ChapterPDF Available

The Role of Money for a Healthy Economy

Authors:

Abstract

If we take a look at any newspaper in any country, two major problems frequently are addressed: inequality and the increasing destruction of the natural environment, that is unsustainability in the stricto sensu.
The Role of Money for a Healthy
Economy
Felix Fuders
1 Key Messages
1. All but one of the SDGs are directly linked to our current financial system which—
being completely unnatural—can be seen as the most important but at the same
time least recognized reason for market failure.
2. Only if we change the unnatural design of our money to a more natural one as
proposed 100 years ago by Silvio Gesell, we will be able to create a healthier
economy and reach the goals.
3. Such a reform of our financial system will also reduce the possibility of the
occurrence of major financial crisis and, furthermore, could be an alternative
way to address the imminent economic crisis that threatens world economy as a
result of the COVID-19 quarantine measures.
2 Background: The World Is on a Collision Course
If we take a look at any newspaper in any country, two major problems frequently
are addressed: inequality and the increasing destruction of the natural environment,
that is unsustainability in the stricto sensu. In 2015, more than 190 world leaders
recognized that the world is on a “collision course” (Max-Neef 2010) and committed
to 17 Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs). All but one goal are either linked to
the unsustainability of our current lifestyle (goals 9, 11–15) or to inequality (goals
1–8, 10, 16). Many conferences and high-level meetings have been held since then
F. Fuders (B
)
Right Livelihood College—Campus Austral and Economic Policy Chapter of the
Transdisciplinary Research Center for Socio Ecological Strategies for Forest Conservation
(TESES), Universidad Austral de Chile, Economics Institute, Valdivia, Chile
e-mail: felix.fuders@uach.cl
© Zhejiang University Press 2021
F. W. Gatzweiler, Urban Health and Wellbeing Programme,
Urban Health and Wellbeing,
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-33-6036-5_4
17
18 F. Fuders
and one of the major topics is how to finance these goals. However, it is not only more
money that is required but a different kind of money. In fact, both the overexploitation
of the natural environment and the income inequality are directly connected to our
unnatural financial system, and especially a misunderstanding of what money is and
what it should be.
3 Insights and Findings
3.1 Money Is Like the Blood of the Economy
Unlike real goods, money is easily storable and does, therefore, not easily circulate
in the economy. However, this is what it is supposed to do. Money can be described
as the blood of our economy. Blood needs to circulate, otherwise the body gets
ill. Similar to the blood circulation in the human body also the economy gets ill
if money does not circulate well. Money as a calculation unit is supposed to be a
medium to facilitate the exchange of goods and services. But, because people tend
to preserve what Keynes (1936: 165 ff., 194 ff.) called the “preference for liquidity
we like to save up money, the more the better. With real goods, hoarding would
only be possible in a very restrictive way, since real goods perish. Any excessive
hoarding would, in time, result in the loss of the hoarded goods. But our money, as it
is designed today, makes it possible to hoard any surplus almost without restriction.
The unnatural design of our current financial system makes possible the hoarding of
values produced, which provides a strong incentive to produce more than is actually
needed.
3.2 Our Monetary System Obligates to Grow
The design of our money does not only give a powerful incentive to produce more
than is actually needed; it even obligates to do so and here, again, the driver is the
unnatural storability of money (for similar argumentation see Kennedy 2011; Creutz
2018). Money stored under the pillow does not circulate and, therefore, cannot serve
the economy. This puts the owner of money in a monopolistic-like position to either
choke the economy or to blackmail the person in need of money and “press” interest
(Gesell 1949: 205, 344). To put it in the words of Keynes (1936: 167), interest is
a“reward for parting with liquidity”, the incentive to lend the money out (or to
bring it to the bank which then lends it out for us). To come back to the above-used
metaphor of money as the “blood of the economy”, interest can be seen as the “drug”
that makes money circulate in the economy. And as any drug that is applied for a
prolonged period of time, also the money interest rate brings along heavy side effects,
especially the obligation to grow and inequality.
Because the publishing house holds the copyright, it
cannot be shown more.
