ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

Over one-third of humanity lives under populist regimes—and many of those regimes are turning increasingly authoritarian. It is a worldwide challenge to liberal democracy. The conventional wisdom is that bad economics is to blame: the losers from globalization are angry and voting populists into office is their revenge. The policy implication is a kind of technocratic fantasy: fix the economy and populism will fade away. That view has weak empirical foundations, since many emerging countries that are clear winners from globalization have recently elected populists. In this essay I argue that we cannot understand the surge in populism without understanding the rise of identity politics around the world. Identity is the intermediate stopover in the two-way feedback between economics and politics. A focus on identity politics has important practical implications. One of them is that, to succeed in the fight against populism, democratic politicians have to learn to practice identity politics, but of the right kind. The challenge is to build national identities based not on nativism or xenophobia, but on liberal democratic values.
Velasco A. Populism and Identity Politics.
LSE
Public Policy Review
. 2020; 1(1): 1, pp. 1–8.
DOI: https://doi.org/10.31389/lseppr.1
RESEARCH
Populism and Identity Politics
Andrés Velasco
London School of Economics and Political Science, GB
A.Velasco1@lse.ac.uk
Over one-third of humanity lives under populist regimes—and many of those regimes are turning
increasingly authoritarian. It is a worldwide challenge to liberal democracy. The conventional wisdom is
that bad economics is to blame: the losers from globalization are angry and voting populists into oce
is their revenge. The policy implication is a kind of
technocratic fantasy
: x the economy and populism
will fade away. That view has weak empirical foundations, since many emerging countries that are clear
winners from globalization have recently elected populists. In this essay I argue that we cannot understand
the surge in populism without understanding the rise of identity politics around the world. Identity is
the intermediate stopover in the two-way feedback between economics and politics. A focus on identity
politics has important practical implications. One of them is that, to succeed in the ght against populism,
democratic politicians have to learn to practice identity politics, but of the right kind. The challenge is to
build national identities based not on nativism or xenophobia, but on liberal democratic values.
Keywords: democracy; populism; rule of law; authoritarianism; inequality; identity; national identity
1. The Technocratic Illusion
Narendra Modi governs nearly 1,340,000,000 Indians. Donald Trump rules over 330 million Americans. Add Brazil, with
210 million people and a populist president who makes Trump look like an apprentice. Add the 170 million Europeans
who live under governments with at least one populist party in the cabinet.1 Add Mexico, a country of over 130 million.
And the Philippines, with 100 million. And Turkey, with nearly 80 million. And Poland, with 38 million. And Venezuela,
with 32 million. And you can keep adding. Over one-third of humanity lives under regimes one can safely call popu-
list—and many of those regimes are turning increasingly authoritarian. It is a worldwide challenge to liberal democracy.
Why is this happening? The conventional wisdom is that bad economics is to blame: the losers from globalization are
angry and voting populists into office is their revenge. The policy implication is a kind of technocratic fantasy: fix the
economy and populism will fade away.
That view has weak empirical foundations. Countries like Hungary, India, Israel, Mexico, Poland, the Philippines and
Turkey are clear winners from globalization, and yet they have all recently elected populists. The conventional wisdom
has been shaped by the experiences of the United States and the United Kingdom, where median wages have stagnated
and income distribution worsened over the last three decades. Yet even in the US and Western Europe, the evidence that
economic insecurity alone has fueled the rise of populism is inconclusive.
The conventional wisdom also has weak conceptual foundations. Of course economics matters, but there is no auto-
matic relationship between economic changes and political outcomes. Politics and culture mediate the effect of any
economic shock—and they can also be an independent source of shocks. In this essay I argue that we cannot understand
the surge in populism without understanding the rise of identity politics around the world. Identity is the intermediate
stopover in the two-way feedback between economics and politics.
A focus on identity politics has important practical implications. One of them is that to succeed in the fight against
populism, democratic politicians have to learn to practice identity politics, but of the right kind. The challenge is to
build national identities based not on nativism or xenophobia, but on liberal democratic values. It is a tall order, but
not an impossible one.
2. The age of innocence
Thirty years ago, history was supposed to have ended. Liberalism had won. The Berlin Wall had fallen and democracy,
in the words of Yale professors Juan Linz and Alfred Stepan [1], was ‘the only game in town’. The liberal-democratic
wave swept through Central and Eastern Europe and made countries like Poland, Hungary and the Czech Republic into
1 “How Populism emerged as an electoral force in Europe”. The Guardian, 16 November 2018.
Velasco: Populism and Identity PoliticsArt. 1, page 2 of 8
poster children for liberal-democratic transitions. In Southern Europe, democracy and economic growth were flourish-
ing again. Autarky, nationalism and military coups in Greece, Spain and Portugal seemed the stuff of decades past.
Turkey was a working democracy and would soon become, many hoped, a member of the European Union.
In South Africa, the hideous apartheid regime was crumbling. A negotiated political settlement would soon allow
Nelson Mandela to move from prison to high office. In the New World the news was just as inspiring. Argentina, Brazil,
Chile and Uruguay had recently returned to democracy. Soon, countries from Mexico to Peru would take steps toward
this greater freedom.
How distant that moment now seems. Venezuela has slid back into dictatorship and Nicaragua is almost there. The
shadow of far-right authoritarianism has reappeared in Italy, Spain, and Greece, while all over Southern Europe nation-
alists and demagogues call the European democratic enterprise into question. Something far more dramatic is under-
way in Central and Eastern Europe. Poland and Hungary are quasi-autocracies that trample on civil rights and pack
once-autonomous institutions with government cronies. The same is true of Turkey.
Even long-established democracies are under stress. In the United States, Donald Trump has repeatedly clashed
with Congress and the courts. Narendra Modi, India’s prime minister, openly disdains India’s secular constitution. The
Economist recently criticized him ‘for his apparent determination to transform India from a tolerant, multi-religious
place into a chauvinist Hindu state’.
As Steven Levitsky and Daniel Ziblatt wrote in their 2018 book How Democracies Die [2], we tend to think the end
comes with rolling tanks and machine gun rattle. But it need not be that dramatic: ‘Democracies also die at the hands
not of generals but of elected leaders (…) who subvert the very process that brought them to power. Some of these
leaders dismantle democracy quickly (…). More often, though, democracies erode slowly, in barely visible steps.’
3. Dening Populism
So populism is a threat to liberal democracy. But what is populism? Economists, unsurprisingly, have defined the
phenomenon in exclusively economic terms. Dornbusch and Edwards (1991) provided the now-classic definition:
populism is ‘an approach to economics that emphasizes growth and income redistribution and deemphasizes the risks
of inflation and deficit finance, external constraints, and the reaction of economic agents to aggressive nonmarket
policies’ [3].
