ChapterPDF Available

The Myth of a Food Crisis

Authors:
  • The Bioscience Resource Project

Abstract

Previously I have suggested that the fate of the global food chain rests on a moral question. Customers will either come to believe that sustainable organic local and ethical (SOLE) food can feed the globe, or they will acquiesce to the narrative of the industrialised food system on the decisive grounds of moral necessity–that only pesticides, corporate concentration, and GMOs can forestall mass starvation. The defining assertion in this space is the claim of a potential global food production deficit: the supposed challenge of 'feeding the 10 billion'. The crisis narrative has been led by the UN's Food and Agriculture Organisation (FAO) whose mathematical modelling of the food system has predicted a 70% increase (now 60%) in the annual amount of food needed by 2050. By carefully examining the assumptions underlying its modelling, however, I show here that FAO modellers have consistently underestimated global food supplies and consistently overestimated food demand. But, as shown by its ability to adjust to the biofuel boom, the food system contains massive amounts of under-utilised capacity which goes uncounted by current quantitative models.
Rethinking Food and Agriculture. https://doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-12-816410-5.00005-0
© 2021 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
5
The myth of a food crisis
Jonathan Latham
The Bioscience Resource Project, Ithaca, NY, United States
5.1 Introduction
World Agriculture Towards 2030/2050 is a major report predicting global agricultural
trends (Alexandratos & Bruinsma, 2012). It was produced by the economics division
of the UN Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO). In its abstract the FAO authors
make a prominent disclaimer. Its projections, they stress (both on p. i and p. 7), are
not to be used for normative purposes; that is, their report is not a prescription of how
the global food system should develop. It is merely an exploratory model; their most
reliable projection of business as usual (Alexandratos & Bruinsma, 2012).
In all probability this disclaimer resulted from the intense global attention that its
predecessor (FAO, 2006) received. This “interim report” was cited across the globe
as claiming that the world must produce 70% more food by the year 2050. This 70%
number (sometimes even adjusted to a “doubling”) was almost invariably recruited
to bolster a number of technological modernizing agendas for agriculture, for in-
stance, in the promotion of genetically modified crops. Thus the UK’s chief scientist
in 2009 predicted an imminent “perfect storm” of climate change and food shortages
(Beddington 2009). Similar analyses were repeated in scientific articles, in generalist
publications such as the Economist magazine, and by agribusiness (Peekhaus, 2010;
Tomlinson, 2011; Stone & Glover, 2011).
Thus FAO’s number was repeatedly taken out of context and presented as a grand
challenge requiring special efforts or difficult compromises. That is, it was used nor-
matively. Those citing FAO may not have said that:
The battle to feed all of humanity is over. In the 1970s the world will undergo
famines—hundreds of millions of people are going to starve to death in spite of any
crash programs embarked upon now. (The Population Bomb, Paul Ehrlich, 1968).
However, the implications were comparable.
But this is not merely a simple story of statistics being taken out of context. In 2016,
the same FAO department described in more detail their modeling system (in 2012 it
was renamed the Global Agriculture Perspectives System, or GAPS) used to derive
the original prediction (Kavalleri etal., 2016). Drawing attention, in a clearly norma-
tive fashion, to its newest quantitative prediction the authors wrote: “A key finding…
is that world food production should increase by some 60% from 2005/07 to 2050”
(Kavalleri etal., 2016, p. 1, emphasis added). By contradicting their colleagues’ pre-
vious disclaimer, Kavalleri etal. raised the issue, since FAO is a stakeholder in the
food crisis narrative, of whether the original disclaimer was sincere and whether more
could not have been done to avoid the normative usages of FAO numbers.
94 Rethinking Food and Agriculture
The answer given in this chapter supports the analysis of Tomlinson that a “slide”
is operating in many of the texts written by FAO, and that this slide is particularly
problematic in texts written by FAO leadership (cited in Tomlinson, 2011). Given that
FAO oscillates between normative and nonnormative statements, this slide might be
better called a “shuffle,” but it embodies perfectly the central paradox of all quantita-
tive models of the global food system, whether produced by FAO or by others. This
paradox is that, though FAO modeling supposedly exists to “identify challenges in
world food and agricultural sectors and to offer strategic policy perspectives” in an
unbiased fashion (Kavalleri etal., 2016, p. 1), what GAPS does in practice is quan-
tify food. This frames agriculture as primarily a question of production. The focus
on production, no matter any disclaimer, is normative, because it marginalizes issues
of poverty and access to food, ecological costs, and social costs. These are either
unexamined or subsidiary. So while the titles of FAOs reports and models are broad,
e.g., World Agriculture: Towards 2015/30, the focus is narrowly on the quantification
of production, even though, according to the International Assessment of Agricultural
Knowledge, Science and Technology for Development (IAASTD), the truly “key”
questions swirling around agriculture are not about productivity (IAASTD, 2009).
Productivity, concluded the IAASTD report, is a distraction. As Robert Watson, chair
of IAASTD, told the press at its launch, in agriculture, “Business as usual is not an op-
tion.” The real question of agriculture is: Can we feed the people without also feeding
social and ecological disasters?
But farmer suicides and insect declines, salinization, dead zones, and the pollu-
tion of water bodies and other consequences of dysfunctional agriculture are absent
from World Agriculture Towards 2030/2050. Moreover, World Agriculture Towards
2030/2050 even fails, ultimately, to show that productivity per se merits specific mod-
eling attention. First, because the model it describes predicts that any necessary pro-
duction increases will be solved by business as usual. Second, it also predicts “Modest
reductions in the numbers undernourished” by 2050 but this reduction is dependent
on continued economic growth (i.e., increases in wealth); that is, not on agricultural
production (Alexandratos & Bruinsma, 2012).
FAO’s previous iteration, World Agriculture Towards 2015/2030, had reached a vir-
tually identical conclusion. It projected that out of a then total of 850 million hungry
people, just 120 million would be lifted out of hunger if food production reached its
target increase of 70% by 2030 (Bruinsma, 2003).
So, even according to FAO’s own models, increasing production does not solve
hunger. This result mirrors the conclusion of Amartya Sen in his celebrated history
Poverty and Famines. When hunger and famine strike, he found, production shortfalls
have virtually never been the cause (Sen, 1981). To many food system commentators
this is settled beyond question (e.g., Lappé & Collins, 2015). But it is a finding that
has nevertheless been disregarded by many, including FAO leaders (Tomlinson, 2011),
who have instead commonly cited FAO in support of a scarcity narrative with its con-
sequent need for a productivity focus (e.g., Conway, 2012). Thus the scarcity view,
whose credibility rests almost purely on the findings of models like GAPS, finds, at
best, only equivocal support there.
The myth of a food crisis 95
5.1.1 Global food models and projections
The purpose of this chapter, however, is to provide a quantitative critique of models
like GAPS at the level of their underlying assumptions.
Unless otherwise noted the focus will be on FAO’s GAPS. This focus is specifically
not intended to validate the quantification of food; indeed, quantification of food as
calories and weight is detrimental to a full understanding of food systems. It is rather
an acknowledgment that FAO’s work is the most prominently cited and that, encour-
aged by FAO’s shuffle, the world has overwhelmingly interpreted this 70% number as
normative. In 2012 FAO's prediction was updated to 60%, mainly to reflect a shifting
baseline: we are now much closer to 2050 than we were in 2003 (Alexandratos &
Bruinsma, 2012). So, at the risk of appearing to validate the general approach, it is on
a purely quantitative level that these models are most transparently open to challenge.
Malthus, 1798 is considered to have made the first mathematical model of a food
system. His simple projection concluded that exponential population growth would
eventually outstrip linear supply growth. The basic form of his model, followed ever
since, was to separate food supply from food demand (McCalla & Revoredo, 2001).
Besides FAO, institutions such as the International Food Policy Research Institute
(IFPRI) have developed their own models (Robinson etal., 2015). In addition, spe-
cial projects such as the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment, the Comprehensive
Assessment of Water Management, and Agrimonde (2009) (a joint project of the
French Institut Nationale de la Recherche Agronomique and the Centre de Cooperation
Internationale en Recherche Agronomique) have extended the general method but with
an emphasis on investigating specific questions, such as water constraints, climate
impacts, and the effects of specific policy decisions (de Fraiture etal., 2007; Fischer
etal., 1988; Rosegrant etal., 1995, 2001; Parry etal., 2004; Chaumet etal., 2009).
All are intended to inform decision making. However, those more suited to exploring
diverse potential outcomes are often called scenarios. These distinctions, along with
some of the strengths and weaknesses of the models, have previously been reviewed
by Reilly and Willenbockel (2010) and by Wise (2013).
What these reviewers note, above all, is that there is overall a strong degree of con-
sistency among models and scenarios that there is no need for extraordinary measures
to enhance production. To quote FAO: “from the standpoint of global production poten-
tial there should be no insurmountable constraints” (Alexandratos & Bruinsma, 2012).
None foresees a classic Ehrlich-style crisis, unless they expressly incorporate in their
scenarios some form of mismanagement. For instance, the Millennium Assessment
has as one of its four scenarios “Order through Strength” (OS) that envisages low
cooperation and high trade barriers. Under OS conditions there is no overall global
food shortage but there is increased malnutrition and even civil war in parts of Africa.
This is a broadly reassuring conclusion, but it should nevertheless be qualified by
the looming shadow of climate change (Battisti and Naylor, 2009; Nelson etal., 2010).
Agreement that food production is unlikely to develop into a crisis situation (climate
excepted) has not banished the alarmist narrative in the media, however (see, e.g.,
Hincks, 2018).