22 F. Fuders
References
Agarwal R, Kimball M (2015) Breaking through the zero lower bound—IMF Workig Paper. IMF,
Washington
Assenmacher K, Krogstrup S (2018) Monetary policy with negative interest rates: decoupling cash
from electronic money—IMF Working Paper. IMF, Washington
Bárcena A, Cimoli M, García-Buchaca R et al (2018) The inefficiency of inequality. ECLAC,
Santiago de Chile
Buiter W (2005) Overcoming the zero bound on nominal interest rates: Gesell’s currency carry tax
vs. Eisler’s parallel virtual currency. Int Econ Econ Policy (IEEP) 2:89–200
Creutz H (2018) Das Geldsyndrom. Kubo, Münster
Fuders F, Max-Neef M (2014) Local money as solution to a capitalistic global financial crisis. In:
From capitalistic to humanistic business. Palgrave Macmillan, Hampshire, NY
Gesell S (1949) Die natürliche Wirtschaftsordnung durch Freiland und Freigeld, 9th edn. Rudolf
Zitzmann, Lauf
Hamilton C (2003) Growth fetish. Allen & Unwin, Crows Nest
Kennedy M (2011) Occupy money. Kamphausen Verlag, Bielefeld
Keynes JM (1936) General theory of employment, interest and money. Hartcourt, New York
Max-Neef M (2010) The world on a collision course and the need for a new economy. Ambio
39:200–210
Seltmann T (2010) Umlaufsicherung von Banknoten - Wie sich die Einführung der Liquiditätsge-
bühr bei Geldscheinen systemkonform realisieren lässt. Humane Wirtschaft 2:10–16
Soddy F (1934) The role of money—what it should be contrasted with what it has become.
Routledge, London
Suhr D (1989) The capitalistic cost-benefit structure of money—an analysis of money’s structural
nonneutrality and its Effects on the economy. Springer, Berlin
... This in turn creates a potential for asset price inflation, that is, an increase in stock market prices. This is why prices investment markets and interest rate in the long run develop synchronously see already (Fuders, and Max-Neef 2014;Fuders, et al. 2013) and (Fuders 2021). We could prove here this heterodox interpretation and show that interest rates and stock market return are indeed positively correlated. ...
Article
Calibration of interest rate models benefits from grouping data to homogenous classes. Such an approach is typical in many financial time series. Preliminaries have been developed for Cox–Ingersoll-Ross models but this issue remains an open problem for many more realistic interest rate models. Here we develop such a strategy for general class interest rate and classes are based on p-value thresholds for testing for normality and gamma distributions. We use as the benchmark financial series of Chilean stock market index IPSA (Indice de precios selectivo de acciones) and its log-returns. We also study the relationship between interest rate and the market returns represented by the IPSA indicator, with positive correlation in some lags which reveals some interesting facts in the contrary to the conventional theory.
... In fact, this is not just a business model for banks but a crucial service that is necessary for the economy to function, since otherwise people would hoard surpluses at home "under the mattress". In consequence money would not circulate well, people would not (or much less) be able to exchange goods and services, thus strongly affecting allocative efficiency, i.e., causing net losses in societal welfare; in other words, the economy would plunge into a permanent depression (Fuders, 2021). What we generally are not aware of is that through the granting of loans the money supply grows-at least if money is understood, as central banks do and as 1 Werner (2014) and Gross and Siebenbrunner (2019) identified a third view. ...
Chapter
Full-text available
I once read in a textbook on economic and financial policy that, according to the author, it is not necessary to explain in detail what money is since everyone already knows this. How mistaken this statement is! In fact, money is not only not well understood, but there is so much ignorance in this regard that most scholars do not even recognize that they do not correctly understand what money is and how it is created. And among those relatively few scholars who have conducted research on this topic, we can identify two major currents, and followers of both currents are far from reaching a consensus. This chapter discusses both theories and explains where the different points of view come from.
