ArticlePDF Available

Abstract and Figures

Co-management is advocated as a means to improve human equity and the ecological sustainability of common-pool resources. The promotion of co-management of fisheries often assumes the participation of resource users in decision-making ensures more ecologically sustainable outcomes than top–down management approaches while improving livelihoods and food security. However, in fisheries co-management approaches, participation is often poorly defined and measured by co-management proponents. For resource users, it may not be clear what their participation in co-management entails, and what such participation might involve or achieve. For the fisheries of Lake Victoria (Kenya), the introduction of co-management established Beach Management Units (BMUs) on a model of participatory decision-making. Unsurprisingly, given global experiences of institutions for resource users’ participation in co-management, the structures established across Lake Victoria (Kenya) have not resulted in effective participation of fisher folk. We examine why this is so. Specifically, we examine the influence of institutions on fisher folks’ participation in co-management, using critical institutionalism to explain how participation of resource users is shaped by the relation between formal government institutions and informal social norms. We take four BMUs as case studies to investigate how historical administrative structures shape the development of co-management, how power relationships within co-management are negotiated at the local beach level and the fisher folks’ understanding of their participation in co-management. We document how informal institutions undermine and replace formal institutions at the local beach level, while formal institutions suppress and ignore informal ones at the national and regional levels. From this, we argue power sharing between the government and fisher folk is key for fisher folk participation in fisheries co-management, capable of addressing both social and ecological challenges facing fisheries management.
This content is subject to copyright. Terms and conditions apply.
RESEARCH
Participatory governance in Lake Victoria (Kenya) fisheries: whose
voices are heard?
Christine Adhiambo Etiegni
1,2,3
&Kenneth Irvine
1,2
&Michelle Kooy
1,4
Received: 19 February 2020 / Accepted: 8 July 2020
#The Author(s) 2020
Abstract
Co-management is advocated as a means to improve human equity and the ecological sustainability of common-pool resources.
The promotion of co-management of fisheries often assumes the participation of resource users in decision-making ensures more
ecologically sustainable outcomes than topdown management approaches while improving livelihoods and food security.
However, in fisheries co-management approaches, participation is often poorly defined and measured by co-management
proponents. For resource users, it may not be clear what their participation inco-management entails, and what such participation
might involve or achieve. For the fisheries of Lake Victoria (Kenya), the introduction of co-management established Beach
Management Units (BMUs) on a model of participatory decision-making. Unsurprisingly, given global experiences of institu-
tions for resource usersparticipation in co-management, the structures established across Lake Victoria (Kenya) have not
resulted in effective participation of fisher folk. We examine why this is so. Specifically, we examine the influence ofinstitutions
on fisher folksparticipation in co-management, using critical institutionalism to explain how participation of resource users is
shaped by the relation between formal government institutions and informal social norms. We take four BMUs as case studies to
investigate how historical administrative structures shape the development of co-management, how power relationships within
co-management are negotiated at the local beach level and the fisher folksunderstanding of their participation in co-manage-
ment. We document how informal institutions undermine and replace formal institutions at the local beach level, while formal
institutions suppress and ignore informal ones at the national and regional levels. From this, we argue power sharing between the
government and fisher folk is key for fisher folk participation in fisheries co-management, capable of addressing both social and
ecological challenges facing fisheries management.
Keywords BMUs .Co-management .Critical institutionalism .Fisheries .Lake Victoria .Participation
Introduction
Co-management has been widely promoted as a preferred
approach for managing common-pool resources such as
fisheries, moving away from topdown government control
and providing greater opportunities to integrate views of
stakeholders in decision-making (Armitage et al. 2009;
Ayers and Kittinger 2014; Pomeroy and Berkes 1997). A
powerful drive toward co-managed resources is the claimsthat
it improves resource yields, ecological sustainability and le-
gitimacy of governance (Herrera-Racionero et al. 2015;
Measham and Lumbasi 2013). A co-managed resource im-
plicitly involves greater participation among resource users.
There are different typologies and definitions of participation.
Here, we mean an active process through which resource users
influence the management of natural resources to enhance
their livelihoods and improve food security (Tiller et al.
2015). A fundamental necessity for a move from traditional
topdown to co-management arrangements is that the govern-
ment must be willing to share power and involve resource
users in decision-making (Pinkerton et al. 2014). This might
*Christine Adhiambo Etiegni
c.etiegni@un-ihe.org
1
IHE Delft, P.O. Box 3015, 2601 DA Delft, The Netherlands
2
Aquatic Ecology and Water Quality Management, University of
Wageningen, P.O. Box 47, 6700 AA Wageningen, The Netherlands
3
Kenya Fisheries Service, Lake Victoria Regional Office, P. O. Box
1084- 40100, Kisumu, Kenya
4
Department of Human Geography, Planning and International
Development Studies, Amsterdam Institute for Social Science
Research, University of Amsterdam, Nieuwe Achtergracht, 166,
1018 WV Amsterdam, The Netherlands
https://doi.org/10.1007/s40152-020-00195-x
/ Published online: 21 July 2020
Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
involve creation by government of appropriate facilitation and
logistics for participation, including provision of resources to
support the process. At the local level, cultural values and
practices, leadership by resource usersleaders and attention
to the influence of power dynamics among stakeholders are
important to foster participation and equity (Ho et al. 2016b;
Ostrom 1990).
A number of approaches to participation have been identi-
fied depending on the management goals and power dynamics
(Puente-Rodríguez 2014). Arnstein (1969) described increas-
ing levels of participation, using the analogy of a ladder. The
lower rungs, manipulation and therapy coincide with non-par-
ticipation. At these levels, the government is expected to train
resource users on what they are expected to do. The next three
rungsinforming, consultation and placationallow for lim-
ited consultations among resource users and government. The
views of resource users may be invited, but these may have
limited influence on the actions of more powerful stake-
holders. The last three upper rungspartnership, delegated
power and citizen controlallow for more decision-making
power to be vested in resource user communities, who are
better empowered to make decisions on the management of
resources. In the recent past, other participation typologies
have been described. For instance, Fung (2006)participatory
cube consists of three participation dimensions, namely, direct
participation by those who participate, how information is
shared by stakeholders for decision-making, and the link be-
tween what is decided and action taken. The cube consists of
three axes that focus on interactive communication, access to
space for participation and power for decision-making. Pretty
(1995) presents a seven-level participation typology, from ma-
nipulation in which unelected and powerless representatives
participate, to self-mobilization in which participation consists
of people taking initiatives. Another typology by White
(1996) provides some insights into how various stakeholders
use participation to drive their interests. The typologies
highlighted previously indicate that participation is about
power and control (Cornwall 2008).
Introduction of co-management often involves the devel-
opment of new institutions at the local level to enable resource
usersparticipation in management decisions. Co-
management integrates institutionsunderstood as rules,
norms and organizations (Hodgson 2006)and stakeholders
at different scales, providing linkages among resource users,
government and other stakeholders (Nielsen et al. 2004). The
linkages may be horizontal or vertical, enabling collaboration
among stakeholders (Pomeroy and Berkes 1997). The vertical
linkages involve institutions at the local level with those at the
national and regional levels. Horizontal linkages involve in-
stitutions for managing natural resources that involve multiple
uses such as fisheries and other economic activities like tour-
ism, aquaculture and wildlife management (Pascaul-
Fernández et al. 2005). The development of new institutions
to encourage resource usersparticipation (Islam et al. 2017)
includes Beach Village Committees (BVCs) in the fisheries of
Lake Malawi (Njaya et al. 2012), forest committees
established in the Amazon to manage timber and other forest
productsuse (de Koning 2011), Gippsland Plains Tree Health
Group (GPTHG) to conserve and manage remnant vegetation
in the threatened grassy woodland in Australia (Measham and
Lumbasi 2013) and fishersorganizations, called van,inthe
Tam Giang Lagoon in Vietnam, involved in the management
of fisheries in collaboration with the government (Ho et al.
2016a). For Lake Victoria, Africa, community-based institu-
tions known as Beach Management Units (BMUs) were
formed in 2007, with networks at the regional, national and
beach levels, to enable fisher folk participation in co-manage-
ment. Despite the widespread emphasis on the development of
these local institutions, there is limited discussion in literature
about how power is negotiated among the co-management
partners and how this influences participation of resource
users.
Power sharing is an important element of co-management
(Béné et al. 2009; Njaya et al. 2012). However, discussions of
power within co-management often centre on power sharing
within formal institutions, with limited attention to power
exercised among resource users and within informal arrange-
ments (Quimby and Levine 2018). Formal institutions include
government and resource usersregulations, rules and organi-
zations, while informal institutions are socially embedded and
include accepted norms and bonds of kinship (Etiegni et al.
2016,2019; Nunan et al. 2015). These institutions play a key
role in guiding practice and interactions among resource users.
Power relations are inseparable from institutions and inevita-
bly shape interactions among stakeholders (Berger and
Luckmann 1967; Chuenpagdee and Jentoft 2007;Van
Hecken et al. 2015). This applies to both formal and informal
institutions (Agrawal and Gibson 1999;Hoetal.2015;
Lwenya et al. 2009; Njaya et al. 2012; Nunan et al. 2015).
More understanding is needed on how formal and informal
institutions influence resource usersparticipation in co-man-
agement. Other factors identified in literature that influence
participation include logistical, relational and trust issues
(Ballou et al. 2016).
Within co-management, institutions can be political, ad-
ministrative or social in nature and are the mechanisms
through which power and authority are held and exercised
(May 2012). Power is continuously negotiated (Berkes
2009; Njaya et al. 2012; Nunan et al. 2015;Quimbyand
Levine 2018), creating new forms of power (Carlsson and
Berkes 2005). Participation in co-management involves pow-
er sharing among resource users and external agents such as
government (Borrini-Feyerabend et al. 2004; Cleaver and
Whaley 2018;Nunanetal.2015; Quimby and Levine
2018). Unequal power relations have been shown to impede
participation of resourceusers (Ballou et al. 2016; Nunan et al.
490 Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
2015), while poorly crafted co-management simply redistrib-
utes power among co-management partners, disadvantaging
categories of resource users (Béné et al. 2009). Power influ-
ences who gets to participate, where to participate (space for
participation), what can be put on the agenda and decisions to
be made (Gaventa 2006). Limited participation happens more
often within invited spaces (Gaventa 2006; Nunan et al.
2012), meaning that those who invite have the opportunity
to control what goes on within those spaces. Power redistri-
bution in co-management happens within institutions and,
therefore, understanding co-management requires an under-
standing of institutions, including those operating within local
communities (Agrawal and Gibson 1999; Borrini-Feyerabend
et al. 2004;Nunan2006; Nunan et al. 2015).
Literature on institutions for resource usersparticipation in
co-management is divided into two distinct groups: main-
stream institutionalism and critical institutionalism. The anal-
ysis of institutions for natural resource management under
mainstream institutionalism has focused mostly on formalized
institutional arrangements (bureaucratic institutions), includ-
ing legislative frameworks and policy processes aimed at
achieving optimum resource use (Ostrom 1990). The assump-
tion has been that institutions are crafted for a specific pur-
pose. This assumption overlooks the fact that there are socially
embedded institutions that play a key role in determining par-
ticipation in natural resource management (Cleaver 2002;de
Koning 2011). Mainstream institutionalism does not take into
account the local specific situations in which power
asymmetries occur, with varied interests among stakeholders
(de Koning 2011).
Critical institutionalism recognizes both social and histori-
cal contexts in which institutions are embedded, with more
focus on local institutions and practices (de Koning 2014;
Etiegni et al. 2016; Nunan et al. 2015). It draws on a critical
realism in that decisions are shaped not by rules and regula-
tions but through human actions determined by formal and
informal institutions (Cleaver and Koning 2015). This ap-
proach to institutional analysis views institutional influence
in natural resource governance as a non-linear process (de
Koning 2011), away from the formalinformal dichotomy.
Critical institutionalism emphasizes (i) the complexity of in-
stitutions entwined in every day social life; (ii) their historical
formation;and (iii) the interplay between traditional and mod-
ern, formal and informal arrangements(Hall et al. 2014).
Specifically, critical institutionalism provides the conceptual
lens through which governance arrangements are understood,
how power is shared (benefiting some and not others) and
how these arrangements have meaning and legitimacy among
stakeholders (Cleaver and Whaley 2018). It recognizes that
institutions are entrenched within specific social, political
and economic structures (Mosse 1997), providing insights
on processes, power and meaning within co-management
(Cleaver and Whaley 2018). Attempts, therefore, to introduce
new institutions at the local level, without regard to existing
social relations and cultural practices, often lead to unintended
outcomes (de Koning 2011; Russell and Dobson 2011). A
critical institutionalism perspective also avoids a more norma-
tive approach assessing deviation from compliance and views
of goodor badpractice.
A good deal of critical institutionalism engages institution-
al bricolagea concept that describes the way resource users
consciously and unconsciously piece together institutional ar-
rangements from social and cultural resources available to
them (Cleaver 2002). This is a process that occurs when
new formal institutions are introduced within a local context
where socially embedded institutions already exist (Cleaver
2002;deKoning2014). In her research on forest practices
within the Amazon, de Koning (2011) identified three pro-
cesses of institutional bricolage as aggregation, alteration
and articulation. Aggregation involves recombining intro-
duced institutions with existing ones in order to come up with
institutions that are practical to the prevailing circumstances at
the local level. Alteration involves changing both formal and
informal institutions in order to adapt them to the local con-
text. Articulation entails making traditions and norms visible
in resistance to introduced formal institutions.
For Lake Victoria (Africa), the BMUs were created to fol-
low co-management principles. BMUs comprise registered
members engaged in all the fish value chains of the lakes
fisheries, primarily the Nile perch (Lates niloticus), Nile tila-
pia (Oreochromis niloticus), a high economic value cichlid
and a small cyprinid omena (Rastrineobola argentea), also
known in the lake as dagaa. The fisheries of the three main
species provide a major source of food and support for liveli-
hoods. Thispaper focuses on the Nile perch fishery because of
its dominance in influencing the structure of the fishery and its
economic importance as a high-value fish for international
markets.
Three decades after its introduction to the lake in the 1950s,
the Nile perch had proliferated to an extent that it both sup-
ported an industrial fishery and, through its predation onother
fish species, led to the decimation of endemic haplochromines
and the traditional fishery they supported (Marshall 2018).
