ArticlePDF Available

Abstract and Figures

This document makes a comprehensive analysis of the inequality of the water market in Chile, measured by the Gini coefficient method. The situation of water rights in Chile is of particular interest because it is a wholly privatized system, where rights are traded in the market and therefore water is presented as a commodity. This privatization of water in Chile occurred as part of the process of neo-liberalization since the 1981 Water Code. The results of this study indicate that both concentration and inequality in the distribution of water rights are very high, which undermines a just social development process and facilitates the economic exploitation of the environment. It proposes a profound revision of the application of a mercantile logic to a scarce essential resource for life such as water and explores the importance of its role as a national good for public use.
Content may be subject to copyright.
water
Article
Water Privatization and Inequality: Gini Coecient
for Water Resources in Chile
Juan Correa-Parra 1, * , JoséFrancisco Vergara-Perucich 1and Carlos Aguirre-Nuñez 2
1
Centro Producci
ó
n del Espacio, Universidad de Las Am
é
ricas, Providencia 7500975, Chile; jvergara@udla.cl
2Escuela de Construcción, Universidad de Las Américas, Providencia 7500975, Chile; caguirre@udla.cl
*Correspondence: juan.correa.correa@edu.udla.cl; Tel.: +56-97-373-9644
Received: 24 September 2020; Accepted: 24 November 2020; Published: 1 December 2020


Abstract:
This document makes a comprehensive analysis of the inequality of the water market in
Chile, measured by the Gini coecient method. The situation of water rights in Chile is of particular
interest because it is a wholly privatized system, where rights are traded in the market and therefore
water is presented as a commodity. This privatization of water in Chile occurred as part of the
process of neo-liberalization since the 1981 Water Code. The results of this study indicate that both
concentration and inequality in the distribution of water rights are very high, which undermines a just
social development process and facilitates the economic exploitation of the environment. It proposes
a profound revision of the application of a mercantile logic to a scarce essential resource for life such
as water and explores the importance of its role as a national good for public use.
Keywords: water; Gini coecient; concentration; privatization; Chile
1. Introduction
The World Health Organization and UNICEF indicated that Chile is the Latin-American country
with the highest access to safely managed drinking water services [
1
]. However, water rights are
privatized and diverse conflicts are related to this legal framework regarding a natural resource.
For instance, an increasing number of slums in the country have limited access to safe water [
2
].
The privatization scheme has triggered conflicts between water rights owners and local communities,
such as the Mapuche-Huilliche case in the south of the territory [
3
] and with the Atacama communities
in the north [
4
,
5
]. Furthermore, the privatized water market has fostered the creation of economic
groups related to the provision of this resource to households; nevertheless, the quality of the products
is not better than the safe water produced by independent firms and scarce regulation concerning
these entrepreneurial activities undermines access to better water for consumers [
6
]. The water market
in Chile has exploited the resource at such a level that, nowadays, a social movement on a national
scale has organized to contest the privatization of water and to pursue its nationalization as a public
good [
7
]. There is a contradiction between the global data indicating high access to safely managed
drinking water services and the conflicts occurring in the territories related to the water market in
Chile. In order to illuminate the potential origins of these conflicts, we investigated water inequalities
at global and local levels using a statistical approach. The trigger for the privatization of water started
in 1975, with the political-economic project of the dictatorship, in relation to implementing a radical
free-market economic model privatizing public services usually allocated at the state level. This process
is known as neo-liberalization.
As part of the Chilean process of neo-liberalization, in 1981 the Water Code was created, and this
scarce natural resource began to be commercialized, generating negotiable property rights in what
is known as the water market. Chile is the only country in the world with fully privatized water.
Another particularity in Chile is that the owner of the land has no right over the water that may be
Water 2020,12, 3369; doi:10.3390/w12123369 www.mdpi.com/journal/water
Water 2020,12, 3369 2 of 13
present on that piece of land. Such conditions make the Chilean water market a unique study case,
now critical due to the climatic crisis. In general, the creation of a water market can be based on
the privatization of rights, institutionally controlled business cycles, pricing according to availability,
or determining its free disposal as a fundamental human right for subsistence [
8
]. In the face of
the climate emergency, water scarcity is a challenge and the management of the resource must be
adapted to the current planetary crisis [9,10]. It is for this reason that it is relevant to critically review
those cases in which water resource management instruments have not been adapted to the climate
crisis. This occurs in the Chilean case, which takes on greater relevance in the face of resistance from
democratic authorities to recognizing the importance of adapting regulation in the water domain
to current times. On 7 January 2020, the Senate of the Republic decided to reject the designation of
water as a national good for public use [
11
], despite the fact that Chile faces a severe drought [
12
]
and that the international literature raises the urgency of rethinking models of governance over
natural resources [
13
]. This article presents relevant evidence regarding the urgency of resuming
this discussion by exposing how the Chilean case can illustrate the complexity of creating a market
through the privatization of water rights for consumption purposes which leads to a high concentration
of ownership of a natural resource, generating speculative scenarios with the commercialization of
property and significant inequality in water access. The water market creates a compounded scenario
that Mehta et al. [
14
] define as a scarcity policy, where unequal access to water is naturalized, a decision
justified by exclusionary property regimes [
15
], serving as a strategy to divert attention from other
problems such as the causes of inequality or poverty [
16
]. Therefore, studying the water market in
Chile provides a view on dierent aspects of inequality, and not only in access to water.
When a water market was proposed, it is crucial to understand that this is one of the particularities
of Chilean reality, wherein in 1981 water rights were privatized and the values and mechanisms
necessary in order to exchange water for money established a market that sets its prices by the law
of supply and demand. For Boelens [
17
], in the study of water rights it is critical to identify the
aordability of the resource for users, determining how the owner of the water rights exercises his
power by controlling a scarce resource elemental for the development of life. Boelens proposes that
power relations will define the distribution of water resources, but the discussion also concerns the
restructuring of power relations across society. In the specialized international literature, there is
consensus that the water market should not operate like that for any other type of tradable good and
requires democratic and institutionalized regulations. In some cases, the development of a water
market can improve the eciency in the distribution of water resources [
18
], but in the case of weak
regulatory institutions, it can generate speculative frameworks that end up reducing the population’s
access to water [
18
20
]. The conflictive relationship between water owners and communities has been
presented in literature from qualitative approaches, [
21
,
22
] so this article contributes by oering a
nation-wide perspective on how uneven the water market is from a quantitative approach.
Hence, this article seeks to contribute to the discussion of the eects of generating a water market
in a situation of water scarcity, that is to say, a scarcity policy; from the review of its distribution and
sustainability, it takes the case of water rights in Chile. Specifically, it studies the inequality of water
distribution in Chile as measured by the Gini index. To frame the problem, the article presents a
general framework for the origin and scope of water management in Chile, from the first regulations
to the creation of a market through privatization in 1981. The data for the study and the methods used
are then discussed. The source of information analyzed is based on secondary data obtained from
the General Water Directorate of the Ministry of Public Works. These data are georeferenced and the
inequality of the allocation of this resource for consumption is studied, i.e., for waters that are extracted
without reincorporation into supply channels. The method used is a geo-localized Gini index to review
the distribution of the resource spatially. The results argue that privatization optimizes the distribution
of the water resource. The proposal is to open discussion based on the specialized international
literature in order to rethink how to manage water resources in Chile from the institutional and public
policy point of view, considering the important drought that the country faces and in view of the
Water 2020,12, 3369 3 of 13
climate emergency. Although Chile presents good indicators of human access to drinking water in
urban areas, this study considers total water rights, as the treatment and management of drinking
water for human consumption does not reach more than 12%. In this sense, the concentration of rights
and their use in extractive areas presents a clear risk for these positive indicators in the future.
Historical Review of the Formation of the Water Market in Chile
In 1819, Bernardo O’Higgins, the architect of Chile’s independence, drafted a supreme
decree to determine how water should be used, based on a metric configuration of the irrigators,
clearly establishing how water should be marketed and assigning responsibility for the correct use of
the resource by the controllers of water intake. Already by 1857, water resources had been nominated as
national public goods. In view of the emergence of drought episodes, in 1872 several regulations sought
to generate mechanisms to manage water in the event of alterations in annual rainfall, focusing on rural
agricultural productivity. These were the first approaches to regulating water use in Chile, without a
market as such but rather with a system of concessions for use for specific productive purposes.
