis for the Circular Economy:
Operational Experiences, Best Practices and Obstacles to a Collaborative Business Ap-
proach. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-36660-5.
Chang, Y.-C., Smith, H.E., 2016. Structure and style in comparative property law. In:
Eisenberg, T., Ramello, G.B. (Eds.), Comparative Law and Economics. Edward Elgar,
Cheltenham.
Charmaz, K., 2006. Constructing Grounded Theory: A Practical Guide through Qualitative
Analysis. SAGE Publications, London.
Chertow, M., Ashton, W., Kuppalli, R., 2004. The industrial symbiosis research symposium at
Yale: Advancing the study of industry and environment. Yale F&ES Publication Series.
Report Number 3.
Chertow, M.R., 2007. Uncoveringindustrial symbiosis. J. Ind. Ecol. 11 (1), 1130. https://
doi.org/10.1162/jiec.2007.1110.
Chertow, M.R., Lombardi, D.R., 2005. Quantifying economic and environmental benets of
co-located rms. Environ. Sci. Technol. 39 (17), 65356541. https://doi.org/10.1021/
es050050+.
Cheyne, I., Purdue, M., 1995. Fitting denition to purpose: the search for a satisfactory de-
nition of waste. J. Environ. Law 7 (2), 149168. https://doi.org/10.1093/jel/7.2.149.
Ciriacy-Wantryp, S.V., Bishop, R.C., 1975.Common-property as a concept in natural resource
policy.Nat.Resour.J.15,713727.
Clarke, A., Kohler, P., 2005. Property Law: Commentary and Materials. CambridgeUniversity
Press, Cambridge.
Clarke, A., Malcolm, R., 2016. The role of property in water regulation: Locating communal
and regulatory property rights on the property rights spectrum. In: Godt, C. (Ed.), Regu-
latory Property Rights: The Transforming Notion of Property in Transnational Business
Regulation. Brill/Nijhoff, Leiden.
Clayton, A., Muirhead, J., Reichgelt, H., 2002. Enabling industrial symbiosis through a web-
based waste exchange. Greener Management International 40 (2), 93106. https://doi.
org/10.9774/GLEAF.3062.2002.wi.00008.
Clift, R., 1997. The ECTEL trials. J. Ind. Ecol. 1 (2), 35. https://doi.org/10.1162/
jiec.1997.1.2.3.
Commons, J.R., 1924. Legal Foundations of Capitalism. The Macmillan Company, New York.
Dalhuisen, J.H., 2013. Transnational Comparative, Commercial, Financial and Trade Law.
Volume 2. 5th edition. Hart Publishing, London.
Demsetz,H., 1967. Toward a theory of property rights. Am. Economic Assoc. 57(2), 347359.
https://doi.org/10.1057/9780230523210_9.
Desrochers, P., 2012. Freedom versus coercion in industrial ecology: a reply to Boons. Eco-
nomic J. Watch 9 (2), 7899.
Dictionary, Oxford English, 2018. Resource, n. www.oed.com Accessed August 2018.
Directive 2008/98/EC on waste and repealing certain directives (2008) OJ L312/3.
Directive 2018/851 amending Directive 2008/98/EC on waste (2018) OJ L150/09.
Doménech, T., Davies, M., 2011. The role of embeddedness in industrial symbiosis networks:
Phases in the evolution of industrial symbiosis networks. Bus. Strateg. Environ. 20,
281296. https://doi.org/10.1002/bse.695.
Domenech,T., Bleischwitz, R.,Doroanova, A., Panayotopoulos,D., Roman, L., 2019. Mapping
industrial symbiosis development in Europe: Typologies of networks, characteristics, per-
formance and contribution to the Circular Economy. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 141,
7698. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2018.09.016.
Economy,Circle, 2020. The Circularity GapReport 2020 (Available on circularity-gap.world).
Edwards, V., 2013. A review ofthe court of justice's caselaw in relation to waste and environ-
mental impact assessment: 19922011. J. Environ.Law 25 (3), 515530. https://doi.org/
10.1093/jel/eqt026.