96 Rethinking Food and Agriculture
Yet, there are grounds to suppose that even this convergence, which does predict
a need for increased production, is excessively pessimistic. In 2011 researchers from
the World Bank Institute proposed that the world already produced enough food for
14 billion people (Herren etal., 2011). This number is well above UN population pre-
dictions, which are expected to reach 10–11 billion in 2050 and perhaps even decline
thereafter (UN, 2017).
Moreover, models also contradict global food price trends. Before the 2007/2008
price spike caused by changes in US and EU biofuel policies (de Gorter etal., 2015),
food prices had been declining at approximately 4% per year. Since that spike, prices
appear to have returned approximately to that track. This long-term decline, across
every sector of agriculture, suggests strongly that food supply significantly exceeds
current food demand and that the gap is if anything widening. The exact extent of this
excess is not clear but the 2017 FAO estimate for global cereal stocks is 762 million
tons. This amount represents approximately one-third of annual global production
(FAOSTAT). Thus, independent of any modeling, there are strong grounds for suppos-
ing that even the most optimistic models are still pessimistic. They are overestimating
demand or underestimating supply, or both. The overarching questions are: How does
one reconcile low (and declining) food prices and persistent global commodity gluts
with the projections, claimed by GAPS and other models, of the need to produce more
food? Are the models flawed? If so, what are those flaws?
5.1.2 How flawed are food system models?
The use of highly complex models always raises many questions of how well they
represent reality (Scrieciu, 2007). But food system models are especially complex,
seeking as they do to integrate biophysical, social, economic, and institutional com-
ponents. Thus a criticism sometimes made of such models is their use of calories as
the measure of nutrition (e.g., Herforth, 2015). Both nutritionists and those seeking
a more expansive definition of food security have pointed out that calories fall well
short of the definition of food security adopted at the 1996 World Food Summit: “Food
security exists when all people, at all times, have physical and economic access to
sufficient, safe and nutritious food to meet their dietary needs and food preferences”
(e.g., Burchi etal., 2011). Thus the achievement of caloric sufficiency may ultimately
be irrelevant.
To frame this diversity of critiques the primary issues with quantitative models
are sometimes divided into technical uncertainties, methodological uncertainties, and
epistemological uncertainties (Funtowicz & Ravetz, 1990).
Narrower technical concerns include the “knowledge gaps and priorities” raised
by Reilly and Willenbockel (2010) and also by Wise (2013). On this level these au-
thors agree there exist very significant problems with data quality. In many countries
that extends to quantifying even the most basic inputs of the models: poverty, GDP,
water availability, even simple population. The problem of questionable data is high-
lighted by the case of Ghana. Its national statistical agency announced in 2010 that it
was revising all future GDP estimates upward by over 60%. This made Ghana into a
lower-middle-income country literally overnight (Jerven, 2012). Such difficulties are
The myth of a food crisis 97
acknowledged (though ultimately dismissed) in FAO’s Food balance sheets: a hand-
book (FAO, 2001).
Problems of comparable magnitude also apply to modeling the relationships be-
tween data points. According to Reilly and Willenbockel: “more work on the vali-
dation of model components used in integrated assessment studies is required.” But
these authors equally caution that validation is a two-edged sword; calibrating models
to past experiences, especially in the presence of climate change and other poten-
tial abrupt changes, introduces the problem commonly known as “overfitting.” Some
of these “technical”-level difficulties are acknowledged by the modelers themselves
(e.g., Bruinsma, 2003).
A yet further significant problem is that, because they come from many different
nations, datasets in separate parts of the models are based on different scales, time peri-
ods, and conceptual schemes (FAO, 2 001). Methods to reconcile such disparities are not
available, however. Unsurprisingly perhaps, having discussed these limitations, Reilly
and Willenbockel conclude that “model outputs should not be misinterpreted as fore-
casts with well-defined confidence intervals. Rather they are meant to provide quantified
insights about the complex interactions in a highly interdependent system and the poten-
tial general order of size effects” (Reilly & Willenbockel, 2010). This comment raises
some important issues. The first is that this limitation seems to have generally eluded
those who cite these numbers. Second, without confidence intervals no one—including
the modelers themselves—knows what this “general size order of effects” is.
We can gain insight into how such uncertainties might affect the quality of predic-
tions by examining an extended critique made by Thomas Hertel in his presidential
address to the American Agricultural and Applied Economics Association (Hertel,
2011). A major assumption in FAO and other models, notes Hertel, concerns how they
relate prices, demand, and supply. Focusing on FAO’s quantitative model (pre-GAPS)
he notes that it assumed that agricultural supply hardly responds to higher prices. This
assumption was introduced because measurements of how food supply responds to
demand in agriculture have mostly been taken over the short term. The remit of these
models is the longer term, however. Measurements taken over the long term suggest
that the elasticity picture is very different. Hertel contends that if future growth in
demand was sufficiently great for food prices to rise, then this would in turn stimulate
supply. Thus higher agricultural prices can be expected to favor high yields, raise land
prices (protecting existing land and bringing more into production), stimulate agri-
cultural research, and reduce waste, and this is indeed what the longer-term evidence
shows (Hertel, 2011). Even the declining trend in the growth of global crop yields,
which according to FAO is a major determinant of future food availability, may be a
function of price. To this end, Hertel quotes economist Robert Herdt: “the economics
of substantially higher yields is not attractive” (International Rice Research Institute,
1979). In this connection, Hertel also quotes FAO economist Jelle Bruinsma: “given
the right incentives, much of the increased demand for cereals and oilseeds in 2050
could be met using existing technology.” Hertel therefore concludes that the frequently
noted long-term “slowing of yield growth may simply be due to a slowing of net de-
mand growth.And he summarizes: “it is not clear that the resulting models are well-
suited for the kind of long run sustainability analysis envisioned here.
98 Rethinking Food and Agriculture
To summarize Hertel: there is strong evidence that incentives acting on farmers and
other decision-makers are key to explaining agricultural productivity, but since com-
modity prices have been in long-term decline, FAO has been modeling a low-incentive
system.
With this as background the next section is devoted to analyzing four additional
assumptions underlying predictive models and using GAPS as the example.
5.2 The assumptions of GAPS
Key assumptions made by GAPS that strongly affect its predictions of future produc-
tion needs are as follows:
Assumption 1: That biofuels are driven by “demand”
Since 2002 the development of the liquid biofuel sector (ethanol and biodiesel) has
been very rapid. According to US Department of Agriculture figures, the US biofuel
industry consumed 127 million tons of maize in 2011, which was 15.6% of world
maize production. Additionally, in Brazil over 50% of sugarcane is used for biofuels
and in 2009 the EU consumed as biofuel 9 million tons of vegetable (mostly rapeseed)
oil as well as 9 million tons of cereals (Alexandratos & Bruinsma, 2012). Specifically
for ethanol, the 2016 figures for global production were, in millions of gallons, United
States (15,250), Brazil (7295), European Union (1377), China (845), and Canada
(436) (Mohanty & Swain, 2019).
The initial consequences of the biofuel boom were price spikes that propagated
through the global supply chain to affect most commodities (de Gorter, Drabik & Just,
2015; McMichael, 2009). These price spikes induced riots, hunger, and financial hard-
ships and, in some countries, political upheaval. The diversion of substantial quantities
of presumptive agricultural produce into biofuels is a perturbation that has, however,
ultimately been absorbed by the physical supply chain. Commodities have now all but
returned to their prespike prices (OECD-FAO, 2016).
In the models of the FAO, biofuels are deemed a demand. That is, they reduce
availability but they don’t contribute to feeding the population (except when certain
residues are fed to animals). Looking to the future, FAO further assumes that biofuels
will continue to expand in area, plateauing in 2020 (Alexandratos & Bruinsma, 2012,
p. 97).
The justification for treating biofuels as demand is that biodiesel and bioethanol
are environmentally beneficial products of deliberative policy choices. This position is
highly questionable. First, biofuels from palm oil or soybeans and ethanol from corn
cause immense biodiversity losses. Additionally, their net greenhouse gas emissions
provide no benefits or are only positive when measured over hundreds of years (e.g.,
Germer & Sauerborn, 2008; Danielsen etal., 2009). Second, the necessity justification
is dubious since the development of biofuel policies has been driven not by climate
concerns but by complex agglomerations of lobbying interests seeking to boost agri-
cultural demand so they can sell more inputs (Baines, 2015; ActionAid, 2013). The
significant point about markets driven by lobbying, rather than genuine demand, is
that if demand for food were, as expected, to increase (and/or food prices were to rise)
The myth of a food crisis 99
the interest in biofuels would vanish because their key political attraction is to prop
up demand (Baines, 2015). In other words, land devoted to biofuels is available, if
needed, for feeding populations but this opportunity is rendered invisible when models
such as GAPS categorize biofuels as a demand. The amounts of food converted into
biofuels are very substantial. For instance, ActionAid concluded that the G8 countries
(which exclude Brazil) consumed annually enough biofuel to feed 441 million people
(ActionAid, 2013). If measured today that figure would undoubtedly be much greater.
It is curious that FAO modelers do not address the ethics of biofuel diversion. First,
because, in a hungry world, the dilemma raised by diverting biofuels at the expense
of food availability is a rather obvious one (Chakrabortty, 2008), and second, because,
elsewhere in discussing their models, FAO economists do digress on the environmen-
tal and ethical implications of various actions, thus violating their supposed nonnor-
mative stance (e.g., Alexandratos & Bruinsma, 2012, p. 131). Third, given that the
premise of models like GAPS is that increasing production is an ethical imperative,
why is it not equally ethically problematic to subtract from food availability by burn-
ing it for transportation? FAO’s modelers have again been inconsistent in the applica-
tion of the nonnormative approach.
