Content uploaded by David Miles
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by David Miles on Aug 24, 2020
Content may be subject to copyright.
R60 NatioNal iNstitute ecoNomic Review No. 253 august 2020
*Professor of Economics, Imperial College, London. E-mail: d.miles@imperial.ac.uk. **RES Consortium. E-mail: mstedman@resconsortium.com. ***The
School of Medicine, University of Manchester. E-mail: adrian.heald@manchester.ac.uk. The authors thank two anonymous referees and Jagjit Chadha for
many helpful comments on an earlier draft.
LIVING WITH COVID-19: BALANCING COSTS AGAINST
BENEFITS IN THE FACE OF THE VIRUS
David Miles,* Mike Stedman** and Adrian Heald***
This paper analyses the costs and benefits of lockdown policies in the face of COVID-19. What matters for people is
the quality and length of lives and one should measure costs and benefits in terms of those things. That raises difficulties
in measurement, particularly in valuing potential lives saved. We draw upon guidelines used in the UK for public health
decisions, as well as other measures, which allow a comparison between health effects and other economic effects. We
look at evidence on the effectiveness of past severe restrictions applied in European countries, focusing on the evidence
from the UK. The paper considers policy options for the degree to which restrictions are eased. There is a need to
normalise how we view COVID because its costs and risks are comparable to other health problems (such as cancer, heart
problems, diabetes) where governments have made resource decisions for decades. The lockdown is a public health policy
and we have valued its impact using the tools that guide health care decisions in the UK public health system. The evidence
suggests that the costs of continuing severe restrictions in the UK are large relative to likely benefits so that a substantial
easing in general restrictions in favour of more targeted measures is warranted.
Keywords: value of lives saved, cost benefit analysis, COVID-19.
JEL codes: I18; D61; E65.
Introduction
In early March 2020 it seemed that the COVID-19 virus
in the United Kingdom was spreading exponentially with
no clear sign of imminent slowing; the fatality rate was
unknown and the ability of the National Health Service
(NHS) to deal with rapidly rising numbers of seriously
ill people was unclear. Estimates made at that time put
the likely level of UK deaths if there was no change in
behaviour at 500,000 (Ferguson et al., 2020). Based on
that and other assessments, the UK government followed
the example of several other European countries in
introducing severe restrictions on individual movement
that were backed by legislation and actively policed. The
key message was to stay at home; this was a lockdown.
This served both to slow the spread of the virus and
to signal in a very clear way that people needed to
change behaviours quickly; but it also generated great
costs. The extent to which the lockdown contributed
to a subsequent slowing in the rate of new infections
and deaths is not easy to estimate precisely, but that it
did bring it down signicantly seems clear. But whether
keeping such tight restrictions in place for three months
(until restrictions began to be eased substantially at the
end of June) was warranted, given the large costs, is
very far from clear. This paper summarises the evidence
on this in an assessment of costs and benets of severe
restrictions – ‘lockdowns’. We do so to inform the
decisions on how restrictions in the UK should be lifted.
What we mean by a lockdown is wide ranging government
restrictions on activity that dramatically reduce mobility
and the ability of people to work. A lockdown obviously
goes beyond guidance and it also goes further than
closing just schools, bars, sports venues and restaurants.
It includes general restrictions on movement and involves
rules that people should stay at home except in exceptional
circumstances. Such a lockdown was introduced in the
UK in the second half of March 2020 and only began to
be eased some three months later.
While it is clear that the cost of the lockdown in the UK
has been large, just how great it is will not be known
for many years. This cost – as well as the benets of the
three-month lockdown – should be measured in terms of
human welfare in the form of impacts upon the length
and quality of lives. Such measurement is profoundly
difcult. Yet measurement of the costs of restrictions
© National Institute of Economic and Social Research, 2020.
DOI: 10.1017/nie.2020.30
miles, stedmaN aNd Heald liviNg witH covid-19: balaNciNg costs agaiNst beNefits iN tHe face of tHe viRus R61
The cost of severe restrictions plausibly rises more than
in proportion to the length of a lockdown. Two months
of missed treatments for cancer, of company closures, of
postponed screening for serious health conditions, of lessons
missed at schools and universities, of many people living in
very stressful situations is likely more than twice as bad as
one month. In contrast the benets of maintaining a severe
needs to be weighed against benets of different levels
of restrictions to assess what is the best policy now. A
signicant part of costs and benets is in potential lives
lost and saved under different policies. We draw upon
guidelines used in the UK for public health decisions,
and other measures, to allow a comparison between
health effects and other economic effects.
Figure 1. Number of reported cases (7-day rolling average) per million national population
Source: Our World in Data COVID-19 dataset. Our World in Data
is a collaborative effort between researchers at the University of
Oxford, who are the scientific editors of the website content, and
the non-profit organisation Global Change Data Lab, which publishes
and maintains the website and the data tools https://ourworldindata.
org/coronavirus. Downloaded 1/7/2020.
-20
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
140
160
180
23/02 01/03 08 /03 15 /03 22/03 29/03 05 /04 12 /04 19/04 26 /04 03 /05 10/05 17/05 24 /05 31 /05 07/06 14/06 21 /06 28 /06
Reported cases ro lling previous 7 day average /mil lion populati on
Belg i um De n mark F ran c e Germa ny
Italy Netherlands Norway P o rtu g al
Spa in Sweden United Ki ngdom
2020
6.7
5.3
5.3
4.6
4.1
4.0
2.9
2.5
2.3
2.2
1.6
Sweden
Spa in
Be lgium
United Kingdom
Portugal
Italy
Netherlands
F ra nce
Ge rm any
Denmark
Norway
Cumulative up to 30/6/2020
R62 NatioNal iNstitute ecoNomic Review No. 253 august 2020
set of restrictions – the lockdown – may be diminishing
(see for example Bongaerts et al., 2020). Decisions on how
to ease restrictions are therefore of immediate signicance.
In this article we aim to calibrate what the costs and benets
of sustained severe restrictions might be and what that
implies about the policy that should now be followed. We
look at evidence from many countries, focusing particularly
on European countries with similar levels of income and of
healthcare resources. We then draw out what this implies
for policy in the UK. We nd that the costs of a three-
month lockdown are likely to have become high relative
to benets so that a continuation of severe restrictions is
unlikely to be warranted.
Figure 2. Number of deaths reported associated with COVID-19 cases (7-day rolling average) per million of the national
population
Source: Our World in Data COVID-19 dataset. Downloaded
1/7/2020.
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
19/02 26/02 04/03 11/03 18/03 25/03 01/04 08/04 15/04 22/04 29/04 06/05 13/05 20/05 27/05 03/06 10/06 17/06 24/06
Reported deaths rolling previous 7 day average /million
population
Be lgium Denmark F ra n ce Ge rm an y
Italy Netherlands Nor way Portugal
Spa in Sweden United Kingdom
2020
841
642
615
575
526
457
356
154
107
104
46
Be lgium
United Kingdom
Spa in
Italy
Sweden
F ra nce
Netherlands
Portugal
Ge rm any
Denmark
Norway
Cumulative up to 30/6/2020
miles, stedmaN aNd Heald liviNg witH covid-19: balaNciNg costs agaiNst beNefits iN tHe face of tHe viRus R63
Figure 3. Excess deaths in weeks 8–21 2020(a)
Source: The Human Mortality Database, Department of Demography
at the University of California, Max Planck Institute for Demographic
Research, Center on the Economics and Development of Aging (CEA),
www.mortality.org. Downloaded 9/6/2020.
Note: (a) Difference from average in same week in previous 3 years
(2017/2018/2019) and shown as % of average.