It was in 1927 that a proper water code was drawn up, within the framework of the civil code,
with 476 articles covering a large number of the provisions relating to water resource management and
enshrining it as a national good for public use, where the State would govern the modes of allocating
the use of the resource for activities other than human consumption. This project saw a set of revisions
in 1928 and 1930, until the final configuration of the 1936 water code, where concessions for the use of
the resource were designated as part of the State’s role. The water code took a more definitive and
consensual form at the level of parliament in 1951, the year in which the role of the State was specified,
establishing that it was the President of the Republic who would approve applications for water use
rights [
23
]. Then, under the government of Eduardo Frei Montalva and in the midst of the search
to improve the functioning of agriculture, in 1967 a new water code was created that emphasized
the public domain. Under this code, exploitation would be defined according to a rationalized rate
by the central planning agencies, thus limiting the volume of maximum use flows [
24
]. In this first
review, it can be seen that Chile historically privileged the understanding that water was a national
good for public use whose fair distribution should be supervised by government authority (i.e., by the
President of the Republic himself), with a rationality typical of a protagonist State’s role in the national
economy using a centralized planning approach. With neoliberalism, the paradigm changed completely.
The State reduced its participation in the regulation of productive activities, and in matters of public
interest markets were created, such as in social security, education, health and water, among others.
The neo-liberalization of public goods in the case of water will took form in the 1981 Water Code.
With the framework provided by the Constitution of the Republic promulgated in 1980, a private
property regime would be the focus of this new mechanism for regulating water resources. Thus,
the management of this resource would be oriented towards the possibilities of its commercialization
and acquisition, without State regulation. The State, on the other hand, would play a role in assigning
use rights, but without the eective capacity to control such uses, much less the markets for water
use transactions between private parties. In this way, water in Chile becomes a commodity [
24
].
For Humberto Peña [
25
], the main characteristics of the Chilean water code can be identified as the
following aspects:
Transfer of water management from the State as a public good to the market as a commodity.
The enshrining of original water rights to generate ownership.
The work of inspection and conflict resolution among private parties is organized, giving this role
top government.
Strategic planning for water resource management is generated with a focus on its productive
role, without sucient emphasis on the sustainability of its use.
With these transformations, the territory as a whole entered a process of privatization for
commercial purposes. For Carl Bauer, the separation of water rights from land rights would be another
Water 2020,12, 3369 4 of 13
problematic factor since water tributaries crossing a land will not have a direct commercial relationship
with the landowner. This will account for the overlap of property rights on the same land. The use
of water will not have much territorial weight, but will be valuable as an economic resource, so its
primary role for the development of life is subjugated to its commercial eciency. Making water a
commodity via the 1981 Water Code also marks the emergence of a water market that in those years
followed the recommendations of the Inter-American Development Bank and the World Bank [
21
].
The main objective argued by the promoters of these reforms was the need to manage water scarcity.
These water policies proposed that access and coverage would be achieved in a better way if the
until then public management of the water resource passed to private hands, in search of increasing
eciency and improving management, favoring competitiveness in the sector, eliminating barriers for
international companies, reducing regulations, and assuring a 10.3% profitability [
16
18
]. This was the
fundamental argument of neoliberalism [26].
To be precise, the perspective of increasing eciency and improving management of the resource
is defined by Panayotakis [
27
] as “the order of the day”, where governments and elites use the idea of
scarcity to legitimize the capitalist system and its logic, just like the privatization or financialization
of public goods, reserving an exclusive access to these assets to producers only. This privatization
generates severe eects on environmental equilibrium and also on social groups in rural and urban
areas. Mehta [
28
] considers these eects as a those of a new type of policy regime, where the practice
of resource control ends up by making vulnerable the most deprived communities.
For Bauer [
25
], the freedom to buy and sell water rights has led to the revaluation of water resources
in certain areas. Still, the adverse eects are related to the normative rigidity of the constitutional and
legal framework of the Water Codes. This makes it dicult for regulations to be adapted to the diverse
uses of water and the nature of water flows, which eventually leads to the aforementioned potential
conflicts over water between companies and communities, or the reduction of ecient management of
the resource due to inadequate exploitation, despite scarce conditions. Using this short-term logic,
water privatization with a focus on productive activities does not consider the common good but
instead aspires to economic return on such activities, thus neglecting the ecological role of water
resources, since productive processes have other objectives related to income and commercial eciency.
In 2005, a change to the Water Code was introduced. Although the water market was not
disestablished, a monetary tax was generated on the non-exploitation of water resources by those who
held the corresponding water rights, seeking to avoid speculation. According to Peña and Jaeger [
29
],
the objective of preventing speculation and monopolistic frameworks was to generate a better balance
between the productive role of water and social needs, in addition to adding sustainability criteria
to water resource management. However, it was Peña himself, the author of the reform, who later
recognized that it was made in an adverse political climate, in which the Constitution facilitates the
hindering of progressive reforms, favorable to the conservative political forces that in Chile tend
to prioritize the market over the social function of water [
24
]. In other words, the reforms were
limited, without managing to resolve the conflicts related to the sustainability of the water market,
preserving the negative characteristics that tend to concentrate resources and access unequally.
Inequality in the distribution of water is a complex scenario. The Water Code establishes a
situation in which the owner of the land has no rights over the water flowing on that land. As the
community leader Rodrigo Mundaca indicates, in Chile there are no planning regulations associated
with the productive capacities of agricultural soil. Therefore, with the person holding water rights on
the one hand and agricultural production on the other, communities’ access to water may be aected
by the consumption industry [
1
]. Studying the water market in Chile is a means to observe how a
non-comprehensive planning apparatus may undermine community access to natural resources.
2. Materials and Methods
The data set used for this study comes from the national water rights databases of registered
with the General Water Directorate of the Ministry of Public Works of the Government of Chile,
Water 2020,12, 3369 5 of 13
where original rights and new applications for water rights are identified according to Article 122 of
the Water Code. The database corresponds to the National Consolidated Rights, dated 20 January 2020.
In particular, we have applied the study to consumptive water rights, that is, those assigned so that
water is consumed without returning to its original course. Even so, in the presentation of the results,
global water rights are presented, against these consumptive rights [30].
However, it should be reported that the original database presented some consistency problems,
so a thorough review of the information had to be carried out. In this process of cleaning up the
database, inconsistent information had to be removed. In short, from the national consolidated data,
out of a total of 131,124 cases, only 97.62% were used (128,015 permits), given that the rest presented
problems of various kinds, including typing errors, records without data on the volume of water
transferred and units of measurement that cannot be converted into volumes of water, as is the case
with the so-called shares or irrigators, which are measures proportional to the flow of a given course,
information that is not entirely suitable for the calculation of the Gini Coecient. The corrected table is
attached as a complementary database annex to this publication and has also been sent to the Ministry
of Public Works for further correction.
Based on the above, it was decided to work with the 97.62% of the data already processed,
on which dierent spatial concentration analyses were carried out, starting with the spatialization
of the water resource capture points (Figure 1). From the data set, several analyses were executed,
specifically, (i) distribution according to rights to the resource, (ii) nature of origin, (iii) volume of
water extracted and finally (iv) an analysis of how concentrated the water resource is, based on its Gini
coecient, at a national, zonal and regional scale.
Water 2020, 12, x FOR PEER REVIEW 5 of 13
2. Materials and Methods
The data set used for this study comes from the national water rights databases of registered
with the General Water Directorate of the Ministry of Public Works of the Government of Chile,
where original rights and new applications for water rights are identified according to Article 122 of
the Water Code. The database corresponds to the National Consolidated Rights, dated January 20
2020. In particular, we have applied the study to consumptive water rights, that is, those assigned so
that water is consumed without returning to its original course. Even so, in the presentation of the
results, global water rights are presented, against these consumptive rights [30].
However, it should be reported that the original database presented some consistency problems,
so a thorough review of the information had to be carried out. In this process of cleaning up the
database, inconsistent information had to be removed. In short, from the national consolidated data,
out of a total of 131,124 cases, only 97.62% were used (128,015 permits), given that the rest presented
problems of various kinds, including typing errors, records without data on the volume of water
transferred and units of measurement that cannot be converted into volumes of water, as is the case
with the so-called shares or irrigators, which are measures proportional to the flow of a given course,
information that is not entirely suitable for the calculation of the Gini Coefficient. The corrected table
is attached as a complementary database annex to this publication and has also been sent to the
Ministry of Public Works for further correction.
Based on the above, it was decided to work with the 97.62% of the data already processed, on
which different spatial concentration analyses were carried out, starting with the spatialization of the
water resource capture points (Figure 1). From the data set, several analyses were executed,
specifically, (i) distribution according to rights to the resource, (ii) nature of origin, (iii) volume of
water extracted and finally (iv) an analysis of how concentrated the water resource is, based on its
Gini coefficient, at a national, zonal and regional scale.