On one level, FAO’s failure to incorporate biofuels as potential food supplies for
hundreds of millions of people and instead integrate them into their model as “de-
mand” is an error. But it also represents a further instance of inconsistency: shuffling
in and out of normative modes. Is it a coincidence that FAO’s economists only take an
explicitly normative stance when it aligns with powerful interest groups? At the same
time, the shuffle is very much facilitated by GAPS having as its underlying paradigm
the normative expectation that production trumps all.
Assumption 2: That current agricultural production systems are optimized for
productivity
According to FAO statistics, if we truly wanted to maximize global yield as mea-
sured by calories/ha per day we would all eat sweet potatoes (70 × 10(3) kcal/ha/day).
Or, if we lived further from the equator, potatoes (54 × 10(3) kcal/ha/day) (FAO, http://
www.fao.org/docrep/t0207e/T0207E04.htm). Of course, there are reasons why we do
not eat only these crops. Those reasons range from the agronomic benefits of crop
rotations to the physical and cultural needs for a varied diet. However, farmers also
grow many crops (such as coffee and grapes for wine) that have very limited ability to
feed people. As a consequence, world agriculture has the potential to greatly enhance
productivity through crop substitution.
This potential exists rather obviously in developed countries such as the United
States and the European Union, where subsidies and market monopolies are far more
powerful drivers of production than are calories or nutrition. One might suppose, how-
ever, that countries like Bangladesh (whose population of 160 million resides in an
area the size of New York state) might be different. Bangladesh has one of the highest
population densities in the world and one of the highest poverty and food insecu-
rity rates. However, although wheat yields about half that of winter season rice in
Bangladeshi conditions, the market price of wheat is higher and the input costs are
much lower (J. Duxbury, pers. comm.). Bangladeshi farmers therefore grow wheat on
415,000 ha (FAOSTAT, 2017). Such farmers are chasing markets not nutrition.
100 Rethinking Food and Agriculture
But perhaps the most glaring instance of suboptimal nutritional performance in
agriculture is meat consumption. Historically, much meat and dairy production took
advantage of marginal land that was less suited or unsuited to other forms of crop-
ping. Increasingly, however, especially in many “developed” countries, prime land
is cropped for animal feed. Even the most efficient converters of this feed (fish and
chickens) yield a worse caloric return per hectare than the least nutritious vegetable,
while the least efficient (beef) yields approximately fourfold less again (Cassidy etal.,
2013). Thus it has been estimated that beef, in a feedlot system, has a feed conversion
efficiency, measured in calories, of 3% (compared to chicken with 12%) (Cassidy
etal., 2013). Clearly, this implies major opportunities for substitution since about 35%
of the US corn crop goes to animal feed (Baines, 2015).
In spite of these diverse opportunities, substitutions of higher-yielding crops for
lower-yielding ones is a possibility neglected by GAPS. In contrast, GAPS does allow
substitution in the opposite direction. This is when GAPS allows higher meat con-
sumption following income rises. GAPS is thus again inconsistent.
The standard justification for allowing this substitution is “consumer demand.”
As populations become wealthier they “naturally” eat more meat, goes the theory.
Predominantly vegetarian countries excepted, there is certainly a correlation between
wealth and meat consumption. The caveat required is that OECD countries spend
$318 billion annually on agricultural subsidies. These overwhelmingly go to support-
ing either meat or biofuels (OECD, 2002). Virtually none of it goes to subsidizing
fruits and vegetables. Consequently, “the power and freedom of choice attributed to
consumers are questionable” and so also is any straightforward expectation that other
nations will closely follow this path, unless they too decide to subsidize meat produc-
tion (Rivera-Ferre, 2009).
How much extra food could result from crop substitutions overlooked by GAPS?
Any calculation is a difficult one since much depends on what crop is substituted and
what replaces it. The case studied most intensively is the impact of meat consump-
tion. A recent estimate is that 4 billion additional people could be fed if animals were
absent from the global feed chain (Cassidy etal., 2013). This study did not substitute
animal rearing with the most calorific crop, however. It is worth noting that this con-
clusion largely assumed Western-style rearing and consumption patterns. Thus it is
not applicable to those parts of the world where nomadic and seminomadic systems
predominate.
Another type of substitution is the growing use of mixed cropping, agroecological
production systems, and conservation agriculture. These can further increase yields
beyond the monocultures assumed in GAPS, sometimes dramatically (Sampson,
2018; Kassam etal., 2009). In 2015/16, conservation agriculture occupied approxi-
mately 180 million hectares of cropland globally, and since 2008/09 has expanded by
over 10 million hectares a year (Kassam etal., 2018).
In conclusion, models in general (and not only GAPS) are disregarding clear oppor-
tunities for crop substitutions that have the potential to feed many billions of people.
Assumption 3: The existence of maximum “yield potentials”
An important assumption found in GAPS and other models is the use of the con-
cept of “yield potential.Yield potential describes the theory that crops have a genetic
The myth of a food crisis 101
yield ceiling beyond which cropping systems (usually envisaged as inputs of fertilizer
or chemicals) cannot lift them. Because of this ceiling, GAPS presumes that produc-
tivity increases can only come in either of two ways. Either slowly through long-term
research and breeding efforts that raise the yield potential of each crop, or, alterna-
tively, by persuading those farmers who use “suboptimal” seeds or methods and there-
fore operate far below this ceiling to approach the current yield potential. Thus yield
potentials figure prominently in GAPS. FAO states this assumption in many places,
e.g.: “There is a realization that the chances of a new Green Revolution or of one-off
quantum jumps in yields, are now rather limited” (Alexandratos & Bruinsma, 2012,
p. 125).
Yet these yield potentials are theoretical only. They are not proven to exist and
may not exist. Perhaps the leading exemplar of this is rice, the world’s most important
crop. The yield potential of rice is standardly estimated at 8–10 t per hectare (Peng
etal., 1999). Such high yields are assumed to occur only under agronomic conditions
of very high fertilizer and chemical inputs and with ideal soil and watering regimes.
Yet the world record for rice production is 22.4 t (Diwakar etal., 2012). This record
was achieved with few inputs by a farmer using a method called the System of Rice
Intensification (SRI). What this record implies, and peer-reviewed SRI research sup-
ports this, is that rice is far below its supposed yield potential when grown under stan-
dard “optimal” conditions (or that yield potential has no real-world meaning) (Kassam
etal., 2011; Taylor & Bhasme, 2019).
The implication of the yields achieved by SRI is that sustainable yields and pro-
ductivity exceed those assumed by all quantitative global models by several multiples.
Since theoretical yield potentials are ordinarily rarely met on real farms, 22.4 t rep-
resents in practice a potential tripling of yields over standard expectations. SRI meth-
ods have also been applied to other crops, again giving significant yield improvements
(Abraham etal., 2014). In 2013, SRI was estimated to have 9.5 million practitioners
(Uphoff, 2017). By 2019 this number had at least doubled (N. Uphoff, pers. comm.).
By accepting the concept of yield potential and ignoring SRI, quantitative models are
overlooking one of the most rapidly spreading developments in agriculture (Stoop
etal., 2017).
Since rice is the staple of half the globe (3.5 billion people) it can be readily ap-
preciated that a tripling of yields, especially since SRI is a more sustainable method,
represents the potential to feed perhaps a further 7 billion people (Fageria, 2007).
Assumption 4: That global food production is approximately equal to global food
consumption.
Unlike in most sectors of the economy, agricultural production can exceed con-
sumption at the global or local scale. If we take cereals (wheat, rice, barley, millet,
sorghum, and oats) as an example, excess production occurs even in densely populated
countries such as India and China. In 2017, FAO estimated global stores of cereals
at 762 million tons; this is out of a total global cereal production (in 2017) of 2595
million tons (FAOSTAT).
These stocks represent an insurance against calamity. However, this 762 million
tons also represents an excess of supply over global demand. An important property
of these stocks is their perishability. Depending on the climate, the quality of storage,
102 Rethinking Food and Agriculture
and the crop species, they may rot or be eaten by rodents or insects; thus even if stocks
are not growing, crops may still be entering them at a high rate. The second relevant
property of stocks is that, if there are multiple harvests per annum, quantities of lost
stocks may represent multiples of the steady-state amount of an annualized store. For
example, if 33% of each rice crop is lost in storage and there are three rice storage pe-
riods, corresponding to three harvests, then 100% of the annual total stock is, in effect,
lost each year. The consequence of these properties is that it is very important to count
quantities entering stocks since, if needed, they are available for use. Even if stored
well, stocks eventually degrade. In China, wheat stocks are considered by analysts to
last maximally 3–4years and an average of 2years. For this reason, China, which is
one of the biggest stock holders of rice and wheat, began a biofuel policy to consume
excess stocks of wheat. This has steadily grown and now generates 845 million gallons
of ethanol per year (Mohanty & Swain, 2019). Despite this program, Chinese wheat
stocks are still growing.
What this ultimately means is that it is important to understand how much is en-
tering stocks each year. Unfortunately, for modeling purposes, FAO assumes that “At
the world level production equals consumption” (Alexandratos & Bruinsma, 2012;
see also FAO, 2001). This assumption is restated in the 2016 GAPS description: “The
model assumes a closed world economy so that at the end of every simulation period
global demand equals supply” (Kavalleri etal., 2016). Amounts entering stocks are
counted, but only as the difference between opening stocks and closing stocks (FAO,
2001). The net effect is to ignore losses to insects, mold, rodents, and age.