Chapter
Full-text available
In their ‘Human Scale Development’ approach Max-Neef et al. (1991) proposed a matrix of nine axiological (subsistence, protection, affection, understanding, participation, idleness, creation, identity, liberty) fundamental human needs that are each viewed in four existential modes or dimensions (being, having, doing, interacting) as an instrument to be able to identify potential satisfiers, and in this to contribute to achieve a development that serves people helping them to satisfy their needs. This chapter argues that development, even if defined in terms of the fulfilment of fundamental human needs, so far fails to explain happiness. Further the article discusses whether religion could help to explain happiness and concludes that sound evidence exists that practicing spirituality is indeed key for feeling deep and abiding happiness. It is then suggested that if, as already Aristotle argued, happiness —or felicity (eudemonia) as he termed it— is to be regarded the highest aspirational good, then “spirituality” should be added to the matrix as 10th axiological fundamental human needs.
Chapter
Full-text available
This chapter challenges the so-called environmental Kuznets curve and explains why we can extrapolate from the laws of thermodynamics that perpetual economic growth on a planet with finite resources is impossible. In the long run economic growth cannot be sustainable.
Chapter
Full-text available
This chapter explains why the unnatural design of money not only creates a powerful incentive to produce more than is needed, but it even requires us to do so. In this context, we will survey the various explanatory theories of inflation and show how they all boil down to one primary phenomenon viewed from different perspectives.
Chapter
Full-text available
This chapter connects the proposed reform of our monetary system with classical microeconomics and development theory. The proposed financial system would eliminate the growth imperative. On the other hand, it would not hinder economic growth if this was considered desirable for people to “develop”—understanding “development” in terms of fulfilment of fundamental human needs as proposed by Max-Neef et al. (Human scale development – conception, application and further reflections. Apex, New York, 1991) in their theory of Human-Scale-Development. However, the authors of this approach did not specifically address which market structure is most conducive to achieving development at human scale. This chapter explains why, in order to get as close as possible to this ideal, i.e., development where each person can best satisfy their fundamental human needs, we need to create a market structure that approximates as closely as possible the microeconomic notion of perfect competition, which is, as outlined above, only possible if we achieve true monetary neutrality.
Chapter
Full-text available
Let me conclude this book with some philosophical thoughts. As any unnatural behavior in the long run is likely to cause pathologies for the human body, such is the case with our unnatural money and especially the unnatural phenomenon of interest, which makes our economy sick. In this last chapter I would like to offer some further reflections on why a natural economic order is prerequisite for a healthy economy. A healthy economy is an economy in which everyone gains according to their effort, and which does not oblige us to grow. This is an economy that serves people and not vice versa people serving the economy. The chapter ends describing the utopic but beautiful situation of what could be termed an economy of neighborly love.
Article
Full-text available
We aim to examine stock market returns before and after key events in the U.S. Sino trades between 2016 and 2019. The study tracks Cumulative Abnormal Returns (CAR) of the Índice de Precio Selectivo de Acciones (IPSA or S&P/CLX IPSA is a Chilean stock market index) for 26 important events throughout this time period. By testing for both directions and significance of market reaction to said events this study aims to clarify if these events and policy announcements were sufficient to influence local equity markets, and in which direction. A simple analysis of CAR showed 16 negative reactions and 10 Positive reactions. An estimated 13 billion USD in market capitalization was lost as a result. Of the 26 events studied 18 were found to produce statistically significant reactions and 8 did not. The IPSA’s reaction to the significant events was mixed with 11 negative reactions and 7 positive reactions. We also checked for the normality of the distribution by robust normality tests and expected returns possess significant asymmetry and above-normal kurtosis. As such on aggregate it can be concluded that Chilean capital markets reacted negatively to the U.S. Sino trade war. We model IPSA in the period 2016–2022, where we can observe qualitative differences before and after 2019. To the best knowledge of the authors, the model of IPSA in this article is the first attempt in this direction.
Article
Full-text available
Monetary policy space remains constrained by the lower bound in many countries, limiting the policy options available to address future deflationary shocks. The existence of cash prevents central banks from cutting interest rates much below zero. In this paper, we consider the practical feasibility of recent proposals for decoupling cash from electronic money to achieve a negative yield on cash which would remove the lower bound constraint on monetary policy. We discuss how central banks could design and operate such a system, and raise some unanswered questions.