-20%
0%
20%
40%
60%
80%
100%
120%
140%
160%
23/02/2001/03/2008/03/2015/03/2022/03/2029/03/2005/04/2012/04/2019/04/2026/04/2003/05/2010/05/2017/05/2024/05/2031/05/20
Weekly excess deaths as % of expected
Week Ending
Be lgium Denmark F ra n ce Ge rm an y
Italy Netherlands Norway Portugal
Spa in Sweden Great Britain
23/02 01/03 08/03 15/03 22/03 29/03 05/04 12/04 19/04 26/04 03/05 10/05 17/05 24/05 31/05
2020
Section 1 summarises evidence on recorded cases of the virus,
deaths, and excess deaths – all in the context of restrictions
adopted. Section 2 turns to issues of interpretation,
focusing on how much of the slowdown in the spread of
the virus, and of deaths attributed to it, may have been due
to lockdowns and how much to the curves turning down
independently of severe restrictions. Section 3 summarises
evidence from countries with different policies and draws
some conclusions on the scale of benets of the lockdown.
Section 4 focuses on the costs of restrictive policies to slow
the spread of the infections; section 5 brings costs and
benets together and section 6 considers policy options for
coming out of lockdown. Conclusions are drawn in a
nal section.
Spa in
Great Britain
Italy
Be lgium
Netherlands
F ra nce
Sweden
Portugal
Ge rm any
Denmark
Norway
Cumulative % up to 3/06/20
42,539, 21%
58,393, 20%
52,479, 18%
7,057, 13%
7,831, 11%
23,649, 8%
2,515, 6%
1,642, 3%
–3,374, 1%
–779, –3%
–766, –4%
R64 NatioNal iNstitute ecoNomic Review No. 253 august 2020
1. Recorded cases, deaths and excess
deaths
Figure 1 shows the number of new positive cases tested
for in several European countries between early 2020 and
the end of June. Figure 2 shows cumulative deaths where
there is evidence that the deceased had the COVID-19
infection. Figure 3 shows a measure of excess deaths –
that is total deaths in excess of the average of such deaths
over the comparable months in previous years. Figure
4 shows a measure of the stringency of government
restrictions introduced in European countries to counter
the spread of the virus.
Several measurement issues make it difcult to draw
conclusions from these data with high condence. The
number of tests undertaken (relative to population) varies
within countries over time and also between countries and
this will clearly affect the numbers who tested positive for
the virus and the prevalence of untested cases. While data
on the numbers of deaths is reliable, ascribing death to
the virus is not – even if one could accurately measure the
numbers who have died with the virus the prevalence of
co-morbidities means that drawing conclusions about the
scale of deaths caused by the virus is more problematic.
Focusing on ‘excess deaths’ is a different way of assessing
the impact of the virus but since some deaths will be a
result of restrictions, rather than infections, it is also an
imperfect measure.
Despite measurement issues, certain conclusions from
the data in gures 1–4 seem robust.
(i) The spread of the infection after the rst few recorded
cases within European countries was extremely rapid
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
Government response stringency index ((0 to 100, 100 = strictest))
United Kingdom Portugal F ra nce Denmark
Netherlands Germ any B e lgiu m Sweden
Italy Spain No rway
Figure 4. Date of implementation and relaxation of national responses in selected countries
Source: Blavatnik School of Government, University of Oxford, https://www.bsg.ox.ac.uk/research/research-projects/coronavirus-government-response-
tracker.
Note: The series is the COVID-19 Government Response Stringency Index which is a composite measure based on nine response indicators including
school closures, workplace closures, and travel bans, rescaled to a value from 0 to 100 (100 = strictest response).
22/01 05/02 19/02 04/03 18/03 01/04 15/04 29/04 13/05 27/05 10/06 24/06
2020
miles, stedmaN aNd Heald liviNg witH covid-19: balaNciNg costs agaiNst beNefits iN tHe face of tHe viRus R65
and consistent with initial reproduction numbers (the
average number of people infected by each person with
the virus) far in excess of 1 and quite likely close to 3.
(ii) In late February or early March 2020 many European
countries brought in severe restrictions on movement,
meaning that the majority of populations stayed
home and numbers able to work fell dramatically.
Such restrictions came in earlier in countries where the
numbers recorded with the infection had risen sharply
earliest – most notably Italy. There were also places
where restrictions were much less severe than in most
countries – most notably in Sweden.
(iii) New measured cases of the infection and of deaths
ascribed to the virus were signicantly lower within
a few weeks of restrictions being introduced. There
is some evidence of a attening in new cases ahead of
severe restrictions being introduced.
(iv) The slowing in new infections and in deaths has been
marked in all countries during late March and into
April 2020, though the severity of restrictions and the
timing of those restrictions differs.
2. How much was due to lockdowns?
What is not clear from data on measured deaths of
people who are recorded as having the virus, on tested
new cases of the infection and on excess deaths is the
precise extent to which they have fallen because of (in
many cases severe) restrictions on the population. There
are at least three reasons why new infections and deaths
could have fallen, perhaps sharply, even with much more
limited government restrictions short of a lockdown: (i)
individuals would have altered their behaviour (washing
hands more frequently, avoiding crowded spaces, staying
home if you have symptoms) with no legal restrictions
on ability to leave the home and with much more limited
disruption to life; (ii) a degree of immunity may have built
up by the time severe restrictions were introduced because
the infection may have spread quite widely and largely
unnoticed with the asymptomatic a large fraction of the
infected. (iii) a signicant proportion of the population
may have been effectively immune from the virus when
lockdowns started not just because of recovery from past
infections that conferred a degree of immunity but also
because some proportion of the population was never
susceptible. All three factors may have played some role,
and all would mean that deaths and new infections would
have slowed, at least to some extent, in the absence of
the sort of severe government restrictions introduced in
the UK where people were told to stay at home except in
exceptional circumstances.
These three factors are not mutually exclusive and
there is some (less than conclusive and often disputed)
evidence that each of them may have played some role.
An Oxford University research team used death data to
estimate the proportion of the population who might
have built up some form of immunity before the UK
lockdown was introduced in mid-March. They put that
fraction at around 60 per cent (Lourenço et al., (2020).
Stedman et al. (2020) used data on differences in the
spread of the infection across English regions to assess
how many might have been infected and put that fraction
at similarly high levels. Dimdore-Miles and Miles (2020)
tted a SIR (Susceptible-Infected-Recovered) model to
data on new cases of infections across several countries
and estimated that the numbers who might have been
infected with no (or few) symptoms was likely to be
ten times or more as large as those who had symptoms
and were more likely to have been tested up to late
April 2020. This is at the high end of estimates of the
asymptomatic as a proportion of the infected.
Wieland (2020) modelled the spread of the infection
across Germany and concluded that infections were
past their peak and starting to decline ahead of the
introduction of government restrictions there. The
results were summarised thus: “In a large majority
of German counties, the epidemic curve has attened
before the social ban was established (March 23). In
a minority of counties, the peak was already exceeded
before school closures.”
Friston et al. (2020) concluded that the numbers of
people not susceptible to the COVID-19 virus were
substantial before lockdowns were introduced and that
the virus may have been burning itself out.
Despite these pieces of evidence, direct measures
of how many people in the wider population have
been infected by COVID-19, and the extent to which
immunity from the virus has been built up by that
route, are not high. Most estimates based on limited
testing of a random sample of the population for
antibodies put the level of those who have had the
infection in European countries where the virus has
spread most rapidly at 5–10 per cent, though in some
areas within countries it is still high enough to have
had a signicant impact on R.1
While there are reasons to believe that the spread of the
infection may have slowed short of a lockdown which
kept most people at home, it remains highly likely that
this level of restriction did bring the spread down faster
than it otherwise would.
R66 NatioNal iNstitute ecoNomic Review No. 253 august 2020
3. The evidence from countries with
different policies: Sweden vs UK
In contrast to many other European countries the
Swedish strategy has been one of adopting much less
restrictive measures that are far short of a lockdown (see
gure 4). In terms of the health impacts, there is mixed
evidence over how different they are compared to those
in countries that adopted lockdown policies. Cases of
the infection – relative to population - have been higher
than in most other European countries (gure 1); deaths
have not been higher (gure 2). Excess deaths in Sweden
up to end-June have been one third the levels seen in
Italy, Spain and Great Britain.