The simple way to show how this method ignores lost and degraded stocks is to
work through an example. If 762 million tons was the amount in stock on January
1 and all of it was lost to rats and insects in the subsequent year and then the entire
amount was replaced in the following year, FAO’s counting method would register no
change to stocks and no addition to stocks. That is, it would appear that nothing had
entered stocks even though 762 million tons had in reality done so.
How much of the global grain supply is lost in storage? Estimating postharvest
losses is difficult and seems to be a low priority. Furthermore, many estimates are not
necessarily applicable to stocks but rather to postharvest in general. FAO estimates
that postharvest losses in low–middle-income countries are approximately 6.4% for
cereals. Most cereal and pulse loss estimates are much higher, but also highly vari-
able and they acknowledge much uncertainty (Boxall, 2001; Kumar & Kalita, 2017;
Sharon etal., 2014). Estimates include 20%–30% for maize in Africa (Tefera etal.,
2011); 12% and 44% for maize in the West Cameroonian highlands during the first
6months of storage (Tapondjou etal., 2002); 11%–17% for rice in India, without
counting storage (Alavi etal., 2012); and 35% for rice in India (Scrimshaw, 1978).
Some reports estimate very high levels, for example, 59% after 90days in sub-Saharan
Africa (Kumar & Kalita, 2017). Thus FAO’s figures for postharvest losses are very
much at the low end, especially since storage is often considered the stage of greatest
deterioration (Kumar & Kalita, 2017).
One could say that GAPS makes two errors that cancel each other out to balance
the model. It ignores what enters stocks (unless they change) and it ignores losses
within them. This is fine from the point of view of building a closed model but the
The myth of a food crisis 103
significance of the errors for the purpose of estimating food availability is potentially
very great: there is an uncounted annual excess of production, which is lost in storage,
but is available to meet future demand. To state this in Malthusian terms, population is
below current production and population (at least demand) can afford to grow before
the two become equal. This is not to say that stocks and reserves are undesirable or
unnecessary, but it is to say that a very significant unacknowledged gap likely exists.
Current estimates of both stocks and stock losses are highly uncertain. However, if
we accept its numbers at face value then FAO is undercounting food equivalent to the
cereal needs of perhaps 1–2 billion people, even without counting the losses of more
perishable (noncereal) crops.
In summary, the four assumptions discussed here generate the following esti-
mate of extra food potentially available (over and above the estimates of FAO’s
GAPS). Assumption 1: 500 million; Assumption 2: 4 billion; Assumption 3: 7 bil-
lion; Assumption 4: 1–2 billion. The sum total (12.5 billion) is certainly a low-end
figure because Assumption 1 underreports current biofuels because its data are old;
Assumption 2 only includes the substitutions of meat by crops and not higher calorie
crops by lower calories ones (because no studies exist); and Assumption 3 only in-
cludes rice, whereas SRI suggests other yield ceilings may also be similarly flawed.
Nevertheless, 12.5 billion people’s worth of spare food is a very large underestimate.
5.3 What are models for?
The foregoing discussion has highlighted that quantitative models such as FAO’s
GAPS are highly reliant on questionable assumptions. Summarized briefly, first,
GAPS does not adequately take into account the potential to substitute higher-
yielding food species for lower-yielding ones. Second, GAPS neglects that food can
and would be grown instead of biofuels if needed. Third, GAPS contains unreason-
ably low expectations of achievable yields of existing crops, in particular rice, which
is the staple of half the global population. Fourth, GAPS neglects annual surpluses
lost in storage.
To this critique of GAPS and related food models should be added that of Thomas
Hertel, who has asserted that FAO has underestimated the potential for food availabil-
ity to rise with prices (Hertel, 2011).
Thus the discrepancy that prompted this chapter to be written, which was between
long-term (decreasing) global prices that demonstrate increasing overproduction and
quantitative models that predict looming scarcity, can readily be resolved. The mod-
els are flawed. They underestimate actual or potential supply and they exaggerate
demand.
Quantitative models in science, in technology, and in economics have never been
more popular (Porter, 1995). To explain this ascent, two distinct schools of thought
have arisen. The standard explanation is that quantitative models are objective ap-
proximations to reality that have become more prevalent because, with computers and
other developments, they have become progressively more powerful and more useful
tools.
104 Rethinking Food and Agriculture
The second, rival, explanation is that the rise of such models is attributable to their
usefulness as pretenses to objectivity. As British scientist Lancelot Hogben wrote in
1933, they allow the possibility of “concealing assumptions which have no factual
basis behind an impressive façade of flawless algebra.(Another formulation is at-
tributed to ecological modeler Dick Levins: “All quantitative models are qualitative
models in disguise.”) In this way, models can function as smokescreens (disguises)
for either conscious or unconscious institutional biases and objectives. In the words
of Theodore Porter: “Quantification is a way of making decisions without seeming to
decide” (Porter, 1995).
The standard explanation of the rise of modeling is surely flawed, at least in part.
All modeling is a retreat from reality in which complexity is reduced to uniformity
and qualities to quantities. In whittling data and simplifying interactions, choices
must be made. Perhaps nowhere in all of quantitative modeling is simplification
more problematic than in a representation of the food system whose component
parts are biological, climatic, hydrological, economic, and social in character; that
is, they are incommensurable. Thus modelers are inevitably faced with difficult
choices over which of the myriad potential contributory factors to include and
which to exclude. In the same way, they have to devise how to mathematically
simplify the likely nature of the relations between them. These choices represent
challenges to objectivity.
A good example of this objectivity problem as it applies to food models is the
time frame of FAO’s annual accounting. Its agricultural year runs from the beginning
of January to the end of December (FAO, 2001). It is thus calibrated to the needs of
Europe and North America and not those of the Southern Hemisphere or the tropics.
This choice exemplifies how the values of the West, but also of international trade,
and of finance are subtly present in all such models at the expense of the much less
prominent or quantifiable priorities of the poorer countries (predominantly Southern
and tropical) whose interests these models claim to serve.
The assertion of an objective modeler is therefore untenable. This does not mean
that all models are necessarily valueless. But it does suggest we ask a more subtle ques-
tion about the good faith and disinterestedness of its authors and funders: What steps
do the builders of such models take to minimize the potential for unconscious bias?
From this perspective it is not reassuring that FAO claims to rely “as much as pos-
sible” on in-house experts (Alexandratos & Bruinsma, 2012). Nor that FAO presents
its data with an implied high degree of confidence, especially in prominent fora (e.g.,
Diouf, 2008, cited in Tomlinson, 2011). Meanwhile, the references in FAO documents
to assumptions, limitations, and uncertainties are sparse and relegated to middle pages
or back pages or annexes. Sometimes these are therein even discounted without expla-
nation (Reilly & Willenbockel, 2010; Wise, 2013).
Third, the frequent shifts into the normative language (of “should”) and back again
by FAO in its successive reports is again suggestive that institutional preferences exist
but are not well managed. Perhaps the most instructive formulation of the disinterest-
edness question is to ask (if only rhetorically): If its models gave answers that were di-
ametrically inverse to the ones presented (i.e., that food provision was ample), would
FAO stand by them?
The myth of a food crisis 105
5.3.1 Conflicts of interest amid the food crisis
This question leads to the consideration of what is most noticeable about the four
questionable assumptions identified in this chapter, that they are not neutral in their
effects. Each has the consequence either of exaggerating demand or of underestimat-
ing supply, either in the present or in the future. Thus they all serve to exaggerate a
Malthusian scenario. The same is true for the assumption noted by Hertel, that FAO
fails to appropriately take into account the effects of price on production (Hertel,
2011). It too underestimates future food supply. Together the effect amounts to the
food requirements of, minimally, many billions of people.
A potential explanation for the Malthusian exaggeration is that FAO, like almost
every large institution in the food/academic/philanthropic nexus, has a conflict of in-
terest. If there were no threat of a food crisis of some kind, FAO’s institutional raison
d’etre (motto: Fiat Panis) would vanish. Additionally, given these conflicts, some food
crisis variants are clearly preferable, from FAO’s perspective, over others. If institu-
tions like FAO, IFPRI, or the World Bank were to frame the problems of agriculture
as resulting primarily from maldistribution of land, democratic deficits, poverty, or
the excessive power of agribusiness, they would come into conflict with agribusiness,
governments, and wealthy landowners, the very people who, directly or indirectly,
fund or control these institutions. Far safer, politically, to blame hunger on lack of
production; that is, the farmers (Food First, 2016; Sampson, 2018).
In this context it is useful to recall the seemingly neglected predictions of FAO’s
own models that increasing food production would have little effect on the number of
people going hungry (Alexandratos & Bruinsma, 2012; Bruinsma, 2003). This pre-
diction came true. In 2018, even though food production did subsequently increase,
and food prices fell, the number of malnourished rose to 821 million. If FAO wants to
solve hunger, their own model is telling them to look elsewhere than increasing pro-
duction. This is a highly damaging finding to models, like GAPS, with a productivist
premise. Yet, 17years on from 2003 FAO still targets productivity, as does almost
every major food security institution and philanthropic effort (Food First, 2016).
