ArticlePublisher preview available
To read the full-text of this research, you can request a copy directly from the authors.

Abstract and Figures

Organizations devoted to the production of goods and services, such as guilds, partnerships and modern corporations, have dominated the economic landscape in our species’ history. We develop an explanation for their evolution drawing from cultural evolution theory. A basic tenet of this theory is that social learning, under certain conditions, allows for the diffusion of innovations in society and, therefore, the accumulation of culture. Our model shows that these organizations provide such conditions by possessing two characteristics, both prevalent in real world organizations: exclusivity of membership and more effective social learning within their boundaries. The model and its extensions parsimoniously explain the cooperative nature of the social learning advantage, organizational specialization, organizational rigidity and the locus of innovation. We find supportive evidence for our predictions using a sample of premodern societies drawn from the Ethnographic Atlas. Understanding the nature of these organizations informs the debate about their role in society.
This content is subject to copyright. Terms and conditions apply.
Articles
https://doi.org/10.1038/s41562-020-00957-x
1London Business School, London, UK. 2School of Management, Pontificia Universidad Catolica de Chile, Santiago, Chile. 3Instituto Sistemas Complejos de
Ingeniería, Santiago, Chile. e-mail: fbrahm@london.edu
Organizations, defined as a stable and interacting collec-
tion of individuals with a common and specific goal1, have
played a crucial role throughout human history. One type
of organization, which we define as a productive organization (PO),
focuses on producing and delivering the goods and services that
satisfy the needs of human populations (for example, food, shelter,
clothes and tools). Whether it is the societas in Roman times2, the
guilds in medieval times3, the partnerships in early Renaissance4 or
the modern corporation5, POs have played a crucial role in our spe-
cies’ success. Not surprisingly, Herbert Simon noted that our ‘mar-
ket economies’ are in reality ‘organizational economies’6.
An often-neglected corollary is that the theories about the nature
of these organizations have an important impact on public policies
about markets and organizations, as well as how these organiza-
tions are managed. Consider, for example, the consequential debate
around the role of corporations in society7,8. However, while extant
theories explain how POs work (that is, their inner workings), we
lack a clear explanation for their evolution. This is not a minor gap,
as understanding POs’ origin is a requisite to fully understand and
thus to improve the capacity to harness, manage or regulate this
dominant institution.
In this paper, we propose such an explanation drawing from
cultural evolution theory914. Cultural evolution studies the trans-
mission and inheritance of culture, defined as information—beliefs,
norms, knowledge, skills and techniques—acquired from other indi-
viduals via social learning (for example, imitation, teaching). A cen-
tral insight of this theory is that social learning, by way of diffusing
innovations in a society, produces their gradual accumulation over
time. This process of cultural accumulation has allowed humans to
adapt and conquer every environment in the globe. We propose that
POs evolved because they enhance the capacity of social learning to
generate cumulative culture. This contributes to the nascent discus-
sion on the importance of studying organizational evolution and its
impact on cumulative culture1518.
Our model and its extensions can illuminate several aspects of
POs that have eluded an integrated and parsimonious explanation
so far. First, we use culture as the main explanatory lever, away from
the focus on incentives and governance in the existing (economic)
theories of POs. These theories propose that POs’ role is to avoid the
myriad of transaction hazards involved in market exchange1924. For
each type of hazard, POs provide a distinct solution. For example,
when assets are specific to a transaction and therefore hold-up is
likely, POs resolve ex post conflict using authority22. While empiri-
cal evidence supports this approach25, recent evidence shows that
POs are, to a large extent, carriers and transmitters of culture2630.
Our theory informs the latter: it proposes that two specific and
ever-present characteristics of POs—restricted access and improved
social learning—favour cultural accumulation in societies. Thus,
while current theories assume a pre-existing cultural pool from
which transactions emerge, we endogenize culture and POs.
Second, the importance of cooperation for POs’ nature is a point
that has been frequently made6,18,3134 but scarcely formalized17,35.
Our theory proposes that cooperation is a cultural quality of POs
that evolves via group selection, instead of being enforced on
self-interested agents via incentives and other governance devices.
For this, we use the idea of teaching as a cooperative act that
enhances the effectiveness of social learning14,36,37.