Ehrenfeld, J., Gertler, N., 1997. Industrial ecology in practice: the evolution of interdepen-
dence at Kalundborg. J. Ind. Ecol. 1 (1), 6779. https://doi.org/10.1162/
jiec.1997.1.1.67.
Ellickson, R.C., 2011. Two cheers for the bundle-of-sticks metaphor, three cheers for Merrill
and Smith. Economic J. Watch 8 (3), 215222.
Environmental Protection Act 1990.
van Erp, S., 2006a. Comparative property law. In: Reimann, M., Zimmermann, R. (Eds.), The
Oxford Handbook of Comparative Law. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
van Erp, S., 2006b. European and National Property Law: Osmosis or Growing Antagonism.
Europa Law Publishing, Amsterdam.
European Commission, 2011. Roadmap to a resource efcient Europe. Communication. COM
(2011) 571 nal.
European Commission, 2012. Circular European Resource Efciency Platform: Manifesto and
policy recommendations. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/resource_efciency/docu-
ments/erep_manifesto_and_policy_recommendations_31-03-2014.pdf Accessed March
2019.
European Commission, 2020. A new circular economy action plan. Commun. COM(2020) 98
nal.
European Commission DG Environment News Alert Service, 2012. Regulatory barriers to in-
dustrialsymbiosis in the metalsector. https://ec.europa.eu/environment/integration/re-
search/newsalert/pdf/291na2_en.pdf Accessed August 2019.
Fluck, J., 1994. The term wastein EU law. Eur. Environ. Law Rev. 3, 7984.
Flyvbjerg, B., 2006. Five misunderstandings about case-study research. Qualitative Enquiry
12 (2), 219245. https://doi.org/10.1177/1077800405284363.
France-Hudson, B., 2017. Surprisingly social: private property and environmental manage-
ment. J. Environ. Law 29, 101127. https://doi.org/10.1093/jel/eqw032.
Geissdoerfer, M., Savaget, P., Bocken, N.M.P., Hultink, E.J., 2017.The circular economy = a
new sustainabilityparadigm? J. Clean.Prod. 143 (1), 757768. https://doi.org/10.1016/
j.jclepro.2016.12.048.
Gertler, N., 1995. Industrial ecosystems: Developing sustainable industries. Masters thesis.
Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Boston, MA, USA.
Giurco, D.,Prior, J., Boydell, S.,2014. Industrial ecology and carbon property rights. J. Clean.
Prod. 80, 211223. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2014.05.079.
Grant, G.B., Seager, T.P., Massard, G., Lies,L., 2010. Informationand communicationtechnol-
ogy for industrial symbiosis. J. Ind. Ecol. 14 (5), 740753. https://doi.org/10.1111/
j.1530-9290.2010.00273.x.
H&M, 2018. Recycle your clothes. www.hm.com/garment-collecting Accessed July 2018.
Hammersley, M., 1996. The relationship between qualitative and quantitative reserach:
Paradigm loyalty versus methodological eclecticism. In: Richardson, J.T.E. (Ed.),
Handbook of Qualitative Reserach in Psychology and the Social Sciences. BPS Black-
well, Oxford.
Hanna, S., Folke, C., Mäler, K.-G., 1995. Property rights and environmental resources. In:
Hanna, S., Muasinghe, M. (Eds.), Property Rights and the Environment. Beijer Interna-
tional Institute of Ecological Economics and The World Bank, Washington.
Hardin, G., 1968. The tragedy of the commons. Science 162 (3859), 12431248. https://doi.
org/10.1126/science.162.3859.1243.
Hashimoto, S., Fujita, T., Geng, Y., Nagasawa, E., 2010. Realizing CO
2
emission reduction
through industrial symbiosis: a cement production case study for Kawasaki. Resour.
Conserv. Recycl. 54 (10), 704710. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2009.11.013.
Heller, M.A., 2000. Three faces of private property. Oregon Law Rev. 79, 417434.
Herranz, A.G., 2018. Dutch project gives plastic waste new life as oating park. https://en.
reset.org/blog/dutch-project-gives-plastic-waste-new-life-oating-park-07172018
Accessed April 2020.