5.3.2 Final thoughts
One interest group in particular benefits from the premising of models such as GAPS
on the question of productivity. “Feeding the world” is the principal public relations
gambit of international agribusiness. Only agribusiness has the yields to save the poor
and starving, is their claim (Peekhaus, 2010; Stone & Glover, 2011). If the scarcity
narrative is true, that claim is powerful. It transforms agriculture into a moral issue
(Dibden etal., 2013; Latham, 2015). Pesticides, genetically modified organisms
(GMOs), and monocultures may have negative consequences, goes the narrative, but
they are the necessary alternative to starvation. The sole alternative, accordingly, is
merely a luxury for the privileged and of no interest to policymakers. Alternatively, if
scarcity is a myth, then all pesticides are sprayed, and all GMOs exist, exclusively for
profit. The destruction of the ecosphere, which is largely for the sake of agriculture, is
effectively a waste (IAASTD, 2009; IPBES, 2019). The stakes are high.
106 Rethinking Food and Agriculture
Agribusiness stands or falls on this point. The reason, as George Lakoff has argued,
is that humans think and act in moral terms. They wish to think of themselves as
“good” (Lakoff, 2004). Thus the focus of quantitative models on productivity, which
asserts a moral essence, is a gift to agribusiness since, to be effective, a credible third
party has to legitimize the scarcity narrative.
So, while very significant effort and attention have been directed toward creat-
ing GAPS and other models devoted to estimating and predicting global agricultural
demand and production, there remains effectively no clear evidence that lack of pro-
ductivity plays a pivotal role in the hunger epidemic that supposedly stimulates them
(Lappé & Collins, 2015; Sen, 1981). In contrast, there is abundant, even overwhelm-
ing, evidence that agriculture, and in particular industrial monocultures, needs to be
realigned to become kinder to ecosystems and more beneficial for the individuals and
the communities that feed us (HLPE, 2013; IAASTD, 2009). This will not occur, how-
ever, until the scarcity narrative is set aside.
The necessity of following an alternative path is acknowledged in places by FAO
modelers. The foreword to FAO’s latest major modeling report, The future of food and
agriculture: Alternative pathways to 2050, says: “Swift and purposeful actions are
needed to ensure the sustainability of food and agriculture systems in the long run”
(FAO, 2018). Yet even that report still perpetuates the scarcity narrative. It privileges
a quantitative productivist focus as the ultimate arbiter of the alternative pathways it
explores, thereby undermining all such possibilities. What is needed instead, from the
FAO as well as others, is a focus on the broad consequences of agriculture and food
systems, that is, their multifunctionality.
Multifunctionality is the idea that agriculture is deeply embedded in other systems,
and therefore how it is conducted has consequences well beyond the single metric
of crop production by volume (IAASTD, 2009; Kremen & Merenlender, 2018). For
instance, industrial agriculture is the single largest contributor to climate change and
other forms of atmospheric pollution (Bauer etal., 2016; Goodland & Anhang, 2009;
Steinfeld etal., 2006). Agriculture also provides livelihoods; it cleans or pollutes wa-
ter (aquifers, surface waters, and oceans); it conserves or degrades biodiversity; it
provides landscape value and culturally appropriate food; and so forth (IUCN Task
Force on Systemic Pesticides, 2017). These contributions of agriculture, all effectively
ignored by quantitative models of calorific production, should receive at least as much
consideration as does productivity from decision-makers, if only because, unlike pro-
ductivity, these functions are often more at risk.
Having discussed some of the limitations of modeling agricultural productivity, which
is a comparatively simple output, it can reasonably be questioned whether modeling of
agriculture on a global level can ever perform a constructive role. Perhaps ultimately a
more useful role for modeling is at more local scales, and modeling that asks questions
of a more defined nature. Work on nitrogen modeling of the Paris basin constitutes an
example of how modeling can have more modest aims yet be useful to policymakers and
others (Billen etal., 2012). Perhaps FAO should now move its focus to assessing the rel-
ative effects of pesticides and other inputs on biodiversity or human health from different
agricultural systems? This is a domain that the current regulation of pesticides is failing
to address (Va nd e n b e r g e t a l . , 2 0 1 2). Such an analysis would beneficially serve to put ag-
riculture on notice that its long-ignored externalities will in future move to center stage.
The myth of a food crisis 107
Acknowledgments
The author is extremely grateful to Timothy Wise, Philip McMichael, Allison Wilson, and three
anonymous reviewers for reading and constructively commenting on drafts of this chapter.
References
Abraham, B., Araya, H., Berthe, T., Edwards, S., Gujja, B., Khadka, R. B., Verma, A. (2014).
The system of crop intensification: Reports from the field on improving agricultural pro-
duction, food security, and resilience to climate change for multiple crops. Agriculture and
Food Security, 3, 4.
ActionAid. (2013). Rising to the challenge: Changing course to feed the world in 2050. https://
www.actionaidusa.org/publications/feed-world-2050/.
Agrimonde. (2009). Scenarios and challenges to feeding the world in 2050. In Summary report.
France: CIRAD-NAR.
Alavi, H. R., Htenas, A., Kopicki, R., Shepherd, A. W., & Clarete, R. (2012). Trusting trade and
the private sector for food security in Southeast Asia. Washington, DC, USA: World Bank
Publications.
Alexandratos, N., & Bruinsma, J. (2012). World agriculture: Towards 2030/2050. ESA working
paper no. 12-03 Rome: FAO.
Baines, J. (2015). Fuel, feed and the corporate restructuring of the food regime. The Journal of
Peasant Studies, 42(2), 295–321.
Battisti, D. S., & Naylor, R. L. (2009). Historical warnings of future food insecurity with un-
precedented seasonal heat. Science, 323, 240–244.
Bauer, S. E., Tsigaridis, K., & Miller, R. (2016). Significant atmospheric aerosol pollution
caused by world food cultivation. Geophysical Research Letters, 43, 5394–5400.
Beddington, J. (2009). As reported in the guardian. In World faces ‘perfect storm’ of prob-
lems by 2030, chief scientist to warn. Wednesday 18 March 2009. Available at http://www.
guardian.co.uk/science/2009/mar/18/perfect-storm-johnbeddington-energy-food-climate.
(Accessed 6 2 2019).
Billen, G., Garnier, J., Silvestre, M., Thieu, V., Barles, S., & Chatzimpiros, P. (2012). Localising
the nitrogen imprint of Paris food supply: The potential of organic farming and changes in
human diet. Biogeosciences, 9, 607–616.
Boxall, R. A. (2001). Post-harvest losses to insects—A world overview. International Biodeterioration
& Biodegradation, 48, 137–152. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0964-8305(01)00076-2.
Bruinsma, J. (2003). World agriculture: Towards 2015/30 an FAO perspective. London:
Earthscan.
Burchi, F., Fanzo, J., & Frison, E. (2011). The role of food and nutrition system approaches
in tackling hidden hunger. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public
Health, 8(2), 358–373. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph8020358.
Cassidy, E. S., West, P. C., Gerber, J. S., & Foley, J. A. (2013). Redefining agricultural yields:
From tonnes to people nourished per hectare. Environmental Research Letters, 8, 034015.
Chakrabortty, A. (2008). Secret report: Biofuel caused food crisis. https://www.theguardian.
com/environment/2008/jul/03/biofuels.renewableenergy. (Accessed 6 February 2019).
Chaumet, J., etal. (2009). Agrimonde: Scenarios and challenges for feeding the world in 2050.
Paris: CIRAD-INRA.
Conway, G. (2012). One billion hungry: Can we feed the world?. New York: Cornell University
Press.
108 Rethinking Food and Agriculture
Danielsen, F., etal. (2009). Biofuel plantations on forested lands: Double jeopardy for biodiver-
sity and climate. Conservation, 23, 348–358.
de Fraiture, C., etal. (2007). Looking ahead to 2050: Scenarios of alternative investment ap-
proaches. In D. Molden (Ed.), Water for food, water for life: A comprehensive assessment
of water management in agriculture (pp. 91–145). London, UK: Earthscan.
de Gorter, H., Drabik, D., & Just, D. R. (2015). The economics of biofuel policies: Impacts on
price volatility in grain and oilseed markets. (Palgrave studies in agricultural economics
and food policy). Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan.
Dibden, J., Gibbs, D., & Cocklin, C. (2013). Framing GM crops as a food security solution.
Journal of Rural Studies, 29, 59–70.
Diwakar, M. C., Kumar, A., Verma, A., & Uphoff, N. (2012). Report on the world record SRI
yields in Kharif season 2011 in Nalanda District, Bihar State, India. In Agriculture today.
June 54–56.
Ehrlich, P. (1968). The population bomb. Sierra Club/Ballantine Books.
Fageria, N. K. (2007). Yield physiology of rice. Journal of Plant Nutrition, 30, 843–879.
FAO. (2001). Food balance sheets: A handbook. Rome: FAO. http://www.fao.org/worldfoodsit-
uation/foodpricesindex/en/. (Accessed 7 March 2019).
FAO. (2006). World agriculture: Towards 2030/2050. In Interim report. Rome: FAO.
FAO. (2018). The future of food and agriculture: Alternative pathways to 2050. Rome: FAO.
FAOSTAT. (2017). http://www.fao.org/faostat/en/#home.
Fischer, G., Frohberg, K., Keyzer, M. A., & Parikh, K. S. (1988). Linked national models: A tool
for international food policy analysis. Dordrecht: Kluwer.
Food First. (2016). The true extent of hunger: What FAO isn’t telling you. https://foodfirst.org/
wp-content/uploads/2016/06/Summer2016Backgrounder.pdf. (Accessed 10 May 2019).
Funtowicz, S. O., & Ravetz, J. R. (1990). Uncertainty and quality in science for policy.