Third, we lack an understanding of the evolutionary mechanisms
that selected POs. Current theories focus on how POs work, that is,
they provide a ‘proximate explanation’ by detailing the mechanisms
of governance and incentive provision20,22,24,38,39. The spread of POs
is then explained by invoking agents’ causal understanding whom
adopt POs to increase their expected use. However, causal under-
standing does not need to be present to produce complex cultural
phenomena13,40,41 and thus, POs might not be adopted via complex
foresight and calculations. Instead, as with other traits that societies
carry and transmit over time, entrepreneurs may simply adopt POs
as the inherited default at their disposal. Therefore, if one assumes
limited causal understanding in humans6,13,40, asking how, when
and why POs originated and spread is pertinent. This is the type of
explanation we provide in this paper, known as ‘ultimate explana-
tion’ in biology39,42,43. Just as biologists study the function of a trait
for reproduction and survival, we unpack the POs’ function for
cumulative culture, the key enabler of our species’ success13,14,40. Our
ultimate explanation of POs complements evolutionary approaches
in economics44—that focus on change but not origin—and, by
unpacking the role of exclusivity and enhanced social learning, it
provides a clue that can guide empirical work in cultural evolution,
be that historical2,29,45,46, cultural-phylogenetic47 or archaeological48.
In this paper, we provide a step in that direction by testing the model
The evolution of productive organizations
Francisco Brahm 1 ✉ and Joaquin Poblete 2,3
Organizations devoted to the production of goods and services, such as guilds, partnerships and modern corporations, have
dominated the economic landscape in our species’ history. We develop an explanation for their evolution drawing from cultural
evolution theory. A basic tenet of this theory is that social learning, under certain conditions, allows for the diffusion of innova-
tions in society and, therefore, the accumulation of culture. Our model shows that these organizations provide such conditions
by possessing two characteristics, both prevalent in real world organizations: exclusivity of membership and more effective
social learning within their boundaries. The model and its extensions parsimoniously explain the cooperative nature of the
social learning advantage, organizational specialization, organizational rigidity and the locus of innovation. We find supportive
evidence for our predictions using a sample of premodern societies drawn from the Ethnographic Atlas. Understanding the
nature of these organizations informs the debate about their role in society.
NATURE HUMAN BEHAVIOUR | VOL 5 | JANUARY 2021 | 39–48 | www.nature.com/nathumbehav 39
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved
... Then, in the third section, we explain the distinction between proximate and ultimate explanations, we provide examples from biology and the social sciences at large, and we discuss how these two types of explanation need to be consistent with one another. In this section we also: (i) explain why the social sciences, and organization and management by extension, tend to lack (or assume away) ultimate explanations; (ii) drill down into how CET generates ultimate explanations, by introducing the methods of microevolution (analysis of evolutionary dynamics within a single population using formal models) and macro-evolution (documenting ancestry and lineage by performing empirical analysis across populations); and (iii) explain in detail an example from our own research which exemplifies how CET can be applied to study the origins of (pre-modern) firm-like organizations such as guilds and partnerships (Brahm & Poblete, 2021a). Finally, in the last section of the paper, we explore how CET can serve as a general explanatory framework for many of the proximate explanations and theories we have in our field. ...
... We argue that the predominant mode of explanation in organization and management scholarship is in the form of proximate explanations. The field studies the details of how organizations operate; how people are selected, trained, monitored and rewarded; how workers come together and interact in teams or larger groups; how formal and informal structures operate and interact; how culture influences behavior; how to organize the different parts of the firm (production, logistics, finance, etc.); how decision-making occurs; how innovation can be fostered within organizations; and a long The evolution of productive organizations (Brahm & Poblete, 2021a) Proximate explanation Mechanisms that regulate and trigger a phenomenon. It answers "how" questions; ...
... Standard, widespread econometric techniques can be utilized successfully. Two tests using econometric analysis across societies support the theory: (i) Ethnographic atlas (Brahm & Poblete, 2021a), (ii) Long-run persistence of tradition (see Brahm & Poblete, 2021b). ...
Article
Full-text available
Fully explaining organizational phenomena requires exploring not only “how” a phenomenon works – i.e., the details of its internal structure and mechanisms – but also “why” the phenomenon is present in the first place – i.e., explaining its origins and the ultimate reasons for its existence. The latter is particularly important for central questions in organizational research such as the nature of organizations, the evolution of organizational culture, or the origin of organizational capabilities. In this article, we propose that cultural evolution theory (CET) can be usefully applied to organizational scholarship to pursue such “origin” questions. CET has adapted ideas and methods from evolutionary biology to successfully explain the evolution of culture in human societies, exploring the origins of various social phenomena such as religion, technological progress, large-scale cooperation, and cross-cultural psychological variation. We elaborate how CET can be also applied to understand the evolution and origin of important organizational phenomena. We discuss how CET provides ultimate explanations using micro-evolutionary formal models and deploying macro-evolutionary tools for empirical analysis. We provide a detailed application of these ideas to explain the origin of productive organizations (e.g., firms, partnerships, guilds). We also propose several avenues for future research; in particular, we explore how CET can serve as an overarching theoretical framework that helps integrate the myriad of theories that explain how organizations operate and evolve.