Figure 1. Location of water capture points registered as rights at the General Water Directorate of the
Ministry of Public Works. Source: drawn up by the authors based on data from the Dirección General
de Aguas (DGA).
To analyze this data, a study of unequal access to water rights was carried out using the Gini
coefficient. The Gini coefficient is a method for measuring levels of inequality in the distribution of a
Figure 1. Location of water capture points registered as rights at the General Water Directorate of the
Ministry of Public Works. Source: drawn up by the authors based on data from the Direcci
ó
n General
de Aguas (DGA).
To analyze this data, a study of unequal access to water rights was carried out using the Gini
coecient. The Gini coecient is a method for measuring levels of inequality in the distribution of a
specific factor in a given population. It is usually used to measure income inequality, as suggested
by its creator, Conrado Gini. The result of the calculation ranges from 0 (total equality) to 1
Water 2020,12, 3369 6 of 13
(complete inequality). Its interpretation is simple, which is crucial in a study that seeks to review the
problem of water rights in Chile so that its discussion is taken up by dierent disciplines, from human
rights approaches to marketing. In particular, we have classified rights to consumptive water according
to the volume of water assigned for each user registered with the General Water Directorate, in order
to achieve clarity on the levels of inequality in the allocation of water resources.
Then, based on the distribution patterns of water rights, we will be able to review which actors
consume the most greatest amount of liters per second and how these results are interpreted in the
light of the water crisis the country is experiencing.
To obtain the Gini coecient, the following calculation was made:
Gini =1
n1
X
k=1
(Xk+1Xk)(Yk+1Yk)(1)
where X corresponds to the cumulative proportion of the variable stakeholders owning water rights
included in this study, while Y corresponds to the cumulative proportion of water volume measured in
L/s.
3. Results
For a general description of the sample, out of a total of 131,124 permits granted and registered in
the original database, 128,015 (97.62% of the total) are identified. In this database, 54.1% of the licenses
were for groundwater and 45.9% for surface water. Of the total number of permits, those corresponding
to consumptive water are studied, whose flow estimate is 4,293,280 L/s. As indicated in Figure 2,
most of the non-consumptive licenses are located near the mountain range in the central-southern zone
of the country (regions of Valpara
í
so, Metropolitana, O’Higgins, Maule, Ñuble, Biobio, Araucan
í
a,
Los R
í
os and Los Lagos), while consumptive licenses are distributed throughout the national territory.
Water 2020, 12, x FOR PEER REVIEW 6 of 13
specific factor in a given population. It is usually used to measure income inequality, as suggested by
its creator, Conrado Gini. The result of the calculation ranges from 0 (total equality) to 1 (complete
inequality). Its interpretation is simple, which is crucial in a study that seeks to review the problem
of water rights in Chile so that its discussion is taken up by different disciplines, from human rights
approaches to marketing. In particular, we have classified rights to consumptive water according to
the volume of water assigned for each user registered with the General Water Directorate, in order
to achieve clarity on the levels of inequality in the allocation of water resources.
Then, based on the distribution patterns of water rights, we will be able to review which actors
consume the most greatest amount of liters per second and how these results are interpreted in the
light of the water crisis the country is experiencing.
To obtain the Gini coefficient, the following calculation was made:
𝐺𝑖𝑛𝑖 = 1 (𝑋 −𝑋
)(𝑌 −𝑌
)


(1)
where X corresponds to the cumulative proportion of the variable stakeholders owning water rights
included in this study, while Y corresponds to the cumulative proportion of water volume measured
in L/s.
3. Results
For a general description of the sample, out of a total of 131,124 permits granted and registered
in the original database, 128,015 (97.62% of the total) are identified. In this database, 54.1% of the
licenses were for groundwater and 45.9% for surface water. Of the total number of permits, those
corresponding to consumptive water are studied, whose flow estimate is 4,293,280 L/s. As indicated
in Figure 2, most of the non-consumptive licenses are located near the mountain range in the central-
southern zone of the country (regions of Valparaíso, Metropolitana, O’Higgins, Maule, Ñuble, Biobio,
Araucanía, Los Ríos and Los Lagos), while consumptive licenses are distributed throughout the
national territory.
Figure 2. National map with the permits according to consumptive or non-consumptive rights.
Source: Compiled by the authors based on information from the DGA.
Figure 2.
National map with the permits according to consumptive or non-consumptive rights. Source:
Compiled by the authors based on information from the DGA.
Figure 2show the distribution of the consumptive and non-consumptive rights throughout the
Chilean territory. In addition to the concentration of extraction spots in the central zone of the country
Water 2020,12, 3369 7 of 13
(where about 75% of the population is concentrated), more than the 90% of the non-consumptive
rights are localized in this area, particularly in the mountainous area (over 1000 MSL). In these areas,
the water rights are linked principally to hydroelectric companies which generate electricity to supply
urban areas and for economic activities nearby.
When quantifying the value of the water market for surface consumption rights, it is estimated
that it corresponds to a market of USD 45,868,679. One of the problems found in the study is that
the General Water Directorate holds 57.4% of permits, without information on the owners or the
destination relating to these water rights. For this reason, we present the concentration of water rights,
incorporating those protagonists for whom we do not have data (Table 1) and a table of consumptive
rights considering only those for which uses for the water are identified (Table 2).
Table 1.
Consumptive water rights by use, including “No data” cases. Source: Author ’s elaboration
based on DGA data.
Consumptive Water Rights
Water Use L/s. %
Recount Add Up Of the Total
No data 73,591 2,465,931 57.4%
Drink/Domestic Use/Sanitation 13,008 352,034 8.2%
Hydroelectric Energy 40 5746 0.1%
Other Uses 1983 95,927 2.2%
For Observation and Analysis 3 2 0.0%
Fish Farming 332 21,858 0.5%
Irrigation 24,524 1,296,526 30.2%
Silvo-Agropecuario 127 1223 0.0%
Industrial Use 380 26,915 0.6%
Medical Use 4 67 0.0%
Mining use 479 27,050 0.6%
Total 114,471 4,293,280
Table 2.
Consumptive water rights by use, excluding “No data” cases. Source: Author ’s elaboration
based on DGA data.
Consumptive Water Rights
Water Use L/s. %
Recount Add Up Of the Total
Drink/Domestic Use/Sanitation 13,008 352,034 19.3%
Hydroelectric Energy 40 5746 0.3%
Other Uses 1983 95,927 5.2%
For Observation and Analysis 3 2 0.0%
Fish Farming 332 21,858 1.2%
Irrigation 24,524 1,296,526 71.0%
Silvo-Agropecuario 127 1223 0.1%
Industrial use 380 26,915 1.5%
Medical Use 4 67 0.0%
Mining use 479 27,050 1.5%
Total 40,880 1,827,348
One of the main observations is that irrigation as a consumptive activity and at the same time a
productive activity, registers 71% of the volume of water transferred, with clear identification of use.
The use of water for irrigation in Chile is equivalent to the annual consumption of 243 million homes,
similar to the number of households in India or 10 times that of the United Kingdom (Figure 3).
Water 2020,12, 3369 8 of 13
Water 2020, 12, x FOR PEER REVIEW 8 of 13
Figure 3. Water rights according to the main destination of water use. Source: Author’s elaboration
according to DGA data.
Figure 3 presents a clear pattern of the distribution of activities using water for production, such
as mining activity, which in relation to water rights tenure is predominant in both location and
volume, despite the scarcity of water resources in the Atacama Desert, where most mining activities
are situated (northern area of the territory). On the other hand, in the central valley of Chile both
irrigation and hydroelectric activities capture most of the water rights. This relationship is related to
the greater extent of cities, industrial activities, and agriculture. Products with high demand for water
are produced in this valley, especially fruit and wines.
This result makes it necessary to review whether this water consumption makes a similar
contribution to the treasury through production taxes, when only 2.75% of annual sales are
concentrated, representing only 6.27% of companies in Chile and contributing through income tax
from agricultural activities only 0.46% of the fiscal budget (0.11% of GDP). It is also essential to review
the volume of privatized water distributed in the regions, where Maule (14.69%), O’Higgins (14.04%)
and the Metropolitan Region (13.52%) are where a significant part of the total national consumption
flow is concentrated (Table 3). This initial descriptive review allows us to recognize the general profile
of consumptive water rights in Chile (Figure 4) and the importance of studying levels of inequality
and concentration.