Hutchinson, T., 2013. Doctrinal research: Researching the jury. In: Watkins, D., Burton, M.
(Eds.), Research Methods in Law. Routledge, Oxon.
Jacobsen, N.B., 2002. The industrial symbiosisin Kalundborg, Denmark Industrial network-
ing and cleaner industrial production. In: Lens, P., Hulshoff Pol,L., Wilderer, P., Asano, T.
(Eds.), Water Recycling and Resource Recovery in Industry: Analysis, Technologies and
Implementation. IWA, London.
Jacobsen, N.B., Anderberg, S., 2004. Understanding the evolution of industrial symbiotic net-
works: The case of Kalundborg. In: van den Bergh, J., Janssen, M. (Eds.), Economics of
Industrial Ecology: Materials, Structural Change, and Spatial Scales. MIT Press,
Cambridge.
Jambeck, W., Geyer, R., Wilcox, C., Siegler, T.R., Perryman, M., Andradt, A., Narayan, R.,
Law, K.L., 2015. Plastic waste inputs from land into the ocean. Science 347 (6223),
768771. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1260352.
Johnson, D.R., 2007. Reections on the bundle of rights. Vermont Law Review 32, 247272.
Joined Cases C-206/88 and C-207/88, 1990. Vessoso and Zanetti ECR I-1461.
Joined Cases C-241/12 and C-242/12, 2013. Shell Nederland Verkoopmaatschappij BV and
Belgian Shell NV ECR I-821.
Joined Cases C-418/97 and C-419/97, 2000. ARCO Chemie Nederland Ltd v Minister van
Volkshuisvesting, Ruimtelijke Ordening en Milieubeheer, Vereniging Dorpsbelang Hees
and Others v Directeur van de dienst Milieu en Water van de provincie Gelderland ECR
I-4475.
Judge, R.P., 2002. Restoring the commons: Toward a new interpretation of Lockes theory of
property. Land Economics 78 (3), 331338. https://doi.org/10.2307/3146893.
Kaza, S., Yao,L., Bhada-Tata, P.,Van Woerden, F., 2018. What a Waste 2.0. A Global Snapshot
of Solid Waste Management to 2050. International Bank for Reconstruction and Develop-
ment / The World Bank, Washington.
Kirchherr,J., Reike, D., Hekkert, M., 2017. Conceptualizing the circular economy: an analysis
of 114 denitions. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 127, 221232. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
resconrec.2017.09.005.
Lange, B., Shepheard, M., 2014. Changing conceptions ofrights to water? an eco-socio-legal
perspective. J. Environ. Law 26 (2), 215242. https://doi.org/10.1093/jel/equ013.
Laybourn, P., 2005. Delivering the circular economy. Paper presented at Seeding the
BioEconomy 15 March, Edmonton.
Leopold, A., 1968. A Sand County Almanac and Sketches Here and there. Oxford University
Press, Oxford.
Libecap, G.D., 2009. The tragedy of the commons: property rights and markets as solutions to
resource and environmental problems. Aust. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 53 (1), 129144.
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8489.2007.00425.x.
Lieber, F., 1838. Legal and Political Hermeneutics. CC Little and J Brown, Boston.
Lindhqvist, T., 2000. Extended producer responsibility in cleaner production: Policy principle
to promote environmental improvements of product systems. Ph.D. thesis. Lund Univer-
sity, Lund, Sweden.
Locke, J., 1980. In: Macpherson, C.B. (Ed.), Second treatise of government. Hackett Publish-
ing Company Inc., Indianapolis.
Lowe, E.A., Evans, L.K., 1995. Industrial ecology and industrial ecosystems. J. Clean. Prod. 3
(12), 4753. https://doi.org/10.1016/0959-6526(95)00045-G.
Macpherson, C.B., 1978. The meaning of property. In: Macpherson, C.B. (Ed.), Property:
Mainstream and Critical Positions. University of Toronto Press, Toronto.
Maitre-Ekern, E., 2021. Re-thinking producer responsibility for a sustainable circular econ-
omy from extended producer responsibility to pre-market producer responsibility.