... Our second contribution is to introduce a formal model from cultural evolution theory (Cavalli-Sforza and Feldman 1981, Boyd and Richerson 1985Mesoudi 2017, Boyd 2018, Henrich 2016, Brahm and Poblete 2021, 2022 to the literature on organizations. Our model (like most cultural evolution models) is consistent with the Carnegie school (CS) tradition by emphasizing bounded rationality and adaptation via learning. ...
Article
Prior research emphasizes how organizational culture can hinder organizational adaptation. In this study, we investigate how organizational culture can help promote organizational adaptation to environmental changes, using a formal model from cultural evolution theory. In the model, organizational members face a trade-off between innovating versus following tradition (because environmental changes are uncertain). Members can also decide to help others who are following the tradition, thereby improving its diffusion. Organizational leaders shape the culture of their organization, which influences members’ decisions to choose innovation or tradition or to help others following tradition. Culture comprises two dimensions: beliefs and prosocial values. We find that increasing the accuracy of beliefs leads to improvements in both innovation and following tradition, thereby mitigating the trade-off between them and boosting adaptation and performance. On prosocial values, we find that increasing their intensity reduces the cost of following tradition but at the expense of reduced adaptation, resulting in an inverted-U relationship between intensity of prosocial values and performance. Overall, we show how leaders can fine-tune the dimensions of organizational culture to foster improvements in adaptation and performance. The formal model we introduce is novel to the literature and offers a way of studying adaptation to a changing environment and to incorporate social learning into models of adaptation under bounded rationality. Funding: J. Poblete was supported by Instituto Sistemas Complejos de Ingenieria [Grant ANID PIA/PUENTE AFB230002]. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.2022.16791 .
... In the corporate strategy, elites facilitate the redistribution of wealth [18,19]. Through kin-based authority, early elites were facilitators of economic cooperation and levellers of inequality-'bankers' who managed the local economy to everyone's benefit [48]. Early states varied in their degree of redistribution, from temple-based redistributive states (e.g., Mesopotamia) to subsequent expansive and tributary states where wealth and land, as war spoils, were accumulated by state elites, not for redistribution [20,21,49]. ...
Article
Full-text available
The literature on the fall of civilizations spans from the archaeology of early state societies to the history of the 20th century. Explanations for the fall of civilizations abound, from general extrinsic causes (drought, warfare) to general intrinsic causes (intergroup competition, socioeconomic inequality, collapse of trade networks) and combinations of these, to case-specific explanations for the specific demise of early state societies. Here, we focus on ancient civilizations, which archaeologists typically define by a set of characteristics including hierarchical organization, standardization of specialized knowledge, occupation and technologies, and hierarchical exchange networks and settlements. We take a general approach, with a model suggesting that state societies arise and dissolve through the same processes of innovation. Drawing on the field of cumulative cultural evolution, we demonstrate a model that replicates the essence of a civilization’s rise and fall, in which agents at various scales—individuals, households, specialist communities, polities—copy each other in an unbiased manner but with varying degrees of institutional memory, invention rate, and propensity to copy locally versus globally. The results, which produce an increasingly extreme hierarchy of success among agents, suggest that civilizations become increasingly vulnerable to even small increases in propensity to copy locally.
... This growth is, therefore, likely to result from other mechanisms such as cultural specialization or cultural innovations that help preserve knowledge (as we explored in [25]). Furthermore, cultural specialization could potentially benefit the fitness of the entire population, e.g. by increasing its overall productivity and by allowing for more effective social learning [26,27]. However, specialization might be a doubleedged sword in cultural accumulation, since cultural knowledge that is known by only a small subset of a population could be more likely to be lost, particularly during periods of demographic change [14]. ...