Table 3. Spatial distribution of permits in the territory by political-administrative region. Source:
Compiled by the authors based on DGA data.
Region Recount Add Up Of the Total
Arica y Parinacota 2281 20,996 0.49%
Tarapacá 1708 37,273 0.87%
Antofagasta 1022 25,840 0.60%
Atacama 1592 41,040 0.96%
Coquimbo 11,891 149,198 3.48%
Valparaíso 13,958 410,540 9.56%
Metropolitana 9575 580,271 13.52%
O’Higgins 8744 602,980 14.04%
Maule 9022 630,651 14.69%
Figure 3.
Water rights according to the main destination of water use. Source: Author’s elaboration
according to DGA data.
Figure 3presents a clear pattern of the distribution of activities using water for production, such as
mining activity, which in relation to water rights tenure is predominant in both location and volume,
despite the scarcity of water resources in the Atacama Desert, where most mining activities are situated
(northern area of the territory). On the other hand, in the central valley of Chile both irrigation and
hydroelectric activities capture most of the water rights. This relationship is related to the greater extent
of cities, industrial activities, and agriculture. Products with high demand for water are produced in
this valley, especially fruit and wines.
This result makes it necessary to review whether this water consumption makes a similar
contribution to the treasury through production taxes, when only 2.75% of annual sales are concentrated,
representing only 6.27% of companies in Chile and contributing through income tax from agricultural
activities only 0.46% of the fiscal budget (0.11% of GDP). It is also essential to review the volume
of privatized water distributed in the regions, where Maule (14.69%), O’Higgins (14.04%) and the
Metropolitan Region (13.52%) are where a significant part of the total national consumption flow
is concentrated (Table 3). This initial descriptive review allows us to recognize the general profile
of consumptive water rights in Chile (Figure 4) and the importance of studying levels of inequality
and concentration.
Table 3.
Spatial distribution of permits in the territory by political-administrative region. Source:
Compiled by the authors based on DGA data.
Region Recount Add Up Of the Total
Arica y Parinacota 2281 20,996 0.49%
Tarapacá1708 37,273 0.87%
Antofagasta 1022 25,840 0.60%
Atacama 1592 41,040 0.96%
Coquimbo 11,891 149,198 3.48%
Valparaíso 13,958 410,540 9.56%
Water 2020,12, 3369 9 of 13
Table 3. Cont.
Region Recount Add Up Of the Total
Metropolitana 9575 580,271 13.52%
O’Higgins 8744 602,980 14.04%
Maule 9022 630,651 14.69%
Ñuble 7639 161,216 3.76%
Biobío 6909 333,580 7.77%
Araucanía 14,915 465,402 10.84%
De Los Ríos 8166 161,737 3.77%
De Los Lagos 10., 287,634 6.70%
Aysén 4704 230,327 5.36%
Magallanes 1413 154,596 3.60%
Total country 114,471 4,293,280
Water 2020, 12, x FOR PEER REVIEW 9 of 13
Ñuble 7639 161,216 3.76%
Biobío 6909 333,580 7.77%
Araucanía 14,915 465,402 10.84%
De Los Ríos 8166 161,737 3.77%
De Los Lagos 10., 287,634 6.70%
Aysén 4704 230,327 5.36%
Magallanes 1413 154,596 3.60%
Total country 114,471 4,293,280
Figure 4. Water rights according to total liters/second per commune. Source: Own elaboration from
DGA data. Figure 4 shows the distribution and volumes of water rights per commune, which
illustrates the territorial inequalities throughout the country. This map underline the high levels of
water consumed in the northern areas of the national territory and the high levels of inequality
between neighboring communes in the central valley of Chile, where industrial activity, hydroelectric
generation, agro-industrial crops and extended cities act as stresses on natural resources. This
situation adds up to a critical scenario for the most vulnerable communities, especially small
agricultural and livestock producers whose access to water is uneven in relation to the big companies
owning water rights [12,13].
The Gini coefficient for all permits at the national level is 0.9999585 and, in the specific case of
surface consumption rights, this reaches a value of 0.9537 (Table 4). At first glance, the level of
inequality is abysmal, and concentration is very high. In this study, 1% of registered actors own
79.02% of the total volume of water available in the system, which in turn makes up only 4.3% of the
existing water property rights. In other words, we see very high inequality and very high
concentration of water resources.
Figure 4.
Water rights according to total liters/second per commune. Source: Own elaboration from
DGA data. Figure 4shows the distribution and volumes of water rights per commune, which illustrates
the territorial inequalities throughout the country. This map underline the high levels of water
consumed in the northern areas of the national territory and the high levels of inequality between
neighboring communes in the central valley of Chile, where industrial activity, hydroelectric generation,
agro-industrial crops and extended cities act as stresses on natural resources. This situation adds up
to a critical scenario for the most vulnerable communities, especially small agricultural and livestock
producers whose access to water is uneven in relation to the big companies owning water rights [
12
,
13
].
The Gini coecient for all permits at the national level is 0.9999585 and, in the specific case
of surface consumption rights, this reaches a value of 0.9537 (Table 4). At first glance, the level of
inequality is abysmal, and concentration is very high. In this study, 1% of registered actors own 79.02%
of the total volume of water available in the system, which in turn makes up only 4.3% of the existing
water property rights. In other words, we see very high inequality and very high concentration of
water resources.
Water 2020,12, 3369 10 of 13
Table 4.
Study of the Gini Coecient at the national level for the total and specific superficial consumer
rights. Source: Prepared by the authors.
Gini Coecient for All Rights
Total Rights 128,015
Total Owners 63,864
Flow rate (L/s) 4,865,684,475
Gini Coecient 0.999585
Gini Coecient for Surface Consumer Rights
Total Rights 55,853
Total Owners 29,001
Flow rate (L/s) 3,369,691
Gini Coecient 0.9537
The distribution of water rights in all regions of Chile shows very high inequality (Table 5),
fluctuating between 0.8309 (Atacama Region) and 0.9721 (O’Higgins and Ñuble Regions). The most
unequal areas correspond to the central sector of the country, where there are greater population and
agricultural developments, reflected in regions such as O’Higgins, Maule and Metropolitan, which,
although they have fewer water rights, delivered 4726 rights, equivalent to 10.6% of the national
total; each right has in proportion more liters/second than the rest of the nation, equal to 42.9% of the
national total. In other words, the highest consumption of liters/second occurs in the central valley, in
areas with a high preponderance of agricultural activities that demand irrigation, such as vineyards,
avocados, berries and fruits in general.
Table 5. Summary of Gini Coecient results by national regions. Source: Prepared by the authors.
Surface Water Consumption Rights
Region No Rights Sum of L/sNational
Percentage Rights
National
Percentage L/sGini Index
Arica y Parinacota 336 16,944 0.8% 0.5% 0.8993
Tarapacá285 30,596 0.6% 0.9% 0.9499
Antofagasta 446 11,554 1.0% 0.3% 0.8980
Atacama 212 11,672 0.5% 0.3% 0.8309
Coquimbo 695 58,671 1.6% 1.7% 0.9329
Valparaiso 2213 173,222 4.9% 5.1% 0.9569
Metropolitan 1562 385,058 3.5% 11.4% 0.9716
O’Higgins 1213 515,841 2.7% 15.3% 0.9721
Maule 1951 545,045 4.4% 16.2% 0.9598
Ñuble 2312 127,003 5.2% 3.8% 0.9721
Bio Bio 3888 315,563 8.7% 9.4% 0.9535
Araucanía 10,121 441,378 22.6% 13.1% 0.9152
De Los Rios 6482 135,056 14.5% 4.0% 0.8671
De Los Lagos 7693 218,361 17.2% 6.5% 0.9115
Aysen 4346 229,828 9.7% 6.8% 0.9704
Magallanes 974 153,899 2.2% 4.6% 0.8993
Total country 44,729 3,369,692 100.0% 100.0% 0.954
4. Discussion
When speculation occurs, decisions are made about specific actions without enough evidence
about what is believed to generate optimal results for everyone in the future. A speculative process
results from the search for rewards with a strong element of chance. Indeed, speculation has no
scientific basis since it is driven by belief rather than evidence. Using this definition as a starting point,
we can state that in Chile there is a process of water speculation, given that its consumption would
indicate that more water is consumed than is naturally regenerated. A water ownership scheme has
Water 2020,12, 3369 11 of 13
modeled a scenario of scarcity. As Mehta et al. indicate [
14
], this capitalist fueled scarcity produces a
situation in which natural resources have become the focus of global discussion, allowing governments
to legitimize the privatized management of resource rights. In the case of Chile, this benefit becomes
monetary capital which can be accumulated in rights and used for speculative enterprises which
lead to drastic inequality of access to water for people. Restrictions of direct access to user groups
benefits a minority with economic and productive interests, principally linked to the social and
economic inequalities rooted in Chilean society [
31
]. Therefore, in our interpretation, water markets
reduce accessibility to natural resources because the price of water rights hinders universal access
in low-income communities, an everyday reality in rural areas. Given the way in which the water
market in Chile is conducted, the use of water rights as financial assets which increase price over
time is problematic for social development, and the social benefits of this mode of managing natural
resources are dicult to find. Hence, speculation in water rights is one of the results of having a water
market for distributing water.