Landings of Nile perch had grown from 335 tonnes in 1975
(Geheb et al. 2008) to 340,000 tonnes in 1990 (LVFO 2016),
although fluctuations in reported landings were later noted
(Indian Ocean Commission 2015). By that time, there were
also clear signs of overfishing, with a reduction of mean size
of landed perch and reductions of catch per unit effort
(CPUE). Reduced catch of Nile perch has continued, attribut-
ed mainly to the use of outlawed fishing gears, eutrophication,
proliferation of the invasive water hyacinth (Eichhornia
crassipes) in some areas and destruction of fish breeding areas
(Aura et al. 2019). The decline of the Nile perch coincided
with increases of the much smaller omena, used mainly as
local food for humans. Omena contributes to food security,
491Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
nutritional requirements and socio-economic development of
the riparian communities and is also an important raw material
in the fish meal industry. The third main commercial species,
theintroducedNiletilapia(Oreochromis niloticus), currently
comprises about 9.5% of the commercial catch (Mkumbo and
Marshall 2015).
As the nature of the fishery changed, with increasing con-
cerns over sustainable yields of the Nile perch as well as the
quality of fish to meet health standards required for the EU
market (Geheb et al. 2008;Medard2015), the governance of
the fishery moved from topdown to co-management. This
shift in governance reflects a global trend over the last few
decades away from command and control, designed and
implemented by governments and their agencies, to greater
empowerment in decision-making of local communities
(Ann Zanetell and Knuth 2004;May2012; Sen and Nielsen
1996). An underlying assumption is that sustainable yields of
local resources are best managed by local communities, in-
volving local governance structures and processes that have
legitimacy (Ayers and Kittinger 2014; Pomeroy and Berkes
1997). In Lake Victoria, agreement among the riparian gov-
ernments (Kenya, Uganda and Tanzania), development part-
ners (European Union and World Bank) and the regional Lake
Victoria Fisheries Organization (LVFO) led to the production
of government guidelines for the establishment and operations
of the locally organized Beach Management Units (BMUs)
(Nunan et al. 2015;Obieroetal.2015). The guidelines define
roles and responsibilities, and the standardization of fisheries
operations and governance structures (Government of Kenya
2006). Each BMU forms an assembly of stakeholders includ-
ing boat owners, fishers, fish traders, fish gear dealers and ice
sellers.
The changes in fisheries governance in Lake Victoria has
been a major undertaking. In Kenya, this created 283 BMUs
comprising over 40,000 crew and other stakeholders
(Government of Kenya 2014). The BMUs were designed to
enable participation of fisher folk in management decisions
through local democratic structures. The former fisheries in-
stitution mandated through the Fisheries Act of 1989
(Government of Kenya 1989) was managed by local fisheries
officers, with powers of enforcement for breaches of fishery
regulations. This has been replaced by the Fisheries
Management and Development Act, 2016 (Government of
Kenya 2016) that devolves fisheries compliance and enforce-
ment to the BMUs. The shift in governance raises important
questions on the extent that resource users are included in
decision-making and co-management (OECD 2015), the pro-
cess of participation and, especially, the extent power and
decision-making is devolved from upper tiers of governance
to local levels. This is not dependent on how a certain man-
agement structure is created or imagined, but how government
actors, resources users and other stakeholders are actually in-
volved in the process of governance, and the extent that co-
management includes collective decision-making within and
among heterogeneous groups of stakeholders. These move
from high-level government to fisher folk, with stakeholder
participation occurring within hierarchies that are embedded
within formally stated settings, as well as the rules, norms and
practices of informal ones (Nelson 2010;Robinsonand
Makupa 2015).
For the participation of fisher folk within the newly created
Lake Victoria (Kenya) BMUs, how participation was de-
signed and occurs within the new fisheries institutions and
whether they can afford to abide by the new rules are of crit-
ical importance for acceptance by fisher folk of the new order.
All institutions are human constructs bounded by humanly
devised constraints that shape interaction(North 1990)and
elusive to predictions of how they may in practice shape/
determine use of natural resources (Nunan et al. 2015)and,
hence, the actions of fisher folk. Motivations of actors and the
social relations among them shape/determine who partici-
pates, in what, how, when and for whose benefits (Béné
et al. 2009;Hoetal.2015). In the BMUs of Lake Victoria
(Kenya), this can include restriction to decision-making for
the less powerful or, through cultural biases such as clanship,
even to the fishery itself.
Seen from a social ontology perspective, an institution
needs more than a formal declaration to exist.Onlyifthe
status and authority of the BMUs is collectively recognized
and accepted by stakeholders, and the shift of power relations
is reflected in their actions, does an institution, and its struc-
ture, become a realitywith relevance and meaning (Searle
2010). For the BMUs, this can determine compliance of local
users (fishers, boat owners, traders, etc.) with the new regula-
tions and participation in governance procedures. This re-
quires fisher folksrecognition of BMUs as an authority
through which the State Department for Fisheries operates,
enabling BMUs to fulfil their intended (status) functions.
Collective acceptance that maintains the authority of the for-
mal institution
1
of the BMU is demonstrated and re-affirmed
by participants in their actions and speech, and in documents
expressing collective intent. The formal institutions of the
BMUs are different from informal institutions, which are typ-
ically emergent phenomena that do not require any formal
declaration of status by a central authority. Rather, they man-
ifest implicit collective recognition of an authority.
The formal and informal institutions can be connected in
the sense that they both work to shape practices, and can be
fully or partially supportive of, or against, each other. For the
fisheries of Lake Victoria, participatory governance processes
would be expected to include (1) formalized mechanisms of
stakeholder engagement, (2) processes that promote collective
acceptance of the new authority of the BMU demonstrated
1
Formal institution is an institution invested with authority through a formal
act of legislation or regulation.
492 Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
through compliance of rules and (3) mechanisms to maintain
the new institution, with stakeholders demonstrating and re-
affirming their acceptance through on-going participation. For
participation in co-management, it is also necessary that
upper-tier government stakeholders (in this case, the State
Department for Fisheries) recognize the authority and status
of lower tiers (in this case the BMUs). It too has to demon-
strate and re-affirm its recognition of the BMUsdeontic pow-
er (that which is exercised in human institutions formed from
social relations) just like any other stakeholder. If the State
Department for Fisheries demonstrates in its actions that the
BMUs have incomplete power,or will not receive support and
backup, it can send a powerful negative signal to fisher folk
(Ribot et al. 2006).
Participation within the BMUs is therefore a two-way
street. A critical institutionalism approach helps in under-
standing how stakeholder participation is influenced by tradi-
tions of fishing practice, local social order and power dynam-
ics, and the expectation of whether decision-making powers
devolved to the BMUs lead to better management outcomes.
For this study, a critical institutionalism approach seeks to
understand participation within three key aspects of the co-
management of the Lake Victoria (Kenya) Nile perch fishery.
First, how did historical administrative structures shape the
process for stakeholder participation in co-management insti-
tutions? Second, how did the ostensible shift in the
Mainstream Institution from topdown control to co-
management affect power constellations at the beach level?
Third, to what extent is participation understood and has
meaning for fisher folk? This work focuses particularly on
the role of individual participation in design and practice of
co-management of the fishery of the lake, and contributes
empirical evidence on participation to the broader examina-
tion of the interactions between institutions and co-
management provided by Nunan et al. (2015), who drew on
experience of working in Lake Victoria (Uganda) and in Lake
Malawi.
Methods and research area
Our analysis of co-management in Lake Victoria used four
selected BMUs, labelled A, B, C and D to retain confidenti-
ality. In consultations with fisheries officials, the BMUs were
chosen based on (1) willingness of fisher folk to participate
and (2) beach accessibility. The number of BMUs included
was constrained by time and finances, and the need to build
familiarity and trust of the communities with the researcher.
On the advice of local fisheries department personnel, the
selected BMUs were those viewed as two with a good and
two with poor reputation for record and account keeping
based on quarterly inspections of the BMUs. An implicit
assumption was that record keeping would reflect operational
legitimacy of the BMUs.
A case-study approach was used to provide an in-depth
understanding of fisher folksinvolvement in the implemen-
tation of co-management. Information collected through indi-
vidual interviews and document review were followed up with
focus group discussions in each BMU with BMU executives,
fisher folk, fisheries officials and local leaders. Forty-nine (49)
individual interviews concentrated on identifying institutions
involved in the creation and operation of co-management
structure, the stakeholders involved and how they participat-
ed. The questions asked started with howto enable the re-
spondent to talk at length while choosing their own words.
Further probing was done using questions beginning with
whatto understand further what was being explained by
the respondent. In group meetings, questions were chosen to
generate a discussion without fisher folk feeling intimidated
by their leaders or government officials. Data collected from
May 2013 to June 2014 from different methods were triangu-
lated such that findings generated for the research questions
from the different methods used were cross-checked for con-
sistency (Yin 2003).
We asked fisher folk to recall activities that involved par-
ticipation during and following the drafting of BMU guide-
lines and regulations in 2006 and 2007, respectively.
Questions asked of participants required them to remember
past events. To mitigate recall bias, a number of measures
were put in place including (1) ensuring the questions were
well articulated in a language the respondent understands best;
(2) employing interview techniques like probing to get more
and better understanding of the information given by the re-
spondent; and (3) giving the respondent ample time to reflect
on questions before answering them. The term participation
used the Kiswahili kuhusishwa and the Luo tio kanyakla,
followed by a description of what was being drafted.
Prompting and probing were used to help respondentsrecall
(Beegle et al. 2012), while guarding against leading questions
which could lead to biased answers. Individual confidentiality
was central to the study design to avoid any personal reper-
cussions from other fisher folk, their leaders or fisheries offi-
cials. Questioning was both at individual level as well as use
of open questions during the focus group discussions.
Confidentiality was maintained at the individual level inter-
view to avoid identification of illegal activities at specific lo-
cations and to encourage respondents to speak in confidence
and avoid the concern of repercussion for engaging in illegal
activities. Conclusions made are based only on the fourBMUs
studied, with any wider interpretation a matter of conjecture.
To better understand the emerging BMU formal institution-
al structure following the shift from previous government-
directed topdown management to a local participatory ap-
proach, a review of government policy and BMU documents
was done. This was supplemented through the interviews of
493Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
fisher folk, fisheries officials and local leaders using pre-
determined semi-structured questions. The 49 interviews in-
cluded 38 fisher folk and were stratified according to BMU
membership categories (crew, boat owners, traders, proces-
sors, fishing gear makers and repairers and other members
registered with the BMU, and 9 BMU-elected executives).
Interviewees were selected by approaching anyone who was
willing to participate in the interview from each stratum. In
addition, four fisheries officials, three chiefs and four village
heads were interviewed. The chiefs and village heads provide
a link between the government and local population and pro-
vide important perspectives of what took place when co-
management was introduced. The total number of interviews
was deemed sufficient after reaching a point of saturation
where it was considered that the inclusion of more respon-
dents in the study was unlikely to provide additional insights.
Interviews were undertaken in Luo (local) and Kiswahili
(national) languages both of which are spoken at the beaches,
and in which the researcher and anassistant were fluent. Notes
were taken during the interviews and data organized using
ATLAS.ti software and analysed using a thematic content
analysis approach.
Results
Historical formation of institutions for fisheries
governance in Lake Victoria (Kenya)
The review of literature on fisheries governance in Lake
Victoria (Kenya) and interviews constructed the historical de-
velopment of the fisheries institutions from pre-colonial tradi-
tional management to current co-management. Before coloni-
zation, predating 1900, clan elders and local leaders (chiefs,
sub-chiefs and village heads) controlled access to and use of
fisheries by decree, determining when fishing could be done,
where it was allowed and who could do it. The local leaders
were very influential in fisheries management then (Opondo
2011). Following adoption of the co-management model in
Lake Victoria, the local leaders seem to have lost this influ-
ence. From a review of co-management documents (BMU
guidelines, regulations and the Fisheries Act), it was noted
that local leaders have not been allocated any roles in co-
management. Overall demand for fish during the pre-
colonial period was limited by low density of the riparian
population, and fishing gears comprising mainly inshore de-
ployment of nets and baskets, although this could have local-
ized impact on stocks (Kudhongania and Chitamweba 1995;
Marshall 2018).
The colonial period (19011962) coincided with the in-
crease in human population, with documented signs of over-
fishing on some species (Graham 1929). The demand for fish,
both for consumption and export, increased following growth
in local population, immigration to the lake region and expan-
sion of fish export markets (Geheb et al. 2008;Kirema-
Mukasa and Abura 2013; Mkumbo and Marshall 2015).
These changes altered the process of participation in the lake
as demand for fish grew and more efficient gears were used to
harvest fish. The increase in fish demand coincided with an
upsurge in unsustainable fishing practices (Etiegni et al.
2016).
The first Fisheries Act to manage the fisheries was the
Cap 378 of the laws of Kenya of 1945, prohibiting fishing
in certain areas and limiting certain fishing gears and sizes
of fish caught. A major shift in the ecological state of the
lake came from the introduction in the 1950s of the Nile
perch and later that of the Nile tilapia (Marshall 2018). The
impacts of, especially, the Nile perch took two decades to
be clearly realized and coincided with a second major eco-
logical impact from nutrient enrichment (Hecky et al.
1994). Meanwhile, fisheries governance after indepen-
dence in 1963 retained the structure from the colonial pe-
riod while the fishery adapted from one based largely on
species of endemic haplochromines to high-value Nile
perch and Nile tilapia. The increasing profitability of the
Nile perch fishery led to industrial-scale offshore fishing
by trawlers and hook-and-line (Medard 2015) and value
chain that increasingly relied on an international export
market (Schuurhuizen et al. 2005). By the mid-1990s, total
catch and mean size of Nile perch was in decline, with an
increasing catch of the smaller omena suggesting changes
in trophic structure in the lake (Irvine et al. 2019).