J. Clean. Prod. 281 (1). https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.125454.
Malcolm, R., Clarke, A., 2017. Water: A common treasury. In: Xu, T., Clarke, A. (Eds.), Legal
Strategies for the Development and Protection of Communal Property. Oxford University
Press, Oxford.
Malcolm, R., Clift, R., 2002. Barriers to industrial ecology: the strange case of the Tombesi
Bypass. J. Ind. Ecol. 6 (1), 47. https://doi.org/10.1162/108819802320971588.
Masteroast, 2016. Peterboroughcoffee sack recycling scheme. www.masteroast.co.uk/latest-
news/coffee-sack-recycling-scheme, Accessed date: March 2017.
Mattei, U., 2000. Basic Principles of Property Law: A Comparative Legal and Economic Intro-
duction. Greenwood Press, Westport.
Merli, R., Preziosi, M., Acampora, A., 2018.How do scholars approach the circular economy?
A systematic literature review. J. Clean. Prod. 178, 703722.
K. Steenmans Current Research in Environmental Sustainability 3 (2021) 100030
10
Merriam-Webster, 2018. Denition of resource. www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/re-
source Accessed August 2018.
Morales, E.M., Diemer, A., Cervantes, G., Carrillo-González, G., 2019. By-product synergy
changes inthe industrial symbiosis dynamics at the Altamira-Tampico industrial corridor:
20 years of industrialecology in Mexico. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 140, 235245. https://
doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2018.09.026.
Morris, C., Murphy, C.C., 2011. Getting a PhD in Law. Hart Publishing, London.
Neves, A., Godina, R., Azevedo, S.G., Matias, J.C.O., 2020. A comprehensive review of indus-
trial symbiosis. J. Clean. Prod. 247. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.119113.
Orsi, F., 2014. Elinor Ostrom et les faisceaux de droits: lOuverture dun nouvel espace pour
penser la propriété-commune. Revue de la Régulation 14. https://doi.org/10.4000/
regulation.10471.
Ostrom, E., 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Ac-
tion. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Ostrom, E., 2002. Property-rights regimes and goods: A complex link. In: Héritier, A. (Ed.),
Common Goods: Reinventing European and International Governance. Rowman &
Littleeld Publishers, Lanham.
Park, Recycled, 2018. What is Recycled Park? http://recycledpark.com/introduction.html
Accessed August 2018
Pawson, R., 2013. Science of Evaluation: A Realist Manifesto. SAGE Publications, London.
Pawson, R., Tiley, N., 1997. Realistic evaluation. SAGE Publicaitons, London.
Penner, J.E., 1996. The bundle of rightspicture of property. UCLA Law Rev. 43, 711820.
Peterborough Reuse, 2017. www.peterboroughreuse.co.uk Accessed February 2017.
Posner, R.A., 1981. Thepresent situation in legal scholarship. Yale J. Law 90 (5), 11131130.
Raabe, B., Low, J.S.C., Juraschek,M., Hermann, C., Tjandra, T.B., Ng, Y.T., Kurle, D., Cerdas,
F., Lueckenga, J., Yeo, Z., Tan, Y.S., 2017. Collaboration platform for enabling industrial
symbiosis: Application of the by-product exchange network model. Procedia CIRP 61,
263268. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.procir.2016.11.225.
Rotterdamclimate Initiative,2018. About RCI. www.rotterdamclimateinitiative.nl/uk/about-
rci/rci-at-a-glance Accessed August 2018.
RotterdamClimate Initiative, 2018a. www.rotterdamclimateinitiative.nl Accessed June 2018.
Rotterdam Climate Initiative, 2018b. Ongoing projects. www.rotterdamclimateinitiative.nl/
UK/city/ongoing-projects Accessed 27 June 2018.
Saldaña, J., 2012. The Coding Manual for Qualitative Researchers. SAGE Publications,
London.
Sathre, R., Grdzelishvili, I., 2006. Industrial symbiosis in the former Soviet Union. Progress in
Industrial Ecology An Int. J. 3 (4), 379392. https://doi.org/10.1504/
PIE.2006.011743.