But this definition seems ill-fitting when we consider most of the populist regimes that we see in place today. Instead,
there is something we can call political populism, distinct from economic populism. Muller [4] and Mudde and Rovira
[5] provide a useful definition: populism is a way of doing politics in which ‘the people’ are pitted in conflict against
others—various ‘elites’, local minorities, immigrants, foreigners. Muller stresses populists’ moralistic interpretation of
politics: those on the side of the people are moral; the rest are immoral, doing work the of a corrupt elite.
This means populism is not an ideology. It does not pretend to offer ‘complex [or] comprehensive answers to the
political questions that modern societies generate’, and so both right-wing and left-wing types of populism are possible.
Instead, populism rests on a triad: denial of complexity, distrust of pluralism and anti-elitism. Most of us believe that
social choices are complex, and that the existence of plural views about what to do is a natural consequence of this
complexity. Populists deny this. As Ralf Dahrendorf once put it, ‘Populism is simple; democracy is complex’ [6].
Inevitably, then, populists do not believe in pluralism. Since there is only one right view—that of the people—so there
is only one view deserving of political legitimacy. It follows that the complex mechanisms of liberal democracy, with
all that delegation and representation, are unnecessary. Instead, populist leaders make the claim that they alone can
represent the people, unchecked by other institutions or individuals.
Populism is also—crucially—a rebellion against various elites, including, of course, traditional political elites.2 In
Politics as a Vocation, his famous lecture of a century ago, Max Weber warned that a key risk for modern democracy was
that a political class would arise, disconnected from voters and the common people. Well, that political class did arise.
Now people are revolting against it.
The standard refrain is that citizens vote for that politician with whom they would like to have a beer. But rather than
sharing a drink with the average voter, leading politicians spend too much of their time with others like themselves—
bankers, business people, top civil servants, high-flying academics. To ascertain which politicians can be successful
today, Yascha Mounk calls for a ‘inverted likeability test’: voters do not prefer the candidate they would rather have a
beer with; they prefer the candidate who would rather have a beer with them [7]. Too many conventional politicians fail
this test.
4. Politics Trumps Economics
What is behind the rise of populism? Why this new and powerful threat to the liberal-democracy, a political system that
just 30 years ago towered triumphantly above all else?
The standard answer takes the economic perspective and focuses on the pocketbook. In countries like the United
States and the United Kingdom, the distribution of income has worsened and the top 1% is reaping the lion’s share.
In places left behind by technological change and globalization, people have lost their jobs and their patience. The
2 Müller [4] and Mudde and Rovira [5] agree that anti-pluralism and anti-elitism are two key features of political populism.
Velasco: Populism and Identity Politics Art. 1, page 3 of 8
2008 global financial crisis not only caused much pain; it also reinforced the conviction that Wall Street is the enemy
of Main Street. No wonder politics has become confrontational and populists have the upper hand.
If this narrative is right, the policy conclusion is simple: tax the rich, redistribute more income, and throw out the ras-
cals who did the bankers’ bidding. Populism will eventually fade away. This is an appealing story, but is it right? Should
we base policy on it?
There is no shortage of empirical papers that have answered yes, purporting to show that, at least in North America
and Western Europe, the forces behind populism are mostly economic. In their influential paper on ‘China shock’,
Autor, Dorn, and Hanson contend that local US labor markets with a bigger trade exposure to China suffered large job
losses, decreases in labor market participation and persistent unemployment [8].
Autor, Dorn, Hanson, and Majlesi found evidence that congressional districts with larger increases in import penetra-
tion became more politically polarized [9].3 In a companion paper, the same authors [10] related the change in the
county-level Republican vote share to the growth in local labor markets’ exposure to the China shock. They found rising
import competition made Republican vote share gains more likely.
Using a similar methodology, but applied to Western European data, Colantone and Starnig argued that voters in
regions with higher exposure to China shock were more likely to vote for a far-right candidate [37]. In the UK, argued
the same authors in a later piece, more local trade exposure meant an increase in support for Leave [38]. There is also
some evidence that increases in unemployment help explain rising votes for populist parties across Europe [11].
But that is not the end of the story. There is also an abundant supply of papers that single out culture and values,
not economics, as the key explanatory variables for populism. In the aftermath of the 2016 US presidential election,
American statistics guru Nate Silver noted that Hilary Clinton improved on Obama’s 2012 performance in the over-
whelming majority of the best educated counties, but lost ground in the least educated counties. Diana Mutz similarly
concluded that ‘Status threat, not economic hardship, explains the 2016 presidential vote’ [12]. The title of another
influential paper [13] points in the same direction: ‘Vote Switching in the 2016 Election: How Racial and Immigration
Attitudes, Not Economics, Explain Shifts in White Voting.’
In the UK, research by Becker, Fetzer and Novy, examining 382 local authorities, concluded that while education and
demography are good predictors of who voted to leave the European Union, exposure to trade and the extent of budget
cuts are not [14]. And evidence in favor of the ‘cultural backlash’ thesis is not limited to the US and the UK, argue Norris
and Inglehart, who studied the performance of populist parties in 31 European countries [15]. They conclude: ‘Overall,
we find the most consistent evidence supporting the cultural backlash thesis.’
It is unlikely that the debate between the ‘cultural backlash’ and the ‘economic insecurity’ hypotheses will ever be fully
adjudicated, and not just because of standard econometric difficulties related to identification. Disentangling direct
and indirect effects is particularly challenging. It could well be, for instance, that economic shocks lead to changes in
cultural values, which in turn increase support for populist parties. Conversely, changes in social or cultural norms—
increased tolerance of labor market discrimination against immigrants or ethnic minorities is an example—could have
economic consequences, which in turn could affect political outcomes.
Moreover, participants in this debate are not always very precise about what these competing hypotheses are sup-
posed to explain. As Margalit has compellingly argued, the debate often confuses outcome and explanatory significance
[16]. It could be that economic shocks shifted 4% of the UK vote toward Brexit. That is outcome significance, in that
it focuses on the determinants of those few marginal votes that triggered the outcome. But is that what we need to
explain? Perhaps not. Margalit is adamant about this: ‘The overall phenomenon to be explained is why 52% of the elec-
torate voted to leave the European Union.’
So far the bulk of the formal evidence concerns the possible sources of populism in the prosperous countries of North
America and Western Europe. Formal empirical research into the causes of populism in emerging nations is much
scarcer. But the informal evidence available suggests a story that is rather different from that often told about the rich
nations.