Chapter
Full-text available
The aim of this chapter is to show that regional currencies might be a solution to the global financial crisis and, more generally, to a vast array of modern problems, including inflation, asset price bubbles, income inequalities, pollution, and the Euro crisis. http://rd.springer.com/chapter/10.1057/9781137468208_11
Article
Full-text available
Despite the zero lower bound on the short nominal interest rate in Japan having become a binding constraint, conventional monetary policy in Japan, in the form of generalised open market purchases of government securities of all maturities, has never been pushed to the limit where all outstanding government debt and all current and anticipated future government deficits are (or are confidently expected to be) monetised. Open market purchases of private securities can create serious governance problems. Two ways of overcoming the zero lower bound constraint have been proposed. The first is Gesell’s carry tax on currency. The second is Eisler’s proposal for the unbundling of the medium of exchange/means of payment function and the numéraire function of money through the creation of a parallel virtual currency. This raises the fundamental issue of who chooses or what determines the numéraire used in private wage and price contracts—an issue that is either not addressed in the literature or addressed incorrectly. On balance, Gesell’s proposal appears to be the more robust of the two.
Article
Full-text available
The first part of the paper is an attempt to demonstrate that what we are going through at the present time is not just an economic-financial crisis, but a crisis of humanity. It seems that for the first time in human history several crises converge to simultaneously reach their maximum level of tension. The dominant economic model is to a great degree responsible for the world's collision course. Hence a number of myths that sustain the model are listed and analyzed. It is argued that a new economy, coherent with the problematiques of the twenty first century, needs urgently to be devised. The second part proposes the foundations for a new economy based on five fundamental postulates that allow the construction of transdisciplinary, holistic, and systemic visions to adequately understand the interdependence of all the elements that sustain life. It is stressed that it is no longer acceptable that Universities still teach economic theories of the nineteenth century in order to tackle twenty first century problems that have no precedence.
Book
This book was originally published by Macmillan in 1936. It was voted the top Academic Book that Shaped Modern Britain by Academic Book Week (UK) in 2017, and in 2011 was placed on Time Magazine's top 100 non-fiction books written in English since 1923. Reissued with a fresh Introduction by the Nobel-prize winner Paul Krugman and a new Afterword by Keynes’ biographer Robert Skidelsky, this important work is made available to a new generation. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money transformed economics and changed the face of modern macroeconomics. Keynes’ argument is based on the idea that the level of employment is not determined by the price of labour, but by the spending of money. It gave way to an entirely new approach where employment, inflation and the market economy are concerned. Highly provocative at its time of publication, this book and Keynes’ theories continue to remain the subject of much support and praise, criticism and debate. Economists at any stage in their career will enjoy revisiting this treatise and observing the relevance of Keynes’ work in today’s contemporary climate.
Book
The capitalistic cost-benefit structure of money : an analysis of money´s structural nonneutrality and its effects on the economy. - Berlin u.a. : Springer, 1989. - X, 136 S.
Article
There has been much discussion about eliminating the 'zero lower bound' by eliminating paper currency. But such a radical and difficult approach as eliminating paper currency is not necessary. Much as during the Great Depression-when countries were able to revive their economies by going off the gold standard-all that is needed to empower monetary policy to cut interest rates as much as needed for economic stimulus now is to change from a paper standard to an electronic money standard, and to be willing to have paper currency go away from par. This paper develops the idea further and shows how such a mechanism can be implemented in a minimalist way by using a time-varying paper currency deposit fee between private banks and the central bank. This allows the central bank to create a crawling-peg exchange rate between paper currency and electronic money; the paper currency interest rate can be either lowered below zero or raised above zero. Such an ability to vary the paper currency interest rate along with other key interest rates, makes it possible to stimulate investment and net exports as much as needed to revive the economy, even when inflation, interest rates, and economic activity are quite low, as they are currently in many countries. The paper also examines different options available to the central bank to return to par when negative interest rates are no longer needed, and the associated implications for the financial sector and debt contracts. Finally, the paper discusses various legal, political, and economic challenges of putting in place such a framework and how policymakers could address them.
The inefficiency of inequality
  • A Bárcena
  • M Cimoli
  • R García-Buchaca
Bárcena A, Cimoli M, García-Buchaca R et al (2018) The inefficiency of inequality. ECLAC, Santiago de Chile