Interpretation of the raw numbers is therefore not
straightforward. The study by Born et al. (2020)
estimates how the infection might have spread if Sweden
had imposed a lockdown like many other European
countries. They nd essentially no difference in the likely
path of infections.
But the study by Conyon et al. (2020), which compares
deaths in Sweden with those in Norway and Denmark,
nds strong evidence that the looser restrictions in
Sweden compared with its close neighbours led to
signicantly more people dying. The comparison with
immediate neighbours is telling because they are more
similar in terms of climate, health care systems and
density of population than most other countries.
UK data show a signicantly higher cumulative death
rate than Sweden (gure 2 above); Financial Times
estimates, as well as those shown in gure 3 above, put
excess deaths relative to population in the UK at more
than three times the Swedish level by end-June 2020. UK
density of population, age structure and distribution of
income is different from Sweden (and from the European
average) which muddies direct comparison. Figure 3
shows that Sweden sits near the middle of the pack for
European countries. While cumulative death rates for
Sweden remain markedly higher than in its immediate
neighbours, they are not very different from European
averages. Cases of new infections in Sweden during June
2020 did, however, move higher, unlike in most other
European countries where they continued to decline
even as lockdowns have begun to be eased.
There is some, limited, evidence that looser restrictions
in Sweden have meant a lower hit to economic activity.
A recent study by Mackie et al. (2020) notes the stark
contrast between the relative health experience of Sweden
with its immediate neighbours in Denmark and Norway
(much worse) and with the UK (signicantly better). That
report also estimates that the economic performance has
up to June 2020 been somewhat better than Denmark and
Norway and markedly better than the UK. They estimate
that the Swedish economy has benetted by around 6.7
per cent of GDP relative to following the UK prole and
by 2 per cent and 1.4 per cent relative to the Danish and
Norwegian proles respectively.
Krueger, Uhlig and Xie (2020) assess how economies
might have evolved during the pandemic with few
government restrictions. They conclude:
“One may view our results as the “Swedish” outcome:
Sweden has largely avoided government restrictions on
economic activity, allowing people to make their own
choices. These private incentives and well-functioning
labour-and social-insurance markets, we submit, may
solve the COVID19-spread on their own, mitigating
the decline in economic activity.”
How effective was the lockdown in the UK?
There is contradictory evidence on the effectiveness of
the three-month lockdown strategy in the UK. It is hard
to be sure of the precise scale of the health benets: they
range from very few lives saved to a high of perhaps
450,000 lives saved (that is the difference between the
500,000 or so deaths projected by Ferguson et al, 2020,
on the basis of no change in behaviour and the 50,000
or so deaths that might have resulted in the UK by early
June 2020). Figures for lives saved in the UK at the
extreme ends of that spectrum (near zero or as high as
450,000) seem implausible.
The fall in deaths soon after lockdowns is so clear
across many countries that it is very unlikely that those
severe restrictions had no signicant impact at all on
lives lost. Deb et al. (2020) nd signicant impacts of
severe restrictions on new cases of the infection. The
chances that such a sharp slowing in new infections
should consistently have happened across countries
some weeks after the most severe restrictions were
introduced, yet not be partly a result of them, seems
negligible.
But there are also reasons to be sceptical of gures at
the high end of that scale which puts the saving of lives
from the lockdown in the UK at several hundreds of
thousands:
• the low cost of effective forms of behavioural change
(washing hands, avoiding crowds, staying home if
you have symptoms) adopted by individuals makes
miles, stedmaN aNd Heald liviNg witH covid-19: balaNciNg costs agaiNst beNefits iN tHe face of tHe viRus R67
it rather unlikely that in the UK there would have
been 500,000 deaths even with no government
restrictions; the 500,000 gure from Ferguson et al.
(2020) was based on an assumption of no change at
all in individual behaviour;
• the evidence of a turn in the curve before lockdowns
are likely to have had much effect is much disputed
but not easily dismissed;
• even if lockdowns stopped such huge numbers of deaths
over the period March-June 2020, they may not have
permanently stopped them happening if wider immunity
has not signicantly risen so that any substantial easing
of restrictions will just bring them back;
• in the UK deaths were concentrated in care homes
for the elderly (where around 30 per cent of deaths
have occurred) and have been disproportionately
among older people so a blanket lockdown (‘don’t
leave home’) may have been inefcient – it generated
substantial costs (see below) and may have yielded
limited health benets over and above what might
have been achieved with measures which focused on
groups most at risk.
4. The costs of lockdowns
Measurement issues for the costs of lockdowns are
different from those that make the assessment of the
benets difcult, but they are also signicant. While
some of the costs are fairly clear and immediate (GDP
is lower, the scal decit is higher, unemployment has
risen a great deal), even here it is not straightforward to
judge their true scale of cost because of two issues: (a)
how permanent will the losses be? (b) how great would
such problems have been even with no lockdown?
Costs which will come further down the road because
of disruption to healthcare and to education are harder
again to measure relative to the more immediate effects
on economic production and employment.
A great deal of evidence is already emerging on the
(narrow) economic impacts of restrictions. Estimates
made by Deb et al. (2020) to identify the particular
effect of restrictive policies (lockdown) suggest that they
reduced economic activity by 15 per cent in the 30 days
after they were adopted. They nd that stay-at-home
requirements and workplace closures are the costliest
in economic terms. Preliminary estimates from the UK
Ofce for National Statistics showed a slightly more
than 20 per cent fall in GDP in April 2020, the rst full
month after the lockdown. Bonadio et al. (2020) put the
impact on output and incomes (i.e. GDP) of policies to
counter the spread of the infection on GDP averaged
across 64 countries even higher, at around 30 per cent.
Aum et al. (2020) estimate that around one half of all job
losses in the UK and US can be attributed to lockdowns.
Coibion et al. (2020 a) estimate that there were 20 million
lost jobs in the US by 8 April triggered overwhelmingly
by government restrictions, far more than jobs lost
over the entire Great Recession. Furthermore, many
of those losing jobs were not actively looking to nd
new ones. Participation in the labour force declined by
7 percentage points, an unparalleled fall that dwarfs the
three percentage point cumulative decline that occurred
from 2008 to 2016 after the nancial crisis. In a related
paper the same authors undertake surveys of behaviour
and economic outcomes across US regions with different
degrees of restrictions. They conclude:
“We observe a dramatic decline in employment and
consumer spending as well as a bleak outlook for
the next few years. Our estimates suggest that this
economic catastrophe can be largely accounted by
lockdowns.” (Coibion, 2020b)
Around 9 million people (one quarter of the workforce)
have been furloughed in the UK and paid largely by the
government. The OBR reported in May that UK net
government debt rose by over 17 per cent of GDP on a
year earlier to around 100 per cent in April. Extra debt
issuance is likely to be at least 10 per cent of GDP in 2020;
the stock of debt will be well above 100 per cent of GDP
by the end of 2020 and likely to go higher in 2021.
For the UK, the Ofce for Budget Responsibility (OBR)
and the Bank of England estimate that GDP is likely to
have fallen by between 25 per cent and 35 per cent in
2020Q2 and by 10–15 per cent in 2020 relative to 2019;
unemployment may rise to around 10 per cent. The OBR
central estimate, and the illustrative scenario for the
Bank of England made in May 2020, is that in 2020 UK
GDP will be around 13–14 per cent lower than in 2019.
The June Organisation for Economic Cooperation and
Development forecast is for an 11.5 per cent decline in UK
output in 2020 and for output to remain lower in 2021
than it was in 2019. In May, the National Institute of
Economic and Social Research estimated that over a 10-
year period UK output would be lower by a cumulative
amount of around 35 per cent of annual GDP, with much
of that coming in 2020 and 2021.