In the rich-country narrative, economic stagnation and the frustrations of the ‘left-behind’ take centre stage. In
the emerging world, by contrast, right-wing populism is thriving in countries with strong economic performances—
which is just the opposite of what the ‘economic insecurity’ hypothesis would predict. India, the Philippines and
Turkey have grown at rates between 6.5 and 7% since 2010. Poland barely suffered the effects of the European
financial crisis and has been Europe’s growth champion, with an average per capita growth rate of more than 4%
since 1992. The story in Hungary is similar: per capita income has been converging quickly with Western European
levels. Or consider the neighboring Czech Republic, where unemployment is the lowest in the EU and the economy
grew 3.5% in the five-year period ending in 2019. The country has few immigrants and no refugee crisis to speak
of. Nonetheless, populist parties attracted four of every ten voters in the most recent election—a tenfold increase in
two decades.
3 Trade-exposed districts with an initial majority white population or initially in Republican hands became more likely to elect a right-wing
Republican, while trade-exposed districts with an initial majority non-white population or initially in Democratic hands become more likely to
elect a left-leaning Democrat.
Velasco: Populism and Identity PoliticsArt. 1, page 4 of 8
So in these countries populism seems to have been the offspring of economic gain, not pain! India, Turkey, Poland or
Hungary are winners from globalization, yet they are going populist too!
There is one last prickly fact to consider: if surging populism reflected a demand for redistribution, we would expect
the surge to be on the left, not the right. The left has seen some success, with left-wing populist parties governing today
in Argentina and Mexico, while Podemos has joined the cabinet in Spain. But in much of the world the story of left-
wing populists is one of electoral failure, not success—including Jeremy Corbyn’s flop in the recent British elections.
The spectacular success is that of right-wing populists, who often promise and enact policies that are likely to worsen
the distribution of income, yet middle class and working class voter cheer them on.
Dani Rodrik has proposed an explanation to this conundrum [17]. He suggests that political consequences depend
on ‘the forms in which globalization shocks make themselves felt in society’. So in Latin America, where globalization
has involved massive capital flow volatility and frequent financial and debt crises, the populist backlash has been on the
left. In North America and Europe, by contrast, where trade and migration have provided the central cleavage, populism
is of the right-wing variety.
The hypotheses is intriguing, but it raises as many questions as it answers. Given the depth of the 2007–2009 finan-
cial crisis in North America and Europe, why did it not generate Latin American–style left-wing populism?4 Why have
countries like the Philippines and Turkey, which look positively Latin American in their macro and financial instability,
become poster children for right-wing populism? There is also the fact that Brazil, a country long affected by financial
instability, is now governed by a right-wing populist. His economic agenda involves cutting back pension benefits, pri-
vatizing state-owned enterprises and making Brazil more economically globalized.
None of this means to deny the intensity of economic grievances, whether in the north of England, the American rust
belt, the shanties of Manila or the favelas of Brazil. The point is different: economics matters, of course, but politics and
culture dictate how people process the experience of economic success and failure. The main conceptual shortcom-
ing of the economic insecurity hypothesis is that it assumes a simple (and monotonic) mapping between economic
outcomes and political behavior. Such a mapping does not exist. Pre-existing social and value structures can cause eco-
nomic ups and downs to have very different political consequences—for instance, if an adverse economic shock causes
a rise in unemployment, which prompts a turn toward populism in a divided society, but not in a cohesive one. A key
role of politics is to manage grievances, economic and otherwise. The turn toward populism and authoritarianism sug-
gests a failure of democratic politics to handle those grievances effectively. There is a one-word reason for that: identity.
5. The Identity Roots of Populism
Katherine Cramer is a political scientist who visited dozens of small towns in Wisconsin and spoke with hundreds of
people in an effort to understand why the state was so politically polarized. She wanted to know why voters in tradition-
ally left-leaning Wisconsin were supporting Scott Walker, a Republican governor with populistic tendencies. What she
found surprised her:
Perhaps issues are secondary to identities; perhaps when people vote for a candidate their overarching calcula-
tion is not how closely this person’s stances match my own, but instead, is this person like me? Does this person
understand people like me? The answers to those questions include a consideration of issue stances, but issue
stances are not necessarily the main ingredient.
Scott Walker had built political capital by picking a fight with the state’s public sector unions. Cramer found that most
rural residents supported Walker not because of concerns over the budget deficit or the quality of public services, but
because they viewed public sector workers as urbanites, who could not possibly have the interests of rural residents
in mind. A man milking cows blurted out: ‘I’m glad Walker did what he did. It is about time someone takes something
away from those bastards’. The bastards in question were public employees. After many conversations like that one,
Cramer decided to call her book ‘The Politics of Resentment’ [39].
Wisconsin is not alone in the central role identity plays in politics. Look around the world today and you see identity
politics everywhere. What Brexiteers, Catalan separatists, Russian nationalists and Islamic fundamentalists all have in
common is that their politics are all about identity. India’s Modi and Israel’s Netanyahu have both found political profit
in pitting one local identity against another. And what is the massive backlash against immigration if not the assertion
of one identity over another? The more globalized the economy becomes, the more politics around the world is driven
by the very local identities.
Of course many political parties in the West have long understood—and practised—identity politics. To be electorally
successful, parties have differentiate their ‘product’ from that of their competitors. And in the past two or three decades,
that differentiation has come not so much from economics but from other issues that are natural markers for identity: in
the United States, Democrats became the party of racial equality, abortion rights, gay marriage, and liberal immigration
policies, while Republicans the party of nationalistic pride, right-to-life, traditional values and tight immigration controls.
4 Bernie Sanders and Jeremy Corbyn are Latin American-style left wing populists, but so far they have remained far from power in their
respective countries.
Velasco: Populism and Identity Politics Art. 1, page 5 of 8
The reason why identity matters for politics is that identities are shared. In a recent book, Francis Fukuyama argues
that ‘individuals often want not recognition of their individuality, but recognition of their sameness to other people’
[18]. We also want that identity recognized and respected. Fukuyama reminds us that philosophers from Aristotle to
Hegel placed the desire to be treated with respect at the centre of human motivation: ‘identity politics is everywhere a
struggle for the recognition of dignity’.
Populism has a great deal to do with this. To the definitions given above one can add: populism is a style of politics
that manipulates and exacerbates identity cleavages for political gain. For the late Venezuelan autocrat Hugo Chávez,
anyone who opposed him was an enemy of the people and an agent of the corrupt elite. Change corrupt elite for men-
acing foreigners, and that is also the rhetoric of Donald Trump. So populism is a kind of identity politics. It is always us
against them.