A transition from state-led fishery control toward partici-
patory co-management was instigated and financed by devel-
opment partners (World Bank and European Union) as a
higher-level government and regional initiative through the
Lake Victoria Environment Management Programme 1
(LVEMP1) from 1997 to 2002, and the Implementation of
Fisheries Management Plan (IFMP) project from 2003 to
2010. LVFO developed harmonized guidelines for BMUs at
the regionallevel (Government of Kenya 2006). This included
addressing procedures for establishing BMUs, and defining
their role, financing and election of BMU leaders. During this
period preceding implementation of co-management, fisher
folk involvement was confined to fisher folk representatives
and other stakeholders (including government officials and
NGOs) attending LVFO workshops to comment on drafts of
BMU guidelines. Most fisher folk representatives at these
workshops worked as beach leaders, appointed by local chiefs
before the adoption of co-management. They continued work-
ing as the first BMU leaders following formal adoption of co-
management, raising doubts if the primary needs of fisher folk
were fully represented in the workshops since they were not
elected leaders. The draft of the BMU guidelines were further
developed by a team of three co-management specialists
appointed from ministries in-charge of fisheries in riparian
494 Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
states, one from each state. During this period, between 1997
and 1999, Nileperch was subject to three export bans fromthe
European Union because of bacterial contamination (Geheb
et al. 2008;Medard2015) that accentuated the need for im-
proved management of the fishery, providing a motivation for
the creation of the BMUs. A fisheries official at beach C
considered that the bans were as a result of salmonella detec-
tion in fish, cholera outbreaks along the shores of L. Victoria
which were linked to fish contamination and unacceptable
fishing methods including use of toxic substances to capture
fish. The ban affected livelihoods of many fisher folk.To add
to this, a fisheries official at beach D said, The ban did not
only affect livelihood activities around the lake, but the econ-
omy of the country too, due to loss of revenue from fish
exports. However, to lift the ban, co-management was one
of the conditions from the European Union.This placed a
particular focus on the creation of BMUs on landing sites to
improve post-harvest handling of fish. Infrastructure to sup-
port this including toilets, potable water supply and fish han-
dling equipment (gloves and boots) was noted from a review
of co-management documents and interviews with fisher folk,
fisheries officials, local leaders and BMU leaders. Although
co-management was initiated in the late 1990s, it would take
around 7 years for its implementation to begin.
From the harmonized regional guidelines, Kenya de-
veloped country-specific BMU guidelines and develop-
ment of co-management (Fig. 1). A team of fisheries of-
ficers was mandated to design draft country BMU guide-
lines, subject to consultation through government-
organized meetings and workshops at which fisher folk
representatives and other actors (NGOs, local leaders
and research institutes) were invited. This led to the de-
velopment of country-specific BMU regulations by anoth-
er team of fisheries officers. The regulations were crafted
from the BMU guidelines and they provided legal backing
for the BMUs (Government of Kenya 2007). The BMU
regulations were first presented to the Lake Victoria
(Kenya) riparian fisheries officers and later to fisher folk
representatives (BMU chairpersons and secretaries), local
leaders, researchers and local and national NGOs at work-
shops organized by the government. Government orga-
nized training of extension staff, NGOs, faith-based orga-
nizations (FBOs) and community-based organizations
(CBOs) on co-management principles. The NGOs and
FBOshaveahistoryofworkingwithfisherfolkbypro-
viding training, credit and development of alternative
income-generating activities.
It is clear that the creation of the BMUs was a process
driven by the riparian governments in consultation with, and
possibly driven by, powerful external actors, also representing
economic and consumer interests beyond the region. The new
formal structures and implementing institutions were directly
influenced by existing and historical government-led fisheries
management. At best, information was conveyed from the
government of how BMUs should organize fisher folk partic-
ipation at the local level.
Interactions between formal and informal institutions
within Lake Victoria (Kenya) co-management
Following the formal process in creating the BMUs, devel-
opment of their structures and governance at the local level
required the participation of fisher folk. For instance, part
III of the BMU regulations stipulates that fisher folk need
to participate in the election of their BMU leaders. In part
IV of the regulations, fisher folk need to fund the opera-
tions of the BMUs from fees they pay to undertake various
activities on the beach. BMU development also involved
establishing the boundaries of the BMU, its organizational
structure for registration of assembly members, and financ-
ing through payment of membership and fishing gear reg-
istration fees. The BMU boundaries were delineated by the
Director of Fisheries in consultation with local chiefs
(Government of Kenya 2006). The beach area was sur-
veyed and boundaries marked to form the BMU areas of
jurisdiction and this required participation of fisher folk in
various activities (Table 1). Co-management implementa-
tion determined who could earn their livelihood from the
fishery, in contrast to informal institutional arrangements
where clan membership was required. With co-manage-
ment, fisher folk need to register through payment of a
feetobecomeamemberofaBMUandbeallowedto
participate in the fishery. Before co-management adoption,
being a member of a clan was enough to earn entry to the
fishery. In the development of BMU structures at the beach
level, fisher folk participated personally rather than repre-
sented by their leaders. The space for participation was at
the local level where most registered BMU members could
access and participate. Participation at national and region-
al levels required resources that most members did not
have and spaces for participation were located far from
the beach. At the national and regional levels, participation
was through beach leaders who had served before the
adoption of co-management.
Each BMU developed by-laws, based on government
guidelines, for day-to-day running of BMU activities. A re-
view of the by-laws from the four BMUs studied showed no
major differences among them, with all adhering to govern-
ment guidelines. BMU assembly members were allowed to
suggest ways for revenue generation to pay for the day-to-
day running of activities (Table 2) and to be approved as by-
laws by the Director of Fisheries.
The sources of revenue generation for the BMUs are based
on BMU regulations. The regulations set out thatBMUs are at
liberty to identify any means through which they can generate
revenue for their activities. Thus, co-management
495Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
implementation introduced payment of fees, identified by re-
spondents as an assured source of BMU revenue and as com-
pliance to BMU rules. Out of 38 fisher folk interviewed, the
vast majority (95%) were registered members of the BMUs
where they operate, indicating they had paid their annual
membership; as described by a fisherman from beach C:
In this place you cannot fish if you are not registered.
Where will you land your fish because the leaders here
cannot allow you to land if you are not registered? Also,
if you try to land in areas not allowed for fish landing
and they find you, you will be fined a lot of money.
More than the registration fee you would have paid
and they can also make your life difficult by making
sure you do not fish at all. If they do that to me or my
friends here, where shall we get our ugali
2
from?
Look at our area here. Can you farm anything in this
rocky place? This is why I am careful and I must register
with the BMU. I do not want problems.
Payment of an annual membership fee at the beginning of
every calendar year, or through periodic instalments, is an
outcome of formal institutional structure of the BMU. This
illustrates power relations based on authority of the
2
Ugali is a dish made of maize, sorghum, millet, or cassava flour mixed in
boiling water and cookedto a dough-like consistency. It is considered a staple
food for a majority of Kenyans and also consumed in some other parts of
Africa.
Regional Level
The regional body, Lake Victoria
Fisheries Organization (LVFO)
funded by the European Union to
organize the drafting of Harmonized
BMU guidelines for the riparian
states
Development of harmonized
BMU guidelines for riparian
states in 2004
Capacity building (raising
awareness) in 2004-2005
Regional Level
Several workshops held at the
regional level for riparian fisheries
officers, fisher folk representatives,
NGOs and other stakeholders to
create awareness on co-management
Development of national BMU
guidelines and regulations in
2006 and 2007
National Level
folk and other stakeholders on draft
BMU guidelines and regulations
Steps in co-management
development
Level of engagement
Involvement procedure
(Kenya) riparian districts organized
meetings for fisher folk and other
stakeholders on the draft BMU
District Level
Development of BMU structures
starting in 2006 using
harmonized BMU guidelines
Local (beach)
Level
leaders (chiefs and village heads)
involved in the demarcation of BMU
boundaries. BMU leaders also elected
Capacity building (awareness
creation) in 2007
Beach by-laws developed by fisher folk
under guidance from fisheries officers.
By-laws submitted to Director of
Fisheries for approval.
Development of beach specific by-
laws starting in 2006 using BMU
guidelines and regulations
Beach level
Fig. 1 The process of co-management institutionsdevelopment in Lake Victoria (Kenya) that occurred from 2004 to 2007
496 Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
government over the BMUs, which is later reflected as power
of BMU leaders over fisher folk. Non-payment is an observed
reason within the formal BMU institution to exclude individ-
uals from fishing and, hence, not only from their livelihood
but capacity to participate in elections of BMU assembly
members. As such, informal institutions based on clan mem-
bership to access the fisheries appear lost or weakened. A
BMU leader in beach A stated it is only through member
registration that we can have an assembly and some of us
can be elected. If you do not have a membership card, you
cannot vote.A fisheries official from beach D added:
For one to undertake fisheries activities in this lake, they
must register with a BMU. They are free to choose
which BMU they want to register with, but the point
is, they must be registered. That is what the law says,
and we are doing well in this because the BMU leaders
are on the spot to ensure this rule is implemented.
For at least some BMU members, it was possible to cir-
cumvent the formal institutional requirement to register, as
illustrated by a trader from beach A:
Currently I am not registered because I noted there are
some traders who come from outside and they are not
registered but they are allowed to buy fish from this
beach. I used to register but for the last 2 years I have
not because I do not see the point of registering if out-
siders can come and compete with me for fish. The
leaders know I have not registered but there is nothing
they can do to me because they know I am aware of
what they are doing.
Despite not paying the registration fee, BMU leaders did
not stop the trader from engaging in his livelihood, but it does
prevent the trader from voting in BMU assembly elections, for
which a registration card is needed. Such a view was contrary
to that of fisheries officials that registration was mandatory.
However, because registration is related to voting it is in the
interest of more influential candidates at election time for fish-
er folk to be registered. It is not possible to know the motiva-
tion that allowed this particular trader to continue business
without registering (and in contrast to the example of the fish-
er not being allowed to fish given previously), but there was
evidence more generally that inter-personal relationships can
play an important role in the informal institutional aspects that
allows BMU leaders to exert power selectively based on kin-
ship, marriage or friendship. The importance of interpersonal
relations between BMU leaders and their associates in deter-
mining participation of users in formal institutions was cor-
roborated by a fisherman from beach D who noted aBMU
chairman may find a relative using an illegal gear and he will
do nothing, but if he finds someone who is not a friend or
relative, he will confiscate his gear.
Institutions and fisher folk participation in co-
management
To gauge the extent to which institutions developed for co-
management involved fisher folk participation, we considered
Table 1 Lake Victoria (Kenya) BMU structures and institutions developed for fisher folk participation in co-management
BMU structures/institutions Participation level Who participated Area of participation
Structures
BMU assembly Beach level Individual fisher folk Membership registration
BMU executive Beach level Individual fisher folk Election/removal of leaders
BMU sub-committees Beach level Individual fisher folk Election/removal of members
BMU networks All levels Fisher folk/representatives Election of network leaders
Institutions
BMU revenue Beach level Individual fisher folk BMU funding
BMU regulations National level Representatives Development of regulations
BMU guidelines Regional/national level Representatives Development of guidelines
BMU by-laws Beach level Fisher folk/representatives By-laws development
Table 2 Examples of possible sources for BMU revenue generation
identified in the study
1. Membership fee as prescribed in the by-laws
2. Annual registration fee for members based on member categories
3. Fish landing fees
4. Support from development partners
5. Use of BMU assets charges
6. Income from projects
7. Other ways stipulated in the by-laws and approved by assembly such as
fines and penalties
8. Occasional support from the government
497Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
(1) the extent to which fisher folksviews were considered for
decision-making; (2) their knowledge of BMU guidelines,
regulations and by-laws; (3) who represented them in situa-
tions where individual participation was not possible; and (4)
the powers devolved to them by the government within the co-
management arrangement. Fisher folk were involved in vari-
ous activities and steps during the development of co-
management institutions (Table 3).
Fisher folk considered that participation in developing co-
management institutions was through representation by BMU
executives (55% of respondents). At that time, these represen-
tatives, who were not elected but had been serving as beach
leaders selected by chiefs, assumed BMU leadership during
the transition from topdown to co-management and were
considered as group category
3
leaders (19% of respondents).
However, 26% of fisher folk interviewed were not aware of
who participated or represented them in developing BMU
guidelines and regulations. Although a majority of fisher folk
were of the opinion they were represented by BMU chairper-
sons, these leaders were mainly the wealthier and more pow-
erful boat owners. Boat owners may have championed their
interests over those of other fisher folk categories (fishers,
traders, fishing gear repairers, etc.) within decision-making
space where they represent others as members of BMU exec-
utive. BMU regulations specify each BMU executive commit-
tee should comprise at least three women (Government of
Kenya 2007), but none of the chairpersons was a woman
although there were women registered as members of
BMUs. Most of the women were fish traders, although a
few owned boats.
In the four beaches sampled, 71% of fisher folk consid-
ered their views were not collected for the initial drafting
of BMU guidelines and regulations. A fish trader from
beach B, who had witnessed the BMU development,
stated, I was not consulted when the BMU regulations
and guidelines were being drafted. These are things that
were done by our leaders and I do not know what their
contents are.A fisherman from beach A, who was not
consulted, stated only a few people were selected from
the beach to attend the meetings. A boat owner from
beach D added, I was not involved, but some of my col-
leagues were consulted. A fish trader from beach A, who
reported having participated in the development of BMU
guidelines (Fig. 1,tier3)stated,I was involved in the
development of BMU guidelines though the document
hadalreadybeendraftedandwewenttoKisumu(acity
on the shores of Lake Victoria) to familiarize ourselves
with it and we even made amendments to sections we were
not happy with.HeaddedtherewasaclauseintheBMU
guidelines that required all BMU leaders to have primary-
level certificates, but they were able to change the require-
ment to apply only to beach secretaries and treasurers.
Similarly, a fish trader from beach B indicated, the regu-
lations and guidelines were complete by the time we got to
hear about them. However, little has been done to let us
know what they contain. Some of us have not even seen
those documents. We need to be trained on these things.
Of the 11 (29% of the sample) fisher folk who reported
their views were collected, only five indicated that any of
their proposals were included, mainly in the development
of by-laws. A fisherman from beach C claimed, what we
proposed to be paid as allowances for the BMU leaders
was maintained, and a fish trader from beach B stated,
the fines we proposed for those who do not follow the
by-laws are the way we passed them as an assembly.
Referring to a reduction of an annual membership fees
from Ksh 500 (US $5) to Ksh 200 (US $2), a boat owner
from beach C said, I was involved in that the BMU exec-
utives drafted the by-laws after which they called an as-
sembly meeting and the draft laws were discussed. We
were able to remove some of the proposed laws through
Table 3 Response of fisher folk (N= 38) relating to their participation in the development of the co-management institutions for the Lake Victoria
(Kenya) BMUs
Fisher folk in co-management Activity Number of respondents
Fisher folks views for BMU development Views collected by fisheries officials and BMU leaders 11
Views included in the by-laws 5
Views not collected 27
Knowledge of co-management documents (number of
respondent answers in brackets)
Knowledge of BMU guidelines Yes (14) No (24)
Knowledge of BMU regulations Yes (6) No (32)
Knowledge of BMU by-laws Yes (24) No (14)
Fisher folks representation in documents drafting process Represented by BMU leaders 21
Group category leaders 7
Do not know 10
3
Fisher folk are registered in various groups based on activities they undertake
in the beach, e.g. fishermen, traders, boat owners and fishing gear repairers,
and each group has its elected leader.