Dordrecht: Kluwer.
Germer, J., & Sauerborn, J. (2008). Estimation of the impact of oil palm plantation establish-
ment on greenhouse gas balance. Environment, Development and Sustainability, 10(6),
697–716.
Goodland, R., & Anhang, J. (2009). Livestock and climate change. Washington, DC: World
Watch.
Herforth, A. (2015). Access to adequate nutritious food: New indicators to track progress and
inform action. In D. E. Sahn (Ed.), The fight against hunger and malnutrition: The role of
food, agriculture and targeted policies (pp. 139–162). Oxford University Press. https://doi.
org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198733201.003.0007.
Hertel, T. W. (2011). The global supply and demand for agricultural land in 2050: A perfect
storm in the making? American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 93, 259–275.
Herren, H., Chihyoka, A., Scaramella, C., Mpandeli, S., Sirengo, A., & Mwendandu, R. (2011).
WBI global dialogue on adaptation and food security. World Bank Institute.
Hincks, J. (2018). The world is headed for a food security crisis. Here’s how we can avert
it. http://time.com/5216532/global-food-security-richard-deverell/. (Accessed 9 February
2019).
HLPE. (2013). Investing in smallholder agriculture for food security. In A report by the High
Level Panel of Experts on Food Security and Nutrition of the Committee on World Food
Security, Rome.
IAASTD. (2009). Agriculture at a crossroads. Nairobi: United Nations Environment Programme
(UNEP).
IUCN Task Force on Systemic Pesticides. (2017). Worldwide integrated assessment of the ef-
fects of systemic pesticides on biodiversity and ecosystems. IUCN.
The myth of a food crisis 109
IPBES. (2019). The IPBES global assessment report on biodiversity and ecosystem services,
summary. http://bit.ly/IPBESReport. Accessed on 10.5.2019.
International Rice Research Institute. (1979). Farm-level constraints to high rice yields in Asia:
1974–1977. Los Baños, Laguna, Philippines: International Rice Research Institute.
Jerven, M. (2012). Poor numbers. Ithaca, USA: Cornell University Press.
Kavalleri, A., Conforti, P., & van der Mensbrugghe. (2016). The global perspectives system
(GAPS) version 1.0. Rome: FAO.
Kassam, A., Freidrich, T., Shaxson, F., & Pretty, J. (2009). The spread of conservation ag-
riculture: Justification, sustainability and uptake. International Journal of Agricultural
Sustainability, 7(4), 292–320.
Kassam, A., Stoop, W., & Uphoff, N. (2011). Review of SRI modifications in rice crop and
water management and research issues for making further improvements in agricultural
and water productivity. Paddy and Water Environment, 9, 163. https://doi.org/10.1007/
s10333-011-0259-1.
Kassam, A., Friedrich, T., & Derpsch, R. (2018). Global spread of conservation agriculture.
International Journal of Environmental Studies. https://doi.org/10.1080/00207233.2018.1
494927. Published online at.
Kremen, C., & Merenlender, A. M. (2018). Landscapes that work for biodiversity and people.
Science, 362. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.aau6020. eaau6020.
Kumar, D., & Kalita, P. (2017). Reducing postharvest losses during storage of grain crops
to strengthen food security in developing countries. Food, 6, 8. https://doi.org/10.3390/
foods6010008.
Latham, J. R. (2015). How the great food war will be won. Independent science news. https://
www.independentsciencenews.org/environment/how-the-great-food-war-will-be-won/.
(Accessed 8 February 2019).
Lakoff, G. (2004). Don’t think of an elephant: Know your values and frame the debate. Chelsea
Green Publishing. ISBN 978-1-931498-71-5.
Lappé, F. M., & Collins, J. (2015). World hunger: Ten myths. Grove Press.
Malthus, T. R. (1798). An essay on the principle of population. London: J. Johnson.
McCalla, A. F., & Revoredo, C. L. (2001). Prospects for global food security: A critical ap-
praisal of past projections and predictions. In Food, agriculture, and the environment dis-
cussion paper 35. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.
McMichael, P. (2009). A food regime analysis of the ‘world food crisis’. Agriculture and Human
Values, 26, 281–295. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10460-009-9218-5.
Mohanty, S. K., & Swain, M. R. (2019). Bioethanol production from corn and wheat: Food,
fuel, and future. In R. C. Ray, & S. Ramachandran (Eds.), Bioethanol production from food
crops sustainable sources, interventions, and challenges (pp. 45–59). Academic Press.
Nelson, G. C., Rosegrant, M. W., Palazzo, A., Gray, I., Ingersoll, C., Robertson, R., … You,
L. (2010). Food security, farming, and climate change to 2050: Scenarios, results, policy
options. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.
OECD. (2002). Agricultural policies in OECD countries: A positive reform agenda. Paris:
OECD.
OECD-FAO. (2016). Agricultural outlook 2016-2025. Rome: FAO.
Parry, M. L., Rosenzweig, C., Iglesias, A., Livermore, M., & Fischer, G. (2004). Effects
of climate change on global food production under SRES emissions and socioeco-
nomic scenarios. Global Environmental Change, 14, 53–67. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
gloenvcha.2003.10.008.
Peekhaus, W. (2010). Monsanto discovers new social media. International Journal of
Communication, 4, 955–976.
110 Rethinking Food and Agriculture
Peng, S., Cassman, K. G., Virmani, S. S., Sheehy, J., & Khush, G. S. (1999). Yield potential
trends of tropical rice since the release of IR8 and the challenge of increasing rice yield
potential. Crop Science, 39, 1552–1559. https://doi.org/10.2135/cropsci1999.3961552x.
Porter, T. M. (1995). Trust in numbers the pursuit of objectivity in science and public life.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Reilly, M., & Willenbockel, D. (2010). Managing uncertainty: A review of food system scenario
analysis and modelling. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society, 365, 3049–3063.
Rivera-Ferre, M. G. (2009). Supply vs. demand of agri-industrial meat and fish products: A
chicken and egg paradigm? Journal of Sociology of Agriculture, 16, 90–105.
Robinson, S., etal. (2015). IFPRI discussion paper 01483. In The international model for policy
analysis of agricultural commodities and trade (IMPACT). Washington, DC, USA: IFPRI.
Rosegrant, M. W., Agcaoili-Sombilla, M., & Perez, N. D. (1995). Global food projections to
2020: Implications for investment. Washington, DC, USA: The International Food Policy
Research Institute.
Rosegrant, M. W., Paisner, M. S., Meijer, S., & Witcover, J. (2001). Global food projections to
2020: Emerging trends and alternative futures. Washington, DC, USA: The International
Food Policy Research Institute.
Sampson, D. (2018). Productivism, agroecology, and the challenge of feeding the world.
Gastronomica: The Journal of Critical Food Studies, 18, 41–53.
Scrimshaw, N. S. (1978). Global use of the instruments of scholarship for the conquest of hun-
ger—The World Hunger Program of the United Nations University. In J. C. Somogyi (Ed.),
Vol. 28. Solution of nutritional problems: The contribution of producers, distributors and
nutritionists symposium organized by the Institute for Nutrition Research of the Green
Meadow Foundation, Zürich (pp. 155–166). Rüschlikon-Zürich, Basel: Karger. 1979.
Scrieciu, S. (2007). Commentary: The inherent dangers of using computable general equilib-
rium models as a single integrated modelling framework for sustainability impact assess-
ment. A critical note on Böhringer and Löschel 2006. Ecological Economics, 60, 678–684.
Sen, A. (1981). Poverty and famines. Oxford: Clarendon.
Sharon, M. E. M., Abirami, C. V. K., & Alagusundaram, K. (2014). Grain storage management
in India. Journal of Postharvest Technology, 02, 12–24.
Steinfeld, H., etal. (2006). Livestock’s long shadow: Environmental issues and options. Rome:
United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization.
Stone, G. D., & Glover, D. (2011). Genetically modified crops and the ‘food crisis’: Discourse
and material impacts. Development in Practice, 21, 509–516.
Stoop, W. A., Sabarmatee, Sivasubramanian, P., Ravindra, A., Sen, D., Prasad, S. C., & Thakur,
A. K. (2017). Opportunities for ecological intensification: Lessons and insights from the
system of rice/crop intensification—Their implications for agricultural research and devel-
opment approaches. CAB Reviews, 12(036), 1–19.
Tapondjou, L. A., Adler, C., Bouda, H., & Fontem, D. A. (2002). Efficacy of powder and essen-
tial oil from Chenopodium ambrosioides leaves as post-harvest grain protectants against
six-stored product beetles. Journal of Stored Products Research, 38, 395–402.
Taylor, M., & Bhasme, S. (2019). The political ecology of rice intensification in south India:
Putting SRI in its places. Journal of Agrarian Change, 19, 3–20.
Tefera, T., Kanampiu, F., De Groote, H., Hellin, J., Mugo, S., Kimenju, S., Banziger, M.
(2011). The metal silo: An effective grain storage technology for reducing post-harvest
insect and pathogen losses in maize while improving smallholder farmers’ food security in
developing countries. Crop Protection, 30, 240–245.
The myth of a food crisis 111
Tomlinson, I. (2011). Doubling food production to feed the 9 billion: A critical perspective on a
key discourse of food security in the UK. Journal of Rural Studies, 29, 81–90. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.jrurstud.2011.09.001.
UN. (2017). World population prospects: The 2017 revision. https://www.un.org/develop-
ment/desa/publications/world-population-prospects-the-2017-revision.html. (Accessed 2
February 2019).