The estimates from the Bank of England and the OBR
assume that restrictions are eased after June and that
effectively the lockdown is then soon over; it seems
R68 NatioNal iNstitute ecoNomic Review No. 253 august 2020
plausible that their estimates of economic cost are
therefore estimates of the impact of the lockdown that
has been in place in the UK from March to June and
not of a continuation of the lockdown into the second
half of 2020 and beyond. The OBR is explicit about this;
in describing their forecasts they note: “The table below
summarises the results of our three-month lockdown
scenario where economic activity would gradually return
to normal over the subsequent three months.” The
Bank of England in its May economic assessment takes
a similar line: “Underlying the illustrative scenario for
both the UK and the rest of the world is an assumption
that enforced social distancing measures remain in place
until early June and that they are then lifted gradually
over the following four months, until the end of Q3”.
In that illustrative scenario GDP in 2020 is 14 per cent
below the 2019 level (Table 1A, Bank of England May
Monetary Policy Report). But it is hard to be sure how
these assessments would have been different with much
less restrictive policies; economic activity would almost
certainly have been lower, at least to some extent.
Many elements of the cost of the lockdown in the UK are
not reected at all in current incomes, employment and
GDP. Health costs – including mental health – are not yet
showing up in a measurable way. They are likely to be
large and long lasting. Referrals for cancer investigations
were 70 per cent down in April 2020;3 there were hardly
any follow-up routine appointments for long-term
conditions in UK Primary Care between mid-March
2020 and the beginning of June 2020; outpatient seen
were 64 per cent down and elective admissions were
75 per cent down;4 attended appointments in General
Practice were down 35 per cent.5 The impact of the
stress of the lockdown on anyone with a pre-existing
mental health condition, let alone the population as a
whole, is yet to be determined.
The cost from disrupted education of children and
students will be felt over a horizon of many years, even
decades.
5. Bringing costs and benefits together:
Bringing together costs and benets is necessary if good
policy decisions are to be made. There is no simple way
to do this that is clearly ethically justiable, empirically
reliable and widely accepted. But to make no assessment
is just to make policy in a vacuum. One approach is to
focus on quality adjusted life years (QALYs) that may
have been saved as a result of restrictions that have been
in place in the UK up to the end of June and to convert
that to a metric that can be compared with estimates of
the cost of the restrictions. That is the strategy we follow.
We then go on to make estimates of costs and benets
of alternative ways forward with restrictions eased to
different extents.
We make use of the guidelines established in the UK by
the National Institute for Health and Care Excellence
(NICE) for the use of resources in the UK health
system (see NICE, 2013). These are guidelines applied
to resource decisions that have a direct impact on lives
saved. It is hard to see how you could run a public health
care system without such rules. The guidelines in the UK
set out by NICE are that treatments that are expected
to increase life expectancy for a patient by one year (in
quality of life adjusted years, QALYs) should cost no
more than £30,000. We apply that gure to possible
total numbers of QALYs saved by restrictions to estimate
their benet. We also assess the sensitivity of results to
using much higher gures for the value of potential extra
years of life.
To implement this we need to assess how many likely
extra years of good life might be enjoyed by the people
who would have died but for a lockdown. We assume
that the age and health of those who would have died
is similar to that of those who have died with the virus.
The Ofce for National Statistics (ONS) has been
publishing each week the number of deaths where
COVID-19 has been recorded as a possible cause by
quinary age and gender. In total up to week ending 22
May this was 43,694 in England and Wales. (This total
is 21 per cent below the excess all causes deaths gure
of 55,504 up to the week ending 24 May (Week 21)
calculated by comparing the actual recorded number in
2020 to the average deaths over previous three years in
the same period).
By applying the average life expectancy6 to the actual
recorded COVID-19 deaths by age and gender, a total
life expectancy years lost can calculated. The table below
shows the calculation. Average life expectancy loss comes
out at 10.1 years per COVID-19 death. (The average life
expectancy years lost for a non-COVID death is only
slightly higher at 11.4, conrming that the age prole
for COVID mortality matches natural mortality.) The
median COVID-19 age at death is around 80 and the
average life years lost for the older 50 per cent is ve
years and the for younger 50 per cent is fteen years.
The average gure of 10.1 years of life lost does not
account for the fact that those who have died with
COVID-19 have often been in poor health, conditional
on their age. In their detailed study of 23,804 hospital
miles, stedmaN aNd Heald liviNg witH covid-19: balaNciNg costs agaiNst beNefits iN tHe face of tHe viRus R69
deaths in England from COVID-19 from 1 March 2020
to 11 May 2020, Valabhji et al. (2020) found that various
different life-shortening risk factors were signicantly
more prevalent in those patients who died of COVID-19
than in the general population. This included Diabetes
(33 per cent vs 5 per cent), and previous hospital
admission for signicant cardiovascular comorbidities
including coronary heart disease (31 per cent vs 3.5 per
cent), cerebrovascular disease (19.8 per cent vs 1.5 per
cent) and heart failure (17.7 per cent vs 1 per cent).
Other comorbidities such as dementia in its various
forms, chronic obstructive pulmonary disease (COPD),
vitamin D deciency, and hyperlipidaemia were not
collected and compared, but it is plausible that these
would also show similar levels of differences. Each of
these comorbidities has been shown to increase the
risk of early death signicantly. The National Diabetes
Audit in its mortality study7 found that the presence of
diabetes increases a person’s standard mortality risk by
a factor of 1.6.
It is, therefore, plausible that those patients who died of
COVID-19 were, on average, already in relatively poor
health for their age and this poor health would give them
a life expectancy, on average, signicantly below that of
the age-equivalent general population.
These comorbidities and conditions also reduce the
person’s quality of life, as well as its quantity (see Clarke
et al., 2002). The impact of poor heath through long-term
conditions and comorbidities are usually incorporated
into modelling through a quality of life utility factor
which ranges from 1 (healthy) to 0 (death); this is used
to adjust the total life years. Beaudet et al. (2014), found
that the basic type 2 diabetes without complication had
a factor of 0.79 and then other comorbidities would
reduce this further, including Myocardial infarction
−0.06, Ischemic heart disease −0.09, Heart failure −0.11,
and Stroke –0.16. An average poor health utility factor
of 0.8 could be applied to the population of those who
have died with COVID-19.
A substantial downwards adjustment to the ten years
estimate of the residual life expectancy based on the
general population would seem appropriate for the
group who have died with COVID-19. To get to an
estimate of average quality adjusted years of life lost,
Table 1. The age structure of deaths in 2020
Up to Total Deaths COVID-19 Total Deaths Life Expectancy (Years) Total Expected Life
24 May 2020
Age Group Male Female Male Female Male Female Non COVID COVID-19
<1 576 446 2 0 79.3 82.9 82,476 159
1–4 89 64 0 1 77.1 80.7 11,949 81
5–9 56 31 0 0 72.6 76.3 6,432 0
10–14 61 54 0 1 67.7 71.3 7,907 71
15–19 203 100 5 4 62.7 66.3 18,787 579
20–24 325 142 13 9 57.8 61.4 26,214 1,305
25–29 465 208 29 16 53 56.5 33,950 2,440
30–34 654 358 46 29 48.2 51.6 46,259 3,712
35–39 1,003 635 65 49 43.4 46.7 68,081 5,110
40–44 1,406 856 139 81 38.7 41.9 81,497 8,772
45–49 2,326 1,568 256 153 34.1 37.1 123,136 14,412
50–54 3,884 2,469 476 277 29.6 32.5 172,061 23,085
55–59 5,633 3,625 876 417 25.2 27.9 209,590 33,741
60–64 7,640 5,019 1,234 617 21 23.6 238,458 40,495
65–69 10,575 6,848 1,643 845 17.1 19.3 268,990 44,464
70–74 16,314 11,331 2,665 1,406 13.4 15.4 335,960 57,429
75–79 20,131 15,452 3,640 2,235 10.2 11.7 322,234 63,145
80–84 24,854 22,256 4,782 3,478 7.3 8.5 306,689 64,625
85–89 25,537 28,624 4,650 4,234 5.1 5.9 249,665 48,572
90+ 22,873 42,080 3,812 5,509 2.9 3.2 172,665 28,711
Total 144,605 142,166 24,333 19,361 2,783,000 440,907
Mean age 76.9 81.5 78.7 82.5
Non Covid-19 243,077 Covid-19 43,694 Lost Years/Death 11.4 10.1
Note: Total expected life years lost is the sum of lives lost multiplied by remaining life expectancy for each age group. Average lost years per death is
total expected life years lost divided by total deaths.