Identity concerns also explain the anti-elitist element in populism. Elites have also been arrogant, often dismissive of
the national identities that much of the electorate holds dear. Hillary Clinton’s description of Trump voters as a bunch
of ‘deplorables’ did not help her campaign. In Latin America, left wing intellectuals routinely depict middle class voters
who lean right as consumerist social climbers who have sacrificed class solidarity in the altar of money-grubbing indi-
vidualism. Recall Fukuyama’s definition of identity politics as a demand for dignity. Well, elites have not treated some
citizens with respect and dignity.
Identity politics is not an easy subject for economists. Until recently, economic theory did not make room for iden-
tity. Humans were supposed to have preferences but liking this and disliking that did not amount to a coherent whole
that we could call an identity. Akerlof and Cranton set out to change this [19–23]. They argued that, in a wide range of
contexts, preferences are structured by individuals’ choices of a social identity, and studied the economic implications
of those preferences.
The identity approach helps us understand why people are willing to pay steep costs, pecuniary or otherwise, to
buttress their identities. For instance, in American high schools [20], students who identify as nerds will study hard,
while students who identify as jocks or burnouts will fail to study and underperform, even if that is costly, because such
behavior helps reinforce their identities and their self-esteem.
Acemoglu, Egorov and Sonin [24] and Di Tella and Rotemberg [25] argue that populist politicians adopt extreme and
ultimately unsustainable policies as a way of signaling to voters that they (the politicians) are not in the pocket of pow-
erful elites. So self-defeating economic behavior is quite understandable once identity is accounted for. And populism
certainly involves plenty of self-defeating economic policy choices.
Identity also creates feedback loops between individuals’ beliefs and actions. For instance, as the share of people
that identifies with a certain group goes up, so does the social pressure to identify with that same group and follow its
codes of conduct. Alternatively, as in Gennaioli and Tabellini [26], identifying with a group can cause people to slant
their beliefs toward the group’s prevailing opinion. Or as in Shayo [27], people may choose the group they identify with
and, once there, choose their actions in order to minimize the distance between their own attributes and the group’s
average attributes.
In this context of strong complementarities, small economic or cultural shocks can cause sizeable changes in patterns
of identification and hence in political preferences. This helps explain, for instance, sudden and sharp shifts in support
away from traditional political parties and toward populist movements. Besley and Persson [28] study these issues in
the context of a fully dynamic model, in which there is two-way feedback between identities and policies. When they
allow for endogenous institutional changes, like the entry of new populist or nationalist parties, outcomes exhibit
path dependence, with temporary shocks having persistent effects on the share of support for populist or nationalist
politicians.5
6. Can Liberal Democrats Practice Identity Politics?
If identity is key to populism, and populism is central to contemporary politics, what can democratic politicians do in
response.
To begin with, they can focus on some important issues they have long neglected. Take, for example, the plight of
cities where de-industrialization has destroyed jobs. Previously, the standard advice to residents of Akron, Ohio, or Gary,
Indiana, was to move to California, where high-paying jobs are plentiful. Today, we understand that can be unsound
advice, and not only for the obvious economic reason that the most educated and enterprising move away, leaving
behind communities that struggle to sustain businesses and make ends meet.6 The combination of job losses and
outward migration also weakens the local community, challenges shared identities, and causes the kind of malaise on
which populists and demagogues feed. That is why place-based policies must be an essential component of the toolkit
of a democratic policymaker.7
5 Path dependence also means that even if economic outcomes were to get better in countries governed by populists, this need not mean that the
populists’ share of the vote, nor their political influence, will wane.
6 The main point of Autor et al (2013) is that, while the effect of trade exposure to China may be mild on average, it is anything but mild on certain
cities and communities.
7 In different ways and appealing to different arguments, Austin et al. [29] and Rajan [30] arrive at this conclusion.
Velasco: Populism and Identity PoliticsArt. 1, page 6 of 8
Identities also matter for the way policies are perceived. Take Emmanuel Macron’s flop over gas levies in 2018. He
did what any reasonable policymaker would have done: concerned with both global warming and local pollution, he
proposed taxing diesel more. Before he knew it, the country was up in arms. That was the beginning of the movement
of the gilets jaunes, who complained that the president and his friends live in Paris and ride the subsidized metro, while
they live in the countryside, drive trucks and pay the taxes that finance Parisians’ privileges. They felt that Macron
simply did not understand them and their way of life. Warnings from the Elysée Palace about planetary responsibility
exacerbated the feeling of disconnect. A leader of the gilets jaunes griped that the president was fretting about the end
of the world while they worried about getting to the end of the month.
Convincing middle-class French voters that higher fuel prices were actually good for them was always sure to be an
uphill battle. But Macron’s background and style made it even tougher. Maybe it was the inevitable consequence of the
president’s background as an investment banker, his imperial style, or of the abolition of the wealth tax as the initial
priority of his administration. Macron could have promised to return the fuel tax revenue to middle class families and
businesses, but he did not. What might have been a narrow taxation row became an unwinnable clash of identities. In
the end Macron had to back down. It was his biggest loss.
What else can liberal democrats do? They can also abandon the vain hope that simply by tweaking economic policies
populism will go away. Better and bolder policies to improve income distribution and enhance social mobility are the
beginning of the road, not the end of the road. Populism is a political problem; it requires political solutions.
That is why the way forward cannot be merely technocratic. The title of a recent article by Sheri Berman [31] is spot
on: ‘Populism Is a Problem. Elitist Technocrats Aren’t the Solution.’ Populist politicians are capitalizing on the public’s
dislike and distrust of technocrats. In the midst of the Brexit debate, minister Michael Gove exclaimed ‘people in this
country have had enough of experts’. Donald Trump has said worse. Having experts and technocrats lead the counter-
charge against populism is exactly what populists hope for.
Katherine Cramer discovered in Wisconsin that voters look for a candidate who inspires trust, one who would
make the choices they would have made if only they had had the time, knowledge and inclination to study and
understand the issues. They hope for a candidate who is ‘like them’ when it comes to values and preferences.
Macron comes up short here. So do most other liberal politicians. Liberal democracy has a personnel problem.
Democratic parties need a revamped Human Resources Department with a new mandate: hire better and diversify
your recruitment sources.
But a better HR policy alone will not do the trick. Something else must change: democrats must learn to practice
identity politics—but identity politics of the right kind. Human beings cannot and will not do without narrow identi-
ties, which are the most firmly rooted. But there also exist broadly shared identities, which can serve as the basis for
the sense of shared destiny that is at the core of good politics.8 As Michael Ignatieff [32] has observed, ‘national identity
is a continual contest about who belongs to the national we’. Democrats must provide an expansive definition of that
national we.