To illustrate this problem with an analogy, it is as if water is being consumed that the glaciers will
not run out, while in reality the water supplies of the planet are reaching an abundance threshold,
producing scarcity. The mere fact that runois much lower than productive consumption generates a
deep concern, where sustainability of water resources are compromised in the future. Do we know if
the runoof glaciers is enough for domiciliary consumption and more sustainable forms of production?
Some authors [
31
,
32
] assert that the naturalization of the scarcity of natural resources, as an acceptable
phenomenon not created by society, justifies exclusionary property practices, as with the public right
to access nature.
Without regulatory mechanisms appropriate to the Chilean reality [
33
35
], the water market
and its speculative characteristics are dangerous for subsistence in Chile. This complexity, that
especially aects rural communities [
36
], needs to be remedied through public policy and the structural
transformation of property management in Chile.
On the one hand, the World Bank proposes that water markets should be formalized and more
transparent, which leads to significant price dispersion, unclear operating costs and considerable
information asymmetries among market participants. The latter could lead to the development
of inequitable economic activities concerning exchange processes. Recently, the Organization for
Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) has proposed that Chile increase its tax collection by
increasing (or creating) taxes on the exploitation of natural resources (such as water) to finance new
social and infrastructure projects needed to advance development.
The water market is more important in areas where the resource is scarcer [
37
39
]. However, this
is contradicted by much of the literature that presents a critical view of water resource distribution.
To understand the idea of the water market, then, we can conclude that water privatization is far from
being a socially just way of distributing resources in a society that, in addition, presents high levels of
inequality and segregation [4042].
The climate emergency represents another critical point in the discussion. This crisis will increase
the intensity and frequency of extreme events which will cause mass migration waves and food and
water insecurity, increasing the occurrence of violent climate conflicts [
27
,
32
]. Chile is no exception,
considering the social and political conflicts in the Latin-American region, where people from dierent
countries migrate to Chile in search of better opportunities, working in primary economic activities like
mining, forestry or agriculture, three activities entirely linked to water rights and community conflicts.
Finally, this work represents the first approximation of an inequality metric and spatial perspective
on the concentration of water rights in the continental territory of Chile. With a nation-wide perspective,
the article links not only with localization but also indicates the type of rights assigned, the number of
liters granted and the ways of using of the resource, all strongly related to the productivity of mining,
forestry and agriculture, which are the primary resources of the Chilean economy. We have shared the
data freely to contribute to further analysis and studies related to water rights.
Water 2020,12, 3369 12 of 13
Author Contributions:
Conceptualization, J.F.V.-P.; methodology, J.C.-P.; validation, J.C.-P., C.A.-N. and J.F.V.-P.;
formal analysis, J.C.-P., C.A.-N. and J.F.V.-P.; investigation, J.C.-P.; resources, J.C.-P.; data curation, J.C.-P. and
J.F.V.-P.; writing—original draft preparation, J.F.V.-P.; writing—review and editing, J.C.-P., C.A.-N. and J.F.V.-P.;
visualization, J.C.-P.; funding acquisition, J.F.V.-P. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of
the manuscript.
Funding:
This research was funded by ANID, grant number FONDECYT 11180569 and Universidad de
Las Américas.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.
References
1.
UNICEF and WHO. Joint Monitoring Programme for Water Supply, Sanitation and Hygiene JMP WASH.
2017. Available online: https://washdata.org/data/household#!/table?geo0=region&geo1=sdg&geo2=Latin%
20America%20and%20the%20Caribbean (accessed on 17 November 2020).
2.
Ojeda, L.; Mansilla, Q.P.; Rodr
í
guez, J.C.; Pino, V.A. The access to water in informal settlements. The case of
Valparaíso, Chile. Bitácora Urbano Territ. 2020,30, 151–165. [CrossRef]
3.
Rojas, M.A.L.; Garcia, P.A. Estrategias cosmopolticas para la defensa del agua en territorio Mapuche-Huilliche.
Agua Territ. 2019,14, 45–56. [CrossRef]
4.
Bolados, G.P.; Babidge, S. Rituality and extractivism. The cleaning of channels and the disputes for the water
in the salt flat of Atacama, north of Chile. Estud. Atacamenos 2017,54, 201–216.
5.
Prieto, M. Irrigation that the Market Does Not Want to See: History of the Water Dispossession in the
Communities of Lasana and Chiu-Chiu (Atacama Desert, Chile). J. Lat. Am. Geogr.
2017
,16, 69–91. [CrossRef]
6.
Molinos-Senante, M.; Far
í
as, R. Evaluation of the influence of economic groups on the eciency and quality of
service of water companies: An empirical approach for Chile. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res.
2018,25, 23251–23260
.
[CrossRef] [PubMed]
7.
Torres-Salinas, R.; Garc
í
a-Carmona, A.; Rojas-Hern
á
ndez, J. Privatizando el agua, produciendo sujetos
h
í
dricos: An
á
lisis de las pol
í
ticas de escala en la movilizaci
ó
n socio-h
í
drica contra Pascua Lama e HidroAys
é
n
en Chile. Agua Territ. 2017,10, 149–166. [CrossRef]
8.
Bakker, K. The Business of Water: Market Environmentalism in the Water Sector. Annu. Rev. Environ. Resour.
2014,39, 469–494. [CrossRef]
9.
Gosling, S.N.; Arnell, N.W. A global assessment of the impact of climate change on water scarcity. Clim. Chang.
2016,134, 371–385. [CrossRef]
10.
Hanjra, M.A.; Qureshi, M.E. Global water crisis and future food security in an era of climate change.
Food Policy 2010,35, 365–377. [CrossRef]
11.
Senado de la Rep
ú
blica de Chile. Rechaza Reforma Constitucional Sobre Dominio y Uso de Aguas,
Valpara
í
so, Chile. 2020. Available online: https://www.senado.cl/appsenado/index.php?mo=tramitacion&
ac=getDiscusion&nrobol=612409_P&idsesion=8454 (accessed on 10 October 2020).
12.
Vergara-Perucich, F.; Jara, B.; Lufin, M.; Roco, L.; Arias-Loyola, M. El Mercado del Agua: Una Mirada Econ
ó
mica
al Caso de Chile. El Agua en Antofagasta; Centro de Investigaci
ó
n Tecnol
ó
gica del Agua en el Desierto
CEITSAZA: Antofagasta, Chile, 2017; pp. 27–45.
13.
Aldunce, P.; Borquez, R.; Adler, C.; Blanco, G.; Garreaud, R.D. Unpacking Resilience for Adaptation:
Incorporating Practitioners’ Experiences through a Transdisciplinary Approach to the Case of Drought in
Chile. Sustainability 2016,8, 905. [CrossRef]
14.
Mehta, L.; Hu, A.; Allouche, J. The new politics and geographies of scarcity. Geoforum
2019
,101, 222–230.
[CrossRef]
15.
Champeyrache, C. Artificial scarcity, power, and the Italian Mafia. J. Econ. Issues
2014
,48, 625–640. [CrossRef]
16. Mehta, L. The Limits to Scarcity: Contesting the Politics of Allocation; Earthscan: London, UK, 2010.
17.
Boelens, R. Water rights, indigenous management and national legislation. The indigenous struggle for
water and cultural policies of participation. Boletín Arch. Histórico Agua 2003,8, 5–19.
18.
Pahl-Wostl, C. A conceptual framework for analysing adaptive capacity and multi-level learning processes
in resource governance regimes. Glob. Environ. Chang. 2009,19, 354–365. [CrossRef]
19.
Kirsch, B.R.; Maxwell, R.M. The Use of a Water Market to Minimize Drought-Induced Losses in the Bay Area
of California. J. Am. Water Work. Assoc. 2015,107, E274–E281. [CrossRef]
Water 2020,12, 3369 13 of 13
20.