R70 NatioNal iNstitute ecoNomic Review No. 253 august 2020
some adjustment for both lower life expectancy, and
perhaps also for lower quality of life, is justiable.
How great an adjustment is hard to be precise
about, but it might plausibly be by one half. In the
calculations below we apply either no adjustments for
co-morbidities or an adjustment of one-half, using lost
average quality adjusted years per COVID19 death of
ten or ve years.
A cost benefit analysis of the lockdown:
Suppose that a group of people who each had an
expected quality-adjusted remaining years of life of
ten years, and who might have died with the virus,
has been spared that because of severe government
restrictions (‘the lockdown’). We will assume that the
benet of the restrictions that prevented such deaths
are the value of ten quality-adjusted years of life
multiplied by the number of lives saved. The NICE
£30,000 threshold is an assessment of the (maximum)
resource cost that would be justied for the UK health
service to make an expected saving of one quality
adjusted year of life. To save ten QALY would be
worth up to £300,000.
We initially apply this gure of £300,000 (or a gure of
£150,000 if we make an adjustment for co-morbidities
and take ve average quality-adjusted life years lost per
death) to estimates of the possible number of lives saved
as a result of lockdowns to give an overall benet number.
(The impact of using much higher values for extra years
of life is discussed shortly.) We compare that aggregate
number with an estimate of the cost of the lockdown. As
noted above there is no single, reliable estimate of lives
that have been saved by the UK lockdown and nor is there
a widely accepted single gure for the comprehensive
overall cost of the lockdown (which should include lost
and damaged lives into the future as a result of severe
restrictions and not just lost incomes in 2020). There is
much uncertainty here and presenting a single estimate
of costs and benets is not sensible. So we present a
range of estimated costs and benets based on a wide
range of assumptions that we think encompass plausible
upper and lower limits on both costs and benets.
At the high end of estimated lives saved is the
difference between the projected deaths from the
study of Professor Ferguson’s group at Imperial
assuming no change in behaviour (500,000) less an
estimate of excess UK deaths (approximately 60,000
by June 2020). This 440,000 net lives saved number
is likely to be a signicant overestimate of likely lives
saved. As noted above it does not account for changes
in behaviour that would have occurred without the
government lockdown; it does not count future higher
deaths from side effects of the lockdown (extra cancer
deaths for example); and it does not allow for the fact
that some of those ‘saved’ deaths may just have been
postponed because when restrictions are eased, and in
the absence of a vaccine or of widespread immunity,
deaths may pick up again. (If the epidemic is dying out
anyway those deaths will not come as the lockdown is
eased but in this case the 440,000 saved lives is also
excessive because the lockdown may have come as a
decline in infections was happening for other reasons).
At the other end of the spectrum would be estimates of
net saved lives that are effectively zero. That too seems
very unlikely. We set the lowest estimated net saved lives
well above that and use (rather arbitrarily) a ‘lowest’
estimate of 20,000.
For each life saved we apply a factor of either ve or ten
quality-adjusted extra years of life, each initially valued
with the NICE guideline gure of £30,000.
On the cost side, the lowest estimate is just to count the
GDP that would have been produced in 2020 but for
the lockdown established in March and assuming the
lockdown to be eased from the end of June. This assumes
a rapid bounce-back by the end of the year so there is
no effect on incomes and output from the start of 2021
onwards. That was the scenario envisaged by the Bank of
England in their May 2020 assessment of the economic
outlook, when they put the GDP loss in 2020 at around
14 per cent. The OBR estimate for lost output in 2020,
also based on an assumed rapid recovery in the second
half of the year, is close to 13 per cent. It seems plausible
that a large fraction of these estimates of lost output is due
to the lockdown. Even absent a government mandated
lockdown there would have been some reduction in
incomes, but with no restrictions on leaving home and
most workplaces still open it seems likely the hit to
GDP would have been far less. Simulations undertaken
by Bradley et al. (2020), using a model of behavioural
choice about work calibrated to the UK, show that absent
a lockdown falls in output and employment would be
very much lower than with a lengthy lockdown. If the
lockdown effect was two thirds of what the OBR and
Bank of England suggest is the loss in GDP for 2020, that
might imply around a 9 per cent fall in GDP as a direct
result of it. That is around £200 billion.
That 9 per cent of GDP cost is likely to be a low-end
estimate of overall costs of the UK lockdown from mid-
March to late June; it assumes lost output from the rst
half of 2020 comes back quickly, it ignores wider health
miles, stedmaN aNd Heald liviNg witH covid-19: balaNciNg costs agaiNst beNefits iN tHe face of tHe viRus R71
costs of future lives damaged,9 and it assumes zero costs
from disruption to the education of the young.10
At the high end of the spectrum would be an estimate of
15 per cent of GDP lost in 2020 and lower output for the
next few years on top of that, as economic activity does
not return to normal for several years with some rms
permanently damaged by the lockdown and the large rise
in unemployment slow to be reversed, even if restrictions
are quickly removed from mid-2020. A shortfall of GDP
of 15 per cent in 2020, 7.5 per cent in 2021 and 2.5 per
cent in 2022, would be at the more pessimistic end of
the spectrum for the impact of the March-June lockdown,
though for many economists such a gure seems realistic
rather than pessimistic.11 The cumulative lost output
would then be 25 per cent of GDP.
It should be stressed that these are scenarios – not
forecasts. But we believe they cover high and low ends of
a plausible range for both costs and benets of lockdown.
Tables 2 and 3 below show the cost-benet calculations
of the lockdown based on such ranges: in each cell we
report three numbers: benets (+), costs (–) and (in red)
the balance of the two – all measured as £ billions.
The fous here is on the lockdown that was in place
up to the end of June. In the next section we consider
policy going forwards from then and factor in explicitly
scenarios where infections and deaths rise again as a
result of relaxing restrictions.
For every permutation of lives saved and GDP lost the
costs of lockdown exceed the benets. Even if lives saved
Table 2. Benefits (+), costs (–) and net benefits(a) of March-June UK lockdown; converted to an index of £bn, 5 QALY
are assumed lost for each COVID-19 death
9% GDP loss 15% GDP loss 20% GDP loss 25% GDP loss
Lives not lost
440,000 £66b, –£200b, £66b, –£330b, £66b, –£440b, £66b, –£550b,
–£134b –£264b –£374b –£484b
200,000 £30b, –£200b, £30b, –£330b, £30b, –£440b, £30b, –£550b,
–£170b –£300b –£410b –£520b
100,000 £15b, –£200b, £15b, –£330b, £15b, –£440b, £15b, –£550b,
–£185b –£315b –£425b –£535b
50,000 £8b, –£200b, £8b, –£330b, £8b, –£440b, £8b, –£550b,
–£192b –£322b –£432b –£542b
20,000 £3b, –£200b, £3b, –£330b, £3b, –£440b, £3b, –£550b,
–£197b –£327b –437b –£547b
Notes: Each life saved is estimated to result in 5 more quality adjusted years of life. The NICE resource threshold of £30,000 is applied to each of these
quality adjusted years. The money value of GDP losses is taken as a proportion of 2019 GDP of £2.2 trillion. All resulting figures are in £ billions.
(a) Net benefits are shown in red.