Schlager, E., Ostrom, E., 1992. Property-rights regimes and natural resources: a conceptual
analysis. Land Econ. 68 (3), 249262. https://doi.org/10.2307/3146375.
Schroeder, P., Anggraeni, K., Weber, U., 2019. The relevance of circular economy practices to
the Sustainable Development Goals. J. Ind. Ecol. 23 (1), 7795. https://doi.org/10.1111/
jiec.12732.
Scotford, E., 2007. Trash or treasure: Policy tensions in EC waste regulation. J. Environ. Law
19, 367388. https://doi.org/10.1093/jel/eqm022.
Screpanti, E., 1999. Capitalistforms and the essence of capitalism. Rev. Int. Polit. Econ. 6 (1),
126. https://doi.org/10.1080/096922999347326.
Siems, M., 2014. Comparative Law. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Stebek, E.N., 2011. Rethinking de fa cto rural open access to common-pool resources in
Ethiopia. Mizan Law Review 5 (1), 140. https://doi.org/10.4314/mlr.v5i1.68766.
Steenmans, K., 2018. Enabling industrial symbiosis through regulations, policies and property
rights. Ph.D. thesis. University of Surrey, Guildford, UK.
Steenmans, K., 2019. Extended producer responsibility:an assessment of recentamendments
to the European Union Waste Framework Directive. Law, Environ. Develo. J. 15, 116.
Steenmans, K., Malcolm, R., 2020. Transitioning towards circular systems: Property rights in
waste. J. Property, Plann. Environ. Law 12 (3), 219234. https://doi.org/10.1108/
JPPEL-03-2020-0018.
Steenmans, K., Malcolm,R., Marriott, J., 2017. Commodication of waste: Legal and theoret-
ical approaches to industrial symbiosis as part of a circular economy. Paper presented at
SMART Conference on Life-cycle based Management and Reporting for Sustainable Busi-
ness, 29-30 November, Oslo.
Steenmans, K., Malcolm, R., Clarke, A., 2020. Guest editorial: Rethinking property approaches
in resources for the circular economy. J. Property, Plann. Environ. Law 12 (3), 185186.
Symbiosis, Kalundborg, 2018. Explore the Kalundborg Symbiose. www.symbiosis.dk/en/
Accessed September 2018.
Thayer, E.R., 1908. Legal essays. Boston Book, Boston.
The Guardian, 2014. Three charged with stealing food from skipbehind Iceland supermarket.
www.theguardian.com/uk-news/2014/jan/28/three-charged-vagrancy-act-food-skip-
iceland Accessed May 2018.
Thomas, S., 2019. Personalproperty law for a zero-wastecircular economy: using retentionof
title clauses to reduce plastics waste. Law, Environ. Develo. J. 15 (2), 176207.
Tromans, S., 2001. EC waste lawa complete mess? J. Environ. Law 13, 133156. https://
doi.org/10.1093/jel/13.2.133.
UCL ISR and Systemiq, 2019. Making materials work for life Introducing producer owner-
ship. www.systemiq.earth/wp-content/uploads/2020/02/Producer-Ownership-Project-
LAUNCH-White-Paper.pdf Accessed April 2020.
Van Calster, G., 1997. The EC denition of waste: the Euro Tombesi Bypass and the Basel Re-
lief Routes. Eur. Business Law Rev. 5 (6), 137143.
VerdraaidGoed, 2018. VerdraaidGoed: Maakt waardelos weer waardevol. https://
verdraaidgoed.nl Accessed August 2018.
Waldron, J., 1984. Locke, Tully and the regulation of property. Political Studies 32 (1),
98106. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9248.1984.tb00168.x.
Waldron, J., 1988. Right to Private Property. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Waste (England and Wales) Regulations 2011, SI 2011/988.
Welch, W.P., 1983. The political feasibility of full ownership property rights: the cases of pol-
lution and sheries. Policy. Sci. 16, 165180. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00138349.
Wet milieubeheer van 13 juni 1979.
Widerquist, K., 2010. Lockean theories of property: Justications for unilateral appropriation.