According to Paul Collier [33], the United Kingdom built that shared identity in the battlefields of the world wars,
an immense common endeavor in which leaders had crafted narratives of belonging and mutual obligation’. The leg-
acy was to turn the nation ‘into a gigantic community, a society with a strong sense of shared identity, obligation and
reciprocity’. But, laments Collier, in recent decades much of that was lost. Highly educated professionals in London
came to feel they had more in common with their peers in Amsterdam or Paris than with working-class Britons in
Sheffield (Collier’s home town), who in turn sought refuge in anti-EU English nationalism.
In the United States the process has been similar, but perhaps even more radical, with prosperous residents of the
coasts looking down on the rest as mere ‘flyover country’, while rural dwellers and Southerners fall prey to a nativism
based on ‘blood and soil’—which is what white supremacists (the very same ones who Trump described as ‘very fine
people’) chanted as they marched down the streets of Charlottesville, Virginia.
The only alternative to this chasm is a shared identity, a love of country based not on a misplaced sense of racial supe-
riority, but on the fact that our homeland stands for noble universal values. Emmanuel Macron calls himself a proud
French patriot because France gave the world liberté, égalité, and fraternité. Justin Trudeau likes to say that inclusive
diversity is what Canada and the Canadian spirit are all about. These are examples of what the philosopher Jürgen
Habermas has called constitutional patriotism. Yes, patriotism. Liberals need not be frightened by the word.
As early as 1945, George Orwell explained the difference between nationalism and patriotism: ‘By Nationalism… I
mean the habit of identifying oneself with a single nation or other unit, placing it beyond good and evil and recogniz-
ing no other duty than that of advancing its interests…. By “patriotism,” I mean a devotion to a particular place and a
particular way of life, which one believes to be the best in the world but has no wish to force on other people’ [36].
Nationalism is toxic; patriotism is not. And the best kind of patriotism is one based on age-old values such as liberty,
dignity, and mutual respect. Why not call it liberal patriotism?
Now the key is to root these abstract concepts in everyday experience. If leaders talk about inclusion but the eve-
ryday experience of citizens is one of discrimination, then the rhetoric will be of no consequence. American political
8 In the model of Grossman and Helpman [35], voters can choose a narrow identity or a broader national identity. When the latter is eroded,
political pressures for protection from imports go up.
Velasco: Populism and Identity Politics Art. 1, page 7 of 8
philosopher Martha Nussbaum, in a book entitled Political Emotions [34], has argued that the key is to elicit positive
emotions toward democratic institutions, and to do this through very concrete actions, words and rituals.
Think of Lincoln and Gandhi, suggests Nussbaum. The words they uttered, the clothes they wore and the rituals they
designed fostered a broad and inclusive sense of republican we. Or think of Mandela: he donned the green jersey of the
white rugby team for precisely that reason. It the best example imaginable of liberal patriotism—and of democratic and
healthy identity politics.
7. The Way Forward
The standard account of the rise of populism—call it the economic insecurity hypothesis—is an inadequate description
of reality. It does not fit the facts in emerging nations such as Poland or Turkey. It has little relevance in Israel and India,
where right-wing populism has clear ethnic and religious overtones. And it cannot explain the full story in the US and
the UK or other advanced democracies, where support for nationalist and extremist forces goes well beyond people ‘left
behind’ by globalization.
The conventional wisdom also fundamentally misunderstands the nature of populism. Only once we understand the
identity basis of populist politics can we single out the policies—place-based policies are only one example—that can be
effective in fighting populism. A focus on identity also reveals that liberal democracy needs not only a better message
but also better messengers, with whom voters can plausibly identify. Liberal democrats must not spurn identity politics;
instead, they need to reinvent it, helping build strong national identities based on shared liberal values like dignity and
respect. Put it this way: Joe Biden’s only chance against Donald Trump is to beat him at his own game.
Competing Interests
The author is a member of the commissioning board of the LSEPPR.
Author Information
I am indebted to George Akerlof, Tim Besley, Erik Berglöf, Julia Black, Daniel Brieba, Chris Canavan, Francesco Caselli,
Roberto Chang, Jason Furman, Robert Funk, Luis Garicano, Sara Hagemann, Sara Hobolt, Ricardo Hausmann, Simon
Hix, Sebastián Hurtado, Michael Ignatieff, José Gabriel Krauss, Yascha Mounk, Pipa Norris, Esteban Ovalle, Toni Roldán,
Minouche Shafik, Paul Sullivan, Nick Stern and Tony Travers for comments and/or conversations on the topics of this
essay. Parts of it are based on my inaugural lecture as Dean of the LSE School of Public Policy, entitled “Policymaking at
a Time of Populism”. Errors are all my own.
References
1. Linz J, Stepan A. Problems of Democratic Transition and Consolidation. Southern Europe, South America, and Post-
Communist Europe. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press; 1996.
2. Levitsky S, Ziblatt D. How Democracies Die. New York: Crown Books; 2018.
3. Dornbusch R, Edwards S. The Macroeconomics of Populism in Latin America. In: Dornbusch R, Edwards S (eds.),
The Macroeconomics of Populism in Latin America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 1991. DOI: https://doi.
org/10.7208/chicago/9780226158488.001.0001
4. Müller J. What Is Populism? Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania; 2016. DOI: https://doi.org/10.9783/
9780812293784
5. Mudde C, Rovira C. Populism: A Very Short Introduction. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2017. DOI: https://doi.
org/10.1093/actrade/9780190234874.001.0001
6. Dahrendorf R. A History of the London School of Economics and Political Science 1895–1995. Oxford: Oxford
University Press; 1995. DOI: https://doi.org/10.2307/40203191
7. Mounk Y. The Inverted Likability Test. The Atlantic. (2 January 2020).
8. Autor D, Dorn D, Hanson G. The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the
United States. American Economic Review. October 2013. DOI: https://doi.org/10.3386/w18054
9. Autor D, Dorn D, Hanson G, Majlesi K. A Note on the Effect of Rising Trade Exposure on the 2016 Presidential
Election. Working Paper, MIT, January 2017a.