Table 3. Benefits (+), costs (–) and net benefits(a) of March-June UK lockdown; converted to an index of £bn, 10 QALY
are assumed lost for each COVID-19 death
9% GDP loss 15% GDP loss 20% GDP loss 25% GDP loss
Lives not lost
440,000 £132b, –£200b, £132b, –£330b, £132b, –£440b, £132b, –£550b,
–£68b –£198b –£308b –£418b
200,000 £60b, –£200b, £60b, –£330b, £60b, –£440b, £60b, –£550b,
–£140b –£270b –£380b –£490b
100,000 £30b, –£200b, £30b, –£330b, £30b, –£440b, £30b, –£550b,
–£170b –£300b –£410b –£520b
50,000 £15b, –£200b, £15b, –£330b, £15b, –£440b, £15b, –£550b,
–£185b –£315b –£425b –£535b
20,000 £6b, –£200b, £6b, –£330b, £6b, –£440b, £6b, –£550b,
–£194b –£324b –434b –£544b
Notes: Each life saved is estimated to result in 10 more quality adjusted years of life. The NICE resource threshold of £30,000 is applied to each of these
quality adjusted years. The money value of GDP losses is taken as a proportion of 2019 GDP of £2.2 trillion. All resulting figures are in £ billions.
(a) Net benefits are shown in red.
R72 NatioNal iNstitute ecoNomic Review No. 253 august 2020
are as high as 440,000, each of which means an extra ten
years of quality adjusted life – and when the lost output
(assumed to be a sufcient and comprehensive measure of
all costs of the lockdown) is simply the likely shortfall in
incomes in 2020 – costs are still over 50 per cent higher
than the benets of a three month lockdown (benets =
£132 billion; costs = £200 billion). In all other cases costs
are a multiple of benets. In most cases costs are 10 times
or more the scale of benets. This result reects the fact
that the economic costs of a three month lockdown – even
on the most conservative estimate of £200 billion – is
probably far larger than annual total expenditure on the
UK national health service (which runs at around £130
billion); the benets of that level of resources applied to
health and using the NICE guidelines would be expected to
generate far more lives saved than is plausibly attributable
to the lockdown in the UK.
Another way of making the same point is that the cost
per QALY saved of the lockdown looks to be far in
excess (generally by a factor of at least 3 and often by a
factor of 10 and more) of that considered acceptable for
health treatments in the UK.
Sensitivity to the value of extra years of life:
Taken at face value, the numbers in tables 2 and 3
would suggest a lockdown that lasted three months
was not an effective policy and that severe restrictions
should have been eased sooner because the economic
costs of such protracted restrictions on mobility have
been high relative to likely benets. But there is much
uncertainty, indeed controversy, about how to value
potential lives saved and that conclusion is sensitive to
whether using the NICE gure of £30,000 for valuing
a potential year of life saved is sensible. As noted by
Layard et al. (2020), a much higher gure per QALY of
£60,000 is often advocated. If we use that gure all the
benet numbers in tables 2 and 3 would be doubled.
But of the 40 permutations of scenarios in tables 2 and
3 the result that costs of a three-month lockdown are
greater than benets would then only be overturned in
one case.
Might it be that such calculations massively understate
the benets of lockdown? That would be the case if
the value of potential years of life saved is dramatically
too low; some would say that it is. Layard et al. (2020)
advocate enormously higher levels.12 Estimates used in
the US for the statistical value of a life place it slightly
above $10 million (see Viscusi, 2020 and 2018, and
Murphy and Topel, 2006). For a new-born who might
expect 80 good years of life, the NICE £30,000 number
would generate a life value of £2.4 million – just under
a third of the value if a statistical life is worth $10
million. Adler (2020) presents powerful arguments why
using such high VSL gures may be inappropriate for
assessing policy with respect to COVID-19, especially if
the impact of lockdowns falls disproportionately on the
less well off.
Goldstein and Lee (2020) note that US health economists
use values of around $125,000 per year of life. That is
a bit over three times the NICE gure. However, the
£30,000 gure per QALY is the gure used in resource
decisions within the UK health system. It is not an
arbitrary number. It is not based on likely future earnings
lost or the value of future consumption – calculations that
are open to the moral objection that they reduce the value
of human life to how much people would have spent on
commodities. Instead the gure we use for the value of
a QALY is a measure of what is considered the highest
level of resources (i.e. what part of GDP) in the UK health
system that should be used to generate extra quality
adjusted years of life – and it is saving of lives which is
what the lockdown was for. In using this yardstick, we are
treating decisions on how to face COVID-19 in the same
way as decisions in the UK are made about resources to
apply to the treatment of cancer, heart disease, dementia
and diabetes. On that basis it would seem as though the
benets of the three-month lockdown were likely to have
been lower – perhaps far lower – than its costs. Yet even
if one used a valuation of a QALY three times as great, the
gures in tables 2 and 3 (with benets raised by a factor
of 3) would still generate costs of the lockdown in excess
of benets in nearly all the cases considered.
That judgement is, however, made with the benet of
hindsight; we now know more about the scale of the
economic costs of the lockdown than was known in
March 2020, and also know about how deaths and
new infections have evolved across Europe. The more
interesting policy issue is what it is best to do now; how
quickly should the lockdown be eased given what we
know now? That issue we consider in the next section.
6. What policy to adopt now?
We apply a similar cost-benet methodology to consider
policy options for the level of restrictions applied in the
UK over the next 3 months (July–September 2020). The
options we consider fall under two broad headings:
1) Carry on with only very limited easing of restrictions.
2) Move quickly to minimal lockdown (easing restrictions
for the general population rapidly, focusing resources
on high risk groups and relying on existing tracking
miles, stedmaN aNd Heald liviNg witH covid-19: balaNciNg costs agaiNst beNefits iN tHe face of tHe viRus R73
of the cases/deaths to help prevent re-emergence of
the virus).
We consider the following scenarios for the consequences
of each policy for the evolution of COVID-19 deaths:
1. Very limited easing of restrictions results in a
continuing steady fall in the death rate over 13 weeks
down to single gures per week at the end of three
months. Each week deaths are assumed to be 0.7 x
deaths of the previous week.
2. For the policy of more rapid easing of restrictions we
consider three possible scenarios:
(i) Deaths continue to fall but at a signicantly slower rate
than with a slow and limited easing of lockdown; each
week deaths are 0.9 x deaths of the previous week.
(ii) Deaths move back to the start-June level of 1,230 per
week and stay there.
(iii)Deaths steadily increase back up to levels seen at the
height of the UK pandemic; each week over a three-
month period they are 15 per cent higher than the
week before.
These are macabre thought experiments and many
will feel uneasy at such calculations. But there are
implications in terms of deaths and misery on both sides
of the ledger from any policy. To think such comparisons
are distasteful is to not face that reality.
The assumed paths of deaths under the four scenarios
is shown in table 4. In each case we set the initial level
of deaths in the week prior to each scenario at the last
ONS recorded gure for UK deaths in the week to 12
June (1230 deaths).
The implied cost of the extra deaths from the easing
policies (under scenarios i, ii. and iii) are shown towards
the bottom of the table. These are the projected excess
deaths under each easing scenario relative to the policy
of continuing with the lockdown multiplied by the lost
QALY per death and valued at £30,000 per QALY. These
numbers are in £ billions and should be set against the
estimated benets from easing the lockdown.