Public Reason 2 (1), 326.
Williams and Others v Phillips and Roberts and Others v Phillips (1957) 41 Cr. App. R. 5.
Yin, R.K., 2009. Case Study Research: Design and Methods. 4th edition. SAGE Publications,
London.
K. Steenmans Current Research in Environmental Sustainability 3 (2021) 100030
11
... It is relevant to mention the promotion of circular economies at regional level (Silvestri et al. 2020;Chen et al. 2021). In some cases, industries and other organizations exchange their waste and its by-products to be reused, resulting in social, economic, and environmental benefits for both parties (Steenmans 2021). Sustainable consumption is also achieved with the circular economy because it is considered an effective way to achieve Sustainable Development Goals (Silvestri et al. 2020;Chen et al. 2021). ...
Chapter
Full-text available
An increase in consumerism and the use of plastic severely affect the faunal diversity of the planet due to the lack of proper disposal techniques. Inserted in the discussion of SDG 12, ensure sustainable consumption and production patterns, this chapter aims to analyze strategies and the environmental impact of the use of reusable bags in direct sales systems between farmers and consumers, through literature review and success case. The SDGs were addressed by the UN in the 2030 Agenda with goals and indicators that contemplate society and the environment. One month later, this action resulted in approximately 20% less use of plastic bags at the producer’s fair. It has brought a vision of sustainability to the activity, and in parallel to this, it broadened the farmers’ and consumers’ knowledge about production and consumption. The social action also disseminated the importance of using returnable bags
Article
Full-text available
The purpose of this article is to study existing and emerging trends in property relations, which have a significant impact on the investment attractiveness of the country. This study is relevant because insufficient attention is paid to the issues of a comprehensive assessment of property relations as a key indicator of investment attractiveness in the context of Next Normality and Industry 4.0. The systematization method as a cognition function of economic processes has been used. The application results of general scientific research methods, using tabular and graphical methods are clearly presented by the authors. The peculiarities of the historical development and relations of property formation taking into account the concept of the Fourth Industrial Revolution (Industry 4.0) are considered in the article. An abstract concept of property relations is analyzed, as well as general scientific methods of systematization, explanation, and forecasting, with elements of synthesis and elementary theoretical analysis in order to identify the latest trends in research, are applied in the article. The study identified factors of positive and negative impact, that affect the investment attractiveness of Ukraine for foreign investors, namely: increasing the importance of the intellectual property impact and its protection rights to it; the growing role of virtual organizations; increasing the possibility of goods counterfeiting (due to 3D printing); significant benefits for inventors, shareholders and investors, who simultaneously provide intellectual and physical capital, increase the level of general confidence in the economic system; updating issues of brand registration; the problem of property rights in the circular economy; reforming property relations. The dynamics and parts of organizational and legal forms of legal entities of Ukraine for 2015–2020 are described. A detailed analysis of methodological approaches of foreign and domestic scientists, in order to identify key factors for improving investment attractiveness, is made in the article, and also, reforming property relations in the context of Next Normality and Industry 4.0 is proposed by the authors.