498 Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
the assembly and we also added some.In reference to
being involved in the drafting of beach by-laws, a boat
owner from beach D stated:
Yes, I was involved but some of the issues we gave were
not fully included. We discussed as assembly members
and proposed in our by-laws we should use money col-
lected from licenses sold to crew, boat owners and
traders as part of BMU revenue but this was rejected
by the government.
The influence of fisher folk in crafting fisheries man-
agement rules seems to have been minor. There was no
evidence that the management rules included any degree
of co-design with users of the resource, but a firm de-
piction of government as the higher authority and adju-
dicator of what was included in fisheries management
rules. This influences the way the rules are viewed by
fisher folk, although they are required to comply with
fisheries regulations of the Fisheries Act (Government
of Kenya 2016). Nonetheless, fisher folk seemed to have
a larger influence on whether fisheries rules would be
implemented or not, and outcome of co-management.
From observations at the four beaches studied, it was
evident that although the government expected fisher
folk to implement fisheries rules, observed practice in
all four BMUs were contravening government fisheries
rules, most clearly seen through the increased use of
illegal fishing gears and methods.
Fisher folk, however, were able to craft various rules for
managing beach activities and fines to be administered in
case of violation of BMU rules, and included in specific
by-laws. For example, an ice seller from beach C described
how they took part in developing the by-laws by demon-
strating his understanding of the laws by stating by-laws
are used to ensure members work in a secure environment.
They are also used to solve problems that occur among
members. We are also able to propose conditions under
which work should be done such as the type of uniform
to be worn while on duty.
A boat owner from beach A described how conflicts at the
beach were resolved using by-laws, stating we (complainant
and the accused) go to the BMU office to have our case heard.
We both first pay Ksh 200 (approximately US$2) each for
taking the case to the BMU office. The case is heard and
determined using our by-laws. Nevertheless, limited types
of cases could be resolved using the by-laws, as described
by a fish trader in beach C, BMU office also solves problems
that emanate from family issues. What they cannot resolve is
referred to the chiefs.The limit to the cases that could be
heard and determined using the by-laws was further con-
firmed by a fisheries officer-in-charge of beach C who
indicated:
The by-laws basically contain rules used to run the
beaches by the BMU executives and resolve minor
problems in the beach. There are also fines in the by-
laws administered by the BMU executives. However,
that goes as far as beach running is concerned, but fish-
eries rule violations are handled by courts. When fish-
eries rules are violated, the BMU executives report the
same to fisheries officials who take the matter to court.
The capacity of the BMU executives to levy fines under the
by-laws suggests a leverage of power and influence over other
fisher folk, with possible consequences on fisher folk partici-
pation in the BMU.
Fisher folk participated in the crafting of by-laws and they
have a good awareness of them, but less so on the meaning of
co-management. Enabling fisher folk participation in co-manage-
ment, capacity building through training and raising awareness
were reported by respondents as activities undertaken to prepare
fisher folk for participation. BMU leaders, trained at the national
and regional levels, were expected to create awareness of other
fisher folk on co-management and how to structure BMUs and
develop institutions (by-laws) at the beach level. Fisheries offi-
cials and local leaders (chiefs and village elders) were also in-
volved in the awareness creation on co-management and the
crafting of by-laws at the beach level. A majority (63%) of fisher
folk interviewed agreed there were attempts to create awareness
on co-management by BMU leaders during assembly meetings.
This comprised stating the importance of co-management, com-
position of BMU committees and procedures such as electing
and removing their leaders from office, most of which seemed to
involve them in the formation of BMU structures at the local
level. Only 13% of respondents reported having undergone train-
ing in co-management. Local leaders used barazas
4
to create
awareness on co-management among fisher folk and local beach
inhabitants who may not be involved in active fisheries.
However, interviews eliciting fisher folksviewsofco-
management demonstrated little understanding of co-
management principle of involvement of fisher folk and the state
in fisheries management decision-making, what is required of
them, and how they are supposed to benefit from co-manage-
ment. For instance, when asked about their understanding of co-
management, a majority (90%) of fisher folk linked co-
management to government rules, suggesting governments
dominance in co-management.
Only in BMUs A and C were some leaders conversant with
the meaning of co-management as some form of collaboration
among stakeholders. A leader from beach A defined co-
management as collaboration between fishers and govern-
ment in the management of L. Victoria fisheries, while a
leader from beach C defined co-management as
4
Village gatherings convened by local leaders (chiefs and village heads) to
share information and discuss matters that concern the community.
499Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
collaboration of stakeholders in fisheries management.A
leader from BMU D attributed his lack of understanding of
co-management by I was just elected 2 years ago and I was
not in office when BMUs were being established,whilea
leader from BMU B linked his low knowledge of co-
management to absence of training since elected to office.
Limited knowledge of co-management was also evident
among some fisheries officials. For instance, a fisheries offi-
cial from beach C understood co-management as the drafting
of new laws by government to improve fisheries manage-
ment, while a fisheries official from beach B defined co-
management as implementation of fisheries rules.In addi-
tion, there were three fisheries officials who could not attempt
to define co-management during the interviews, indicating
their own low level of awareness.
To understand power sharing between the two main co-
management stakeholders (government and fisher folk) in-
volved in fisheries governance, we examined the powers held
by the government before co-management and powers de-
volved afterwards to fisher folk through the institutions of
BMUs (Table 4). Our results indicate the government still
holds most of the formal decision-making powers within co-
management except for power of enforcement of fisheries
rules, which have been fully devolved to BMUs. Fisher folk
found violating fisheries rules by BMU executives are handed
over to fisheries officials for onward transmission to the
courts. In the previous order, it was the duty of fisheries offi-
cials to enforce fisheries rules, a task that they did not have the
human capacity to perform. The power to levy fines under by-
laws for non-compliance with rules, although described as a
minor operational issue, was found to be a lucrative source of
income for the BMU executives. The real power and influence
stems from the national regulations.
Discussion
Resource usersparticipation has long been considered as an
important part of natural resource governance (Ansink and
Bouma 2013;AyersandKittinger2014) for benefits that in-
clude inclusive decision-making (Armitage 2005) and em-
powerment of resource users (Ho et al. 2015;Nunan2006).
These elements are linked to sustainable resource manage-
ment outcomes (Ann Zanetell and Knuth 2004). The present
study used the case of Lake Victoria (Kenya) to explore how
fisher folk participate in co-management decision-making.
In the introduction of this paper, we posed three questions,
which we re-visit here:
1. How did historical administrative structures shape the
process for stakeholder participation in co-management
institutions?
From the findings, it was established that the historical
administrative structures at the local level consisting of
chiefs, sub-chiefs, and village heads played a key role in
determining how fisher folk participated in the develop-
ment of co-management local institutions. The local leaders
were powerful and influential in fisheries management pri-
or to co-management, and in most cases, they were obeyed
without questioning. They determined who, when, where,
and how fishing was done (Opondo 2011). The local ad-
ministrative structures provided a link between the govern-
ment and fisher folk during co-management development.
However, during co-management implementation, the local
administration seems to have lost fisheries management
power. Instead, implementation of fisheries rules within
co-management at the beach level is undertaken by the
Table 4 A summary ofpowers heldby the key stakeholdersinvolved in fisheries governance identified from interviews with respondents involved in
Lake Victoria co-management
Powers held by government
before co-management
Power held by government after co-
management adoption
Powers devolved to
BMUs by government
Extent of power devolution to BMUs
Create rules or modify old
ones (legislative)
Create fisheries rules or modify old ones Craft by-laws for
managing internal
BMU activities
Limitedtoby-laws
Power to make decisions on
fisheries resource use held
by the government
Power to make decisions on fisheries
resource use remained with the
government
No power devolved to
the BMUs by the
government
No resource use decision-making powers devolved to
BMUs. They implement fisheries rules contained
in the Fisheries Act
Government the main
enforcer of fisheries rules
Government still involved in fisheries
rule enforcement
Power to enforce
fisheries rules
Power to enforce fisheries rules fully devolved to
BMUs. Both government and BMU institutions
involved in fisheries rule enforcement
Conflict resolution (judicial) Powers to resolve conflicts from rule
enforcement held by the judicial arm
of the government (courts)
Power to adjudicate
social disputes
among BMU
members
Limited-only power to resolve conflicts among BMU
members devolved
500 Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
BMUs, while local leaders handle social disputes within
their locations.
Formal institutions including Fisheries Act, BMU regula-
tions, guidelines and by-laws do not include the roles played
by local leaders in fisheries management (Government of
Kenya 2007,2016). This has largely removed the participa-
tion of those leaders in fisheries management. This is contrary
to what has been reported in the fisheries of Lake Malawi,
where chiefshave an influential and important role in fisheries
co-management (Njaya et al. 2012; Russell and Dobson
2011). The local leaders have power to make fisheries man-
agement decisions, although these can be motivated primarily
by self-interest rather than improving fisheries management
(Njaya et al. 2012). The powers exercised by local leaders,
who are not elected in Lake Malawi, is used to marginalize
fishers further, suggesting that co-management does not guar-
antee fisher folk participation. In some instances, poorly de-
signed co-management merely re-enforces control by the
more powerful stakeholders (Béné et al. 2009).
Co-management in Lake Victoria was instigated and im-
plemented from the highest tiers of government (Beem 2007;
Herrera-Racionero et al. 2015; Njaya et al. 2012), influenced
by donors and external partners over international food safety
concerns of exported Nile perch (Medard 2015). This drove a
process that relied on existing formal institutional structures as
provided by the Fisheries Act and associated regulations. The
process appeared to have largely ignored the realities of the
informal institutions of fishing. Such an approach can have
little effect on informal institutions (Pejovich 2006), leading to
an undermining of formal structures and ambitions for sustain-
able resource use (Etiegni et al. 2016; Nunan et al. 2018).
While co-management theory acknowledges the influence of
institutions on the participation of fisher folk in co-
management (Agrawal and Gibson 1999;Rahmanetal.
2012; Snell et al. 2013), the interaction between formal and
informal institutions are important to co-management.
2. How did the ostensible shift in the mainstream institution
from topdown control to co-management affect power
constellations at the beach level?
Power is key to participation in co-management (Njaya
et al. 2012; Nunan et al. 2012; Quimby and Levine 2018).
Power devolved to fisher folk in Lake Victoria by the govern-
ment to enable their participation in co-management is limited
and, therefore, does not enable meaningful resource users
participation (Béné et al. 2009). The ostensible shift from
topdown management to co-management has not changed
substantially the way power is distributed and exercised with-
in the fisheries of Lake Victoria (Kenya). Only limited powers
to enforce/implement fisheries regulations are fully devolved
by the government to fisher folk, while the government still
controls the more important fisheries management powers,
including power to craft and modify fisheries regulations
and power to make decisions on fisheries resource use.
Limited power devolution from the government to fisher folk
is a barrier to fisher folk participation. This impedes them
from having a voice in fisheries management decision-mak-
ing. However, that does not mean that they implement what
the government prescribes for them. They implement what
they perceive as acceptable to them based on their accepted
norms and practices, influenced by informal institutions and
the need to earn a livelihood. Such approach to participation
by resource users is mainly due to lack of involvement in the
initial stages of co-management planning and development,
which are needed for building legitimacy of co-management
institutions. A similar outcome was discussed by Herrera-
Racionero et al. (2015) among fishermen operating in the
Spanish Mediterranean port of Gandia, who lost legitimacy
of co-management institutions due to lack of their involve-
ment in the development of those institutions.
Among the different fisher folk categories, the limited powers
that were devolved by government are held and exercised by a
few wealthier and more powerful boat owners who determine
how co-management is implemented and, therefore, how fisher
folk participate. More centres of power were developed within
BMUs with co-management, giving rise to more fisheries elites at
the local level (Etiegni et al. 2019). Power to implement fisheries
rules is devolved to the BMUs, which in practice are extremely
limited in their role to craft fisheries management rules. However,
informal rules operating within the BMUs determine what rules
are implemented at the beach level. As such, BMUs may not have
been influential in the planning and structuring of Lake Victoria
co-management institutions, but they determine to a larger extent
the effect of co-management on the fishery. Within the BMUs,
our work concurs with Nunan et al. (2012,2015) in Uganda that
BMU chairperson and executive positions are dominated by the
wealthier and more powerful boat owners who champion their
interests, and not the interests of the people they represent. While
BMU regulations stipulate that at least three of the executive
committee positions should be reserved for women and 30% of
positions should go to crew, it is unusual, although not impossi-
ble, for women, traders or crew to be elected to the more powerful
position of the BMU chairperson. Relations of power are critical
to the outcome of co-management (Quimby and Levine 2018).
These relations, however, should be considered not only between
the government and the recipients of devolved powers (resource
users) but also among resource users. The findings of this research
have shown that power relations/sharing among fisher folk was
not considered during the design and shift to co-management. The
domination of boat owners in the BMU executive provides un-
equal power relations among fisher folk, leading to interference
and inefficiencies in fisheries management.
3. To what extent is participation understood and has mean-
ing for fisher folk?
501Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
Co-management is implemented in many countries and in
different contexts, and focuses on increasing resource users
participation in management for improved ecological sustain-
ability and livelihoods (Ayers and Kittinger 2014;Measham
and Lumbasi 2013; Quimby and Levine 2018). To understand
the extent to which participation is understood and has mean-
ing for resource users, we first determined fisher folksunder-
standing of co-management since participation is a key prin-
ciple of co-management (May 2012; Quimby and Levine
2018). The general understanding of co-management by fisher
folk, and even fisheries officials, weakens the likelihood of
fisher folksunderstanding of participation or, more impor-
tantly, the benefits of participating (Ostrom 1990; Pomeroy
et al. 2001). Among the fisher folk of the four Kenyan BMUs
involved in the study, co-management is viewed as a govern-
ment project they implement or, at least, need to conform to.
To them, participation is some sort of government support
which they can give or fail to give, instead of being active
partners in co-management. This appears to fit the reality of
what does happenas opposed to what should happen
(Blackstock et al. 2012). Overall, the disconnect between the
stated rationale for a devolution to co-management has hardly
translated to a serious engagement of fisher folk to support the
process, risking a lack of institutional legitimacy of fisheries
policies, perceived as made by far-away decision centres
(Herrera-Racionero et al. 2015).