Article
Full-text available
The transition to specialization of knowledge within populations could have facilitated the accumulation of cultural complexity in humans. Specialization allows populations to increase their cultural repertoire without requiring that members of that population increase their individual capacity to accumulate knowledge. However, specialization also means that domain-specific knowledge can be concentrated in small subsets of the population, making it more susceptible to loss. Here, we use a model of cultural evolution to demonstrate that specialized populations can be more sensitive to stochastic loss of knowledge than populations without subdivision of knowledge, and that demographic and environmental changes have an amplified effect on populations with knowledge specialization. Finally, we suggest that specialization can be a double-edged sword; specialized populations may have an advantage in accumulating cultural traits but may also be less likely to expand and establish themselves successfully in new demes owing to the increased cultural loss that they experience during the population bottlenecks that often characterize such expansions. This article is part of the theme issue ‘Human socio-cultural evolution in light of evolutionary transitions’.
... It is not clear what implications CCE studies in small groups should have for larger populations, such as the urban environments humans have lived in for millennia. Extrapolating the hypothesized correlation between CCE and population size, it would seem that larger social learning networks would surface the best technologies [16,33,34], productive organizations [35], government institutions [36,37] and technical knowledge [38][39][40]. As innovation rate scales with population density [18,41], however, the number of similar options can increase by orders of magnitude, and social learners need to update more frequently to keep up. ...
Article
Full-text available
Cumulative cultural evolution (CCE) occurs among humans who may be presented with many similar options from which to choose, as well as many social influences and diverse environments. It is unknown what general principles underlie the wide range of CCE dynamics and whether they can all be explained by the same unified paradigm. Here, we present a scalable evolutionary model of discrete choice with social learning, based on a few behavioural science assumptions. This paradigm connects the degree of transparency in social learning to the human tendency to imitate others. Computer simulations and quantitative analysis show the interaction of three primary factors—information transparency, popularity bias and population size—drives the pace of CCE. The model predicts a stable rate of evolutionary change for modest degrees of popularity bias. As popularity bias grows, the transition from gradual to punctuated change occurs, with maladaptive subpopulations arising on their own. When the popularity bias gets too severe, CCE stops. This provides a consistent framework for explaining the rich and complex adaptive dynamics taking place in the real world, such as modern digital media.
... Organizations that are cohesive may be subject to selection at the group level, whereby those organizations that provide greater overall benefits to their members can outcompete other organizations, thereby ensuring that the structures that are associated with those benefits persist [74]. The framework of "cultural group selection" [75][76][77] has recently been applied to understanding competition between organizations in contexts such as lobster fishing [78], forest management [79], and a large sample of U.S. firms [80]. ...
Article
Full-text available
A critical task for organizations is how to best structure themselves to efficiently allocate information and resources to individuals tasked with solving sub-components of the organization’s central problems. Despite this criticality, the processes by which organizational structures form remain largely opaque within organizational theory, with most approaches focused on how structure is influenced by individual managerial heuristics, normative cultural perceptions, and trial-and-error. Here, we propose that a broad understanding of organizational formation can be aided by appealing to generative entrenchment, a theory from developmental biology that helps explain why phylogenetically diverse animals appear similar as embryos. Drawing inferences from generative entrenchment and applying it to organizational differentiation, we argue that the reason many organizations appear structurally similar is due to core informational restraints on individual actors beginning at the top and descending to the bottom of these informational hierarchies, which reinforces these structures via feedback between separate levels. We further argue that such processes can lead to the emergence of a variety of group-level traits, an important but undertheorized class of phenomena in cultural evolution.
... The \shoulders of giants" model places the strength of science in social interaction, essential in what has come to be called the \collective intelligence" of groups [41,57,80,81]. Ideally, a massive social learning network would surface the best technologies [6,7,82], cooperative institutions [83] and science [50,[84][85][86]. Contrary to CCE ideal [23][24][25][26][27][28][29][30][31][32][33][34][35], scienti¯c innovation may not accelerate with the number of interacting researchers if they are forming siloed cliques, pursuing fashionable ideas [58,87], and otherwise overlooking relevant precedents in the literature [88]. ...
Article
Full-text available
Evolutionary studies of cultural complexity often assume that group members select the best information available in the group, effectively diffusing the best innovations, whose advantages are subsequently passed on to the next generation. This would seem to describe the ideal of the scientific process — each cohort of papers in a field surfacing the best innovations, refining them and passing on to the next “layer” or cohort of scientific works. Here, we use academic journal databases to explore this “forking” (branching) process in the evolution of a scientific paradigm. We apply citation network visualization and Latent Dirichlet allocation topic analysis to three different paradigms defined pragmatically as the set of papers citing a highly influential paper in each respective case. Our three case studies indicate a founder effect in how the seminal paper is highly-embedded in the citation network, and yet peripheral to the evolution of topics in subsequent “layers” of publications within the paradigm. This and additional evidence suggest certain topics are selected and followed, while others are left behind. From these case studies we discuss how hitherto undeveloped ideas of the past might be located in the topic space of seminal works of the same fruitful time period.