Article
Full-text available
Ensuring the growth of the national economy, economic efficiency and freedom is impossible without knowledge of the ba- sics of economic systems, which are associated with the study of the nature and patterns of previous economic theories. In order to understand the current state and develop optimal models of economic development of Ukraine, the history and basic ideas of economic doctrines from mercantilism, physiocracy, classical political theory to Marxism, Keynesianism, monetarism and institutionalism are considered. Clarification of the essence and patterns of historically previous doctrines and the current state of economic relations is associated with the definition of characteristics and scientific concepts of economic doctrines that are important for understanding possible trends and directions of their future development, as well as for developing and forming optimal models of economic relations. The studied doctrines are based both on the methodology of economic science and the history of economic doctrines, and on the junction of methods of history, philosophy and sociology. The history of economic development of Ukraine as a component of world history, economic teachings of prominent Ukrainian scientists are given. Within the framework of the transitional period of market transformation, which is taking place in Ukraine, the most relevant for further economic growth, improving the welfare of society economic theories are presented. Practical value of the article lies in the study that in order to implement economic policy through institutional measures in the development of economic pro- grams proposed the use of certain laws and categories of economic life through Keynesianism, monetarism and institutionalism. Scientific concepts of economic theories that are relevant today are presented,in particular: Mercantilism, which reflects the transition from the accumulation of capital to the transformation of trade capital into industrial capital, is associated with the need to develop an export industry that operates on domestic or imported raw materials; Macroeconomic model of movement of aggregate product is connected with physiocracy; The classical model of economics is associated with the use of functional analysis, economic modeling, maximum of economic freedom, microeconomics; Marxism is associated with the concept of cri- sis theory, the theory of capital; Keynesianism is associated with long-term regulation of the economy in the form of national planning, state participation in economic restructuring; Monetarism is concerned with taking into account the macroeconomic effects of the money supply and the activities of central banks; Theories of industrial-technocratic institutionalism, evolutionary institutionalism, the theory of industrial and post-industrial society are connected with institutionalism. Keywords: economics, economic doctrine, state regulation, capital, crisis theory, market, method.
Article
Full-text available
This paper identifies the extent to which circular economy (CE) practices are relevant for the implementation of the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs). The results of a literature review and a matching exercise to determine the relationship between CE practices and SDG targets show that CE practices, potentially, can contribute directly to achieving a significant number of SDG targets. The strongest relationships exist between CE practices and the targets of SDG 6 (Clean Water and Sanitation), SDG 7 (Affordable and Clean Energy), SDG 8 (Decent Work and Economic Growth), SDG 12 (Responsible Consumption and Production), and SDG 15 (Life on Land). The paper also explores synergies that can be created through CE practices among several of the SDG targets. Furthermore, it identifies several potential trade-offs between targets for decent work, safe working environments, human health and current CE practices relating to recycling of municipal waste, e-waste and wastewater, and provides suggestions how these can be overcome. The paper concludes that CE practices can be applied as a “toolbox” and specific implementation approaches for achieving a sizeable number of SDG targets. Further empirical research is necessary to determine which specific types of partnerships and means of implementation are required to apply CE practices in the SDG context.
Article
Full-text available
Purpose The purpose of this paper is to explore the impact that property rights can have on the implementation of circular waste economies, in which waste is reused, recycled or recovered, within the European Union’s Waste Framework Directive. Design/methodology/approach A theoretical lens is applied to the legal definition as well as production and treatment cycle of waste to understand the property rights that can exist in waste. Findings This paper argues that even though different property rights regimes can apply to waste during its creation, disposal and recovery, the waste management regulatory and legal system is currently predominantly set up to support waste within classic forms of private property ownership. This tends towards commodification and linear systems, which are at odds with an approach that treats waste as a primary wanted resource rather than an unwanted by-product. It is recommended that adopting state or communal property approaches instead could affect systemic transformative change by facilitating the reconceptualisation of waste as a resource for everyone to use. Research limitations/implications The property rights issues are only one dimension of a bigger puzzle. The roles of social conceptualisation, norms, regulations and policies in pursuing circular strategies are only touched upon, but not fully explored in this paper. These provide other avenues that can be underpinned by certain property regimes to transition to circular economies. Originality/value The literature focused on property rights in waste has been very limited to date. To the best of the authors’ knowledge, this paper is the first to consider this question in detail from a legal perspective.
Article
‘Communal’ property is an important mechanism for allocating natural resources and regulating their use – whether for economic exploitation, recreational use or the promotion of biodiversity and nature conservation. The form which communal property regimes take, however, and their relationship to private property structures, varies from jurisdiction to jurisdiction and is poorly understood. Nevertheless, the importance of communal property, transcending the public/private divide in property rights, is increasingly apparent globally. Contributions to this volume focus on legal strategies for the development and protection of communal property and how these strategies ‘map’ over different jurisdictions (England and Wales, Scotland, South Africa, Cameroon, Italy, Israel and China) and jurisprudential approaches. They look at property beyond the traditional, individualist, and exclusive ownership model, engaging with communal property ‘practices’ in different jurisdictions to explore the theoretical grounding of communal property, not only linking theory with practice but also linking the local with the global.