Uphoff, N. (2017). Developments in the system of rice intensification (SRI). In T. Sasaki
(Ed.), Vol. 2. Achieving sustainable rice cultivation (pp. 183–211). Cambridge, UK:
Burleigh-Dodds.
Vandenberg, L. N., Colborn, T., Hayes, T. B., Heindel, J. J., Jacobs, D. R., Jr., Lee, D.-H.,
… Myers, J. P. (2012). Hormones and endocrine-disrupting chemicals: Low-dose ef-
fects and nonmonotonic dose responses. Endocrine Reviews, 33(3), 378–455. https://doi.
org/10.1210/er.2011-1050.
Wise, T. (2013). Can we feed the world in 2050? A scoping paper to assess the evidence. In
Global development and environment institute working paper no. 13-04. https://sites.tufts.
edu/gdae/files/2019/10/13-04Wise_CanWeFeedWorld2050.pdf.
Further reading
Bruinsma, J. (2009). How to feed the world in 2050. In Paper prepared for the high level expert
forum. Rome 12e19 October 2009. Available at http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/templates/
wsfs/docs/expert_paper/How_to_Feed_the_World_in_ 2050.pdf. (Accessed 7 March
2019).
Perfecto, I., & Vandermeer, J. (2010). The agroecological matrix as alternative to the land-
sparing/agriculture intensification model. Proceedings of the National Academy of
Sciences, 107, 5786–5791.
... Advocates for the status quo argue that crops should be grown where the highest yields can be achieved and that transport costs and emissions are only a small part of the total cost, thus hardly playing a role [29,30]. Low yields are not a viable solution, according to this argument, because population growth, income growth and changing diets are predicted to increase the demand for agricultural products by about 60% by 2050 (from the base year of 2005) [31,32]. The increase in animal welfare in Germany and, thus, the reduction in the number of animals kept for meat production demanded by more sustainably minded people are in contrast to the argument that meat should not become a luxury good that only wealthy people can afford [33][34][35]. ...
... These include, for example, FAO models such as the partial equilibrium and computable general equilibrium for forecasts, Food Security Models for assessing food security and Food Balance Sheets, which provide information on imports, exports and production at the national level [41][42][43]. However, these models have faced criticism for being inaccurate, incomplete and neglecting the ecological and social aspects of agriculture [32,[44][45][46][47][48]. To address this criticism and take regional specifics into consideration, our calculations are based on regional data from the state of Hesse. ...
... With our metrics at hand, people who change their dietary habits can determine their own decrease in land consumption, awarding themselves that "smiley face". Studying smaller areas, but in detail, is essential [32]. ...
Article
Full-text available
Nowadays dietary habits in many countries are disconnected from the locally available resources and land. Current diets harm ecosystems and people’s health. (Re-)regionalising food systems and aligning diets with planetary boundaries can be one way to reconnect people to the food that they eat. Within academic discourse, there are numerous debates about the benefits and drawbacks of regional agriculture, and the circumstances that determine the viability of regional agriculture as a preferable approach. An argument that often merges is that feeding a whole population using local resources cannot be accomplished. However, is this true? To test this argument, we used statistical data and created a framework to calculate land consumption in square meters per capita according to different dietary habits, among other factors. This study will focus on scenario analyses for the region of Hesse, Germany—with an emphasis on the livestock sector—as land consumption for the production of meat, milk and eggs is relatively high there. Our results show that the region is far from being able to feed the current livestock population and that it does not have the land to support the livestock needed to sustain current consumption patterns. However, the region could support a smaller livestock population with the implementation of the planetary health diet, especially if farmers were to adopt crop rotation systems and (more) extensive husbandry.
... A variety of studies have explored our global food system and its impact on the environment, climate as well as health, focusing on global data [25][26][27][28][29]. Although these studies are extremely important for understanding the interconnections of our global food system and the impacts on humanity, wildlife and plants, it is also essential to look at smaller areas, but in detail [30]. To be able to calculate and process details, local conditions must be considered, such as current local supply and demand, types of agriculture (e.g., grass land vs. arable land), soil conditions etc. ...
... Key factors in food sovereignty include prioritizing local agricultural production; access of peasants and landless people to land, water, seeds and credit; the right of farmers and peasants to produce food and the right of consumers to be able to decide what they consume, how and by whom it is produced; the right of countries to protect themselves from too low priced agricultural and food imports; the right to impose taxes on excessively cheap imports if they commit themselves 3 of 29 quality of food that local people need. Low yields are also not a viable solution, the argument goes, because population growth, income growth and changing diets are predicted to increase demand for agricultural products by 60-120% by 2050 (from a base year of 2005) [30,31]. However, if independence from global food supply chains and thus national food sovereignty is the goal, individual regions should feed themselves according to the arable and pasture land available to them. ...
Preprint
Full-text available
The way people in many countries eat today is disconnected to the resources and land locally available. In Europe, for instance, too much meat is eaten, but often cannot be fed by local resources. The percentage of non-local and non-seasonal food is tremendous, exploiting other regions and their water reservoirs. Current diets harm eco systems and people’s health. (Re-)regionalising food systems and aligning diets to planetary boundaries could be one way to reconnect people to the food they eat. Before demanding the (re-)regionalisation of food, it should be analysed whether current consumption patterns can be met at all with the regionally available agricultural land. We looked at the region Hesse in Central Germany, calculated and compared land consumption of current diets with the consumption as recommended by the Planetary Health Diet. Our focus is on livestock because land consumption to produce meat, dairy and eggs is relatively high. Our results show that the region is far from being able to feed the current livestock population, that it does not have the land to support the livestock needed to meet current consumption patterns, but that it could support a smaller livestock population according to the Planetary Health Diet, especially if farmers adopt crop rotation systems and extensive husbandry.
... Their proposed system can provide predictive support to food supply chain vehicles to reroute if they encounter any restricted route. The food yield requirement is justified in (Latham, 2021) for the coming year. The authors clarify the food's unreported requirements and thus estimate the food's future needs for the world population. ...
... • Controlled the HVAC based on multi-agent deep reinforcement learning with an attention mechanism. (Latham, 2021) Hunger and food deficit analysis ...
Article
Future smart cities are the key to fulfilling the ever-growing demands of citizens. Information and communication advancements will empower better administration of accessible resources. The eventual fate of the world's betterment lies in its urban environment advancement. The fast influx of individuals creates possibility, yet it additionally causes challenges. Creating sustainable, reasonable space in the world's steadily extending cities is tested confronting governments worldwide. The model of the smart cities rises, where the rights and well-being of the smart city citizens are assured, the industry is in action, and the assessment of urban planning from an environmental point of view. This paper presents a survey on analyzing future technologies and requirements for future smart cities. We provide extensive research to identify and inspect the latest technology advancements, the foundation of the upcoming robust era. Such technologies include deep learning (DL), machine learning (ML), internet of things (IoT), mobile computing, big data, blockchain, sixth-generation (6G) networks, WiFi-7, industry 5.0, robotic systems, heating ventilation, and air conditioning (HVAC), digital forensic, industrial control systems, connected and automated vehicles (CAVs), electric vehicles, product recycling, flying Cars, pantry backup, calamity backup and vital integration of cybersecurity to keep the user concerns secured. We provide a detailed review of the existing future smart cities application frameworks. Furthermore, we discuss various technological challenges of future smart cities. Finally, we identify the future dimensions of smart cities to develop smart cities with the precedence of smart living.
... The model also takes no account of any negative effects that the global economic system will have on resource-poor farmers and on their food and land sovereignty. Nor does it take account of the negative impacts on human health of modern Western diets in terms of rising levels of obesity and associated noncommunicable diseases occurring globally Latham, 2020). ...
... The creation of new participatory epistemologies is urgent, in which the political character of all thought, of all ideas is recognized, where "all social actors and actresses have something important to say about the object and product, thus generating an extended community of evaluators" (Martínez Alier cited in Sevilla Guzmán and Solier Montiel 2010:199). Perhaps most conclusively, the Green Revolution, with its founding tenet of ending world hunger, has failed even in its own terms, as today about 12% of the world's population still suff ers from malnutrition, and almost 30% suff er from obesity induced by the type of diet promoted by the industrial agri-food system ( Latham 2021 ). ...
Article
Full-text available
A nivel mundial, la agricultura se enfrenta a una crisis alimentaria, que ha incentivado a la aplicación de prácticas inadecuadas con el fin de incrementar su productividad y satisfacer la demanda de alimentos. Sin embargo, el uso indiscriminado de agroquímicos ha impactado negativamente en el medio ambiente, principalmente en los suelos agrícolas, que han presentado eutrofización, salinidad, e infertilidad de producción para muchos cultivos. En la búsqueda de estrategias para reducir el impacto ecológico y cuidar la salud del suelo, el desarrollo de bioestimulantes representa una herramienta potencial para contribuir en las prácticas agrícolas convencionales, promoviendo el uso eficiente de insumos con el fin de aprovechar al máximo la productividad de los cultivos. En este sentido, los bioestimulante se definen como cualquier sustancia o producto que al aplicarse en cantidades adecuadas mejora una o más características de la planta, como la eficiencia en el uso de nutrientes, l tolerancia al estrés (biótico o abiótico), rasgos de calidad de frutos y la disponibilidad de nutrientes confinados en el suelo o la rizosfera. Por lo cual, el objetivo de este artículo es dar a conocer el efecto de los bioestimulantes relacionados con el cuidado y la salud del suelo.