Article
Markets and firms offer contrasting methods to arrange production. In markets, contracts govern the purchase of parts and services. In firms, the shared values, customs and norms coming from a corporate culture govern employees' joint development of parts and services. We argue for this distinction as a theory of the firm. Firms exist because corporate culture at times is more efficient to carry out production than are detailed contracts. The firm's boundary encircles the areas of production for which a manager optimally chooses corporate culture as the organizing device. Consistent with empirical evidence, the model explains why some mergers and acquisitions fail, and why corporate cultures are hard to change.
Chapter
Our society is based on cooperation. In our daily lives, there are a lot of examples; the parent–teacher association (PTA), paying tax, participating in voting, and making an effort to maintain the public facilities such as irrigation systems and reservoirs in farmland. As a simple game such as the prisoner’s dilemma game showed, mutual cooperation is hard to achieved. In reality, even though free-riders exists, we cooperate together to some extent. Researchers in various fields have been investigating what mechanism promotes cooperation among people and can explain cooperation in our real world. This study field is named “the evolution of cooperation.” Chapter 1 summarizes the previous studies about mechanisms promoting mutual cooperation, providing readers with some basic knowledge to understand “the evolution of cooperation.”
Article
Full-text available
It has been suggested that the human species may be undergoing an evolutionary transition in individuality (ETI). But there is disagreement about how to apply the ETI framework to our species, and whether culture is implicated as either cause or consequence. Long-term gene-culture coevolution (GCC) is also poorly understood. Some have argued that culture steers human evolution, while others proposed that genes hold culture on a leash. We review the literature and evidence on long-term GCC in humans and find a set of common themes. First, culture appears to hold greater adaptive potential than genetic inheritance and is probably driving human evolution. The evolutionary impact of culture occurs mainly through culturally organized groups, which have come to dominate human affairs in recent millennia. Second, the role of culture appears to be growing, increasingly bypassing genetic evolution and weakening genetic adaptive potential. Taken together, these findings suggest that human long-term GCC is characterized by an evolutionary transition in inheritance (from genes to culture) which entails a transition in individuality (from genetic individual to cultural group). Thus, research on GCC should focus on the possibility of an ongoing transition in the human inheritance system.
Article
We examine a determinant of cultural persistence that has emerged from a class of models in evolutionary anthropology: the similarity of the environment across generations. Within these models, when the environment is more stable across generations, the traits that have evolved up to the previous generation are more likely to be suitable for the current generation. In equilibrium, a greater value is placed on tradition and there is greater cultural persistence. We test this hypothesis by measuring the variability of climatic measures across 20-year generations from 500–1900CE. Employing a variety of tests that use different samples and empirical strategies, we find that populations with ancestors who lived in environments with more cross-generational instability place less importance on maintaining tradition today and exhibit less cultural persistence.
Book
A new theory of the evolution of human cognition and human social life that emphasizes the role of information sharing across generations. Over the last three million years or so, our lineage has diverged sharply from those of our great ape relatives. Change has been rapid (in evolutionary terms) and pervasive. Morphology, life history, social life, sexual behavior, and foraging patterns have all shifted sharply away from those of the other great apes. In The Evolved Apprentice, Kim Sterelny argues that the divergence stems from the fact that humans gradually came to enrich the learning environment of the next generation. Humans came to cooperate in sharing information, and to cooperate ecologically and reproductively as well, and these changes initiated positive feedback loops that drove us further from other great apes. Sterelny develops a new theory of the evolution of human cognition and human social life that emphasizes the gradual evolution of information-sharing practices across generations and how these practices transformed human minds and social lives. Sterelny proposes that humans developed a new form of ecological interaction with their environment, cooperative foraging. The ability to cope with the immense variety of human ancestral environments and social forms, he argues, depended not just on adapted minds but also on adapted developmental environments. Bradford Books imprint
Article
This paper exploits the introduction of the first regularized patent system, which appeared in the Venetian Republic in 1474, to examine the factors shaping inventors’ propensity to use a new form of intellectual property. We combine detailed information on craft guilds and patents in Renaissance Venice and show a negative association between patenting activity and guild statutory norms that strongly restricted entry and price competition. Our analysis shows that the heterogeneity in patenting activity documented by the industrial organization literature is not a special feature of modern technologies, but is rather a persistent phenomenon affected by market power.