Larra
í
n, S. El Agua en Chile: Entre los Derechos Humanos y las Reglas del Mercado. Polis. Rev. Latinoam.
2006,14, 1–21.
21.
World Bank. CHILE. Diagn
ó
stico de la Gesti
ó
n de los Recursos H
í
dricos; Departamento de Medio Ambiente y
Desarrollo Sostenible Región para América Latina y el Caribe: Santiago, Chile, 2011.
22.
Bauer, C. Water Conflicts and Entrenched Governance Problems in Chile’s Market Model. Water Altern.
2015,8, 147–172.
23.
Donoso, G. Water (Rights) Markets: Experiences and Proposals in South America; United Nations Publications:
New York, NY, USA, 2014.
24.
Bauer, C.J. Contra la Corriente: Privatizaci
ó
n, Mercados de Agua y el Estado en Chile; Lom Ediciones: Santiago,
Chile, 2002.
25.
Peña, H. Meaning and Scope of Water Code Reform in Chile; Circular N. 22; Network for Cooperation in
Integrated Water Resource Management for Sustainable Development in Latin America and the Caribbean:
Santiago, Chile, 2005.
26.
Larra
í
n, S. Glaciares chilenos: Reservas estrat
é
gicas de agua dulce. Rev. Ambiente Desarrollo
2007
,23, 28–35.
27.
Panayotakis, C. Remaking Scarcity: From Capitalist Ineciency to Economic Democracy; Pluto Press: London,
UK, 2011.
28.
Mehta, L. The Politics and Poetics of Water: The Naturalisation of Scarcity in Western India; Orient Blackswan:
Telangana, India, 2005.
29.
Jaeger, P.; Peña, H. Del Orden Neoliberal al R
é
gimen de lo P
ú
blico, en Materia de Aguas; XV Jornadas de Derecho
de Aguas; Universidad Católica de Chile: Santiago, Chile, 2013.
30.
DGA. Derechos de Aprovechamiento de Aguas Registrados en DGA; Direcci
ó
n General de Aguas: Santiago,
Chile, 2020.
31.
Garc
í
a, P.B.; Olgu
í
n, F.H.; Mahn, C.C.; Cuevas, A.S. La eco-geo-pol
í
tica del agua: Una propuesta desde
los territorios en las luchas por la recuperacin del agua en la provincia de Petorca (Zona central de Chile).
Rev. Rupturas 2017,8, 159–191. [CrossRef]
32. Mehta, L. Water and human development. World dev. 2014,9, 59–69. [CrossRef]
33.
Panez-Pinto, A.; Fa
ú
ndez-Vergara, R.; Mansilla-Quiñones, C. Politization of the hydrological crisis in Chile:
An analysis of the conflict over water in the Petorca Province. Agua Territ. 2017,10, 131–148. [CrossRef]
34.
De Carvalho, S.; Ana, C.; Magalh
ã
es, R.D.P.; Iacomini, V. Privatizaç
ã
o dos recursos h
í
dricos no Chile e sua
prevalência sobre o direito fundamental à água. Braz. J. Anim. Environ. Res. 2019,2, 846–849.
35.
Maturana, H. Defensa del Servicio del Agua: Una Postura Sindical. In El Derecho al Agua en el Sur de las
Américas; Alianza Chilena por un Comercio Justo, Ético y Responsable (ACJR): Santiago, Chile, 2002.
36. Bravo, P. Agua: Dónde Estáy de Quién es; Programa Chile Sustentable: Santiago, Chile, 2003.
37.
Pinto, A.P.; Quiñones, P.M.; Moreira-Muñoz, A. Agua, tierra y fractura sociometab
ó
lica del agronegocio.
Actividad frutícola en Petorca, Chile. Bitácora Urbano-Territorial 2018,28, 153–160. [CrossRef]
38.
Schleyer, R.G. Chilean Water Policy: The Role of Water Rights, Institutions and Markets.
Int. J. Water Resour. Dev. 1996,12, 33–48. [CrossRef]
39. Ríos, M.A.; Quiroz, J.A. The market of water rights in Chile: Major issues. Cuad. Econ. 1995,1, 317–345.
40. Harvey, D. A Brief History of Neoliberalism; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2005.
41.
G
ó
mez-Lobo, A.; Paredes, R. Reflexiones Sobre el Proyecto de Modificaci
ó
n del C
ó
digo de Aguas; Universidad de
Chile: Santiago, Chile, 2000.
42.
Donoso, G.; De Chile, P.U.C. Water markets: Case study of Chiles 1981 Water Code. Cienc. Investig. Agrar.
2006,33, 131–146. [CrossRef]
Publisher’s Note:
MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional
aliations.
©
2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
... In many cases, markets are simply not active enough to reallocate water towards more efficient uses (see Bauer, 1997;Hadjigeorgalis, 2002;Prieto, 2016). Lastly, rather than promoting more equitable access to water rights, market-based systems often reflect broader societal inequities, leading to unequal distributions of water (Bjornlund & McKay, 2002;Budds, 2004;Correa-Parra et al., 2020). Even with the neoliberal model's emphasis on lack of State intervention, the State often plays a central role in generating inequities in water rights allocations (Fraser, 2023;Prieto et al., 2022). ...
... Our findings indicate notable inequalities arising from the 1981 Water Code. A small group controls the country's water through receiving the vast majority of DGA allocations (as in Correa-Parra et al., 2020). As shown by the finding that the top 1% receive 79.1% of allocated volume after their respective catchments have crossed the OI threshold, this elite group augments their power when water is scarce, contributing to our finding of greater Gini coefficients for post-overallocation conditions. ...
Article
Full-text available
Neoliberal approaches to water governance, pioneered in Chile in the 1980s, are reappearing today on the centerstage of the water policy debate. While advocates claim that strong property rights, limits on government authority, and water markets can enhance environmental sustainability, efficiency, neutrality, and equity in the distribution of water rights, limited empirical evidence exists on whether neoliberal policies have delivered on these key promises. In this paper, we combine hydrological analysis with a nationwide data set on government water rights allocations between 1981 and 2021 to determine when and where water has been allocated beyond sustainable limits. We then integrate water market transaction and agricultural data to assess how allocations and scarcity conditions relate to spatial and temporal patterns in irrigation, crop distribution, and water market activity. Our results indicate that 30% of catchments are overallocated, and that continued government allocations of water rights during scarcity exacerbate already‐high inequalities in the distribution of water. We find no evidence that scarcity or water markets induced improvements in numerous efficiency metrics. Overall, our results support growing claims that the neoliberal water model fails to fulfill its key promises, notably to the detriment of nature and marginalized rural communities.
... In addition, some scholars focus on market failure [10] and water rights market rules [11], which are considered to be weak links in the water rights trading market. The implementation of water rights trading also inevitably brings a series of problems, such as exacerbating the imbalance between groundwater and surface water at the demand level [12], the unfairness of water rights trading [13] and the loss of efficiency [14], such as the huge loss of economic benefits. Domestic research on water rights trading started late compared to the international field, which led to the early stage of the research scholars' main work focused on absorbing and learning from foreign mature experiences and theories, mainly focusing on the limitations of water rights trading and its impact on the economy and society [15] and the institutional basis of water rights and its nature [16]. ...
Article
Full-text available
The year 2023 will mark the tenth year of China’s pilot water rights program, with China’s overall water use efficiency improving and the water-related industry continuing to grow. Due to the uneven spatial and temporal distribution of water resources in China, there still exists the real problem of resource-type water shortage and structural water shortage, in which the problem of water poverty is particularly prominent. In order to alleviate water poverty, this paper constructs a water poverty indicator system and measures it, uses a double difference model to study whether the water trading policy is effective in alleviating water poverty, and establishes a tripartite evolutionary game model to simulate the behavioral strategies of the relevant stakeholders in water trading. The main findings of this study are as follows: (1) the degree of water poverty in China’s 31 provinces and municipalities from 2008 to 2022 shows a decreasing trend in general, but there are still regional differences; (2) the pilot policy of water rights trading effectively alleviates the situation of water poverty in China, and the alleviation effect is especially obvious for the western region; (3) The degree of government subsidy, the price of water rights trading, the degree of government punishment for non-trading behavior, and the extra income gained from water rights trading all affect the degree of water poverty of both parties to the water rights trading. Therefore, we should continue to improve the water rights trading platform, promote the construction of a diversified water use market, and strengthen the monitoring, measurement and supervision of water rights trading.