Article
Full-text available
Depuis la fin des années 2010, l’agriculture numérique connaît un essor important caractérisé par la création d’entreprises, de dispositifs de recherche mais également la mise à l’agenda des politiques publiques. Nous proposons ici de comprendre l’agriculture numérique comme une promesse technoscientifique qui renouvelle l’esprit du productivisme agricole. Dans une première partie, nous identifions les régularités discursives et la singularité d’une promesse traversée par deux tensions. L’une oppose l’annonce d’une rupture technologique à l’impératif d’une légitimité qui passe par un ancrage aux structures existantes. L’autre confronte la construction rhétorique d’une agriculture numérique au singulier à la diversité des innovations et des modèles agricoles et alimentaires qu’elle intègre. Dans une seconde partie, nous analysons les réponses que cette promesse fournit aux critiques d’un productivisme en crise renouvelant ainsi l’esprit du productivisme agricole.
Article
Full-text available
Agricultural extension is a key policy to accomplish sustainable agricultural development by improving farmers’ knowledge. Agricultural Extension Model Sites (AEMSs) is a new agricultural extension approach for empowering farmers in Iran. Therefore, the purpose of this research is the economic effect assessment of extension services of AEMSs for irrigated wheat production in Iran. Surveys were conducted with 180 people of the main farmers from irrigated wheat AEMSs throughout Iran. The research tool was a questionnaire, the validity of which was examined using the opinions of a group of experts from the Agricultural Education and Extension Institute in Iran. Data analysis was done using econometric analysis and One-way ANOVA analysis through SHAZAM11 and SPSS27 software. Results showed that the extension services significantly affected irrigated wheat yield with an average increase of 0.66 t/ha. Based on the results, out of the Marginal product value (69USD)oftheextensionservicesprovidedtothemainfarmers,13.369 USD) of the extension services provided to the main farmers, 13.3% (9 USD) had been spent as the cost of extension services and 86.7% ($60 USD) had been net profit gained by farmers. Farmers’ behaviors changed as a result of the AEMs with reduced input costs for growing the crop and increased production and profit from the crop.
Book
Full-text available
This book explores Critical Sustainability Sciences, a new field of scientific inquiry into sustainability issues. It builds on a highly novel integration of elements from relational ontologies, critical theory, political ecology, and intercultural philosophy in support of emancipatory perspectives on sustainability and development. Critical Sustainability Sciences begins by uncovering the weaknesses of mainstream sustainability science and debates on sustainable development. The new field of Critical Sustainability Sciences grows out of deep engagement with relational ontologies. This engagement helps to overcome the dualist ontology underlying mainstream notions of sustainability and development. Dualist ontologies reinforce problematic divisions, for example between humans and nature, subjects and objects, mind and matter, body and soul, etc. Examples from indigenous peoples in Bolivia, India, and Ghana – as well as integrative movements in Chile, Brazil, and Europe – show that relational conceptions of life, rooted in eco- and cosmosophy, can provide an intercultural philosophical foundation for Critical Sustainability Sciences. The book concludes by describing three key topics for exploration in Critical Sustainability Sciences: societal reorganization in view of emancipatory, existential, and cognitive self-determination; living labor and commons; and the development of new comprehensive relational scientific paradigms. This book will be of great interest to students, scholars, and practitioners of emancipatory and intercultural approaches to sustainability and development.
Book
Full-text available
It has been clear for many years that agriculture in Europe needs to become more sustainable and requires fundamental change. In recent years, more and more “innovative” techniques or products have been presented as THE one big solution – examples include precision farming, indoor farming, new genetic engineering or carbon farming. It is often suggested that the problems of the agricultural system can now be solved, although only partial areas are affected. Can carbon farming make agriculture climate-friendly? Is indoor farming sustainable? Can new genetic engineering be used to breed more resistant plants? Does precision farming solve the issue of over-fertilisation? This study takes a closer look at some of the currently prominently discussed technical “sustainability solutions” and asks critical questions about their effectiveness. Do techno-fixes prominently discussed in policy papers and the media bring agriculture into harmony with ecosystems, animal welfare and societal needs?
Article
Full-text available
A nature-friendly matrix As the human population has grown, we have taken and modified more and more land, leaving less and less for nonhuman species. This is clearly unsustainable, and the amount of land we protect for nature needs to be increased and preserved. However, this still leaves vast regions of the world unprotected and modified. Such landscapes do not have to be a lost cause. Kremen and Merenlender review how biodiversity-based techniques can be used to manage most human-modified lands as “working landscapes.” These can provide for human needs and maintain biodiversity not just for ecosystem services but also for maintenance and persistence of nonhuman species. Science , this issue p. eaau6020
Chapter
Full-text available
Bioethanol has recently emerged as a major issue in energy policy to fulfill growing energy demand and sustainable economy. Ethanol as a fuel source today owes positive impact on rural America, the environment, and United States energy security. Bioethanol from corn and wheat is considered as the first-generation biofuel compared to other sources of biofuel because only hexose sugar is targeted for fermentation. High titer ethanol (>5%) can be achieved from corn and wheat by using simpler steps (grinding/milling, cooking, and liquefaction) before fermentation using the yeast strain (Saccharomyces cerevisiae). Recently, bioethanol from corn and wheat is adopted at industrial-scale in several developed and developing countries to fulfill the demands of the bioethanol. Fuel ethanol production is an energy-efficient process today, additional research is ongoing to improve its long-term economic viability.
Article
Full-text available
The system of rice intensification (SRI) has been promoted across Asia as a means to improve rice yields while decreasing water use and external inputs. It is argued to be a generalisable means by which to revalidate smallholder livelihoods and improve food security across the region. Current debates about SRI, however, remain predominantly technical in scope, focusing on field‐level outcomes. To more adequately understand the potential of SRI for smallholder farmers, we argue that it is necessary to situate SRI within a political ecology framework that addresses how the adoption and practice of SRI is shaped by uneven access to key assets including labour, water, and extension networks. Fieldwork conducted in Mahabubnagar district in Telangana, south India—where SRI had been widely disadopted despite the achievement of higher yields—is used to illustrate why agronomic analysis must engage directly with the complex social contexts in which farmers operate.
Article
Full-text available
A growing and increasingly urbanized global population will raise the pressures to intensify agricultural production systems, as the total surface area of arable lands remains constant or even diminishes in many parts of the world. Mainstream agricultural research and development have been emphasizing a ‘green revolution’ type intensification largely based on new seeds of crop varieties, while relying on agrochemicals to achieve short-term economic sustainability. During the 1980s the ‘System of Rice Intensification (SRI)’ was empirically developed in Madagascar. This set of practices was initially and widely rejected by mainstream (rice) research in spite of its often spectacular grain yields as obtained in farmer fields across many Asian and African countries. Some of the practices proved equally relevant for other crops such as wheat maize and sugarcane. SRI’s popularity among Indian smallholders, originated from its attractive yields at reduced rates/costs for seeds, water, nutrients and chemicals (fertilizers and pesticides). These features have sparked research into both the agronomic/biological as well as socioeconomic/humanity disciplines. This paper seeks to capitalize on the lessons learned from SRI, also with respect to other crops, and explores additional opportunities for intensification based on ecological processes as supported by insights from (soil) microbiological, biochemical and molecular research. Recent studies suggest that soil organic matter, plant roots, soil biota and biodiversity of plants and (micro-) organisms – rather than agrochemicals – will be the critical elements of environment-friendly and sustainable forms of agriculture. To capitalize on these factors, large reductions in plant densities (>50%) would be required to allow expanded root systems as the basis for increased plant physiological efficiency. The paper elaborates also on the socioeconomic/cultural issues involved in possible transitions as farmer’s technical/managerial skills and insights were crucial in the successful introduction and dissemination of SRI practices so far. The article is based on an extensive review of literature complemented by field observations and farmer interviews in different parts of India and West Africa.
Article
Full-text available
This article was submitted without an abstract, please refer to the full-text PDF file.
Book
Trusting Trade and the Private Sector for Food Security in Southeast Asia challenges policy makers who oversee the rice sector in Southeast Asia and reexamines deep-rooted precepts about their responsibilities. The authors argue that fixating on national self-sufficiency has been costly and counterproductive, and cooperation can both improve rice production at home and expand regional trade. Trusting Trade specifically examines private sector participation in the rice and (yellow) maize markets in five countries in the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. The study identifies both the private sector s potential role in providing greater regional food security and feasible ways to strengthen public and private sector cooperation in managing regional food supply chains. Trusting Trade also examines actionable ways to deepen and strengthen regional markets that support trade in food staples. The study s recommendations are meant to be implemented primarily through new forms of partnerships between the public and private sectors. Trusting Trade will be of interest to policy makers in the ASEAN member states and its development partners as well as others interested in food security, supply chains, and trade in Southeast Asia.
Article
Among all of the possible approaches to reducing hunger in the world, efforts to increase agricultural productivity dominate in development institutions and large philanthropies. In this productivist paradigm, the function of agriculture is narrow, and further investments in industrial agriculture are the greatest need. This view clashes with the intricate diversity and multiple functions of farms and gardens in Yucatan, Mexico. Agroecosystems there are spectacularly diverse. Besides providing many products to eat and sell, those farms are uniquely well suited to feed households in the increasingly erratic weather of Yucatan, where droughts and storms often wipe out certain crops. In a diverse garden, there is nearly always something to eat. There is little evidence that increasing agricultural production alone promotes food security, and there are many instances in which the drive for productivity has exacerbated hunger. In this article, I investigate why productivism has dominated development policy and discourse for so long.