10. Autor D, Dorn D, Hanson G, Majlesi K. Importing Political Polarization? The Electoral Consequences of Rising
Trade Exposure. Working Paper, MIT, December 2017b. DOI: https://doi.org/10.3386/w22637
11. Algan Y, Guriev S, Papaioannou E, Passari E. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. Fall 2017. DOI: https://doi.
org/10.1353/eca.2017.0015
12. Mutz DC. Status threat, not economic hardship, explains the 2016 presidential vote. Proceedings of the National
Academy of Sciences. 8 May 2018; 11(19). DOI: https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1718155115
13. Reny T, Collingwood L, Valenzuela A. Vote Switching in the 2016 Election: How Racial and Immigration
Attitudes, Not Economics, Explain Shifts in White Voting. Public Opinion Quarterly. Spring 2019; 83(1). DOI:
https://doi.org/10.1093/poq/nfz011
14. Becker S, Fetzer T, Novy D. Who voted for Brexit? A comprehensive district-level analysis. Economic Policy.
Oct. 2017; 32(92). DOI: https://doi.org/10.1093/epolic/eix012
Velasco: Populism and Identity PoliticsArt. 1, page 8 of 8
15. Inglehart R, Norris P. Trump, Brexit, and the Rise of Populism: Economic Have-Nots and Cultural Backlash.
Faculty Research Working Paper Series, RWP16-026, Harvard Kennedy School, August 2016. DOI: https://doi.
org/10.2139/ssrn.2818659
16. Margalit Y. Economic Insecurity and the Causes of Populism, Reconsidered. Journal of Economic Perspectives.
Fall 2019; 33(4). DOI: https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.33.4.152
17. Rodrik D. Populism and the Economics of Globalization. Journal of International Business Policy. 2018. DOI:
https://doi.org/10.3386/w23559
18. Fukuyama F. Identity: The Demand for Dignity and the Politics of Resentment. New York: Farrar Straus and Giroux;
2018.
19. Akerlof G, Kranton R. Economics and Identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2000; 115. DOI: https://doi.
org/10.1162/003355300554881
20. Akerlof G, Kranton R. Identity and Schooling: Some Lessons for the Economics of Education. Journal of
Economic Literature. 2002; 40. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1257/.40.4.1167
21. Akerlof G, Kranton R. A Model of Poverty and Oppositional Culture. In: Basu K, Nayak PB, Ray R (eds.),
Markets and Governments. Oxford and New Delhi: Oxford University Press; 2003.
22. Akerlof G, Kranton R. Identity and the Economics of Organizations. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 2005;
9. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1257/0895330053147930
23. Akerlof G, Kranton R. Identity Economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2010. DOI: https://doi.
org/10.1515/9781400834181
24. Acemoglu D, Egorov G, Sonin K. A Political Theory of Populism. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2012; 127.
DOI: https://doi.org/10.3386/w17306
25. Di Tella R, Rotemberg J. Populism and the Return of the Paranoid Style: Some Evidence and a Simple Model of
Demand for Incompetence as Insurance Against Elite Betrayal. NBER Working Paper 22975, December 2016. DOI:
https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2887389
26. Gennaioli N, Tabellini G. Identity, Beliefs, and Political Conflict. Working paper, Università Bocconi, December
2018. DOI: https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3300726
27. Shayo M. Social Identity and Economic Policy. Working Paper, Hebrew University of Jerusalem, September 2019.
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-082019-110313
28. Besley T, Persson T. The Rise of Identity Politics: Salience, Polarization and Competition. Working paper,
LSE, 2019.
29. Austin B, Glaeser E, Summers LH. Saving the heartland: Place-based policies in 21st century America.
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. Spring 2018. DOI: https://doi.org/10.3386/w24548
30. Rajan R. The Third Pillar: How Markets and the State Leave the Community Behind. New York: Penguin Press; 2019.
31. Berman S. Populism Is a Problem. Elitist Technocrats Aren’t the Solution. Foreign Policy. December 2017.
32. Ignatieff M. Is identity politics ruining democracy? Financial Times. 5 September 2018.
33. Collier P. The Future of Capitalism: Facing the New Anxieties. London: Harper Collins; 2018.
34. Nussbaum M. Political Emotions: Why Love Matters for Justice. Cambridge: The Belknap Press of Harvard University
Press; 2013.
35. Grossman G, Helpman E. Identity Politics and Trade Policy. Working paper, Harvard University, October 2018.
DOI: https://doi.org/10.3386/w25348
36. Orwell G. Notes on Nationalism. Polemic: A Magazine of Philosophy, Psychology, and Aesthetics. London, October
1945.
37. Colantone I, Stanig P. Global Competition and Brexit. American Political Science Review. May 2018; 112(2), 201–
218. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055417000685
38. Colantone I, Stanig P. The Trade Origins of Economic Nationalism: Import Competition and Voting Behavior
in Western Europe. American Journal of Political Science. October 2018; 62(4), 936–953. DOI: https://doi.
org/10.1111/ajps.12358
39. Cramer K. The Politics of Resentment: Rural Consciousness in Wisconsin and the Rise of Scott Walker. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press; 2016. DOI: https://doi.org/10.7208/chicago/9780226349251.001.0001
How to cite this article: Velasco A. Populism and Identity Politics.
LSE Public Policy Review
. 2020; 1(1): 1, pp. 1–8. DOI: https://
doi.org/10.31389/lseppr.1
Submitted: 15 June 2020 Accepted: 15 June 2020 Published: 20 July 2020
Copyright: © 2020 The Author(s). This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution
4.0 International License (CC-BY 4.0), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the
original author and source are credited. See http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.
LSE Public Policy Review
is a peer-reviewed open access journal published by LSE Press. OPEN ACCESS
... Despite a surge of research on populism, there is not much exploration of its relationship with political identities . Only a few recent works have explored the correlation between populist politics and identity politics, in the context of the rise of right-wing populism in Europe and elsewhere (Marchlewska, et al., 2018;Nourey & Roland, 2020;Velasco, 2020). Similarly, studies on populist voting have provided evidence of how race, ethnicity, and gender of the voter can influence their decision of voting for a populist party but these racial, ethnic, and gender identities are often discussed from economic perspective, presenting these groups as have-nots of the neo-liberal democratic societies (Bovens & Wille, 2010;Spierings & Zaslove, 2017). ...
... Trump menggunakan Twitter untuk memobilisasi pendukungnya, mengkritik media mainstream, dan memperkuat narasi bahwa dirinya adalah satu-satunya pelindung "rakyat sejati" dari ancaman imigran dan Muslim. Penggunaan media sosial sebagai alat propaganda populis memungkinkan Trump membangun hubungan langsung dengan basis pendukungnya tanpa harus bergantung pada media tradisional yang sering dianggapnya sebagai bagian dari "elite korup" (Velasco, 2020). ...