Our research suggests many fisher folks seem not to have
understood the problems that co-management aims to solve
and, by extension, why they should be part of the process. The
approach given to co-management development process is
equally important. The topdown approach to co-
management provides less incentives to fisher folk to partici-
pate (Islam et al. 2017). Similarly, when what seems to be
benefits that accrue from co-management, in this case, money
from licensing, goes only to the government, this acts as a
disincentive to fisher folk participation. That they view co-
management as external to them suggest a lack of institutional
legitimacy. It can also be a consequence of low-level engage-
ment during the initial stages of co-management development.
So, while there may be a good to reasonable comprehension of
co-management, the meaning of participation to fisher folk as
indicated by extent of non-compliance seems deficient.
Broader meaning of wider rationale of participation in co-
management for sustainable resource use can, at best, be the-
oretical as, in reality, the BMUs do not, and cannot, lead to
sustainable yields. As all institutions require legitimacy and
meaning (Cleaver and Whaley 2018), the BMUs face a num-
ber of serious challenges.
For the four BMUs that were the topic of this research,
there is little evidence that there was any meaningful engage-
ment of fisher folk in the design of the government-mandated
fishing regulations. Documented participation of fisher folk
leaders in the development of the BMU institutions appears
to comprise informing them of decisions already made, and
they were supported by government through payment of their
transport and accommodation fees to attend workshops.
Fisher folk participation was primarily informative, thus cor-
responding to Arnsteins(1969) lower rungs. Decisions had
already been made at the regional and national levels, and
fisher folksinputs were only considered if they supported
what had already been decided at those levels. Participation
occurred mainly within invited spaces (Gaventa 2006) and the
regional agenda, which was also the national agenda,
prevailed. This corresponds to what was later discussed by
Pretty (1995) as manipulation of stakeholders, in which par-
ticipation is by those who have not been elected and are pow-
erless. For the BMUs, fisher folk leaders who participated in
the development of co-management and in the initial imple-
mentation were not elected and they did not have power to
influence decisions. They did not understand what was ex-
pected of their participation. However, the election of BMU
leaders in the later years has not changed the way co-
management is implemented in Lake Victoria (Kenya). How
fisher folk are to participate is decided externally, although the
participation cube developed by Fung (2006) advocates direct
participation, information sharing for decision-making and
understanding the link between decisions made and action
taken. For Lake Victoria (Kenya) co-management, communi-
cation between fisher folk and the government is not interac-
tive but informative. Power is not devolved from the govern-
ment to fisher folk in a way that encourages meaningful par-
ticipation in co-management. Government, as the more pow-
erful stakeholder at the national level, uses participation to
drive her interests, while at the beach level, the more powerful
boat ownersinterests are advanced. This approach to partic-
ipation is, therefore, determined by power and interests (White
1996). As such, information sharing and linking of fisheries
management decisions to actions are unlikely to play any role
in improving fisheries management.
The government exercised hidden power, used by some
actors due to their positions to achieve their objectives
(Njaya et al. 2012), to decide on who to invite to the workshop
and also control the nature of discussions taking place by
determining the agenda (Cleaver and Whaley 2018). This
conforms with instrumentalco-management (Arthur 2005;
Nielsen et al. 2004) that restricts resource usersparticipation
in decisions. Since the government facilitated fisher folk par-
ticipation, it very much controlled the space for participation
(Gaventa 2006). The review of the by-laws of the four BMUs
showed these simply adhered to government guidelines and
the Fisheries Act (Government of Kenya 2016). This was seen
with the similarities of the sources of revenue suggested by the
four BMUs and what the revenue was to be used for.
The stated formal ambition to establish a sustainable fish-
ery as an outcome of co-management has very little substance
in the face of the maintenance of an open-access fishery
502 Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
(Irvine et al. 2019), the realities of the informal institutions that
subvert compliance of rules (Etiegni et al. 2016) as a result of a
governance structure of co-management providing limited
space for fisher folk participation in the crafting of the fisher-
ies management rules. Participation of fisher folk at the four
BMUs is largely limited to co-management implementation,
with only minor capacity to influence matters of governance.
Nunan (2010), investigating co-management on Lake Victoria
in 2007, also concluded a general lack of participation per-
ceived by BMU members. This concurs with our findings that
participation among most of the BMU members remains re-
stricted, with power very much invested in the BMU execu-
tives. See also Etiegni et al. (2019). The persistence and even
increase in illegal fishing practice (Irvine et al. 2019)providea
strong signal that the formal institutional structure of a regu-
lated fishery is not aligned with the informal institutions,
where clan and kinship relationships foster local corruption
(Etiegni et al. 2016; Nunan et al. 2015;Obieroetal.2015).
This could be viewed as aspects of institutional bricolage in
which fisher folk ignore or bend formal government rules as
they participate in the fishery (de Koning 2011). This they do
with the sole aim of earning a livelihood. BMU leaders use
interpersonal relations to selectively enforce formal regula-
tions that require fisher folk registration to participate. They
use their power to determine who can participate without reg-
istering and who must register to participate. As such, the
formal regulation is not fully implemented, but subverted
through power and interpersonal relations that exist between
the BMU executives and other fisher folk.
The categories of fisher folk laid out in the BMU reg-
ulations comprise a heterogeneous mix and the extent that
each category participates or influences co-management
of the fishery is debatable. For many fisher folk, partici-
pation is dominated by picking their way through the for-
mal and informal institutions, including payment of bribes
and fines to continue fishing (Nunan et al. 2015). At the
very least, this provides a particular flavour to the concept
of participation. For others, it may be about the next sliver
of income. In the fishery of Lake Victoria, many crew are
low-skilled transient workers (personal communication
BMU Chairperson) in the employ of a boat owner, but
nevertheless, crew are required to register with the
BMU. While a noble ideal, especially for collective ac-
tion, boat crew have limited space for participation in co-
management (Nunan et al. 2012), other than providing a
cohort of votes for BMU executives. It is, therefore, a
contestable point why they should be required to partici-
pate in the payment of membership fees to a BMU. This
seems to be recognized in Malawi, where a fisher is de-
fined as a gear owner, restricting any role a crew member
has in formal co-management structures, even though it is
those who actively fish that effect compliant fishing or not
(Hara 2006).
Conclusions
This paper used the case of Lake Victoria (Kenya) to explore
the nature of resource usersparticipation in the development
and implementation of co-management. As currently consti-
tuted, the government still holds most decision-making pow-
ers that structure co-management, with fisheries management
retaining the character of a traditional topdown approach.
Fisher folks participation is largely a formalized action aimed
at implementing externally crafted rules (Nielsen et al. 2004).
However, from the evidence, it can be concluded that institu-
tions and the interactions between them are important for the
socialecological structure of that co-management. The for-
mal and informal institutions interact in ways that are not
complementary, undermining the ambitions of fisheries co-
management. Informal rules shape fisheries practices at the
beach level. For instance, corruption undermines enforcement
of fisheries rules with outcomes that are socially and ecolog-
ically damaging (Etiegni et al. 2016). As such, a greater level
of understanding of how formal and informal institutions in-
teract can help develop more meaningful participation of
stakeholders to better align fisheries management objectives
with fishing practice. This would also improve accountability
of BMU leaders to their local constituents as well as to
government.
Our study suggests that to have meaningful participation of
fisher folk in co-management, there is a need for greater de-
volution of power. Considering both hidden and open sources
of power, taking into account the realities of inter-personal
relations at different scales, and from the earliest stages of
co-management design, will promote better outcomes. For
the Lake Victoria BMUs, this was not done, and revising the
now established governance structures, with their current
power dynamics, will be extremely difficult. At the beach
level, this would require an effort to open spaces for partici-
pation to less powerful fisher folk for their better involvement
in decision-making on fishing practice. It would necessitate an
enabling environment supported by local fisheries officers,
including addressing local instances of criminality and corrupt
practices (Etiegni et al. 2016), and an extension service that
provides better awareness of the benefits of sustainable re-
source use. Enhancing fisher folksunderstanding of the goals
of co-management, and their role in that, can also help identify
misuse of power by their leaders. This will enable participa-
tion of fisher folk that goes beyond being advised by more
powerful actors within co-management, to one that they par-
ticipate on a more equal basis.
To make co-management more inclusive (Armitage 2005),
emphasis should be on resource usersempowerment that also
facilitates the empowerment of marginalized resource users.
Co-management structures that provide more space, vertically
and horizontally, for fisher folk participation foster meaning-
ful participation at all levels. Ceded powers to resource users
503Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
within co-management is a general principle that can lead to
more meaningful participation in fisheries management and
for participants to claim their space in fisheries management
(Béné et al. 2009; Borrini-Feyerabend et al. 2004). Such de-
velopment does not negate the role of informal institutions but
likely moves closer the where processes of bricolage work to
reduce rather than increase potential management conflicts.
The example of how fisher folk participate in co-
management discussed in this study suggests that re-
search on co-management should give greater attention
to factors that impede and facilitate resource userspar-
ticipation in co-management. This view is supported by
Ballou et al. (2016) who, while acknowledging the im-
portance of resource usersparticipation in resource man-
agement, suggest a focus on barriers to participation,
which may be logistical or relational, to boost participa-
tion. For the current structure of fisheries governance in
Lake Victoria (Kenya), it is hard not to conclude that
this is not a simple denial of reality, driven by a top
down management philosophy, inevitably resulting in
non-compliance of fisheries regulations (Etiegni et al.
2016), which themselves fall short of the fundamental
challenge presented by an overexploited open-access re-
source. The critical institutionalism perspective shines a
light on these conclusions but, more importantly, pro-
vides a way forward that can help achieve more sustain-
able outcomes that support local beneficiaries.
The process of co-management development in Lake
Victoria (Kenya) was instigated from the top and it focused
on external interests rather than resource usersinterests.
Fisher folk do not, therefore, know the problems co-
management is intended to solve, why they should participate,
and what benefit participation is to them. The management
benefit of the BMUs is not what was envisaged. In its devel-
opment, fisher folk involvement was effectively absent. Their
involvement in the implementation stage is limited to being
informed of decisions already taken. Since what precedes co-
management implementation and what happens during imple-
mentation stages are important to co-management success
(Chuenpagdee and Jentoft 2007), for the lakes co-manage-
ment, neither the beginning nor the implementation has been
done with any clear objective legitimacy. A lot of focus was
put on developing formal institutions with little regard to the
influence and importance of informal ones. As such, the lakes
co-management is unlikely to provide benefits that include
sustainable fisheries and improved livelihoods for fisher folk
(FAO 1995,2015).
Acknowledgments Lake Victoria (Kenya) fishing communities are
thanked for providing data used in this research. Staff from the State
Department for Fisheries are thanked for assisting with logistics during
field work. Wealso thank two anonymous reviewers of the earlier version
of this paper. Lastly, we would like to thank Prof. Maarten Bavinck for
his valuable comments during the writing of this paper.
Funding information This research draws on a PhD study supported by
the Netherlands Fellowship Programme (NFP).
Compliance with ethical standards
Conflict of interest The authors declare that they have no conflict of
interest.
Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons
Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adap-
tation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as
you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, pro-
vide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were
made. The images or other third party material in this article are included
in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a
credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's
Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by
statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain
permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this
licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.
References
Agrawal, A., and C.C. Gibson. 1999. Enchantment and disenchantment:
the role of community in natural resource conservation. World
Development 27 (4): 629649. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0305-
750x(98)00161-2.
Ann Zanetell, B., and B.A. Knuth. 2004. Participation rhetoric or
community-based management reality? Influences on willingness
to participate in a Venezuelan freshwater fishery. World
Development 32 (5): 793807. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.
2004.01.002.
Ansink, E., and J. Bouma. 2013. Effective support for community re-
source management. Forest Policy and Economics 37 (0): 94103.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2013.01.007.
Armitage, D. 2005. Adaptive capacity and community-based natural re-
source management. Environmental Management 35 (6): 703715.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00267-004-0076-z.
Armitage, D.R., R. Plummer, F. Berkes, R.I. Arthur, A.T. Charles, I.J.
Davidson-Hunt, A.P. Diduck, N.C. Doubleday, D.S. Johnson, M.
Marschke, P. McConney, E.W. Pinkerton, and E.K. Wollenberg.
2009. Adaptive co-management for socialecological complexity.
Frontiers in Ecology and the Environment 7(2):95102.
Arnstein, S.R. 1969. A ladder of citizen participation. Journal of the
American Institute of Planners 35 (4): 216224. https://doi.org/10.
1080/01944366908977225.
Arthur, R.I. 2005. Developing, implementing and evaluating policies to
support fisheries co-management,12. London: MRAG Ltd.
Aura, C.M.,C.S. Nyamweya, J.M. Njiru, S. Musa, Z.Ogari, L. May, and
E. Wakwabi. 2019. Exploring the demarcation requirements of fish
breeding and nursery sites to balance the exploitation, management
and conservation needs of Lake Victoria ecosystem. Fisheries
Management and Ecology 26 (5): 451459. https://doi.org/10.
1111/fme.12311.
Ayers, A.L., and J.N. Kittinger. 2014. Emergence of co-management
governance for Hawaii coral reef fisheries. Global Environmental
Change 28 (0): 251262. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2014.
07.006.
Ballou, L.M., N. Albritton, and L.S. Horowitz. 2016. Enforcement en-
courages participation in resource management: explaining a fisher-
ies management paradox in Hawaii. Asia Pacific Viewpoint 57 (3):
379392. https://doi.org/10.1111/apv.12133.
504 Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
Beegle, K., C. Carletto, and K. Himelein. 2012. Reliability of recall in
agricultural data. Journal of Development Economics 98 (1): 3441.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2011.09.005.
Beem, B. 2007. Co-management from the top? The roles of policy entre-
preneurs and distributive conflict in developing co-management ar-
rangements. Marine Policy 31 (4): 540549. https://doi.org/10.
1016/j.marpol.2006.12.001.
Béné, C., E. Belal, M.O. Baba, S. Ovie, A.Raji, I. Malasha, F. Njaya, M.
Na Andi, A. Russell, and A. Neiland. 2009. Power struggle, dispute
and alliance over local resources: analyzing democraticdecentral-
ization of natural resources through the lenses of Africa inland fish-
eries. World Development 37 (12): 19351950. https://doi.org/10.
1016/j.worlddev.2009.05.003.
Berger, P., and T. Luckmann. 1967. The social construction of reality: a
treatise in the sociology. London: Penguin.
Berkes, F. 2009. Evolution of co-management: role of knowledge gener-
ation, bridging organizations and social learning. Journal of
Environmental Management 90 (5): 16921702. https://doi.org/10.
1016/j.jenvman.2008.12.001.
Blackstock, K.L., K.A.Waylen, J. Dunglinson, and K.M.Marshall. 2012.