Our low-end estimate of the (narrowly dened) cost of the
March to June lockdown was 9 per cent of GDP – a gure
of £200 billion. One might assume that a continuation
of the lockdown over the next three months with only
a very limited easing of restrictions generates a further
cost of the same size. But rapid easing of restrictions
is unlikely to mean narrowly dened economic activity
(GDP) just bounces back. A conservative estimate of the
narrowly dened economic benets of quickly easing the
lockdown is that the £200 billion cost under lockdown
Table 4. Deaths and costs of deaths under different unlocking scenarios
from 12/6/2020 Continue Lockdown (0.7) Ease Scenario i (0.9) Ease Scenario ii (1) Ease Scenario iii (1.15)
week 1 861 1,107 1,230 1,415
week 2 603 996 1,230 1,627
week 3 422 896 1,230 1,871
week 4 295 806 1,230 2,152
week 5 207 725 1,230 2,475
week 6 145 653 1,230 2,846
week 7 102 588 1,230 3,273
week 8 71 529 1,230 3,764
week 9 50 476 1,230 4,329
week 10 35 428 1,230 4,978
week 11 25 385 1,230 5,725
week 12 18 347 1,230 6,584
week 13 13 312 1,230 7,572
Total expected deaths 2,847 8,248 15,990 48,611
Additional expected deaths compared to Lockdown 5,401 13,143 45,764
Cost of easing (£ billions) – each add. death = 5 QALY
valued at £30,000 £0.81 £1.97 £6.86
Cost of easing (£ billions) – each add. death = 10 QALY
valued at £30,000 £1.62 £3.94 £13.73
Note: Deaths are assumed to evolve week by week from the level in the week ending 12 June (1230) by a factor 0.7; 0.9; 1.0; 1.15 for the lockdown and
scenarios i, ii and iii respectively. So, for example, under the most pessimistic scenario iii, deaths each week are 1.15 times deaths in the previous week.
R74 NatioNal iNstitute ecoNomic Review No. 253 august 2020
might become half that size. This would generate a
benet from easing of £100 billion over three months to
be set against any extra lives lost.
Based on that assumption, under all scenarios the cost
of easing restrictions is much lower than its benets –
the maximum cost of £14 billion should be set against
an estimate of benets of £100 billion. One would
need to value QALYs at over seven times the NICE
guideline value of £30,000 to make a continuation of
the lockdown warranted.
Figure 5 presents the same information in a slightly
different way, calculating the net costs of an extension
of the lockdown relative to a policy of immediate
easing. To be clear what we are comparing here are
the costs and benets over a three-month period. The
two alternative strategies would leave the country in
different positions at the end of three months – under
no change to the lockdown the scenario is one with low
deaths and low numbers of people currently infected
at the end of three months. Under the alternative
scenarios the current numbers of those infected at the
end of three months would be greater (and under the
worse scenario would be growing). If it was obvious
that starting from the rst scenario three months
ahead (continued lockdown) was clearly better than
the scenarios where more people were infected (the
three easing scenarios) then it would not be a complete
analysis just to focus on costs and benets over the rst
three months. But in fact it is not obvious that starting
from lockdown three months ahead with low numbers
infected is better. The numbers of people who had ever
been infected would be lower than under the other
scenarios and so the susceptible population would be
greater, so that the impact of then easing restrictions, in
the absence of a vaccine, would be worse.
Once again we stress that the favourable assessment
of easing restrictions versus continuing with a blanket
lockdown is conditional on an assumption about the
value of potential extra years of life. But it would take a
valuation of extra possible years of life massively higher
than that used to guide public health decisions in the
UK to mean that a continuation of lockdown plausibly
looked the better strategy.
Notes: The net extra economic costs of the lockdown relative to easing of restrictions is assumed to be £100 billion. To
that is added the cost of lives lost under lockdown. The benefit of lives not lost, relative to the easing of restrictions, is
then deducted from the lockdown costs to generate a net cost figure under the three scenarios. The easing scenarios are:
(i) deaths still decline but slower than in lockdown, (ii) deaths remain at start June 2020 levels, (iii) deaths increase again
back up to April 2020 peak levels. The equivalent cost/QALY is calculated by dividing the lockdown costs (£100 billion)
by the net number of lives not lost in that scenario times the number of QALYs for each death.
£60 £70 £80 £90 £100 £110 £120
Economic Impact of further 3months Lockdown
QALY Value of Additional 2847 lives lost
Scenario 1: QALY Value of 8248 lives not lost
Scenario 2: QALY Value of 15990 lives not lost
Scenario 3: QALY Value of 48611 lives not lost
Lowest Lockdown Net Costs
Economic Impact of further 3months Lockdown
QALY Value of Additional 2847 lives lost
Scenario 1: QALY Value of 8248 lives not lost
Scenario 2: QALY Value of 15990 lives not lost
Scenario 3: QALY Value of 48611 lives not lost
Lowest Lockdown Net Costs
Cumulative Economic Costs & QALY Value £ billion
Figure 5. Scenarios for costs and benefits of different policies
EACH FUTURE COVID-19 DEATH = 5 QALY @ £30,000/QALY
EACH FUTURE COVID-19 DEATH = 10 QALY @ £30,000/QALY
£100b
£0.43b
£1.2b (equiv.£3.7m/QALY)
£2.4b (equiv.£1.5m/QALY)
£7.3b (equiv.£0.44m/QALY)
£100b
£0.85b
£2.5b (equiv.£1.9m/QALY)
£4.8b (equiv.£0.8m/QALY)
£14.6b (equiv.£0.22m/QALY)
£93.1b
£86.3b
miles, stedmaN aNd Heald liviNg witH covid-19: balaNciNg costs agaiNst beNefits iN tHe face of tHe viRus R75
7. Conclusions
We nd that the costs of the three-month lockdown in
the UK are likely to have been high relative to benets,
so that a continuation of severe restrictions is unlikely to
be warranted. There is a need to normalise how we view
COVID-19 because its costs and risks are comparable to
other health problems (such as cancer, heart problems,
diabetes) where governments have made resource
decisions for decades. Treating possible future COVID-19
deaths as if little else matters is going to lead to bad
outcomes. Good decision-making does not mean paying
little attention to the collateral damage that comes from
responding to a worst case COVID-19 scenario.
The lockdown is a public health policy and we have
valued its impact using the tools that guide health care
decisions in the UK public health system. On that basis,
and taking a wide range of scenarios of costs and benets
of severe restrictions, we nd that having extended the
lockdown for as long as three months is likely to have
generated costs that are greater than likely benets.
Weighing up costs and benets of maintaining general
and severe restrictions is necessary. That is how decisions
over a wide range of public policy issues are made –
many directly concerning public health issues. While
there are inevitably risks in easing restrictions there are
very clear costs in not doing so – a policy of ‘let’s wait
until things are clearer’ is not reliably prudent.
We nd that a movement away from blanket restrictions
that bring large, lasting and widespread costs, and
towards measures targeted specically at groups most at
risk is now prudent. Such a policy should probably have
been started before the end of June 2020.
NOTES
1 It is possible that serology testing for past COVID-19 infection
based on the presence of antibodies is not picking up cases
where the infected had very few symptoms and not identifying
others who are nonetheless not susceptible to the virus.
2 https://www.ft.com/content/a26fbf7e-48f8-11ea-aeb3-
955839e06441.
3 http://www.pulsetoday.co.uk/clinical/clinical-specialties/
respiratory-/gp-urgent-cancer-referrals-decline-by-more-than-
70-as-fewer-patients-come-forward/20040662.article.
4 https://www.england.nhs.uk/statistics/statistical-work-areas/
hospital-activity/monthly-hospital-activity/mar-data/.
5 https://digital.nhs.uk/data-and-information/publications/
statistical/appointments-in-general-practice/april-2020.
6 Using ONS Life Tables based on the normal mortality
rates for each cardinal age and gender: (https://www.
ons.gov.uk/peoplepopulationandcommunity/
birthsdeathsandmarriages/lifeexpectancies/datasets/
nationallifetablesunitedkingdomreferencetables.7 Th e i r
mortality study is available at https://digital.nhs.uk/data-and-
information/publications/statistical/national-diabetes-audit/
report-2--complications-and-mortality-2017-18 .
8 In fact the lasting effects of job losses in the UK seem very
substantial. Typical estimates are of a lasting wage penalty from
unemployment of 8–10% and an employment penalty of 6-9%
(Arulampalam et al., 2001, Tumino 2015). The impacts are
particularly severe for young people.