Article
The transition to a sustainable Circular Economy (CE) requires moving away from linear production processes and the throwaway mentality. Waste needs to be prevented and the consumption of new products must decline. In particular, this involves extending product lifetime (through maintenance and repair) and supporting second-hand trading (reuse). Such a transformation of consumption patterns requires a fundamental change notably in business models. The role of the law is to enable the change. For a long time, the objective of retaining the primary value of products has been linked to waste prevention, which is the main priority of the waste hierarchy as laid out in the EU Waste Framework Directive, 2008/98/EC. However, waste law appears somewhat ill-suited to address these issues. The incentives provided by the extended producer responsibility (EPR) scheme are limited when it comes to promoting upstream design changes. In line with what Lindhqvist, the father of EPR in Europe, originally had in mind, the responsibility of producers should cover products’ entire life cycle, not just their end-of-life. This article explores the current tensions between EU waste law and the objectives of the CE, and calls for incorporating a pre-market producer responsibility (PPR) within a legal framework for products in order to limit market access to durable, reparable and reusable products.
Chapter
Industrial Symbiosis (IS) is a business-focused collaborative approach oriented towards resource efficiency that has been theorised and studied mainly over the last 25 years. Recently, IS seems to have found a renewed impetus in the framework of the Circular Economy (CE), a novel approach to sustainability and Sustainable Development (SD) that has been rapidly gaining momentum worldwide. This opening chapter of the book provides an introduction to the concepts of IS, CE and SD, and summarises their complex evolutionary paths, recalling the relevant developments and implementation challenges. In addition, the authors point out the divergences and interrelations of these concepts, both among themselves and with other related concepts and research fields, such as industrial ecology, ecological modernisation and the green economy. Furthermore, the potential contribution of IS and the CE to SD is briefly discussed, also highlighting critical issues and trade-offs, as well as gaps in research and application, especially relating to the social component of sustainability. Particular attention is given to the potential role of IS in the achievement of targets connected to the Sustainable Development Goals set in the UN Agenda 2030. The recent advances in the IS and CE discussion in the context of the SD research community are further explored, with particular emphasis on the contribution of the International Sustainable Development Research Society (ISDRS) and its 24th annual conference organised in Messina, Italy, in 2018. The programme of that conference, indeed, included specific tracks on the above-mentioned themes, the contents of which are briefly commented on here, after an overview of the whole conference and the main cross-cutting concepts emerged. In the last part of the chapter, a brief description of the chapters collected in the book is presented. These contributions describe and discuss theoretical frameworks, methodological approaches and/or experiences and case studies where IS and the principles of CE are applied in different geographical contexts and at different scales to ultimately improve the sustainability of the current production patterns.
Article
The literature on circular economy consistently references the possibility of an end to waste, and this remains the case in the specific instance of plastics. The doctrine on waste shows the central role of control in the test for whether goods are waste. Thus, a vital step in dealing with plastics waste in a circular economy is to develop mechanisms to provide the necessary levels of control of goods to avoid such wastes from occurring. This article will examine how English personal property law can help address the problem of control of plastics. Specifically, the doctrine of retention of title will be examined. Retention of title clauses may provide means to control plastics surplus and waste down chains of transactions. It is suggested that the strong policy underlying circular economics justifies an alternative interpretation of the doctrine, allowing for the use of retention of title clauses to extend into products. However, in light of the strength of the orthodox perception of the inability of retention of title to extend into products, an alternative approach may be required. Thus, this article addresses the recent development in sales law wrought by the Supreme Court in PST Energy 7 Shipping LLC v O W Bunker Malta Limited [2016] UKSC 23. There it was held that retention of title clauses can take transactions outside the normal statutory framework for sales and generate sui generis contracts of sale. Such contracts arguably enable effective long-term control of goods down chains of transactions. This article thus contends that English personal property law could provide an ideal doctrinal framework for the implementation of circular economic practices, but at the expense of a significant shift in thinking, with the rise of licences for use rather than sales as appropriate transactional forms.