Linking process to outcomesinternal and external criteria for a
stakeholder involvement in river basin management planning.
Ecological Economics 77:113122. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
ecolecon.2012.02.015.
Borrini-Feyerabend, G., Pimbert, M., ., Farvar M.T., Kothari A., &
Renard Y. (2004). Sharing power. Learning by doing in co-
management of natural resources throughout the world,IIED and
IUCN/ CEESP/CMWG,Cenesta, Tehran.
Carlsson, L., and F. Berkes. 2005. Co-management: concepts and meth-
odological implications. Journal of Environmental Management 75
(1): 6576.
Chuenpagdee, R., and S. Jentoft. 2007. Step zero for fisheries co-man-
agement: what precedes implementation. Marine Policy 31 (6):
657668. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.marpol.2007.03.013.
Cleaver, F. 2002. Reinventing institutions: bricolage and the social
embeddedness of natural resource management. European Journal
of Development Research 14 (2): 1130.
Cleaver, F., and J.D. Koning. 2015. Furthering critical institutionalism.
International Journal of the Commons 9(1):118. https://doi.org/
10.18352/ijc.605.
Cleaver, F., and L. Whaley. 2018. Understanding process, power, and
meaning in adaptive governance: a critical institutional reading.
Ecology and Society 23 (2). https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-10212-
230249.
Cornwall, A. 2008. Unpacking participation: models, meanings and
practices. Community Development Journal 43 (3): 269283.
https://doi.org/10.1093/cdj/bsn010.
de Koning, J. (2011). Reshaping institutions, bricolage processes in
smallholder forestry in the Amazon. (PhD), Wageningen
University, Wageningen, the Netherlands, 269 pp.
de Koning, J. 2014. Unpredictable outcomes in forestrygovernance
institutions in practice. Society and Natural Resources 27 (4):
358371. https://doi.org/10.1080/08941920.2013.861557.
Etiegni, C.A., K. Irvine, and M. Kooy. 2016. Playing by whose rules?
Community norms and fisheries rules in selected beaches within
Lake Victoria (Kenya) co-management. Environment,
Development and Sustainability:119. https://doi.org/10.1007/
s10668-016-9799-2.
Etiegni, C.A., M. Kooy, and K. Irvine. 2019. Promoting social account-
ability for equitable fisheries within beach management units in
Lake Victoria (Kenya). Conservation and Society 17 (1): 63.
https://doi.org/10.4103/cs.cs_18_10.
FAO (1995). Code of conduct for responsible fisheries, Rome. 41pp.
FAO (2015). Voluntary guidelines for securing sustainable fisheries,
Rome, 18pp. Retrieved from www.fao.org. Accessed Oct 2018.
Fung, A. 2006. Varieties of participation in complex governance. Public
Administration Review 66 (supplement 1): 6675.
Gaventa, J. 2006. Finding the spaces for change: a power analysis. IDS
Bulletin 37 (6): 2333. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1759-5436.2006.
tb00320.x.
Geheb, K., S. Kalloch, M. Medard, A. Nyapendi, C. Lwenya, and M.
Kyangwa. 2008. Nile perch and the hungry of Lake Victoria: gen-
der, status and food in an East African fishery. Food Policy 33 (1):
8598. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2007.06.001.
Government of Kenya (1989). The Fisheries Act, chapter 378 of the laws
of Kenya.
Government of Kenya (2006). National Beach Management Unit
Guidelines, 33pp.
Government of Kenya (2007). Fisheries Beach Management Units
Regulations, 30pp.
Government of Kenya (2016). The fisheries management and develop-
ment act,2016 Available at wwwkenyalaworg Acessed 11
Dec 2016.
Graham, M. (1929). The VictoriaNyanza and its fisheries. A report on the
fishing survey of Lake Victoria, 19271928, and appendices.
London: Crown agents for the colonies.
Hall, K., F. Cleaver, T. Franks, and F. Maganga. 2014. Capturing critical
institutionalism: a synthesis of key themes and debates. European
Journal of Development Research 26 (1): 7186. https://doi.org/10.
1057/ejdr.2013.48.
Hara, M. 2006. Restoring the chambo in Southern Malawi: learning from
the past or re-inventing the wheel? Aquatic Ecosystem Health &
Management 9 (4): 419432. https://doi.org/10.1080/
14634980601013335.
Hecky, R.E., F.W.B. Bugenyi, P. Ochumba, and J.F. Talling. 1994.
Deoxygenation of the deep water of Lake Victoria, East Africa.
Limnology and Oceanography 39 (6): 14761481. https://doi.org/
10.4319/lo.1994.39.6.1476.
Herrera-Racionero, P., E. Lizcano-Fernández, and L. Miret-Pastor. 2015.
Usand them. Fishermen from Gandía and the loss of institu-
tional legitimacy. Marine Policy 54 (0): 130136. https://doi.org/10.
1016/j.marpol.2014.12.018.
Ho, N.T.T., H. Ross, and J. Coutts. 2015. Power sharing in fisheries co-
management in Tam Giang lagoon, Vietnam. Marine Policy 53 (0):
171179. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.marpol.2014.12.006.
Ho, N.T.T., H. Ross, and J. Coutts. 2016a. Cant three tango?The role of
donor-funded projects in developing fisheries co-management in the
Tam Giang lagoon system, Vietnam. Ocean and Coastal
Management 121:97106. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ocecoaman.
2015.12.011.
Ho, N.T.T., H.Ross, and J. Coutts. 2016b.The influence of leadership in
fisheries co-management: the case of Tam Giang lagoon, Vietnam.
Society and Natural Resources 29 (12): 14051420. https://doi.org/
10.1080/08941920.2016.1138562.
Hodgson, M.G. 2006. What are institutions. Economic issues XL (1): 1
25.
Indian Ocean Commission (2015). LVFO Nile perch fisheries manage-
ment plan 20152019.Port Louis, Mauritius:Indian Ocean
Commission.
Irvine, K., C.A. Etiegni, and O.L.F. Weyl. 2019. Prognosis for long-term
sustainable fisheries in the African Great Lakes. Fisheries
Management and Ecology 26 (5): 413425. https://doi.org/10.
1111/fme.12282.
Islam, G.M.N., S.Y. Tai, M.N. Kusairi, S. Ahmad, F.M.N. Aswani,
M.K.A. Muhamad Senan, and A. Ahmad. 2017. Community per-
spectives of governance for effective management of marine
protected areas in Malaysia. Ocean and Coastal Management 135:
3442. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ocecoaman.2016.11.001.
Kirema-Mukasa, C., & Abura, S. (2013). Introduction of alternative in-
come generating activities for livelihood diversification for fishing
dependent communities on the islands of the three riparian states of
505Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
Lake Victoria: Report: SF-FAO/2013/23. Novemeber 2013. FAO-
smart fish Programme of the Indian Ocean commission, Ebene,
Mauritius. Retrieved from www.fao.org. Accessed 15 Feb 2015.
Kudhongania, A.W., and D.B.R. Chitamweba. 1995. Impact of environ-
mental change, species introductions and ecological interactions on
the fish stocks of Lake Victoria. In The impact of species changes in
African lakes, ed. T.J. Pitcher and P.J.B. Hart, 1932. London:
Chapman and Hall.
LVFO (2016). Regional catch assessment survey synthesis report,
June 2005November/December 2015,Jinja,Uganda.
Lwenya, C., B. Mbilingi, J. Luomba, and E. Yongo. 2009. Gender inte-
gration in the management of the Lake Victoria fisheries. African
Journal of Tropical Hydrobiology and Fisheries 12:5966. https://
doi.org/10.4314/ajthf.v12i1.58033.
Marshall, B.E. 2018. Guilty as charged: Nile perch was the cause of the
haplochromine decline in Lake Victoria. Canadian Journal of
Fisheries and Aquatic Sciences 75 (9): 15421559. https://doi.org/
10.1139/cjfas-2017-0056.
May, C.K. 2012. Active non-participation among local natural resource-
dependent communities: the case of North Carolina fisheries gover-
nance. Journal of Environmental Management 113 (0): 407416.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2012.09.022.
Measham, T., and J. Lumbasi. 2013. Success factors for community-
based natural resource management (CBNRM): lessons from
Kenya and Australia. Environmental Management 52 (3): 649
659. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00267-013-0114-9.
Medard, N.M. (2015). A social analysis of contested fishing practices in
Lake Victoria, Tanzania. (PhD thesis), Wageningen University,
Wageningen.
Mkumbo, O.C., and B.E. Marshall. 2015. The Nile perch fishery of Lake
Victoria: current status and management challenges. Fisheries
Management and Ecology 22: 5663.
Mosse, D. 1997. The symbolic making of a common property resource:
history, ecology and locality in a tank-irrigated landscape in South
India. Development and Change 28 (3): 467504. https://doi.org/10.
1111/1467-7660.00051.
Nelson, F. (2010). Community rights, conservation and contested land:
the politics of natural resource governance in Africa. London:
Earthscan.
Nielsen, J.R., P. Degnbol, K.K. Viswanathan, M. Ahmed, M. Hara, and
N.M.R. Abdullah. 2004. Fisheries co-managementan institutional
innovation? Lessons from South East Asia and Southern Africa.
Marine Policy 28 (2): 151160. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0308-
597X(03)00083-6.
Njaya, F., S. Donda, and C. Béné. 2012. Analysis of power in fisheries
co-management: experiences from Malawi. Society and Natural
Resources 25 (7): 652666.
North, D.C. 1990. Institutions, institutional change and economic
performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Nunan, F. 2006. Empowerment and institutions: managing fisheries in
Uganda. World Development 34 (7): 13161332. https://doi.org/10.
1016/j.worlddev.2005.11.016.
Nunan, F. 2010. Governance and fisheries co-management in Lake
Victoria: challenges to the adaptive governance approach. MAST 9
(1): 103125.
Nunan, F., J. Luomba, C. Lwenya, E. Yongo, K. Odongkara, and B.
Ntambi. 2012. Finding space for participation: fisherfolk mobility
and co-management of Lake Victoria fisheries. Environmental
Management 50 (2): 204216. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00267-
012-9881-y.
Nunan, F., M. Hara, and P. Onyango. 2015. Institutions and co-
management in East African Inland and Malawi fisheries: a critical
perspective. World Development 70 (0): 203214. https://doi.org/
10.1016/j.worlddev.2015.01.009.
Nunan, F., D.E. Cepj, E. Yongo, M. Salehe, B. Mbilingi, K. Odongkara,
et al. 2018. Compliance, corruption and co-management: how
corruptionfuels illegalities and undermines the legitimacy of fisher-
ies co-management. The International Journal of the Commons:12.
Obiero, K.O., R.O. Abila, M.J. Njiru, P.O. Raburu, A.O. Achieng, R.
Kundu, et al. 2015. The challenges of management: recent experi-
ences in implementing co-management in Lake Victoria, Kenya.
Lakes & Reservoirs: Research & Management 20: 116. https://
doi.org/10.1111/lre.12095.
OECD (2015). Stakeholder engagement for inclusive water governance.
Available at https://www.oecd.org/gov/stakeholder-engagement-
for-inclusive-water-governance-9789264231122-en.htm.Accessed
Feb 12 2018. Retrieved November, 22nd, 2019.
Opondo, P. (2011). Fishers and fish traders of Lake Victoria: colonial
policy and development of fish production in Kenya, 18801978.
(PhD thesis), University of South Africa.
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions
for collective action. Cambridge, New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Pascaul-Fernández, J., K. Frangoudes, and S. Williams. 2005. Local in-
stitutions. In Fish for life: interactive governance for fisheries,ed.J.
Kooiman, M. Bavinck, S. Jentoft, and R. Pullin, 153172.
Amsterdam: University of Amsterdam Press.
Pejovich, S. (2006). The effects of the interaction of formal and informal
institutions on social stability and economic development.
Institutions, Globalisation and Empowerment: Edward Elgar
Publishing
Pinkerton, E., E. Angel, N. Ladell, P. Williams, M. Nicolson, J.
Thorkelson, and H. Clifton. 2014. Local and regional strategies for
rebuilding fisheries management institutions in coastal British
Columbia: what components of comanagement are most critical?
Ecology and Society 19 (2).
Pomeroy, R.S., and F. Berkes. 1997. Two to tango: the role of govern-
ment in fisheries co-management. Marine Policy 21 (5): 465480.
https://doi.org/10.1016/s0308-597x(97)00017-1.
Pomeroy, R.S., B.M. Katon, and I. Harkes.2001. Conditions affecting the
success of fisheries co-management: lessons from Asia. Marine
Policy 25 (3): 197208. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0308-597x(01)
00010-0.
Pretty, J.N. 1995. Participatory learning for sustainable agriculture. World
Development 23 (8): 12471263. https://doi.org/10.1016/0305-
750X(95)00046-F.
Puente-Rodríguez, D. 2014. The methodologies of empowerment? A
systematic review of the deployment of participation in the coastal
zone management literature. Coastal Management 42 (5): 426446.
https://doi.org/10.1080/08920753.2014.942029.
Quimby, B., and A. Levine. 2018. Participation, power, and equity: ex-
amining three key social dimensions of fisheries comanagement.
Sustainability 10 (9): 3324. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10093324.
Rahman, H.M.T., G.M. Hickey, and S.K. Sarker. 2012. A framework for
evaluating collective action and informal institutional dynamics un-
der a resource management policy of decentralization. Ecological
Economics 83 (0): 3241. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2012.
08.018.
Ribot, J.C., A. Agrawal, A. Larson, and M. 2006. Recentralizing while
decentralizing: how national governments reappropriate forest re-
sources. World Development 34 (11): 18641886. https://doi.org/
10.1016/j.worlddev.2005.11.020.
Robinson, L.W., and E. Makupa. 2015. Using analysis of governance to
unpack community-based conservation: a case study from Tanzania.
Environmental Management 56 (5): 12141227. https://doi.org/10.
1007/s00267-015-0573-2.
Russell, A.J.M., and T. Dobson. 2011. Chiefs as critical partners for
decentralized governance of fisheries: an analysis of co-
management case studies in Malawi. Society and Natural
Resources 24 (7): 734750. https://doi.org/10.1080/08941920.
2010.501432.
506 Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
Schuurhuizen, R., Tilburg, A.V., & Kambewa, E. (2005). Fish in Kenya:
the Nile-perch chain. Agro-food chains and networks for develop-
ment. Retrieved from http://edepot.wur.nl/38465. Accessed 9
Jan 2020.