9 Recent work by, among others, Carol Propper, of Imperial
College, and researchers at the Institute for Fiscal Studies (IFS)
suggests that the relatively modest increases in unemployment
associated with the 2008–9 financial crisis may have resulted
in 900,000 more people of working age suffering from chronic
health problems. See Propper et al. (2020).
10 Work by Anna Vignoles and Simon Burgess shows that such
costs are likely to be significant.
11 Layard et al. have a central estimate of the total lost GDP from
a lockdown that was lifted at the end of June of 22.8%; if the
lockdown lasted one month longer, their central estimate is that
the total cumulative loss of GDP would be 29.4%. Gottlieb et
al. (2020) conclude that “Overall, a realistic lockdown policy
implies GDP losses of 20–25% on an annualized basis”
12 In an annex they say that they would use a value for a QALY
that is 25 times greater than the NHS guideline level. To use
figures this high would seem to imply that the health system in
the UK should have massively more resources – not just higher
by 10% or 20% above its current level but so as to take spending
to a vastly greater share of GDP. If that really reflected how
people value potential years of life saved one would need to ask
why the political system has never generated a level of health
spending anywhere near those levels, either in the UK or any
other country. One would also need to ask why private health
spending in the UK is not greatly higher than 1.5% of GDP.
REFERENCES
Adler, M. (2020), 'What should we spend to save lives in a pandemic?
A critique of the value of statistical life', Covid Economics, 33, June.
Aum, S., Lee, S.Y. (Tim) and Shin, Y. (2020), ‘Doesn’t need
lockdowns to destroy jobs: the effect of local outbreaks in
Korea’, CEPR Discussion Paper 14822.
Arulampalam, W., Gregg, P. and Gregory, M. (2001), ‘Unemployment
scarring’, The Economic Journal, 111(475), F577–F584.
Beaudet, A., Clegg, J., Thuresson, P., Lloyd, A. and McEwan, P.
(2014), ‘Review of utility values for economic modeling in Type
2 Diabetes’, Value in Health, 17, 4, June, pp. 462–70.
Bonadio, B., Huo, Z., Levchenko, A.A. and Pandalai-Nayar, N.
(2020), ‘Global supply chains in the pandemic’, NBER Working
Paper 27224, May.
Bongaerts, D., Mazzola, F. and Wagner, W. (2020), ‘Closed for
business’, CEPR Discussion Paper 14814, May.
Born, B., Dietrich, A.M. and Müller, G.J. (2020), ‘Do lockdowns
work? A counterfactual for Sweden’, Covid Economics, 16, May.
Bradley, J., Ruggieri, A. and Spencer, A.H. (2020, 'Twin peaks:
Covid-19 and the labor market', Covid Economics, 21, May 2020.
Clarke, P., Gray, A. and Holman, R. (2002), ‘Estimating utility values
for health states of type 2 diabetic patients using the EQ-5D
(UKPDS 62)’, Med Decision Making, 22, pp. 340–9.
Coibion, O., Gorodnichenko, Y. and Weber, M. (2020a), ‘Labor
markets during the Covid-19 crisis: a preliminary view’, Covid
Economics, 21, May.
—(2020b), ‘The cost of the COVID-19 crisis: lockdowns,
macroeconomic expectations, and consumer spending’, Covid
R76 NatioNal iNstitute ecoNomic Review No. 253 august 2020
1/2020.03.24.20042291, March.
Murphy, K.M. and Topel, R.H. (2006), ‘The value of health and
longevity’, Journal of Political Economy, 114, 5, October, pp.
871–904.
Mackie, D., Alexandersson, L. and Monks, A. (2020), Sweden’s
Approach to COVID-19: Some Early Comparisons, JP Morgan
Report, 25 June.
NICE (2013), How NICE measures value for money in relation to
public health interventions, 1 September, available at: nice.org.
uk/guidance/lgb10.
Propper, C., Stoye, G. and Zaranko, B. (2020), ‘The wider impacts
of the coronavirus pandemic on the NHS’, IFS briefing, available
at: https://www.ifs.org.uk/publications/14798, April.
Stedman, M., Davies, M., Lunt, M., Verma, A., Anderson, S.G. and
Heald, A.H. (2020), ‘A phased approach to unlocking during the
COVID-19 pandemic – lessons from trend analysis’, forthcoming
in International Journal of Clinical Practice.
Tumino, A. (2015), ‘The scarring effect of unemployment from the
early ‘90s to the Great Recession’, Institute for Economic and
Social Research Working Paper 2015-5.
Valabhji, J., Holman, N., Knighton, P., Kar, P., O’Keefe, J., Curley,
M., Weaver, A., Barron, E., Bakhai, C., Khunti, K., Wareham,
N., Sattar, N. and Young, B. (2020), ‘Type 1 and Type 2 diabetes
and COVID-19 related mortality in England: a cohort study in
people with diabetes’, pre print available at https://www.england.
nhs.uk/wp-content/uploads/2020/05/Valabhji-COVID-19-and-
Diabetes-Paper-2-Full-Manuscript.pdf.
Viscusi, W.K. (2018), Pricing Lives: Guideposts for a Safer Society,
Princeton University Press.
—(2020), ‘Pricing the lives saved by coronavirus policies’, New IZA
World of Labor Commentaries on the Coronavirus Crisis, 27 March:
https://wol.iza.org/opinions.
Wieland, T. (2020), ‘Flatten the curve! Modeling SARS-CoV-2/
COVID-19 growth in Germany on the county level’, pre print
available at https://www.medrxiv.org/content/10.1101/2020.0
5.14.20101667v2.
Economics, 20, May.
Martin, J., Conyon, L. H. and Thomsen, S. (2020), ‘Lockdowns and
COVID-19 deaths in Scandinavia’, Covid Economics, 26, pp. 17–42.
Deb, P., Furceri, D., Ostry, J.D. and Tawk, N. (2020), ‘The economic
effects of Covid-19 containment measures’, Covid Economics,
24, May.
Dimdore-Miles, O. and Miles, D. (2020), ‘Assessing the spread of
the novel coronavirus in the absence of mass testing’, Covid
Economics, 16, pp. 161–76, May.
Ferguson et al. (2020), ‘Impact of non-pharmaceutical interventions
(NPIs) to reduce COVID- 19 mortality and healthcare demand’,
Imperial College COVID 19 Response team report, 16 March.
Friston, K.J., Parr, T., Zeidman, P., Razi, A., Flandin, G., Jean
Daunizeau, J., Hulme, O.J., Billig, A.J., Litvak, V., Moran, R.J.,
Price, C.J. and Lambert, C. (2020), ‘Dynamic 19 causal modelling
of Covid 19’, Technical Report available at https://arxiv.org/ftp/
arxiv/papers/2004/2004.04463.pdf.
Goldstein, J.R. and Lee, R.D. (2020), ‘Demographic perspectives on
mortality of COVID-19 and other pandemics’, NBER Working
Paper 27043.
Krueger, D., Uhlig, H. and Xie, T. (2020), ‘Macroeconomic dynamics
and reallocation in an epidemic’, Covid Economics, 5, April.
Layard, R., Clark, A., De Neve, J-E., Krekel, C., Fancourt, D., Hey,
N. and O’Donnell, G. (2020), When to Release the Lockdown: A
Wellbeing Framework for Analysing Costs and Benefits, LSE CEPR,
Occasional paper 49.
Levitt, M. (2020), ‘The corona chronologies’ available at: ‘https://
www.dropbox.com/s/r4gxdvlcnrxet1i/1.The_Corona_
Chronologies.%20Part%20I%20-%20China.%20Part%20II.%20
Rest_of_World_Michael_Levitt%2CStanford_r.pdf?dl=0.
Lourenço, J., Paton, R., Ghafari, M., Kraemer, M.,Thompson, C.,
Simmonds, P., Klenerman, P. and Gupta, S. (2020), ‘Fundamental
principles of epidemic spread highlight the immediate need for
large-scale serological surveys to assess the stage of the SARS-
CoV-2 epidemic’, medRxiv preprint doi: https://doi.org/10.110