Article
Full-text available
Penelitian ini mengkaji kebijakan "Muslim Ban" yang diterapkan di Amerika Serikat, Australia, India, dan Denmark dalam konteks persepsi negatif terhadap Islam pasca peristiwa 9/11. Dengan menggunakan metode komparatif dan analisis regresi linear berganda, penelitian ini meneliti faktor-faktor yang mempengaruhi kebijakan tersebut, seperti persepsi masyarakat terhadap Islam sebagai ancaman, trauma nasional, arus imigrasi internasional, dan pengaruh kebijakan AS. Hasil analisis menunjukkan bahwa di Amerika Serikat, semua variabel berpengaruh signifikan terhadap kebijakan Muslim Ban, dengan Klaim Pemimpin Mewakili Rakyat sebagai faktor paling berpengaruh. Sementara itu, di Australia, hanya Penggunaan Isu Populis yang mendekati signifikansi, dan di India serta Denmark, tidak ada variabel independen yang menunjukkan pengaruh signifikan. Temuan ini mencerminkan kompleksitas dan perbedaan dalam penerapan kebijakan di negara-negara tersebut, serta implikasinya terhadap kualitas demokrasi dan perlakuan terhadap komunitas Muslim. Penelitian ini diharapkan dapat memberikan wawasan yang lebih mendalam tentang kebijakan diskriminatif dan tantangan dalam menjaga nilai-nilai demokrasi di tengah masyarakat multikultural.
... So, while failing policies may indeed have contributed to different social and economic problems, especially for some groups, it is hard to see that this is the major explanation. In general, there seems to be a strong bias in large parts of the populist literature to take the economic and social developments in the US, and perhaps the UK, where median wages have stagnated and income distribution worsened over the last three decades, as a being representative to all countries (Velasco, 2020). Margalit (2019), after surveying the relevant literature, concludes that the overall explanatory evidence of the kind of economic arguments presented above for the support of populism is modest: at the most, they can explain the outcome on the margin. ...
Chapter
Full-text available
In this chapter the most popular explanations that have been proposed for why and how populists succeed are discussed and synthesized into “a populist model of autocratization”. Explanations dealing with (1) globalization, immigration, and policy failures; (2) culture and identity; (3) psychology and human nature; (4) social media and echo chambers; and (5) charismatic leaders and policy entrepreneurs, are included in the analysis. My conclusion is that the populist ideas, beliefs, and values, related to identity and shaped by the populist rhetorical style and discourse frames, play the central role.
... He and others have argued that place-based territorial investments are needed to reverse trends of decline in territories [3][4][5]. Others stress the importance of fostering a shared national identity based on liberal democratic values [6]. While the root causes of populism and discontent differ across countries and regions, economic inequality and a lack of government responsiveness to citizens' needs, values and identity appear to be central factors [7]. ...
Article
Full-text available
The twin concepts of territorial cohesion and competitiveness have underpinned European integration and are fundamental to the development of robust democracies. They speak to the importance of reducing territorial inequalities and ensuring that all places deliver good livelihoods and well-being. Governments can strengthen subnational capacities to help deliver on these objectives through administrative, fiscal and political decentralisation and regional development. Driven by a strong, community-oriented social foundation, Ukraine has pursued this path. Since 2014, it has embarked on ambitious decentralisation, anti-corruption and regional development reforms, and progress has been made in a number of areas, such as service delivery, municipal finance and decision-making. Russia’s full-scale invasion that began in February 2022 has disrupted the reforms and led to massive destruction, especially in Ukraine’s eastern regions. Here I argue that the continuation of these reforms is critical for democracy, reconstruction, recovery and eventual European integration and that the future of the global order rests not just upon the success of countries but also on their constituent regions and communities. The international community has a central role to play in supporting such a place-based approach to territorial development.
Article
This article examines the evolution of discourse on social inequality through the concept of ‘guiding distinctions’, a theoretical term introduced by Niklas Luhmann. The study develops criteria for ‘guiding distinctions’, making the concept usable as an analytical tool. Using this framework, the article traces a historical shift from the Marxist focus on economic inequality, rooted in the capital/labor dichotomy, to the contemporary emphasis on identity politics, which is characterized by the novel guiding distinction between privilege and discrimination. The study illuminates how current identity politics redefine social inequality as a multifaceted phenomenon involving various forms of discrimination, beyond just economic issues. Applying the ‘guiding distinction’ framework reveals two key developments: an increasing complexity in the understanding of social inequality and a shift in efforts to address it, moving from class struggle to approaches centered on enlightenment and education. The article argues that recognizing these shifts is crucial for a nuanced analysis of identity politics and its implications for societal understanding of social inequality. The findings contribute to ongoing debates in sociology about the role of identity politics in shaping contemporary social movements and the study of social inequality.
Article
Full-text available
Abstrakt Przedmiotem artykułu jest z jednej strony rekonstrukcja powstania oraz dynamiki współczesnych konfliktów tożsamościowych, których aktualnym odzwierciedleniem jest nie tylko tożsamościowa forma autorytarnego populizmu, ale również merytokratyczno-indywidualistyczne tożsamościowe polityki różnicowania i dystynkcji. Z drugiej strony chodzi o pokazanie, w jaki sposób rozlokowane w szerokim spektrum ideologicznym procesy tożsamościowe przyj-mują polityczną formę wiktymizacji i ostatecznie doprowadzają do niereduko-walnych wojen kulturowych, których ekstensywność oraz intensywność wydaje się być wzmacniana przez aktualny kryzys hegemonii, związany z wyczerpywa-niem się uniwersalizującej mocy neoliberalizmu. W tak zarysowanym kontekście lokuje się podstawowa teza artykułu mówiąca, że wobec egzystencjalnego zagrożenia jakim jest kryzys klimatyczny, edukacja może spełnić istotną funkcję ustanawiania nowego uniwersalizmu, przez z jednej strony, zawieszenie koncentracji na tym co tożsamościowe i z drugiej, skierowanie uwagi na zadanie generowania nowego uniwersum symbolicznego, wobec którego aktualne konflikty tożsamościowe mogłyby zostać unieważnione. Słowa kluczowe tożsamość, polityka tożsamości, uniwersalizm, wiktymizacja, schyłek neoliberalizmu, kryzys hegemonii, kryzys klimatyczny 1 Uniwersytet Gdański, Instytut Pedagogiki, karolina.starego@ug.edu.pl, https://orcid.org/0000-0001-9232-7067 iD
Chapter
This chapter introduces the conceptual and theoretical framework for examining identity construction in Pakistan, a post-colonial Muslim-majority state. It challenges the notion of fixed identities and instead explores their fluid and multifaceted nature. By shifting focus from elite-driven analyses to public-level identity processes, it reveals how individuals navigate and articulate their identities. A key contribution of this chapter is to explain the book’s exploration of the intersection between populist discourse and identity. The chapter explains how populist rhetoric pervades public discourse in Pakistan. It identifies three concurrent meanings of “Pakistaniat” in public narratives: as marginalized underdogs, as a morally superior Muslim nation, and as sovereign democrats. These meanings reflect the populist structuring of identities through antagonistic relationships with “the non-people.”
Chapter
There has been a growing political reaction for several years against almost everything that can be associated with globalization, namely the loss of jobs, their increasingly precarious nature, the increase in inequality, rising legal and illegal migration, the erosion of democracy and cultural foreignization. This is associated in popular (and academic) perception with an increase in social polarization, the thinning of the middle class and a growing distance between citizens and their (elitist) representatives, accompanied by a loss of trust in political institutions.