Searle, J.R. (2010). Making the social world. The structure of human
civilization.Oxford University Press: Oxford.
Sen, S., and J.R. Nielsen. 1996. Fisheries co-management: a comparative
analysis. Marine Policy 20 (5): 405. https://doi.org/10.1016/0308-
597X(96)00028-0.
Snell, M., K.P. Bell, and J. Leahy. 2013. Local institutions and lake
management. Lakes & Reservoirs: Research and Management 18
(1): 3544. https://doi.org/10.1111/lre.12017.
Tiller, R.G., J. Mork, Y. Liu, Å.L. Borgersen, and R. Richards. 2015. To
adapt or not adapt: assessing the adaptive capacity of artisanal fish-
ers in the Trondheimsfjord (Norway) to jellyfish (Periphylla
periphylla) bloom and purse seiners. Marine and Coastal
Fisheries 7(1):260273. https://doi.org/10.1080/19425120.2015.
1037873.
Van Hecken, G., J. Bastiaensen, and C. Windey. 2015. Towards a power-
sensitive and socially-informed analysis of payments for ecosystem
services (PES): addressing the gaps in the current debate. Ecological
Economics 120: 117125. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2015.
10.012.
White, S.C. 1996. Depoliticising development: the uses and abuses of
participation. Development in Practice 6(1):615. https://doi.org/
10.1080/0961452961000157564.
Yin, R.K. 2003. Case study research: design and methods.Thousand
Oaks: Sage Publications.
PublishersnoteSpringer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdic-
tional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
507Maritime Studies (2020) 19:489–507
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
Terms and Conditions
Springer Nature journal content, brought to you courtesy of Springer Nature Customer Service Center GmbH (“Springer Nature”).
Springer Nature supports a reasonable amount of sharing of research papers by authors, subscribers and authorised users (“Users”), for small-
scale personal, non-commercial use provided that all copyright, trade and service marks and other proprietary notices are maintained. By
accessing, sharing, receiving or otherwise using the Springer Nature journal content you agree to these terms of use (“Terms”). For these
purposes, Springer Nature considers academic use (by researchers and students) to be non-commercial.
These Terms are supplementary and will apply in addition to any applicable website terms and conditions, a relevant site licence or a personal
subscription. These Terms will prevail over any conflict or ambiguity with regards to the relevant terms, a site licence or a personal subscription
(to the extent of the conflict or ambiguity only). For Creative Commons-licensed articles, the terms of the Creative Commons license used will
apply.
We collect and use personal data to provide access to the Springer Nature journal content. We may also use these personal data internally within
ResearchGate and Springer Nature and as agreed share it, in an anonymised way, for purposes of tracking, analysis and reporting. We will not
otherwise disclose your personal data outside the ResearchGate or the Springer Nature group of companies unless we have your permission as
detailed in the Privacy Policy.
While Users may use the Springer Nature journal content for small scale, personal non-commercial use, it is important to note that Users may
not:
use such content for the purpose of providing other users with access on a regular or large scale basis or as a means to circumvent access
control;
use such content where to do so would be considered a criminal or statutory offence in any jurisdiction, or gives rise to civil liability, or is
otherwise unlawful;
falsely or misleadingly imply or suggest endorsement, approval , sponsorship, or association unless explicitly agreed to by Springer Nature in
writing;
use bots or other automated methods to access the content or redirect messages
override any security feature or exclusionary protocol; or
share the content in order to create substitute for Springer Nature products or services or a systematic database of Springer Nature journal
content.
In line with the restriction against commercial use, Springer Nature does not permit the creation of a product or service that creates revenue,
royalties, rent or income from our content or its inclusion as part of a paid for service or for other commercial gain. Springer Nature journal
content cannot be used for inter-library loans and librarians may not upload Springer Nature journal content on a large scale into their, or any
other, institutional repository.
These terms of use are reviewed regularly and may be amended at any time. Springer Nature is not obligated to publish any information or
content on this website and may remove it or features or functionality at our sole discretion, at any time with or without notice. Springer Nature
may revoke this licence to you at any time and remove access to any copies of the Springer Nature journal content which have been saved.
To the fullest extent permitted by law, Springer Nature makes no warranties, representations or guarantees to Users, either express or implied
with respect to the Springer nature journal content and all parties disclaim and waive any implied warranties or warranties imposed by law,
including merchantability or fitness for any particular purpose.
Please note that these rights do not automatically extend to content, data or other material published by Springer Nature that may be licensed
from third parties.
If you would like to use or distribute our Springer Nature journal content to a wider audience or on a regular basis or in any other manner not
expressly permitted by these Terms, please contact Springer Nature at
onlineservice@springernature.com
... While these co-management arrangements can deliver substantial benefits to user groups under certain conditions (Evans et al. 2011;d'Armengol et al. 2018;Smallhorn-West et al. 2023), their capacity to address conflicts, mitigate power imbalances and promote social equity remains uncertain (Béné et al. 2009;Berkes 2009;Cinner et al. 2012;d'Armengol et al. 2018). Indeed, some studies have found that co-management has exacerbated existing power imbalances (Berkes 2009;Béné et al. 2009;Etiegni et al. 2020), facilitated elite capture (Cinner et al. 2012;Etiegni et al. 2019) and intensified conflicts (Gelcich et al. 2006). This situation presents a paradox: Co-management was initiated in part to address equity concerns associated with centralised management (Rivera-Guieb 2002;Ratner and Allison 2012). ...
... This situation presents a paradox: Co-management was initiated in part to address equity concerns associated with centralised management (Rivera-Guieb 2002;Ratner and Allison 2012). Influenced by common property theory (Ostrom 1990;Johannes 2002), these reforms largely assumed that co-management's participatory nature would lead to fair distribution of costs and benefits and equitable decisionmaking compared to other approaches (Pomeroy 1995;Castro and Nielsen 2001;Etiegni et al. 2020). However, very few studies have examined equity in CPR governance (Allouche 2020;Agrawal 2014), especially fisheries (Bavinck et al. 2018;d'Armengol et al. 2018;Cochrane 2021), and those that have (Agrawal and Benson 2011;d'Armengol et al. 2018) present mixed evidence. ...
... Lastly, we found that inclusive participation, strong social capital and secure property rights were most often associated with improved equity outcomes, while weak social capital, institutional design and management oversight were most often associated with reduced equity outcomes. Inclusive participation being the most significant driver of improved equity outcomes is consistent with our finding that more devolved co-management types are more likely to yield improved equity outcomes, as well as a significant body of research showing the critical role of user participation in managing CPRs like fisheries (Sultana and Abeyasekera 2008;Trimble and Berkes 2013;Etiegni et al. 2020). Several conceptual frameworks emphasise that superficial, manipulative and passive forms of participation fail to transfer actual decision-making power (Pretty 1995;Agrawal and Ribot 1999;Ruano-Chamorro et al. 2022), which serves to mask the perpetuation of nonaccountability (Agrawal and Ribot 1999) and lack of real influence held by user groups. ...
Article
Small‐scale fisheries (SSF) are commonly governed through co‐management, a widely advocated approach for promoting equitable governance. However, evidence suggests that this governance approach can sometimes exacerbate power imbalances, facilitate elite capture and intensify conflicts. To foster co‐management that successfully enhances equity in SSF governance, it is crucial to understand when and why it leads to positive or negative equity outcomes. To this end, we undertook a scoping review to identify empirical research on the relationship between SSF co‐management and equity outcomes. We identified 30 empirical studies that assessed equity outcomes in SSF co‐management initiatives. Our analysis revealed four key findings: (1) distributional and procedural equity received approximately equal levels of attention, largely without an explicit equity lens; (2) co‐management had mixed impacts on equity, with the most prevalent outcome being improvement to equity; (3) delegated and cooperative co‐management types were more often associated with improved equity outcomes, while consultative co‐management was more often associated with reductions or no change; and (4) inclusive participation, strong social capital and secure property rights were most often associated with improved equity outcomes, while weak social capital, institutional design and management oversight were most often associated with reduced equity outcomes. However, the evidence supporting our findings was limited, with only seven studies robustly documenting the role of inclusive participation in enhancing equity. Our review offers valuable insights into the complex interplay between SSF co‐management and equity, informing future research and practice and policy interventions aimed at achieving social goals through co‐management governance approaches.
... The focus on a protected area also provides a well-defined geographic boundary in which enforcement is concentrated, while the complete closure to all fishing makes effective enforcement more viable [9]. This has led to an acceptance of regulations and collective pride and celebration among fisheries participants [25,[92][93][94]. One aspect that should not be overlooked is the straightforward needs-based approach to the Mbenji Island fishery, in which fishing grounds near Chikombe remain open for the most vulnerable to continue fishing efforts during closed seasons. ...
... Although significant literature has focused on elite capture within fisheries management, occurring when traditional authorities or other elites mobilise their influence to exert control over decentralising initiatives, continuing to ignore existing power structures and institutional realities is not a feasible response. Without this engagement, leaders have frequently proven to be obstructive to different management arrangements [23,64,92,69,98]. ...
... This relates to where different pieces of knowledge are included or empowered too. For example, while BVCs in Malawi are intended to enable decisions based on fishers' ecological and experiential knowledge, the design of these institutions failed to engage with key stakeholders surrounding the social, cultural, institutional, spiritual, and economic contexts shaping fisheries activities [23,24,92,67,68,75]. This means practical knowledge is recognised as essential to inform harvest management but only through institutions that stakeholders were not involved in designing. ...
Article
Full-text available
A history of fisheries management in Lake Malawi and Mbenji: Learning from the past to inform the future. In this paper, we argue that comparative historical analysis of cen tralised and customary management can offer important lessons for future directions for fisheries management
... More recent moves to 'integrate' other forms of knowledge beyond traditional scientific and technical data have in large part continued with this trend, in which knowledges that do not fit the 'normal' science mould have been taken and reshaped in attempts to fit into such moulds. This has reduced such knowledges to ancillary data to better inform scientific models and approaches for problems and challenges already set and defined by governmental or scientific research agendas (Walley, 2004;Etiegni et al., 2020). Such approaches can fail to acknowledge non-traditional scientific knowledge as being more than ecological knowledge, centred on place-based issues with specific contexts, histories, challenges, experiences, and interests. ...
... This requires keen and attentive vigilance to how power, access and participation are realised in decision making. As the above case studies demonstrate, this is an iterative and continual process that requires substantial time, trust, and resources (Gutieŕrez et al., 2011;d'Armengol et al., 2018;Etiegni et al., 2020;Maxwell et al., 2020;Cooke et al., 2021;Reid et al., 2021;Silver et al., 2022). ...
Article
Full-text available
Governance of the ocean and its biodiversity is deeply entangled within social, political and cultural histories. The evolution of marine science has been subject to similar influences, and we (the authors) consider these factors to create, embed and reinforce knowledge hierarchies in ocean governance processes and associated research that set societal patterns of prioritisation and exclusion. Such knowledge hierarchies have constructed dominant Western-oriented knowledge systems as ‘rational’ and ‘objective’ approaches to environmental governance in contrast to non-Western knowledge systems and have led to a dominance of natural (normal) sciences over centralised biodiversity governance. The extraction and incorporation of traditional knowledge into the Western-oriented scientific canon through myriad historical and contemporary processes in ocean biodiversity governance often reproduce knowledge hierarchies, do not benefit knowledge holders and are often considered incomplete, inappropriate or absent. As we address current ocean biodiversity and conservation challenges, researchers must be aware of the history of knowledge extraction, impositions and assumptions within their fields. Researchers must also actively acknowledge and address these histories in their work to avoid marginalisation and support ethical, empathetic, and rigorous knowledge production that meets the needs of society. In this paper, through a development of the concept of knowledge hierarchies, we explore case studies of research diverse in geography and discipline ranging from action research in Namibia, the application of arts-based methodologies in legal proceedings to research focused at an international level, and the concept of ocean literacies, all of which are located under the umbrella of a project specifically targeting transformative ocean governance. It becomes evident that knowledge hierarchies are multi-layered, perpetuating, and often reproduced even when attempting to address hierarchies through such methods as the integration or ‘bringing together’ of diverse knowledge systems. Effective change will therefore require sensitive and multi-faceted approaches to knowledge hierarchies, including processes of embracing discomfort, which will be important to work with, as well as through. While there will be continued tensions between hierarchies, it is a sine qua non that researchers need to build a commitment to understanding where powers lie, rather than ignoring such imbalances or, similarly, by idealising approaches.
... At the workshop organised in Shimoni to validate findings from fieldwork, two major areas around local governance emerged as crucial when it comes to making governance more sensitive to the needs of the local population for food; these were the role and potential of trade conducted by women small-scale traders, and the necessity to strengthen the role and capacity of the BMUs in mediating between actors. These are two areas that are closely connected (Matsue et al. 2014;Nunan & Cepić 2020); the functioning of BMUs as catalysts of participation in fisheries governance in Kenyan fisheries, either inland or coastal, has been marred by a number of conflicts over resources (Murunga et al. 2021), unsustainable fishing practices (Etiegni et al. 2017), and poor integration of formal and informal institutions and rules, with the latter often overriding the first, undermining compliance with rules that BMUs are supposed to implement on the ground (Etiegni et al. 2020). When it comes to women's participation in co-management through formal structures (i.e. ...
Article
Full-text available
This article proposes the case of Kenyan coastal fisheries as a potentially crucial reservoir of food-related benefits for the marginalised and those living in poverty, but where a food-centred lens or approach is seldom mainstreamed in local and national governance. Borrowing insights from post-structuralist marine social sciences, this article presents an ethnographic account of grassroots practices in-the-making such as handling, sorting, and allocating fish once caught, and how these practices lead to local categorisations and classifications of fish. This sort of evidence and knowledge around local categorisations and classifications of fish spotlights the importance of considering the post-harvest sector (as opposed to the activity of fishing alone), that is, how the use of catch determines access through micro relations of power and agency. Through the analysis of two different locations of Watamu and Shimoni in terms of the fisheries economy and overall development, the analysis of these categories and classifications highlights the necessity to account for a fairer access and distribution rather than solely production (of fish) that is overly market-oriented.