... A series of market-driven reforms imposed by force (Klein, 2008) during Pinochet's dictatorship (lasting from 1973 to 1990) focused on the privatization of public services and the weakening of the state as a provider of basic rights (Harvey, 2005). Such structural changes had a negative impact on the social fabric of Chile, affecting access to health, education, pensions, and even access to water (Correa et al., 2020). As such, the Chilean education system is "known worldwide as an extreme case of the educational market, in which education is strongly decentralized, highly privatized" (Bellei et al., 2022, p. 79). ...
Chapter
The growing momentum for building teacher-researcher partnerships in TESOL emphasizes holistic professionalism rather than bifurcation of teaching from research; and reflexive learning rather than privileging academic knowledge. This momentum in the English language education community has involved dialogues centered on a participatory culture of inquiry in which identities as “teachers” and “researchers” have become flexible and permeable. The contributors to this volume illustrate this shift toward a culture of research, which aims to forge a reflexive relationship between educational research and teaching practice by bridging the gap between them. In this introductory chapter, the authors, who are the co-editors of the volume, share their understandings of a culture of research in TESOL. Then, they introduce the chapters brought together in this volume to exemplify a range of perspectives and local practices within such a culture. The chapter concludes with a call for educational institutions and professional organizations to promote the collaborative turn in TESOL research.
... A series of market-driven reforms imposed by force (Klein, 2008) during Pinochet's dictatorship (lasting from 1973 to 1990) focused on the privatization of public services and the weakening of the state as a provider of basic rights (Harvey, 2005). Such structural changes had a negative impact on the social fabric of Chile, affecting access to health, education, pensions, and even access to water (Correa et al., 2020). As such, the Chilean education system is "known worldwide as an extreme case of the educational market, in which education is strongly decentralized, highly privatized" (Bellei et al., 2022, p. 79). ...
Book
This volume focuses on real-world examples of teacher-researcher collaborations in TESOL in a variety of contexts. The book begins with a review of conceptual foundations and cultural factors that facilitate or hinder TESOL educators’ engagement in and with research. The chapters that follow contain diverse geographic representations, topics, and author voices engaged in research collaborations, illustrating approaches to the ethical and cross-cultural challenges of such engagement, as well as successes. The proliferation of a neo-liberal agenda in education that has an impact on local TESOL classrooms has generated a sense of urgency for teacher-researcher collaborations that promote diversity, equity, and inclusion in TESOL, to which this volume responds. The chapters document how a range of TESOL educators developed and reflected on their collaborations with the aim of building a culture of research in English language education. The volume will be of high interest to English language and language teachers, graduate/undergraduate students, teacher educators, researchers in areas of TESOL, language education, applied linguistics, literacy education, and teacher education.
... This contradiction has reached a critical level as in each region of the country, multiple companies own a large portion of the rights to use this resource [32]. In the case of the Antofagasta region, the situation is particularly critical since there is an extreme water deficit that negatively affects people's quality of life and social development, and exacerbates desertification [33]. Therefore, prioritizing water as a national public use good over its commercial use would help mitigate the negative effects of water rights concessions and encourage the industry to seek other alternatives. ...
Article
Full-text available
This study investigates water consumption in two areas with limited water resources—the Salar de Atacama and Salar de Atacama-Vertiente Pacifico basins in Chile’s Antofagasta Region—with the aim of developing strategies that incorporate social and environmental aspects into water management. A qualitative approach was employed that involved a focus group with twelve water management representatives and surveys of the general population (468 responses). Additionally, the current state of water rights in the two basins was examined and the feasibility of the proposed strategies was assessed. The findings reveal that the mining industry’s development approach is mostly viewed as negative, mainly due to inadequate community engagement, confidential consumption data, and limited government oversight. The quantitative findings indicate that 53.8% of respondents see the main obstacle as the lack of a solution satisfying both parties. Additionally, 35.3%, 24.4%, and 22.4% believe transparency, objective information provision, and detailed resource usage disclosure by mining companies would help. Adopting a comprehensive water stewardship approach that considers social and environmental factors would enable a novel contribution to a more effective and sustainable water resource management system in northern Chile, mitigating communities’ negative perceptions of the industry and facilitating the integration of communities and involved agents. Therefore, improved management and transparent collaboration among stakeholders are essential for responsible water resource use in mining.
... An often-mentioned study case in terms of water governance that exemplifies the aforementioned global challenges is Chile, in which the commoditisation of water has been deliberately implemented (Bauer, 1997;2004;Larrain, 2012;Baer, 2014;Prieto et al., 2020;Correa-Parra et al., 2020). The Chilean law guarantees that private water rights can be granted to users (Bauer, 2004). ...
Article
Full-text available
Water use requires monitoring and quantification at different spatial scales to enhance water security, especially in regions facing water scarcity and threats to food security. Consequently, water metering has been implemented in various countries as part of water governance frameworks. This study aims to evaluate the implementation of a water metering network within the Chilean water governance system, which is based on the commoditisation of water through water rights. Additionally, it assesses the potential of supplementing the water metering network with remote sensing-based estimates of actual evapotranspiration (AET) and discusses the need to integrate these estimates into an appropriate water governance scheme. To conduct this study, publicly available water use reports were obtained from the Water Resources Directorate and subsequently processed to eliminate anomalies in the withdrawal time series. Water withdrawal data was supplemented with information on granted water rights to provide additional insights and contrast water allocations with actual withdrawals. AET estimates from the Mapping EvapoTranspiration at high Resolution with Internalised Calibration (METRIC) model using Landsat scenes were also acquired for the period from 2019 to 2022 to compare withdrawals and water demand in the agricultural sector. It was found that only a small fraction of water rights (~ 2%) is currently being metered. Actual reported withdrawals, on average, amount to approximately one fifth to one fourth of the volumes granted through water rights. However, water extractions vary depending on geographical locations and usage categories. Remote sensing-based AET demonstrates a good correlation with withdrawals, suggesting its potential in auditing water withdrawal records provided by water users and calculating water availability and withdrawals at aggregated scales within an adaptive water governance framework. While different applications were explored within the Chilean context, these have a broader application in global water governance, particularly in regions experiencing similar challenges in water resource management.
Chapter
The aim of this chapter is to share the experience of creating and sustaining a grassroots, self-governed, non-profit TESOL research community of practice in Chile—Red Chilena de Investigación en English Language Teaching (RICELT). The RICELT network was founded in 2014 with the aim of connecting academics, school teachers, and student teachers researching English language teaching (ELT). In this chapter, I introduce initiatives developed by this network and how these initiatives serve to value the work of teacher-researchers who have been marginalized from contributing to and learning from academic scholarship. The milestones and challenges of sustaining a research community of practice that advocates for social responsibility and inclusion in language teaching research, which can be inaccessible to and removed from teachers’ real-world experiences are also presented. The chapter closes with a discussion of the future directions of RICELT and reflections on the role of research organizations in local communities.
Article
Full-text available
The pandemic reaches the Andean foothills at a time of profound territorial transformations. Nothing is neutral about its arrival, and the institutional apparatus set up to control it brings consequences that, in their deployment, reflect the deepening of the privatization processes that have governed the territory throughout its history and with particular severity during the last decade. The Maule Mountain range, the setting considered for this study, remained invisible for much of the regional history centered on the valleys. With export agriculture, forest plantations, and hydroelectric generation, the mountain range has acquired greater economic visibility. The dispossession of peoples lands results from the economic exploitation of mountains' resources. The ethnographic perspective of intensified processes in a pandemic world highlights hydropowers role in local dynamics and the resistance it creates among residents. It is installing new common meanings or searching for alternatives in the face of advanced extractivist. As a result of these transformations, the symbolic representation of the mountain as a borderbecomes real. At the same time, its emancipatorypotential is based on the subjectivity of those alienated from it.
Article
Full-text available
En el Sur Global, el hábitat informal se ha vuelto un modo de desarrollo urbano que se enfrenta en diversas dimensiones a los modelos de desarrollo de los gobiernos locales. El presente artículo analiza los problemas asociados a la inexistencia de cobertura de agua potable, alcantarillado, red seca y colectores de aguas lluvias en los asentamientos informales de la ciudad de Valparaíso, Chile, carencia infraestructural generada, en parte, por la privatización del agua dentro del modelo neoliberal chileno a partir de la década de 1980. Para ello, se realizó un análisis espacial que contrastó información obtenida de diversos relevamientos ortofotogramétricos mediante un dispositivo R.P.A.S (dron), con datos censal de propiedad de suelo y cifras de la cobertura de agua de las empresas privadas. Los resultados revelaron que la ausencia de infraestructura hídrica de la Zona de Interfaz Urbano Forestal (ZIUF) en la que se localizan la mayoría de los asentamientos informales de Valparaíso genera un acceso desigual al agua que mantiene y refuerza las condiciones de exclusión y segregación socioespacial de los mismos.