Article
Full-text available
In the aftermath of Donald Trump's 2016 electoral-college victory, journalists focused heavily on the White working class (WWC) and the relationship between economic anxiety, racial attitudes, immigration attitudes, and support for Trump. One hypothesized but untested proposition for Donald Trump's success is that his unorthodox candidacy , particularly his rhetoric surrounding economic marginalization and immigration, shifted WWC voters who did not vote Republican in 2012 into his coalition. Using a large national survey, we examine: (1) whether racial and immigration attitudes or economic dislocation and marginality were the main correlates of vote switching; and (2) whether this phenomenon was isolated among the White working class. Findings indicate that a nontrivial number of White voters switched their votes in the 2016 election to Trump or Clinton, that this vote switching was more associated with racial and immigration attitudes than economic factors, and that the phenomenon occurred among both working-class and nonworking-class Whites, though many more working-class Whites switched than did nonworking-class Whites. Our findings suggest that racial and immigration attitudes may be continuing to sort White voters into new partisan camps and further polarize the parties.
Article
Full-text available
Significance Support for Donald J. Trump in the 2016 election was widely attributed to citizens who were “left behind” economically. These claims were based on the strong cross-sectional relationship between Trump support and lacking a college education. Using a representative panel from 2012 to 2016, I find that change in financial wellbeing had little impact on candidate preference. Instead, changing preferences were related to changes in the party’s positions on issues related to American global dominance and the rise of a majority–minority America: issues that threaten white Americans’ sense of dominant group status. Results highlight the importance of looking beyond theories emphasizing changes in issue salience to better understand the meaning of election outcomes when public preferences and candidates’ positions are changing.
Article
I review evidence that individuals associate themselves—or identify—with groups in two fundamental ways: ingroup bias and conformity to group norms. The evidence spans many spheres of economic activity, including consumption, production, hiring, promotion, education, cooperation, financial investments, and law enforcement. Group identities are not fixed, even when it comes to ethnic and religious identities. I argue that the choice of identity can be captured by a simple trade-off between gains from group status and costs to distance from the group. I outline a simple conceptual framework that captures the main empirical regularities and illustrate how it can be used to study the two-way interaction between economic policy and social identity. The analysis implies, e.g., that inequality and immigration of low-skilled workers can strengthen nationalism and reduce redistribution, and that changes in the economic environment can produce shifts in identification patterns that feed into trade policy. Finally, I discuss open theoretical questions and domains where the interaction between identity and economic activity is not well understood. This includes the provision of public services, the evolution of gender norms, and the use of identity to motivate workers. Expected final online publication date for the Annual Review of Economics, Volume 12 is August 3, 2020. Please see http://www.annualreviews.org/page/journal/pubdates for revised estimates.
Article
Growing conventional wisdom holds that a chief driver of the populist vote is economic insecurity. I contend that this view overstates the role of economic insecurity as an explanation in several ways. First, it conflates the significance of economic insecurity in influencing the election outcome on the margin with its significance in explaining the overall populist vote. Empirical findings indicate that the share of populist support explained by economic insecurity is modest. Second, recent evidence indicates that voters’ concern with immigration—a key issue for many populist parties—is only marginally shaped by its real or perceived repercussions on their economic standing. Third, economics-centric accounts of populism treat voters’ cultural concerns as largely a byproduct of experiencing adverse economic change. This approach underplays the reverse process, whereby disaffection from social and cultural change drives both economic discontent and support for populism.
Article
We investigate the impact of globalization on electoral outcomes in 15 Western European countries over 1988–2007. We employ both official election results at the district level and individual‐level voting data, combined with party ideology scores from the Comparative Manifesto Project. We compute a region‐specific measure of exposure to Chinese imports, based on the historical industry specialization of each region. To identify the causal impact of the import shock, we instrument imports to Europe using Chinese imports to the United States. At the district level, a stronger import shock leads to (1) an increase in support for nationalist and isolationist parties, (2) an increase in support for radical‐right parties, and (3) a general shift to the right in the electorate. These results are confirmed by the analysis of individual‐level vote choices. In addition, we find evidence that voters respond to the shock in a sociotropic way.
Article
We study the implications of the Great Recession for voting for antiestablishment parties, as well as for general trust and political attitudes, using regional data across Europe. We find a strong relationship between increases in unemployment and voting for nonmainstream parties, especially populist ones. Moreover, unemployment increases in tandem with declining trust toward national and European political institutions, though we find only weak or no effects of unemployment on interpersonal trust. The correlation between unemployment and attitudes toward immigrants is muted, especially for their cultural impact. To explore causality, we extract the component of increases in unemployment explained by the precrisis structure of the economy, in particular the share of construction in regional value added, which is strongly related both to the buildup preceding and the bursting of the crisis. Our results imply that crisis-driven economic insecurity is a substantial determinant of populism and political distrust.
Article
We show that support for the Leave option in the Brexit referendum was systematically higher in regions hit harder by economic globalization. We focus on the shock of surging imports from China over the past three decades as a structural driver of divergence in economic performance across U.K. regions. An IV approach supports a causal interpretation of our finding. We claim that the effect is driven by the displacement determined by globalization in the absence of effective compensation of its losers. Neither overall stocks nor inflows of immigrants in a region are associated with higher support for the Leave option. A positive association only emerges when focusing on immigrants from EU accession countries. The analysis of individual data suggests that voters respond to the import shock in a sociotropic way, as individuals tend to react to the general economic situation of their region, regardless of their specific condition.
Article
Has rising trade integration between the U.S. and China contributed to the polarization of U.S. politics? Analyzing outcomes from the 2002 and 2010 congressional elections, we detect an ideological realignment that is centered in trade-exposed local labor markets and that commences prior to the divisive 2016 U.S. presidential election. Exploiting the exogenous component of rising trade with China and classifying legislator ideologies by their congressional voting record, we find strong evidence that congressional districts exposed to larger increases in import competition disproportionately removed moderate representatives from office in the 2000s. Trade-exposed districts initially in Republican hands become substantially more likely to elect a conservative Republican, while trade-exposed districts initially in Democratic hands become more likely to elect either a liberal Democrat or a conservative Republican. Polarization is also evident when breaking down districts by race: trade-exposed locations with a majority white population are disproportionately likely to replace moderate legislators with conservative Republicans, whereas locations with a majority non-white population tend to replace moderates with liberal Democrats. We further contrast the electoral impacts of trade exposure with shocks associated with generalized changes in labor demand and with the post-2006 U.S. housing market collapse.