... Therefore, command and control measures of governance enforced from above may also be ineffective to address the bio-ecological, economic and social concerns of fisheries [6]. As a common pool resource, fisheries could benefit from co-management to improve human equity and ecological sustainability since such approach is based on the assumptions that participation of all resources users in decision making may promote ecologically sustainable outcomes vs top down management approaches [7]. In order to achieve this, measures such as ecosystem-based management, which aims to be an integrated approach including the entire ecosystem, including humans has been developed, however amongst the challenges J of Agri Earth & Environmental Sciences 2024 that this approach faces is the impact evaluation of human activities on ecosystems as well as the trade-off between different social, economic and environmental objectives [8]. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper presents a review on the participatory multi-criteria decision making (MCDM) methods applied in fisheries management. Marine fisheries are an important part of the ecosystem which are under the threat of overexploitation partly due to ineffective management measures. With a significant economic and social role in coastal communities, fisheries are an important natural resource and contributor to food security, livelihoods and employment, export earnings, and economic growth. Fisheries have a complex multi-dimensional dynamic involving aspects related to the marine environment, social and cultural issues and a unique governance structure due their public resource nature. Hence the sustainable management of this resource requires methods that incorporate these aspects as well as the incorporation of multiple stakeholders such as fishermen, processors, NGOs, and policy makers which often have different (conflicting) preferences. This review shows how MCDM methods could be applied for different groups of stakeholders in the marine fishery sector and which set of criteria have been applied more commonly as well as highlighting the gaps that exist in the literature. Participatory MCDM techniques, especially value measurement techniques such as AHP have experienced increased application in the period between 1998-2020 and have been applied globally in single species and multi-species fisheries management.
... However, it should not be assumed that networked approaches will inherently achieve these outcomes or automatically overcome resource management issues (Plummer & Armitage, 2007). Like other ostensibly collaborative approaches, networked governance arrangements may reproduce the socio-political conditions of the existing management regime due to issues such as power imbalances (Cinner et al., 2012;Etiegni et al., 2020;Moyo, 2023), co-option (Singleton, 2000), institutional inertia (Akamani, 2023;Ballet et al., 2009;Livingstone & Anthony, 2023), exclusionary practices (Castro & Nielsen, 2001;Chen et al., 2012;Plummer & Armitage, 2007), and a focus on a narrow range of interests (Leys & Vanclay, 2011;Mizanur Rahman, 2021). Network governance failure to address issues such as institutional inertia has been noted in multiple marine governance systems (Greenhill et al., 2020;Kelly et al., 2019;van Leeuwen et al., 2024). ...
... However, the identification rates for these two ecosystem services was quite low, a result that is comparable to preceding studies that have shown that local people have low identification rates for supporting and regulating ecosystem services (see Ouko et al. 2018;Gouwakinnou et al. 2019;Kimpouni et al. 2021). Interestingly, most people could not identify the role that macrophytes played in ensuring continuity of fish populations, a major source of protein and livelihood for local people living adjacent to these lakes (Ndetei 2006;Omondi et al. 2014;Etiegni, Irvine, and Kooy 2020). Similarly, most respondents could not identify the role of macrophytes in reducing silt deposition into the lakes, which is a leading cause of poor water quality in all three study locations (Awange and Ong'ang'a 2006;Ngugi, Ogindo, and Ertsen 2015;Omondi et al., 2016). ...
Article
Correspondence: Rebeccah Kwamboka Onwong'a (rebeccahonwonga@yahoo.com) ABSTRACT It is increasingly being recognised that local people's knowledge can contribute to the ecological and socioeconomic goals of natural resource management programmes. Yet, few studies have examined local people's knowledge concerning freshwater macrophyte diversity. Consequently, the extent to which local people's knowledge can contribute to mitigating freshwater mac-rophyte degradation and supporting their management remains largely unknown. To contribute towards filling this knowledge gap, we investigated local people's knowledge, perceptions and management practices of freshwater macrophyte species. Data collection involved conducting face-to-face in-depth interviews and focus group discussions among local people who lived in areas adjacent to Lake Baringo, Nyanza Gulf of Lake Victoria and the Kenyan side of Lake Jipe. The sociodemographic characteristics of the respondents were summarised using descriptive statistics. Then, generalised linear mixed-effect models were used to test whether the respondent's sociodemographic characteristics were associated with their macrophyte species recognition skills, benefits and problems associated with macrophytes and management practices. Our respondents named a total of 35 macrophyte species, with each respondent naming an average of six species. Our results showed that respondents who were not involved in fishing and fish-related activities identified more macrophytes than those who participated in such activities. Additionally, individuals who frequently visited the lake named more macrophyte species compared to those who visited either daily or occasionally. While our respondents acknowledged various benefits and problems associated with macrophytes, there was a higher recognition rate for those that directly impacted humans. Regarding local management practices, it was observed that macrophytes were not conserved, with management efforts focusing solely on problematic species. Overall, macrophyte naming skills, knowledge on provisioning and supporting ecosystem services, direct adverse macrophyte impacts and management methods increased with age. We identified knowledge gaps regarding alien species and the indirect impacts of macro-phytes. Addressing these gaps is crucial.
... Active participation and cooperation of the government, non-governmental organizations (NGOs), organized groups, and other stakeholders in management decisions build the basis for its development [10]. Promotion of well-organized management by actors of collective action improves the sustainability of common-pool resources like fisheries, which could improve the livelihood and food security of the users [58]. Well-organized stakeholders, through partnerships and supporters of the actors, create value addition, minimize loss, improve quality, adopt technologies, and improve the economic gain of the sector [59]. ...
Article
Full-text available
Natural resources such as fish are vital for improving human livelihood and serving as sources of food, income and employment opportunities in Ethiopia. But, its degradation and overexploitation lead to anxiety about the living standards of human beings and other living things. The degradation of these resources, which is caused by the less common participation of all stakeholders in protecting the resources, is the most challenging issue in the country. The objective of this paper is to review fishery production and management and their challenges, the extent of the overexploitation of natural resources, the contributions of collective action in fishery production and management, and fishery collective action challenges in Ethiopia. The review paper identified that the existence of a lack of strong coordination among different actors like local communities, the government, development agents, research centers and donor organizations whose concern are with the fishery sector caused the degradation of water bodies and fishery resources in Ethiopia. These issues resulted in challenges in fishery resource production and management, mismanagement in solving social differences among local communities, and low cooperation among communities in protecting fish resources. Besides, these challenges also caused a limited expansion of fishery collective action, overexploitation of fishery resources, and less concern for the protection of fish diversity species in the country. Therefore, essential policy implications forwarded are creating and improving joint collaboration between fish users, local communities, government institutions and development agents; organizing and empowering the local communities in collective action to involve them in the fishery sector to contribute to practical improvements in the protection, production, management and sustainability of fish resources.
Article
Full-text available
Social–ecological systems need to become more sustainable, especially in places undergoing rapid land degradation. The challenge is to reverse the depletion of natural resources while improving human well-being. This is especially critical in Africa where rural populations are often highly dependent on natural resources. Since the 1980s, several territories in Africa have initiated changes to reverse land degradation. This study aims at drawing lessons from these experiences. We identified seventeen cases of African territories that have engaged in sustainability interventions, either restoration or rehabilitation initiatives, with varying degrees of success. The key factors—grouped as information of key actors, their motivation to change practices, and their capacity to do so—that are recognized as potential success factors or obstacles for interventions towards sustainable resource use were analysed. Results highlighted the importance of maintaining a balance of factors over the long term. Managing sustainability transitions in low-income contexts requires integrating poverty-related concerns, mitigating the risks inherent to any change in practices, creating incentives for participation by all actors, and strengthening coalitions over the long term between actors around a sustainability agenda.
Chapter
Full-text available
One billion people around the world rely upon fish as their primary and in many cases, their only source of protein. At the same time, increasing demand from wealthier populations in the U.S. and Europe encourages dangerous overfishing practices along coastal waters. 'Fish for Life' addresses the problem of overfishing at local, national, and global levels as part of a comprehensive governance approach - one that acknowledges the critical intersection of food security, environmental protection, and international law in fishing practices throughout the world.
Article
Full-text available
The decentralisation of resource management through co-management assumes that the devolution of power benefits resource users. This assumption is often premised on the democratic election of leaders within resource user organisations. In this article, we investigate the validity of co-management assumptions about who benefits from a devolution of decision-making power through a case study analysis of political equity in fisherfolk organisations of Beach Management Units (BMUs) in Lake Victoria (Kenya). From the analysis of the distribution of political power, we identify how, where, and for whom greater accountability can work to address the current political inertia of fisherfolk, who form a majority of the BMU membership. We also identify the relationships between the empowerment of fisherfolk, the accountability of the BMU leaders, and the distribution of political power determining decision making in co-management. We conclude with identifying how other mechanisms of social accountability beyond elections can improve accountability of elected leaders of resource users for improved co-management outcomes.
Article
Full-text available
Comanagement of natural resources is a well-established approach to the management of common-pool resources such as small-scale fisheries, operating in multiple contexts and settings for over two decades. These programs are expected to be adaptable and promote social and ecological benefits, such as sustainable livelihoods and biodiversity goals. As programs mature, it is important to consider how some core principles of comanagement have manifested in practice, as well as whether they deliver on these promised benefits. Drawing from the conservation, small-scale fisheries, and fisheries management literature, this paper examines three fundamental principles of fisheries comanagement: participation, equity, and power. The conceptualization, definitions, and measures of each theme are presented, with discussion of the current gaps in the literature. We also demonstrate the deep interrelationships between these key dimensions of comanagement, and the need for greater attention to their combined influence on comanagement outcomes and processes. While the literature offers foundational ideas for incorporating these themes into fisheries comanagement practice, tethering these concepts to clear, but context-specific goals and practices is essential for improving social outcomes. We find that key goals of fisheries comanagement could be impeded by the lack of depth in addressing these themes in practice, and suggest the need for greater critical attention to their expressions in comanagement processes.
Article
Full-text available
Links between corruption and illegal practices within fisheries are recognised in existing literature but little reference has been made to how these interconnected practices affect the performance and legitimacy of fisheries co-management. Research in the three countries bordering Lake Victoria, Kenya, Tanzania and Uganda, demonstrated that corruption is systemic and that members of all stakeholder groups – fishers, fisheries officers, police and the judiciary - are implicated. It was confirmed that corruption is strongly linked to illegalities and that corruption in this context should be viewed as a collection action problem, with fishers reluctant to invest in legal gears and methods when they perceive illegalities and corruption to be prevalent. It was also found that corrupt practices linked to illegalities discourages local level fisheries management structures – the Beach Management Units – from enforcing regulations and contributes to a lack of trust between fishers and government. Linked corruption and illegal fisheries practices were therefore found to be undermining the performance and legitimacy of co-management. The article concludes that whilst co-management offers opportunities for collusive corruption through collaborative arrangements, any management system will be susceptible to the harmful effects of corruption where it is systemic and is not formally recognised or appropriately addressed. Greater official recognition of the links between corruption and illegalities, and a range of appropriate actions taken to this collective action problem, is essential if co-management is to have a chance of success.
Article
Full-text available
Adaptive governance continues to attract considerable interest in academic and policy circles. This is with good reason, given its increasing relevance in a globalized and changing world. At the same time, adaptive governance is the subject of a growing body of critical literature concerned with the ways in which it theorizes the social world. In this paper, we respond to these critiques, which we see as broadly concerning the process, power, and meaning dimensions of environmental and natural resource governance. We argue that adaptive governance theory would benefit from engaging constructively with critical institutionalism, a school of thought that, like adaptive governance, has one foot in commons scholarship. Critical institutionalism conceives of institutional change as a process of bricolage, where those involved piece together new arrangements from the resources to hand. This approach highlights the interplay of structure and agency, and illuminates how new governance arrangements form and come to be seen as natural in dynamic relation to the wider social and cultural landscape. We consider how these arrangements tend to reflect dominant power relations, whilst the plural nature of social life also provides scope for adaptation and transformative change
Article
Full-text available
Debate on the contribution of Nile perch (Lates niloticus) to the demise of Lake Victoria’s 500+ endemic haplochromine cichlids centers around the “top-down” and “bottom-up” hypotheses. The former suggests Nile perch destroyed the haplochromines, causing the disruption of food chains and nutrient cycling and so initiating the accelerated eutrophication of the lake. The latter proposes that haplochromines suppressed Nile perch by preying on its eggs and fry or competing with juveniles for food. A recent paper argued that accelerated eutrophication caused by a climatic event led to their collapse, allowing Nile perch to explode. However, the Nile perch population grew before haplochromines decreased, and they only collapsed once Nile perch biomass exceeded theirs. The chronology indicates that accelerated eutrophication of the lake followed rather than preceded the haplochromine collapse, suggesting that eutrophication was not its cause. A size-selective predation model developed to support the bottom-up hypothesis is discussed in light of existing data, but does not support the bottom-up hypothesis. It was concluded that the top-down model better fits the data and conforms to the law of parsimony.
Article
A primary aim of this paper is to establish some workable meanings of key terms of institutional theory including institution, convention and organization, by drawing on insights from several academic disciplines. Institutions are defined broadly as systems of established and prevalent social rules that structure social interactions. This, in turn, prompts some examination of the concept of a rule, and why rules are followed. The author discusses some general issues concerning how institutions function and how they interact with individual agents, their habits, and their beliefs. The paper also addresses the controversial distinction between institutions and organizations. D. North’s influential formulations of these terms are criticized for being incomplete and misleading. The author examines this distinction and what may be meant by the term formal when applied to institutions or rules. Here an organization is treated as a type of institution involving membership and sovereignty. Further types of institution are also considered, including the difference between self-organizing and other institutions. The article identifies an excessive bias in the discussion of institutions toward those of the self-organizing type, showing theoretically that these are a special case. The author argues that institutions also differ with regard to their degree of sensitivity to changes in the personalities of the agents involved.
Article
Declines in fish yields and shifts in species composition are serious concerns in the African Great lakes of Tanganyika, Malawi (Nyasa/Niassa) and Victoria. Despite management and regulatory structures, all the lakes remain open‐access fisheries, severely depressing yields, economic returns and threatening biodiversity. While the lakes require an ecosystem‐based approach to management, this has not been realised because of a lack of institutional capacities, insufficient political will or simply being overwhelmed by the scale of the endeavour. Sustainable fisheries management can only be achieved through a refocus towards a stronger socio‐ecological approach and re‐evaluating how to realistically improve fish yield and environmental protection. This requires a combination of the following: (1) acceptance of suboptimal fish yields; (2) community‐enforced regulations that restrict access to fisheries and destruction of inshore habitats; (3) enhanced national and local institutional capacities and collaboration among the riparian states; and (4) major awareness and educational efforts that demonstrate the national and international importance of these lakes for food supply and biodiversity in pursuance of the Sustainable Development Goals. Without such actions, the prognosis for long‐term sustainable fisheries is bleak, and international projects and conferences will merely bear witness to further degradation of resources and the livelihoods they support.