Article
Full-text available
La significación del agua que organiza las estrategias cosmopolíticas de los territorios mapuche-huilliche, adquiere renovada importancia frente al actual contexto de privatización de los derechos de aprovechamiento de las aguas en Chile. El caso de la comunidad MapucheHhuilliche de Rupumeica, configura un ejemplo único en Chile de ejercicio político indígena en que se consigue detener por diez años la construcción de un proyecto hidroeléctrico. Para lograrlo la comunidad de Rupumeica ha defendido el agua en nombre de sus mitos, de sus ritos, de los espíritus dueños del territorio en que habitan y de sus antepasados que poblaron ese lugar; así como en nombre de sus títulos de propiedad entregados por el Estado de Chile y del Convenio 169 de la Organización Internacional del Trabajo (OIT), firmado tanto por el Estado Chileno como el de Noruega (Nación a la que pertenece SN Power, empresa que desea construir dicho proyecto). En el presente artículo se busca expresar el carácter que adquieren los ngen (espíritus dueños), especialmente el ngen-ko (espíritu dueño da água) e chao- ngenechen (unidad base, material-inmaterial) en la articulación de las estrategias cosmopolíticas para reclamar la participación Mapuche-Huilliche en la gestión de su territorio. Tal participación ha permitido impedir la construcción de la presa hidroeléctrica Maqueo, la cual propone desviar 6 ríos e inundar aproximadamente 180 hectáreas de sus territorios ancestralmente habitados, en las riberas del lago Maihue, comunas de Futrono y Río Bueno, en la región de los Ríos (andes austral, sur de Chile). En busca de comprender las estrategias y prácticas cosmopolíticas de protesta presentes en el conflicto, se observa un desacuerdo radical frente a la posibilidad de una apertura ontológica, que reivindica territorialidad, hogar y linaje, frente a las transformaciones territoriales impuestas por el desarrollo económico nacional. En este sentido el desacuerdo que emerge entre aquello que se considera a sí mismo “el todo” (El Estado nación) y la existencia de aquello que lo excede (la cosmopolítica indígena que no deja marcas en la historicidad del Estado nación).
Article
Full-text available
El artículo profundiza en las transformaciones socioecológicas que el agronegocio genera en las dinámicas territoriales haciendo uso del concepto de metabolismo social. El estudio se sustenta en: a) el método de estimación de agua virtual para calcular los volúmenes de agua utilizados en la actividad frutícola y sus impactos en la disponibilidad de agua en las cuencas, y b) el análisis de la transformación territorial de las relaciones sociales de ocupación de la tierra y tipologías de cultivo. Se toma como caso de estudio la provincia de Petorca en Chile, lugar que ha vivenciado un intenso conflicto territorial en torno a la cuestión hídrica, generado por el modelo privado de gestión del agua chileno, el agronegocio frutícola y los efectos de periodos prolongados de sequía. Los resultados evidencian la profundización de una fractura sociometabólica en el territorio, ocasionada por la intensificación de la exportación frutícola. Dicha fractura tornó inviable la agricultura campesina al provocar una dinámica territorial en donde campesinos y campesinas no disponen de agua para criar animales y/o plantar los cultivos para su sustento.
Article
Full-text available
The privatization of water and sewerage services (WSS) has led to the foundation of water economic groups, which integrate several water companies and have gained notable importance at the global level. In the framework of benchmarking studies, there are no prior studies exploring the impact that economic groups have on the efficiency and quality of service provided by water companies. This study investigates, for the first time, whether the membership of water companies in an economic group influences their performance. Quantity- and quality-adjusted efficiency scores were computed using data envelopment analysis models. An empirical application was developed for the Chilean water industry since most of their water companies are private and belong to an economic group. The results show that independent water companies provide WSS with better quality than do water companies that belong to an economic group. From a statistical point of view, it was evident that membership in an economic group impacts both the quantity- and quality-adjusted efficiency scores of water companies. The results of this study illustrate that applying the model-firm regulation to the Chilean water industry has significant drawbacks that should be addressed by the water regulator to promote the long-term sustainability of the water industry.
Article
Full-text available
Building upon the contribution of the Latin-American Political Ecology and Critical Geography, we highlight the eco-geo-politics of water from the territories that rise from the practices and discourses of the Movement for the Defense of Water, Land and Environment in the Petorca Province, central zone and its struggle for the reclamation of water. From an ethnographic approach based on interviews with small farmers and an analysis of the water rights granted by the state, we present the struggle for water in Petorca as a historical conflict for the land, which became more radical since the imposition of the water code by the military dictarorship in 1981, and compounded with the expansion of the agro-exportation extractivist frontiers since democracy returned in 1990.
Article
Full-text available
El artículo tiene como objetivo analizar los procesos de politización de los conflictos por el agua en Chile a partir del estudio de caso de la provincia de Petorca (región de Valparaíso) y, particularmente, el surgimiento y trayectoria del Movimiento por la Defensa del Agua, la Tierra y el Medioambiente (MODATIMA). Las principales contribuciones del análisis de dicha experiencia tienen que ver con: a) Los alcances del proceso de politización de este tipo de conflictos en su cuestionamiento al modelo de desarrollo chileno. b) La relación de esta politización con la reivindicación de otras miradas sobre la comprensión del agua. c) La vinculación de la conflictividad en torno al agua con los procesos de acumulación de capital por desposesión que se experimentan en Chile y a nivel global.
Article
Full-text available
Revisamos las respuestas sociales a la privatización del agua en Chile. A través del análisis de dos estudios de caso —HidroAysén y Pascua Lama—abordamos el problema de cómo estos mega-proyectos han generado las condiciones socio-políticas para el surgimiento de nuevos sujetos hídricos que, en el proceso de su constitución como sujetos, han ido configurando los contornos de un movimiento social por el agua de escala nacional. Abordamos el surgimiento y desarrollo del movimiento desde la perspectiva de las políticas de escala, concluyendo que la agenda de cambios empujada por los nuevos sujetos hídricos apunta a transformar el modelo privatizador del agua hacia otro que conciba el agua como un bien común, abriendo nuevos espacios para democratizar y crear modos más sustentables de gobernanza hídrica en el país.
Article
Scarcity is a dangerous idea and has long been a totalising discourse in resource politics and mainstream economics. A large body of work has critiqued the naturalisation of scarcity in discourses of environmental change, and has highlighted problems in how scarcity is conceptualised and the ways in which scarcities are socially and politically generated. Despite this, the ‘scarcity postulate’ – an assumed mismatch between infinitely expanding human desires and finite means to realise them – remains a powerful concept that continues to be deployed and re-deployed in a host of debates concerning environment and natural resources. From the ‘Limits to Growth’ debates that influenced environmental movements in the 1970s, discussions concerning the causes and consequences of the overlapping food, fuel and finance crises of the 2000s to debates concerning climate change, environmental security and militarisation in the Anthropocene, the discursive constellation of scarcity seems always at work. The focus of this special issue is the cross-scalar dynamics of what we identify as a ‘new politics of scarcity’. This new politics is associated with new framings, contestations and entanglements of scarcity that are associated with new configurations of actors, new political economic relations and new spatialities and geographies of resource control and violence. Building on the empirical cases developed in this special issue, we examine the dynamics and the ‘work’ of the new cross-scalar scarcity politics in sustaining elite and capitalist power through justifying resource acquisitions and enclosures, large-scale policy reforms in the name of ‘austerity’ and intensification of extraction whilst politically side-stepping more thorny politics of (re)distribution, mis-appropriation, dispossession and social justice. We conclude by looking at alternative framings and vernacular conceptions of sustainability that challenge dominant scarcity-driven policies and programmes that intensify local exclusions and inequalities.
Book
Neoliberalism--the doctrine that market exchange is an ethic in itself, capable of acting as a guide for all human action--has become dominant in both thought and practice throughout much of the world since 1970 or so. Writing for a wide audience, David Harvey, author of The New Imperialism and The Condition of Postmodernity, here tells the political-economic story of where neoliberalization came from and how it proliferated on the world stage. Through critical engagement with this history, he constructs a framework, not only for analyzing the political and economic dangers that now surround us, but also for assessing the prospects for the more socially just alternatives being advocated by many oppositional movements.